Constrained Maximisation IV- Examples

28
EC115 - Methods of Economic Analysis Spring Term, Lecture 10 Constrained Maximisation IV: Lagrange’s Function - Examples Renshaw - Chapter 16 University of Essex - Department of Economics Week 25 Domenico Tabasso (University of Essex - Department of Economics) Lecture 10 - Spring Term Week 25 1 / 26

description

economics

Transcript of Constrained Maximisation IV- Examples

Page 1: Constrained Maximisation IV- Examples

EC115 - Methods of Economic AnalysisSpring Term, Lecture 10

Constrained Maximisation IV:Lagrange’s Function - Examples

Renshaw - Chapter 16

University of Essex - Department of Economics

Week 25

Domenico Tabasso (University of Essex - Department of Economics)Lecture 10 - Spring Term Week 25 1 / 26

Page 2: Constrained Maximisation IV- Examples

Example 1

Let’s start with a very simple example, just to warm up.A firm has to maximize the output under the total costconstraint TC=100. The maximization problem is given by

maxK ,L

Q(K , L) = 2K + KL

s.t. 100 = 2K + 2L

where the cost of capital and and that of labour are givenby w = r = 2.Find the optimal K ∗ and L∗ using the Lagrangian method.Find also λ∗.

Domenico Tabasso (University of Essex - Department of Economics)Lecture 10 - Spring Term Week 25 2 / 26

Page 3: Constrained Maximisation IV- Examples

First Step: Write down the Lagrangian function

L = Q(K , L)− λ(TC (K , L))

And so in this case:

L = 2K + KL− λ(2K + 2L− 100)

Domenico Tabasso (University of Essex - Department of Economics)Lecture 10 - Spring Term Week 25 3 / 26

Page 4: Constrained Maximisation IV- Examples

First Step: Write down the Lagrangian function

L = Q(K , L)− λ(TC (K , L))

And so in this case:

L = 2K + KL− λ(2K + 2L− 100)

Domenico Tabasso (University of Essex - Department of Economics)Lecture 10 - Spring Term Week 25 3 / 26

Page 5: Constrained Maximisation IV- Examples

Second Step: Write down the First Order Conditions

∂L∂K

= 0 ⇒ 2 + L− 2λ = 0 (1)

∂L∂L

= 0 ⇒ K − 2λ = 0; (2)

∂L∂λ

= 0 ⇒ 100− 2K − 2L = 0 (3)

Domenico Tabasso (University of Essex - Department of Economics)Lecture 10 - Spring Term Week 25 4 / 26

Page 6: Constrained Maximisation IV- Examples

Third Step: Solve the First Order Conditions.From equations (1) and (2) we have

2 + L = 2λ (1)

K = 2λ (2)

The right-hand sides of both equations are identical (= 2λ),so the left-hand must also be equal to each other. Hence

2 + L = K

Domenico Tabasso (University of Essex - Department of Economics)Lecture 10 - Spring Term Week 25 5 / 26

Page 7: Constrained Maximisation IV- Examples

Now our problem only consists in two equations:{2 + L = K2K + 2L = 100

So substituting K = 2 + L form the first equation into thesecond one we get:

4 + 2L + 2L = 100=⇒

L∗ = 24

Domenico Tabasso (University of Essex - Department of Economics)Lecture 10 - Spring Term Week 25 6 / 26

Page 8: Constrained Maximisation IV- Examples

So L∗ = 24 and we know that K = 2 + L: we can obtainK ∗ = 26.

How about λ?Form the second first order condition we have:

2λ = K

⇒ λ =K2

⇒ λ∗ = 13

Domenico Tabasso (University of Essex - Department of Economics)Lecture 10 - Spring Term Week 25 7 / 26

Page 9: Constrained Maximisation IV- Examples

Example 2

Note that sometimes very simple changes can make oursolution very complicated! Consider for example

maxK ,L

Q(K , L) = 2K + 2K12L

s.t. 100 = 2K + 2L

and proceed to the maximization following exactly thesame steps as before.

Domenico Tabasso (University of Essex - Department of Economics)Lecture 10 - Spring Term Week 25 8 / 26

Page 10: Constrained Maximisation IV- Examples

Write down the Lagrangian function

L = 2K + 2K12L− λ(2K + 2L− 100)

and the FOCS:

∂L∂K

= 0 ⇒ 2 + K−12L− 2λ = 0 (1)

∂L∂L

= 0 ⇒ 2K12 − 2λ = 0; (2)

∂L∂λ

= 0 ⇒ 100− 2K − 2L = 0 (3)

Domenico Tabasso (University of Essex - Department of Economics)Lecture 10 - Spring Term Week 25 9 / 26

Page 11: Constrained Maximisation IV- Examples

Solve the First Order Conditions.In this case simply taking the ratio between eq. (1) andeq.(2) is not very helpful since if we do it we end up with:

2 + K−12L

2K12

=2λ2λ

where the left-hand side can not be simplified. Let’s see ifwe can find another way to solve these equations.

Domenico Tabasso (University of Essex - Department of Economics)Lecture 10 - Spring Term Week 25 10 / 26

Page 12: Constrained Maximisation IV- Examples

From equation (1) and (2) we have

2 + K−12L = 2λ (1)

2K12 = 2λ (2)

The right-hand sides of both equations are identical (= 2λ),so the left-hand must also be equal to each other. Hence

2 + K−12L = 2K

12

Domenico Tabasso (University of Essex - Department of Economics)Lecture 10 - Spring Term Week 25 11 / 26

Page 13: Constrained Maximisation IV- Examples

Multiplying everything by K12 we can get:

2K12 + L = 2K

14

from which we can obtain that

L∗ = 2K14 − 2K

12 (4)

Don’t forget we have another equation to play with, thethird first order condition.

−2K − 2L + 100 = 0

Domenico Tabasso (University of Essex - Department of Economics)Lecture 10 - Spring Term Week 25 12 / 26

Page 14: Constrained Maximisation IV- Examples

Solving the constraint for L we get:

L = 50− K

which we can substitute in eq. (4), obtaining:

2K14 − 2K

12 = 50− K

Domenico Tabasso (University of Essex - Department of Economics)Lecture 10 - Spring Term Week 25 13 / 26

Page 15: Constrained Maximisation IV- Examples

OK, now we have one (complicated, sorry /) equation inone unknown. We can try to solve it.

50− K − 2K14 + 2K

12 = 0

K + 2K14 − 2K

12 = 50

Scary!

Domenico Tabasso (University of Essex - Department of Economics)Lecture 10 - Spring Term Week 25 14 / 26

Page 16: Constrained Maximisation IV- Examples

OK, now we have one (complicated, sorry /) equation inone unknown. We can try to solve it.

50− K − 2K14 + 2K

12 = 0

K + 2K14 − 2K

12 = 50

Scary!

Domenico Tabasso (University of Essex - Department of Economics)Lecture 10 - Spring Term Week 25 14 / 26

Page 17: Constrained Maximisation IV- Examples

Example: Cost Minimisation

Suppose the board of directors of a competitive firmhas set a production target of Q0 and asks the chiefexecutive officer (CEO) of the firm to meet the targetat the minimum cost.Suppose the firm’s technology be described by theCobb Douglas function:

Q = F (K , L) = K 1/4L1/2

How do we solve the CEO problem when the prices oflabour and capital are given by w > 0 and r > 0?

We can apply any of our solution techinques to solvethis problem. This time we use the Lagrange multipliermethod.

Domenico Tabasso (University of Essex - Department of Economics)Lecture 10 - Spring Term Week 25 15 / 26

Page 18: Constrained Maximisation IV- Examples

The problem can be expressed as:

minL,K

TC (K , L) = wL + rK s.t. Q0 = K 1/4L1/2

In this case the objective function is given by:

TC = wL + rK .

This describes all the combinations of K and L suchthat at prices w and r they give the same total cost,TC .In this case we say that TC = wL + rK describes aniso-cost line:

K = −wr

L +TCr.

Domenico Tabasso (University of Essex - Department of Economics)Lecture 10 - Spring Term Week 25 16 / 26

Page 19: Constrained Maximisation IV- Examples

The lagrangian function is given by:

L(L,K , λ) = wL + rK + λ(Q0 − K 1/4L1/2)

The first order conditions are:

∂L(K , L, λ)

∂K= r − λ1

4K−3/4L1/2 = 0,

∂L(K , L, λ)

∂L= w − λ1

2K 1/4L−1/2 = 0,

∂L(K , L, λ)

∂λ= Q0 − K 1/4L1/2 = 0,

at K = K ∗, L = L∗ and λ = λ∗.

Domenico Tabasso (University of Essex - Department of Economics)Lecture 10 - Spring Term Week 25 17 / 26

Page 20: Constrained Maximisation IV- Examples

Note that the first two equations generate the tangencycondition:

MRTSL,K =MPL

MPK=

wr

=⇒(12K 1/4L−1/2

)/

(14K−3/4L1/2

)=

wr.

The third equation requires that the targeted outputlevel met:

Q0 = (K ∗)1/4 (L∗)1/2 .

Domenico Tabasso (University of Essex - Department of Economics)Lecture 10 - Spring Term Week 25 18 / 26

Page 21: Constrained Maximisation IV- Examples

From the tangency condtion:

2K ∗

L∗=

wr

=⇒ K ∗ = L∗(w2r

)Using the constraint:

Q0 =(L∗

(w2r

))1/4(L∗)1/2 = (L∗)3/4

(w2r

)1/4

Solving for L∗ and K ∗ we obtain:

L∗ = Q4/30

(2rw

)1/3

,

K ∗ = L∗(w2r

)=⇒ K ∗ = Q4/3

0

(w2r

)2/3

Domenico Tabasso (University of Essex - Department of Economics)Lecture 10 - Spring Term Week 25 19 / 26

Page 22: Constrained Maximisation IV- Examples

Substituting into the expression for total costs we getthe minimised total cost:

TC ∗ = wL∗ + rK ∗ =3

22/3Q4/30 w 2/3r 1/3.

Now consider the effect of increasing the wage rate:

∂L∗

∂w= −1

321/3Q4/3

0 w−4/3r 1/3 < 0,

∂K ∗

∂w=

232−2/3Q4/3

0 w−1/3r−2/3 > 0.

If we increase w from w1 to w2 then L∗ goes down, K ∗

goes up: we substitute capital for labour.

Domenico Tabasso (University of Essex - Department of Economics)Lecture 10 - Spring Term Week 25 20 / 26

Page 23: Constrained Maximisation IV- Examples

Also note that from the first order conditions:

λ∗ =4r(K ∗)3/4

(L∗)1/2 =4r [Q4/3

0 (w/(2)r)2/3]3/4

[Q4/30 (2r/w)1/3]1/2

= 24/3Q1/30 w 2/3r 1/3.

This is the same as the marginal cost of production atQ0 using cost minimising input choices, i.e. ∂TC∗

∂Q0.

Domenico Tabasso (University of Essex - Department of Economics)Lecture 10 - Spring Term Week 25 21 / 26

Page 24: Constrained Maximisation IV- Examples

Example: Profit Maximisation

Now suppose the board of directors of a competitivefirm wants to maximise profits and asks the CEO of thefirm to perform this task by choosing the appropriatelevels of labour and capital.In this case the CEO’s constraint is the firm’stechnology. Suppose this is described by the CobbDouglas function:

Q = F (K , L) = K 1/4L1/2

How to solve the CEO problem when the price of thegood the firm sells is p and the prices of labour andcapital are given by w > 0 and r > 0?

Domenico Tabasso (University of Essex - Department of Economics)Lecture 10 - Spring Term Week 25 22 / 26

Page 25: Constrained Maximisation IV- Examples

We could use an unconstrained maximisation approachin which we we want to maximise:

Π(Q,K , L) = pQ − wL− rK

and we substitute out the constraint and then solve theproblem:

maxK ,L

Π(K , L) = pK 1/4L1/2 − wL− rK .

Domenico Tabasso (University of Essex - Department of Economics)Lecture 10 - Spring Term Week 25 23 / 26

Page 26: Constrained Maximisation IV- Examples

Alternatively we could use a constrained maximisationapproach and maximise profit (equals revenue minuscost) subject to output equaling sales:

maxQ,K ,L

pQ − wL− rK s.t. Q = F (K , L).

Using the Lagrange Multiplier Method then we solvethe following problem:

maxQ,K ,L,λ

L(Q,K , L, λ) = pQ−wL−rK +λ(Q−K 1/4L1/2)

Domenico Tabasso (University of Essex - Department of Economics)Lecture 10 - Spring Term Week 25 24 / 26

Page 27: Constrained Maximisation IV- Examples

The first order conditions are then:

A :∂L∂Q

= p − λ = 0,

B :∂L∂K

= −r + λ

(14

)K−3/4L1/2 = 0,

C :∂L∂L

= −w + λ

(12

)K 1/4L−1/2 = 0,

D :∂L∂λ

= Q − K 1/4L1/2 = 0.

Denoting the solution as(Q = Q∗,K = K ∗, L = L∗, λ = λ∗) then from A we getλ∗ = p.

Domenico Tabasso (University of Essex - Department of Economics)Lecture 10 - Spring Term Week 25 25 / 26

Page 28: Constrained Maximisation IV- Examples

Substituting into B and C gives:

p(14

)K−3/4L1/2 = r , p

(12

)K 1/4L−1/2 = w .

Then:

L1/2 =4rK 3/4

p=

pK 1/4

2w,

so:

K 1/2 =p2

8rw=⇒ K ∗ =

p4

64r 2w 2

and:

L∗ =p2K 1/2

4w 2 =p4

32rw 3

Domenico Tabasso (University of Essex - Department of Economics)Lecture 10 - Spring Term Week 25 26 / 26