Constrained Maximisation I

download Constrained Maximisation I

of 35

Transcript of Constrained Maximisation I

  • 8/10/2019 Constrained Maximisation I

    1/35

    EC115 - Methods of Economic AnalysisSpring Term, Lecture 7Constrained Maximisation I

    (Basic Concepts)

    Renshaw - Chapter 16

    University of Essex - Department of Economics

    Week 22

    Domenico Tabasso (Uni versity of Essex - Depart ment of Economics)

    Lecture 7 - Spring Term Week 22 1 / 33

    http://find/
  • 8/10/2019 Constrained Maximisation I

    2/35

    Topics for this week

    IntroductionConstrained Utility Maximization

    The ConstraintThe Objective FunctionRelation Between Constrained and Unconstrained OptimizationProblems

    Domenico Tabasso (Uni versity of Essex - Depart ment of Economics)

    Lecture 7 - Spring Term Week 22 2 / 33

    http://find/
  • 8/10/2019 Constrained Maximisation I

    3/35

    Introduction

    Through the study of functions with several independent variableswe have been able to understand how economists use them:

    to represent production technologies and consumer preferences(production and utility functions); and

    to analyse their properties using partial differentiation and totaldifferentiation

    When studying maximum points we have used productionfunctions to analyse rms optimal decisions (when they seek to

    maximise prots) in situations where they do not face anyconstraints.

    Domenico Tabasso (Uni versity of Essex - Depart ment of Economics)

    Lecture 7 - Spring Term Week 22 3 / 33

    http://find/
  • 8/10/2019 Constrained Maximisation I

    4/35

    Firms in a competitive market choose output to maximise protsat given prices.Monopolists choose output to maximise prots with a given

    market demand function.We now go one step further and analyse maximisation andminimisation problems when agents face constraints.

    Domenico Tabasso (Uni versity of Essex - Depart ment of Economics)Lecture 7 - Spring Term Week 22 4 / 33

    http://find/
  • 8/10/2019 Constrained Maximisation I

    5/35

    Constrained Utility Maximization

    A typical problem we have in mind is of the following nature.A consumer wants to choose a combination of two goods X andY to maximise her utility,

    u = U (x , y ),

    where x and y represent the quantities of the goods.Typically this consumer will have a x monthly income to spend,M .

    If prices are positive, i.e. p x > 0 and p y > 0, then her decision onhow much to consume of each good must be constrained by theamount of money she can spend.

    Domenico Tabasso (Uni versity of Essex - Depart ment of Economics)Lecture 7 - Spring Term Week 22 5 / 33

    http://find/http://goback/
  • 8/10/2019 Constrained Maximisation I

    6/35

    Everytime the consumer has to decide how much to consume,she faces the following budget constraint :

    p x x + p y y M .

    Note that by writing her budget constraint in this form, we areimplicitly assuming that she cannot borrow or lend money (so nonancial markets).Clearly the assumption of no nancial markets is restrictive as itdoes not capture many real world situations. However,analysing a consumers behaviour when there are no nancialmarkets is helpful for understanding how a budget constraintaffects her consumption choices.

    Domenico Tabasso (Uni versity of Essex - Depart ment of Economics)Lecture 7 - Spring Term Week 22 6 / 33

    http://find/
  • 8/10/2019 Constrained Maximisation I

    7/35

    The consumers maximisation problem is described by:

    maxx ,y

    U (x , y ) s .t . p x x + p y y m.

    The consumers objective is to maximise her utility and thus theobjective function of her maximisation problem problem is her

    utility function U (x , y ).The consumer is constrained by her available income and thusthe constraint of her maximisation problem is given by herbudget constraint p x x + p y y m.

    In almost all of the remainder of this course we will assume thatthe constraint binds so that it becomes p x x + p y y = m.

    Domenico Tabasso (Uni versity of Essex - Depart ment of Economics)Lecture 7 - Spring Term Week 22 7 / 33

    http://find/
  • 8/10/2019 Constrained Maximisation I

    8/35

    The Constraint

    The constraint is an implicit relation, (x , y ) = 0, between x and y that must be satised by the values of x and y that maximisethe objective function.In the case of the consumers problem we can derive acorresponding explicit relation, y = g (x ), given by:

    y =mp y

    p x p y

    x .

    The term (p x / p y ) describes the slope of the g () function:

    dy dx

    = p x p y

    .

    Domenico Tabasso (Uni versity of Essex - Depart ment of Economics)Lecture 7 - Spring Term Week 22 8 / 33

    http://find/
  • 8/10/2019 Constrained Maximisation I

    9/35

    The slope tells us how many units of Y the consumer to give upin order to buy one extra unit of X while keeping expenditureconstant at m (so it measures opportunity cost).The term (m/ p y ) describes the intercept of the g () function, i.e.the value of y when x = 0.The intercept tells how many units of Y the consumer can buywhen she has income m and spends all of it on Y .Similarly (m/ p x ) is the number of units of X the consumer canbuy when she has income m and spends all of it on X .

    Domenico Tabasso (Uni versity of Essex - Depart ment of Economics)Lecture 7 - Spring Term Week 22 9 / 33

    http://find/
  • 8/10/2019 Constrained Maximisation I

    10/35Domenico Tabasso (Uni versity of Essex - Depart ment of Economics)Lecture 7 - Spring Term Week 22 10 / 33

    http://find/
  • 8/10/2019 Constrained Maximisation I

    11/35

    Analysing the Constraint

    Changing p x , p y and/or m changes the consumers budgetconstraint.Reducing m shifts the budget line in towards the origin(increasing m shifts it out away from the origin).

    Reducing p x rotates the budget line by increasing the slope butkeeping the intercept constant (increasing p x reduces the slopebut keeps the intercept constant).Reducing p y rotates the budget line by reducing the slope and

    adjusting the intercept accordingly (increasing p y increases theslope and adjusts the intercept accordingly).

    Domenico Tabasso (Uni versity of Essex - Depart ment of Economics)Lecture 7 - Spring Term Week 22 11 / 33

    http://goforward/http://find/http://goback/
  • 8/10/2019 Constrained Maximisation I

    12/35Domenico Tabasso (Uni versity of Essex - Depart ment of Economics)Lecture 7 - Spring Term Week 22 12 / 33

    http://goforward/http://find/http://goback/
  • 8/10/2019 Constrained Maximisation I

    13/35Domenico Tabasso (Uni versity of Essex - Depart ment of Economics)Lecture 7 - Spring Term Week 22 13 / 33

    http://goforward/http://find/http://goback/
  • 8/10/2019 Constrained Maximisation I

    14/35

    Domenico Tabasso (Uni versity of Essex - Depart ment of Economics)Lecture 7 - Spring Term Week 22 14 / 33

    http://goforward/http://find/http://goback/
  • 8/10/2019 Constrained Maximisation I

    15/35

    We can also use total differentiation to examine the slope of theconstraint.

    We can rewrite the budget line as G (x , y ) = 0 whereG (x , y ) = p x x + p y y m.The total differentiation gives:

    G x dx +

    G y dy = 0.

    But G x = p x and G

    y = p y so we have:

    p x dx + p y dy = 0and thus dy dx = (p x / p y ).

    Domenico Tabasso (Uni versity of Essex - Depart ment of Economics)Lecture 7 - Spring Term Week 22 15 / 33

    http://find/
  • 8/10/2019 Constrained Maximisation I

    16/35

    The Objective Function

    The objective function describes the function that the agent wantto maximise or minimise.This function is normally of several independent variables.Hence our previous techniques for analysing this functions apply.Assume the consumer has a Cobb-Douglas utility function

    u = U (x , y ) = x 1/ 2 y 1/ 2

    This function describes the preferences the consumer has forgoods x and y .

    Domenico Tabasso (Uni versity of Essex - Depart ment of Economics)Lecture 7 - Spring Term Week 22 16 / 33

    http://find/
  • 8/10/2019 Constrained Maximisation I

    17/35

    Applying partial differentiation we obtain that

    MU x (x , y ) = U (x , y )

    x =

    12

    y x

    1/ 2> 0

    MU y (x , y ) = U (x , y )

    y =

    1

    2

    x

    y

    1/ 2

    > 0

    The marginal utilities are positive for positive values of x and y .Recall that the marginal utilities are a measure of how much doesthe utility changes when the consumer increases the consumption

    of x or y .

    Domenico Tabasso (Uni versity of Essex - Depart ment of Economics)Lecture 7 - Spring Term Week 22 17 / 33

    http://find/
  • 8/10/2019 Constrained Maximisation I

    18/35

    Applying partial differentiation one more time we get MU x (x , y )

    x =

    2U (x , y ) x 2

    = y 1/ 2

    4x 3/ 2 < 0

    MU y (x , y ) y =

    2U (x , y ) y 2 =

    x 1/ 2

    4 y 3/ 2 < 0

    That is, the marginal utilities are downward sloping for positivevalues of x and y .

    Domenico Tabasso (Uni versity of Essex - Depart ment of Economics)Lecture 7 - Spring Term Week 22 18 / 33

    http://find/
  • 8/10/2019 Constrained Maximisation I

    19/35

    Finally, using cross partial differentiation we obtain that MU y (x , y )

    x =

    2U (x , y ) y x

    = 2U (x , y )

    x y

    = MU x (x , y )

    y = 14

    1xy

    1/ 2

    > 0

    Thus increasing consumption of X while keeping consumption of Y xed will increase the marginal utility of Y (and vice versa).

    Domenico Tabasso (Uni versity of Essex - Depart ment of Economics)Lecture 7 - Spring Term Week 22 19 / 33

    http://find/
  • 8/10/2019 Constrained Maximisation I

    20/35

    Using total differentiation, we have that for any utility level theindifference curve is given by the implicit function:

    U (x , y ) u 0 = x 1/ 2 y 1/ 2 u 0 = 0du 0 = MU x (x , y )dx + MU y (x , y )dy = 0

    The marginal rate of substitution describes how much of good y the consumer is willing to exchange for more of good x holdingutility constant:

    MRS x ,y =

    dy

    dx u = u 0 =

    MU x (x , y )MU y (x , y ) =

    u 0x

    2

    =

    y

    x .

    Domenico Tabasso (Uni versity of Essex - Depart ment of Economics)Lecture 7 - Spring Term Week 22 20 / 33

    http://find/
  • 8/10/2019 Constrained Maximisation I

    21/35

    That the change in the MRS increases with x , implies that as weconsume more of x the consumer is less willing to substitutemore of good y :

    d 2 y dx 2

    u =

    u 0

    = 2u 20x 3

    > 0.

    This is a reection that the consumer prefers averageconsumption of the two goods to extreme bundles in which thereis a lot of one good and only few units of the other.

    Domenico Tabasso (Uni versity of Essex - Depart ment of Economics)Lecture 7 - Spring Term Week 22 21 / 33

    http://find/
  • 8/10/2019 Constrained Maximisation I

    22/35

    Domenico Tabasso (Uni versity of Essex - Depart ment of Economics)Lecture 7 - Spring Term Week 22 22 / 33

    http://find/
  • 8/10/2019 Constrained Maximisation I

    23/35

    Relation Between Constrained and Unconstrained Optimization Problems

    In the unconstrained optimisation problem, we want to obtain themaximum or minimum values of a function.In the constrained optimisation problem, we want to obtain the

    maximum or minimum values of the the function subject to the constraint .In general, the solutions will be different (in general, the solutionto the unconstrained optimisation problem does not satisfy theconstraint).

    Domenico Tabasso (Uni versity of Essex - Depart ment of Economics)Lecture 7 - Spring Term Week 22 23 / 33

    B t h i ll thi t ff f l?

    http://find/
  • 8/10/2019 Constrained Maximisation I

    24/35

    But why is all this stuff useful?

    Because we can prove that the optimal solution for themaximization of a consumers utility is given by thepoint where the slope of the indifference curve and theslope of the budget constraint are identical.

    Domenico Tabasso (Uni versity of Essex - Depart ment of Economics)Lecture 7 - Spring Term Week 22 24 / 33

    B t h is all this st ff sef l?

    http://find/
  • 8/10/2019 Constrained Maximisation I

    25/35

    But why is all this stuff useful?

    Because we can prove that the optimal solution for themaximization of a consumers utility is given by thepoint where the slope of the indifference curve and theslope of the budget constraint are identical.

    But the slope of the indifference curve in every point ithe MRS!And the slope of the budget constraint is given by p x p y .

    Domenico Tabasso (Uni versity of Essex - Depart ment of Economics)Lecture 7 - Spring Term Week 22 24 / 33

    But why is all this stuff useful?

    http://find/
  • 8/10/2019 Constrained Maximisation I

    26/35

    But why is all this stuff useful?

    Because we can prove that the optimal solution for themaximization of a consumers utility is given by thepoint where the slope of the indifference curve and theslope of the budget constraint are identical.

    But the slope of the indifference curve in every point ithe MRS!And the slope of the budget constraint is given by p x p y .

    So for our solution to dene a maximum it is necessary(but not sufficient!) that MRS = p x p y

    Domenico Tabasso (Uni versity of Essex - Depart ment of Economics)Lecture 7 - Spring Term Week 22 24 / 33

    http://find/
  • 8/10/2019 Constrained Maximisation I

    27/35

    The other condition that need to be satised is that the

    optimal point MUST lay on the budget constraint.So the system:

    MRS = p x p y M = p x X + p y Y

    gives us the necessary and sufficient conditions for ndingthe constrained maximum.

    Domenico Tabasso (Uni versity of Essex - Depart ment of Economics)Lecture 7 - Spring Term Week 22 25 / 33

    So can points A and B constitute optimal solutions?

    http://find/
  • 8/10/2019 Constrained Maximisation I

    28/35

    So can points A and B constitute optimal solutions?

    Y

    X

    NO!!! In both A and B , MRS = p x / p y .Domenico Tabasso (Uni versity of Essex - Depart ment of Economics)Lecture 7 - Spring Term Week 22 26 / 33

    And how about points C and D?

    http://find/
  • 8/10/2019 Constrained Maximisation I

    29/35

    And how about points C and D?

    Y

    C

    X

    Domenico Tabasso (Uni versity of Essex - Depart ment of Economics)Lecture 7 - Spring Term Week 22 27 / 33

    http://find/
  • 8/10/2019 Constrained Maximisation I

    30/35

    In points C and D the slope of the indifference curves (i.e.the slope of the lines tangent to the indifference curves inthose points) is equal to the slope of the budget constraint.So:

    MRS A = MRS B = p x p y

    The problem is that points C and D are NOT on thebudget constraint. So C and D do not satisfy the second

    equation of the system.

    Domenico Tabasso (Uni versity of Essex - Depart ment of Economics)Lecture 7 - Spring Term Week 22 28 / 33

    And the winner is...

    http://find/
  • 8/10/2019 Constrained Maximisation I

    31/35

    Y

    E

    X

    Domenico Tabasso (Uni versity of Essex - Depart ment of Economics)Lecture 7 - Spring Term Week 22 29 / 33

    An example

    http://find/
  • 8/10/2019 Constrained Maximisation I

    32/35

    An example

    A consumer problem is:

    maxX ,Y

    U (X , Y ) = X 1/ 2Y 1/ 2

    s .t . 100 = 2X + Y

    First step: Find the MRS associated with the aboveutility function:

    MRS = dY dX =

    U / X U / Y

    Domenico Tabasso (Uni versity of Essex - Depart ment of Economics)Lecture 7 - Spring Term Week 22 30 / 33

    http://find/
  • 8/10/2019 Constrained Maximisation I

    33/35

    In our case:

    MRS = U / X U / Y

    = 12X

    1/ 2Y 1/ 212X

    1/ 2Y 1/ 2 =

    Y X

    Second step: Set the system: MRS = p x p y

    Y X =

    21

    M = p x X + p y Y 100 = 2X + Y

    Domenico Tabasso (Uni versity of Essex - Depart ment of Economics)Lecture 7 - Spring Term Week 22 31 / 33

    http://find/
  • 8/10/2019 Constrained Maximisation I

    34/35

    Third Step: Solve the system

    From the rst equation we get: X = 0.5Y .Plugging this in the second equation (the budget

    constraint) we get:100 = Y + Y .

    So Y = 50 and since X = 0.5Y X = 25.

    Domenico Tabasso (Uni versity of Essex - Depart ment of Economics)Lecture 7 - Spring Term Week 22 32 / 33

    Graphically:

    http://find/
  • 8/10/2019 Constrained Maximisation I

    35/35

    120

    100 U=U*

    80

    60

    40

    20

    0

    13 14 15 16 17 18 19 20 21 22 23 24 25 26 27 28 29 30 31 32 33 34 35 36 37 38 39 40

    Domenico Tabasso (Uni versity of Essex - Depart ment of Economics)Lecture 7 - Spring Term Week 22 33 / 33

    http://find/