Ch11

27
Chapter Eleven Asset Markets

Transcript of Ch11

Page 1: Ch11

Chapter Eleven

Asset Markets

Page 2: Ch11

Assets

An asset is a commodity that provides a flow of services over time.

E.g. a house, or a computer. A financial asset provides a flow of

money over time -- a security.

Page 3: Ch11

Assets

Typically asset values are uncertain. Incorporating uncertainty is difficult at this stage so we will instead study assets assuming that we can see the future with perfect certainty.

Page 4: Ch11

Selling An Asset

Q: When should an asset be sold? When its value is at a maximum? No. Why not?

Page 5: Ch11

Selling An Asset

Suppose the value of an asset changes with time according to

V t t t( ) 1000 1000 10 2

Page 6: Ch11

Selling An Asset

0 10 20 30 40 50 60-1000

4000

9000

14000

19000

24000

Value

Years

Page 7: Ch11

Selling An Asset

V t t t( ) 1000 1000 10 2

Maximum value occurs whenV t t'( ) 1000 20 0

That is, when t = 50.

Page 8: Ch11

Selling An Asset

0 10 20 30 40 50 60-1000

4000

9000

14000

19000

24000

Value

Years

Max. valueof $24,000is reachedat year 50.

Page 9: Ch11

Selling An Asset

The rate-of-return in year t is the income earned by the asset in year t as a fraction of its value in year t.

E.g. if an asset valued at $1,000 earns $100 then its rate-of-return is 10%.

Page 10: Ch11

Selling An Asset

Q: Suppose the interest rate is 10%. When should the asset be sold?

A: When the rate-of-return to holding the asset falls to 10%.

Then it is better to sell the asset and put the proceeds in the bank to earn a 10% rate-of-return from interest.

Page 11: Ch11

Selling An AssetThe rate-of-return of the asset at time t is

V tV t'( )( ).

In our example,.t10t10001000)t(V 2

V t t'( ) 1000 20 0

V tV t

t

t t

'( )( )

.

1000 20

1000 1000 10 2so

Page 12: Ch11

Selling An Asset

The asset should be sold when

V tV t

t

t t

'( )( )

1000 20

1000 1000 100 1

2

That is, when t = 10.

Page 13: Ch11

Selling An Asset

0 10 20 30 40 50 60-1000

4000

9000

14000

19000

24000

Value

Years

Max. valueof $24,000is reachedat year 50.

slope= 0.1

Page 14: Ch11

Selling An Asset

0 10 20 30 40 50 60-1000

4000

9000

14000

19000

24000

Value

Years

Max. valueof $24,000is reachedat year 50.Sell at 10 years

even though theasset’s value isonly $8,000.

slope= 0.1

Page 15: Ch11

Selling An Asset

What is the payoff at year 50 from selling at year 10 and then investing the $8,000 at 10% per year for the remaining 40 years?

Page 16: Ch11

Selling An Asset

What is the payoff at year 50 from selling at year 10 and then investing the $8,000 at 10% per year for the remaining 40 years?

$8, ( ) $362, $24,000 1 0 1 074 00040

Page 17: Ch11

Selling An Asset

So the time at which an asset should besold is determined by

Rate-of-Return = r, the interest rate.

Page 18: Ch11

Arbitrage Arbitrage is trading for profit in

commodities which are not used for consumption.

E.g. buying and selling stocks, bonds, or stamps.

No uncertainty all profit opportunities will be found. What does this imply for prices over time?

Page 19: Ch11

Arbitrage

The price today of an asset is p0. Its price tomorrow will be p1. Should it be sold now?

The rate-of-return from holding the asset is

I.e.

Rp p

p 1 0

0

( ) .1 0 1 R p p

Page 20: Ch11

Arbitrage

Sell the asset now for $p0, put the money in the bank to earn interest at rate r and tomorrow you have

( ) .1 0 r p

Page 21: Ch11

Arbitrage

When is not selling best? When

I.e. if the rate-or-return to holding the asset the interest rate, then keep the asset.

And if then

so sell now for $p0.

( ) ( ) .1 10 0 R p r p

R r

R r( ) ( )1 10 0 R p r p

Page 22: Ch11

Arbitrage

If all asset markets are in equilibrium then for every asset.

Hence, for every asset, today’s price p0 and tomorrow’s price p1 satisfy

R r

p r p1 01 ( ) .

Page 23: Ch11

Arbitrage

p r p1 01 ( )

I.e. tomorrow’s price is the future-value oftoday’s price. Equivalently,

pp

r01

1

.

I.e. today’s price is the present-valueof tomorrow’s price.

Page 24: Ch11

Arbitrage in Bonds

Bonds “pay interest”. Yet, when the interest rate paid by banks rises, the market prices of bonds fall. Why?

Page 25: Ch11

Arbitrage in Bonds A bond pays a fixed stream of payments

of $x per year, no matter the interest rate paid by banks.

At an initial equilibrium the rate-of-return to holding a bond must be R = r’, the initial bank interest rate.

If the bank interest rate rises to r” > r’ then r” > R and the bond should be sold.

Sales of bonds lower their market prices.

Page 26: Ch11

Taxation of Asset Returns

rb is the before-tax rate-of-return of a taxable asset.

re is the rate-of-return of a tax exempt asset.

t is the tax rate. The no-arbitrage rule is:

(1 - t)rb = re

I.e. after-tax rates-of-return are equal.

Page 27: Ch11

Financial Intermediaries

Banks, brokerages etc.

– facilitate trades between people with different levels of impatience

– patient people (savers) lend funds to impatient people (borrowers) in exchange for a rate-of-return on the loaned funds.

– both groups are better off.