1 Chapter 20 Brownian Motion and Itô’s Lemma. 2 Introduction Stock and other asset prices are...

51
1 Chapter 20 Chapter 20 Brownian Motion and Brownian Motion and It It ô ô ’s ’s Lemma Lemma

Transcript of 1 Chapter 20 Brownian Motion and Itô’s Lemma. 2 Introduction Stock and other asset prices are...

Page 1: 1 Chapter 20 Brownian Motion and Itô’s Lemma. 2 Introduction Stock and other asset prices are commonly assumed to follow a stochastic process called geometric.

1

Chapter 20Chapter 20Brownian Motion andBrownian Motion and

ItItôô’s’s Lemma Lemma

Page 2: 1 Chapter 20 Brownian Motion and Itô’s Lemma. 2 Introduction Stock and other asset prices are commonly assumed to follow a stochastic process called geometric.

2

Introduction

Stock and other asset prices are commonly assumed to follow a stochastic process called geometric Brownian motion.

Given that a stock price follows geometric Brownian motion, we want to characterize the behavior of a claim that has a payoff dependent upon the stock price.

We will discuss Ito’s Lemma, which permits us to study the process followed by a claim that is a function of the stock price.

Page 3: 1 Chapter 20 Brownian Motion and Itô’s Lemma. 2 Introduction Stock and other asset prices are commonly assumed to follow a stochastic process called geometric.

3

The Black-Scholes Assumption about Stock Prices

The original paper by Black and Scholes begins by assuming that the price of the underlying asset follows a process like the following:

(20.1)where S(t) is the stock price, dS(t) is the instantaneous change in the stock price, is the continuously compounded expected return on the

stock, is the continuously compounded standard deviation

(volatility), Z(t) is a normally distributed random variable that follows a

process called Brownian motion. dZ(t) is the change in Z(t) over a short period of time.

)( )(

)(tdZdt

tS

tdS

Page 4: 1 Chapter 20 Brownian Motion and Itô’s Lemma. 2 Introduction Stock and other asset prices are commonly assumed to follow a stochastic process called geometric.

4

The Black-Scholes Assumption about Stock Prices

A stock obeying equation (20.1) is said to follow a process called geometric Brownian motion.

Expressions like equation (20.1) are called stochastic differential equations.

There are 2 important implications of equation (20.1):

1. Suppose the stock price now is S(0). If the stock price follows equation (20.1), the distribution of S(T) is lognormal, i.e.,

ln [S (T)] ~ N (ln [S (0)] + [ – 0.52]T, 2T)

2. Geometric Brownian motion allows us to describe the path the stock price takes in getting to a terminal point.

Page 5: 1 Chapter 20 Brownian Motion and Itô’s Lemma. 2 Introduction Stock and other asset prices are commonly assumed to follow a stochastic process called geometric.

5

A Description of Stock Price Behavior The normal distribution provides an unrealistic description of the

stock price. However, normality can be a plausible description of continuously compounded returns.

If the continuously compounded return is R(0,T), the price is S(0) eR(0,T), which is always positive.

It can be reasonable to assume that over very short periods of time effective stock returns, S(t + h)/S(t), are normally distributed.

Page 6: 1 Chapter 20 Brownian Motion and Itô’s Lemma. 2 Introduction Stock and other asset prices are commonly assumed to follow a stochastic process called geometric.

6

A Description of Stock Price Behavior Suppose that

h, the length of each time period, is small, the return on the stock, rh, is normally distributed with

mean and variance h and 2h.

Thus,

S(t + h) = S(t)(1 + rh) (20.2)

with

rh = ~ N (h, 2h)

Page 7: 1 Chapter 20 Brownian Motion and Itô’s Lemma. 2 Introduction Stock and other asset prices are commonly assumed to follow a stochastic process called geometric.

7

A Description of Stock Price Behavior

The continuously compounded return from 0 to T is

The logarithm of a normal random variable is not normal. However, as h 0, the continuously compounded return from 0 to T is normal. Therefore, S(T) tends toward lognormality.

n

i ihrlnSTSln

1 )1()]0(/)([

Page 8: 1 Chapter 20 Brownian Motion and Itô’s Lemma. 2 Introduction Stock and other asset prices are commonly assumed to follow a stochastic process called geometric.

8

Brownian Motion

Brownian motion is a random walk occurring in continuous time, with movements that are continuous rather than discrete.

A random walk can be generated by flipping a coin each period and moving one step, with the direction determined by whether the coin is heads or tails.

To generate Brownian motion, we would flip the coins infinitely fast and take infinitesimally small steps at each point.

Page 9: 1 Chapter 20 Brownian Motion and Itô’s Lemma. 2 Introduction Stock and other asset prices are commonly assumed to follow a stochastic process called geometric.

9

Brownian Motion

Let Z(t) represent the value of the random walk—the cumulative sum of all the moves—after t periods.

Technically, Brownian motion is a random walk with the following characteristics:

Z(0) = 0.

Z(t + s) – Z (t) is normally distributed with mean 0 and variance s.

Z(t + s1) – Z(t) is independent of Z(t) – Z(t – s2), where s1, s2 >0. That is, nonoverlapping increments are independently distributed.

Z(t) is continuous.

Page 10: 1 Chapter 20 Brownian Motion and Itô’s Lemma. 2 Introduction Stock and other asset prices are commonly assumed to follow a stochastic process called geometric.

10

Brownian Motion

We can think of Brownian motion being approximately generated from the sum of independent binomial draws with mean 0 and variance h.

Let h get arbitrarily small, and rename h as dt.

Denote the change in Z as dZ(t).

Page 11: 1 Chapter 20 Brownian Motion and Itô’s Lemma. 2 Introduction Stock and other asset prices are commonly assumed to follow a stochastic process called geometric.

11

Brownian Motion

Then,(20.5)

where Y(t) is a random draw from a binomial distribution, such that Y(t) is 1 with probability 50%.

Equation (20.5) says “Over small periods of time, changes in the value of the process are normally distributed with a variance that is proportional to the length of the time period.”

dttYtdZ )()(

Page 12: 1 Chapter 20 Brownian Motion and Itô’s Lemma. 2 Introduction Stock and other asset prices are commonly assumed to follow a stochastic process called geometric.

12

Brownian Motion

Since Z(T) is the sum of individual dZ(t)’s, we can write

(20.6)

The integral here is called a stochastic integral.

The process Z(t) is also called a diffusion process.

Among properties of Brownian motion are: “infinite-crossing property,” and “infinite variation.”

T

tdZZTZ0

)()0()(

Page 13: 1 Chapter 20 Brownian Motion and Itô’s Lemma. 2 Introduction Stock and other asset prices are commonly assumed to follow a stochastic process called geometric.

13

Arithmetic Brownian Motion

With pure Brownian motion, the expected change in Z is 0, and the variance per unit time is 1. We can generalize this to allow an arbitrary variance and a nonzero mean.

(20.8)

This process is called arithmetic Brownian motion. is the instantaneous mean per unit time,

2 is the instantaneous variance per unit time,

the variable X(t) is the sum of the individual changes dX. X(t) is normally distributed, i.e., X(T) – X(0) ~ N (T, 2T).

)( )( tdZdttdX

Page 14: 1 Chapter 20 Brownian Motion and Itô’s Lemma. 2 Introduction Stock and other asset prices are commonly assumed to follow a stochastic process called geometric.

14

Arithmetic Brownian Motion

An integral representation of equation (20.8) is

Here are some properties of the process in equation (20.8):

X(t) is normally distributed because it is created by adding together many normally distributed dX’s.

The random term is multiplied by a scale factor that enables us to change variance.

The dt term introduces a nonrandom drift into the process.

TT

tdZdtXTX00

)( )0()(

Page 15: 1 Chapter 20 Brownian Motion and Itô’s Lemma. 2 Introduction Stock and other asset prices are commonly assumed to follow a stochastic process called geometric.

15

Arithmetic Brownian Motion

Arithmetic Brownian motion has several drawbacks:

There is nothing to prevent X from becoming negative, so it is a poor model for stock prices.

The mean and variance of changes in dollar terms are independent of the level of the stock price.

Both of these criticisms will be eliminated with geometric Brownian motion.

Page 16: 1 Chapter 20 Brownian Motion and Itô’s Lemma. 2 Introduction Stock and other asset prices are commonly assumed to follow a stochastic process called geometric.

16

The Ornstein-Uhlenbeck Process

We can incorporate mean reversion by modifying the drift term:

(20.9)

When = 0, this equation is called an Ornstein-Uhlenbeck process.

The parameter measures the speed of the reversion: If is large, reversion happens more quickly.

In the long run, we expect X to revert toward .

As with arithmetic Brownian motion, X can still become negative.

( ) [ ( )] ( )dX t X t dt dZ t

Page 17: 1 Chapter 20 Brownian Motion and Itô’s Lemma. 2 Introduction Stock and other asset prices are commonly assumed to follow a stochastic process called geometric.

17

Example of Mean-Reverting Process

-0.2

0

0.2

0.4

0.6

0.8

1

0 1000 2000 3000 4000 5000 6000

Page 18: 1 Chapter 20 Brownian Motion and Itô’s Lemma. 2 Introduction Stock and other asset prices are commonly assumed to follow a stochastic process called geometric.

18

Geometric Brownian Motion

An equation, in which the drift and volatility depend on the stock price, is called an Itô process.

Suppose we modify arithmetic Brownian motion to make the instantaneous mean and standard deviation proportional to X(t):

This is an Itô process that can also be written

(20.11)

This process is known as geometric Brownian motion.

)( )(

)(tdZdta

tX

tdX

)()( )( )( tdZtXdttXatdX

Page 19: 1 Chapter 20 Brownian Motion and Itô’s Lemma. 2 Introduction Stock and other asset prices are commonly assumed to follow a stochastic process called geometric.

19

Geometric Brownian Motion

The percentage change in the asset value is normally distributed with instantaneous mean and instantaneous variance 2.

The integral representation for equation (20.11) is

TT

tdZtXdttXXTX00

)()( )( )0()(

Page 20: 1 Chapter 20 Brownian Motion and Itô’s Lemma. 2 Introduction Stock and other asset prices are commonly assumed to follow a stochastic process called geometric.

20

Example of Geometric Brownian Motion

0

5

10

15

20

25

30

35

40

45

50

0 1000 2000 3000 4000 5000 6000

Page 21: 1 Chapter 20 Brownian Motion and Itô’s Lemma. 2 Introduction Stock and other asset prices are commonly assumed to follow a stochastic process called geometric.

21

Lognormality

If a variable is distributed in such a way that instantaneous percentage changes follow geometric Brownian motion, then over discrete periods of time, the variable is lognormally distributed.

Page 22: 1 Chapter 20 Brownian Motion and Itô’s Lemma. 2 Introduction Stock and other asset prices are commonly assumed to follow a stochastic process called geometric.

22

Relative importance of the drift and noise terms

Over short periods of time, the character of the Brownian process is determined almost entirely by the random component.

Consider the ratio of the per-period standard deviation to the per-period drift:

The ratio becomes infinite as h approaches dt.

As the time interval becomes longer, the mean becomes more important than the standard deviation.

hhtX

htX

)(

)(

Page 23: 1 Chapter 20 Brownian Motion and Itô’s Lemma. 2 Introduction Stock and other asset prices are commonly assumed to follow a stochastic process called geometric.

23

Relative importance of the drift and noise terms

The results in the table hold for both geometric Brownian motion and arithmetic Brownian motion.

Page 24: 1 Chapter 20 Brownian Motion and Itô’s Lemma. 2 Introduction Stock and other asset prices are commonly assumed to follow a stochastic process called geometric.

24

Correlated Itô processes

Let W1(t) and W2(t) be independent Brownian motions. Then,

(20.16)This is the Cholesky decomposition.

The correlation between Z(t) and Z'(t) is

The second term on the right-hand side is 0 because W1(t) and W2(t) are independent.

)(1)()(

)()(

22

1

1

tWtWtZ

tWtZ

'

0 )]()([1])([)]()([ 2122

1 ttWtWEtWEtZtZE '

Page 25: 1 Chapter 20 Brownian Motion and Itô’s Lemma. 2 Introduction Stock and other asset prices are commonly assumed to follow a stochastic process called geometric.

25

Multiplication rules

We can simplify complex terms containing dt and dZ by using the following “multiplication rules”:

dt dZ = 0 (20.17a)

(dt)2 = 0 (20.17b)

(dZ)2 = dt (20.17c)

dZ dZ' = dt (20.17d)

The reason behind these multiplication rules is that the multiplications resulting in powers of dt greater than 1 vanish.

Page 26: 1 Chapter 20 Brownian Motion and Itô’s Lemma. 2 Introduction Stock and other asset prices are commonly assumed to follow a stochastic process called geometric.

26

The Sharpe Ratio

If asset i has expected return i, the risk premium is defined as

Risk premiumi = i – r

where r is the risk-free rate.

The Sharpe ratio for asset i is the risk premium, i – r, per unit of volatility, i:

(20.18)i

ii

ratio Sharpe

Page 27: 1 Chapter 20 Brownian Motion and Itô’s Lemma. 2 Introduction Stock and other asset prices are commonly assumed to follow a stochastic process called geometric.

27

The Sharpe Ratio

We can use the Sharpe ratio to compare two perfectly correlated claims, such as a derivative and its underlying asset.

Two assets that are perfectly correlated must have the same Sharpe ratio, or else there will be an arbitrage opportunity.

Consider the processes for two non-dividend paying stocks:

dS1 = 1S1dt + 1S1dZ (20.19)

dS2 = 2S2dt + 2S2dZ (20.20)

Because the two stock prices are driven by the same dZ, it must be the case that (1 – r)/ 1 = (2 – r)/ 2.

Page 28: 1 Chapter 20 Brownian Motion and Itô’s Lemma. 2 Introduction Stock and other asset prices are commonly assumed to follow a stochastic process called geometric.

28

The risk-neutral process

Suppose the true price process is

where is the dividend yield on the stock.

We can write a risk-neutral version of this process by subtracting the risk premium, – r, from the drift, – :

(20.25)

The probability distribution (dZ*(t)) associated with the risk-neutral process is said to be the risk-neutral measure.

When we switch to the risk-neutral process, the volatility remains the same.

)()()(

)(tdZdt

tS

tdS

)( )()(

)( * tdZdtrtS

tdS

Page 29: 1 Chapter 20 Brownian Motion and Itô’s Lemma. 2 Introduction Stock and other asset prices are commonly assumed to follow a stochastic process called geometric.

29

Itô’s Lemma

Suppose a stock with an expected instantaneous return of , dividend yield of , and instantaneous volatility follows geometric Brownian motion:

dS(t) = ( – )S(t)dt + S(t)dZ(t) (20.26)

C[S(t), t] is the value of a derivative claim that is a function of the stock price.

How can we describe the behavior of this claim in terms of the behavior of S?

Page 30: 1 Chapter 20 Brownian Motion and Itô’s Lemma. 2 Introduction Stock and other asset prices are commonly assumed to follow a stochastic process called geometric.

30

Itô’s Lemma

Itô’s Lemma (Proposition 20.1) If C[S(t), t] is a twice-differentiable function of S(t), then the change in C is

(20.27)

where we recognize the delta-gamma approximation.

21( , ) ( )

2

S SS tdC S t C dS C dS C dt

Page 31: 1 Chapter 20 Brownian Motion and Itô’s Lemma. 2 Introduction Stock and other asset prices are commonly assumed to follow a stochastic process called geometric.

31

Itô’s Lemma

In the case where S follows a Geometric Brownian motion, we have:

where CS = C/S, CSS = 2C/S2, and Ct = C/t.

The terms in square brackets are the expected change in the option price.

2 2

( )

1 ( )

2S SS t S

dS Sdt σSdZ and so

dC SC S C C dt σSC dZ

Page 32: 1 Chapter 20 Brownian Motion and Itô’s Lemma. 2 Introduction Stock and other asset prices are commonly assumed to follow a stochastic process called geometric.

32

Itô’s Lemma Application

Let C(S) = ln(S) so that the value of C is the logarithm of S.

Let dS = Sdt + SdZ

Compute the path for the changes in C, i.e. compute the expression for dC.

Page 33: 1 Chapter 20 Brownian Motion and Itô’s Lemma. 2 Introduction Stock and other asset prices are commonly assumed to follow a stochastic process called geometric.

33

Itô’s Lemma Application: solution

CS = C/S = (ln(S))/S = 1/S.

CSS = 2C/S2 = (1/S)/S = -1/S2.

Ct = C/t = 0 because C = ln(S) and is not a function of t.

Therefore dC = [ – (1/2)2]dt + dZ

Page 34: 1 Chapter 20 Brownian Motion and Itô’s Lemma. 2 Introduction Stock and other asset prices are commonly assumed to follow a stochastic process called geometric.

34

Multivariate Itô’s Lemma

A derivative may have a value depending on more than one price, in which case we can use a multivariate generalization of Itô’s Lemma.

Multivariate Itô’s Lemma (Proposition 20.2) Suppose we have n correlated Itô processes:

Denote the pairwise correlations as E(dzi dzj) = i,jdt.

nidzdttS

tdSiii

i

i ., . . ,1 , )(

)(

Page 35: 1 Chapter 20 Brownian Motion and Itô’s Lemma. 2 Introduction Stock and other asset prices are commonly assumed to follow a stochastic process called geometric.

35

Multivariate Itô’s Lemma

If C(S1, . . ., Sn, t) is a twice-differentiable function of the Si’s, we have

The expected change in C per unit time is

n

i

n

i t

n

j SSjiiSn dtCCdSdSdSCtSSdCjii1 1 11 2

1), ., . . ,(

n

i t

n

j SSjiijji

n

i Siin CCSSCStSSdCEdt jii 1 111 2

1)] , ., . . ,([

1

Page 36: 1 Chapter 20 Brownian Motion and Itô’s Lemma. 2 Introduction Stock and other asset prices are commonly assumed to follow a stochastic process called geometric.

36

Valuing a Claim on Sa

Suppose a stock with an expected instantaneous return of , dividend yield of , and instantaneous volatility follows geometric Brownian motion:

dS(t) = ( – )S(t)dt + S(t)dZ(t)

Now suppose that we also have a claim with a payoff depending on S raised to some power. For example, we may have a claim that pays S(T)2 at time T.

Page 37: 1 Chapter 20 Brownian Motion and Itô’s Lemma. 2 Introduction Stock and other asset prices are commonly assumed to follow a stochastic process called geometric.

37

Valuing a Claim on Sa

Proposition 20.3 The value at time 0 of a claim paying S(T)a—the prepaid forward price—is

(20.29)

The forward price for S(T)a is

(20.30)

TaaraarTaPT eSeTSF

])1(2

1)([

,0

2

)0(])([

TaaraaaT eSTSF

])1(2

1)([

,0

2

)0(])([

Page 38: 1 Chapter 20 Brownian Motion and Itô’s Lemma. 2 Introduction Stock and other asset prices are commonly assumed to follow a stochastic process called geometric.

38

The process followed by Sa

Consider a claim maturing at time T that pays C[S(T), T] = S(T)a.

We can use Itô’s Lemma to determine the process followed by Sa.

Give it a try, by using:

21( , ) ( )

2

S SS tdC S t C dS C dS C dt

Page 39: 1 Chapter 20 Brownian Motion and Itô’s Lemma. 2 Introduction Stock and other asset prices are commonly assumed to follow a stochastic process called geometric.

39

The process followed by Sa

We get:

(20.31)

Thus, Sa follows geometric Brownian motion with drift

a ( – ) + 1/2a (a – 1)2 and risk adZ.

If is the expected return for S, the expected return of a claim with price Sa will be

a ( – r) + r (20.32)

and the risk premium will be a ( – r). This is necessary to have the same Sharpe ratios.

dZadtaaaS

dSa

a

)1(

2

1)( 2

Page 40: 1 Chapter 20 Brownian Motion and Itô’s Lemma. 2 Introduction Stock and other asset prices are commonly assumed to follow a stochastic process called geometric.

40

Examples

Claims on S: Suppose a = 1. Equation (20.29) then gives us

the prepaid forward price on a stock:

Claims on S0: If a = 0, the claim does not depend on the stock price. Since S0 = 1, it is a bond. Setting a = 0 gives us

the price of a T-period pure discount bond:

TeSV )0()0(

rTeV )0(

Page 41: 1 Chapter 20 Brownian Motion and Itô’s Lemma. 2 Introduction Stock and other asset prices are commonly assumed to follow a stochastic process called geometric.

41

Examples

Claims on S2: When a = 2, the claim pays S(T)2. From equation (20.30), the forward price is

(20.35)

Thus, the forward price on the squared stock price is the squared forward price times a variance term.

TT

TTr

TrrTT

eSFeeS

eSeSF22

2

2,0

)(22

]2[22,0

)]([)0(

)0()(

Page 42: 1 Chapter 20 Brownian Motion and Itô’s Lemma. 2 Introduction Stock and other asset prices are commonly assumed to follow a stochastic process called geometric.

42

Examples

Claims on 1/S: If a = –1, the claim pays 1/S. Using equation (20.30), we get

As with the squared security, the forward price is increasing in volatility.

The payoffs for both the S2 and 1/S securities are convex. Therefore, according to Jensen’s inequality, the price is higher when the asset price is risky than when it is certain.

2( )0, (1/ ) [1/ (0)] r T TTF S S e e

Page 43: 1 Chapter 20 Brownian Motion and Itô’s Lemma. 2 Introduction Stock and other asset prices are commonly assumed to follow a stochastic process called geometric.

43

Valuing a claim on SaQb

Suppose a claim pays S(T)aQ(T)b, where S follows

(20.36)

and Q follows

(20.37)

where

SSSS dZdtS

dS )(

QQQQ dZdtQ

dQ )(

dtdZdZ QS

Page 44: 1 Chapter 20 Brownian Motion and Itô’s Lemma. 2 Introduction Stock and other asset prices are commonly assumed to follow a stochastic process called geometric.

44

Valuing a claim on SaQb

Proposition 20.4 Suppose that the forward prices for Sa and Qb are given by Proposition 20.3. Then the forward price for SaQb is

The forward price for SaQb is the product of those two forward prices times a factor that accounts for the covariance between the two assets.

The variance of SaQb is given by

)(,,, )()()( tTabbTt

aTt

baTt

QSeQFSFQSF

QSQS abba 22222

Page 45: 1 Chapter 20 Brownian Motion and Itô’s Lemma. 2 Introduction Stock and other asset prices are commonly assumed to follow a stochastic process called geometric.

45

Valuing a claim on SaQb

The squared security, S2, is a special case of Proposition 20.4.

When S = Q, a = b = 1, and = 1, the covariance term becomes

This gives us the same result as equation (20.35) for the forward price for a squared stock.

2SQSab

Page 46: 1 Chapter 20 Brownian Motion and Itô’s Lemma. 2 Introduction Stock and other asset prices are commonly assumed to follow a stochastic process called geometric.

46

Valuing a claim on SaQb

Proposition 20.4 can be generalized.

Suppose there are n stocks, each of which follows the process

(20.40)

where dzidzj = ijdt. Let

(20.41)

The forward price for V is then

(20.42)

iiiii

i dzdtS

dS )(

n

i

aiiStV

1)(

n

i

aaaiTT

n

i

n

ij jijiiji eSFVF

1

,0,0

1

1 1)]([)(

Page 47: 1 Chapter 20 Brownian Motion and Itô’s Lemma. 2 Introduction Stock and other asset prices are commonly assumed to follow a stochastic process called geometric.

47

Jumps in the Stock Price

One objection to the Brownian process as a model of the stock price is that Brownian paths are continuous—there are no discrete jumps in the stock price.

In practice, asset prices occasionally seem to jump (e.g., on October 19, 1987).

One way to model such jumps is by using the Poisson distribution mixed with a standard Brownian process.

Page 48: 1 Chapter 20 Brownian Motion and Itô’s Lemma. 2 Introduction Stock and other asset prices are commonly assumed to follow a stochastic process called geometric.

48

Jumps in the Stock Price

Let q(t) represent the cumulative jump and dq the change in the cumulative jump.

When there is no jump, dq = 0.

When there is a jump, we let the random variable Y denote the magnitude of the jump, and k = E(Y) – 1 is then the expected percentage change in the stock price.

If is the expected number of jumps per unit time over an interval dt, then

Prob(jump) = dt

Prob(no jump) = 1 – dt

Page 49: 1 Chapter 20 Brownian Motion and Itô’s Lemma. 2 Introduction Stock and other asset prices are commonly assumed to follow a stochastic process called geometric.

49

Jumps in the Stock Price

We can write the stock price process as

dS(t)/S(t) = ( – k)dt + dZ + dq (20.43)

where

0 if there is no jump

dq =

Y-1 if there is a jump

and E(dq) = kdt.

When no jump is occurring, the stock price S evolves as geometric Brownian motion. When the jump occurs, the new stock price is YS.

Page 50: 1 Chapter 20 Brownian Motion and Itô’s Lemma. 2 Introduction Stock and other asset prices are commonly assumed to follow a stochastic process called geometric.

50

Example of Jumps in the Process

0

10

20

30

40

50

60

70

80

0 1000 2000 3000 4000 5000 6000

Page 51: 1 Chapter 20 Brownian Motion and Itô’s Lemma. 2 Introduction Stock and other asset prices are commonly assumed to follow a stochastic process called geometric.

51

Jumps in the Stock Price

Proposition 20.5 Suppose an asset follows equation (20.43). If C(S, t) is a twice continuously differentiable function of the stock price, the process followed by C is

(20.44)

The last term in the equation is the expected change in the option price conditional on the jump times the probability of the jump.

)] ,() ,([2

1) ,( 22 tSCtSYCEdtCdtSCdSCtSdC YtSSS