The well-travelled yogurt pot_lessons for new freight transport policies and regional...

download The well-travelled yogurt pot_lessons for new freight transport policies and regional production_Stefanie Böge

of 41

Transcript of The well-travelled yogurt pot_lessons for new freight transport policies and regional...

  • 8/2/2019 The well-travelled yogurt pot_lessons for new freight transport policies and regional production_Stefanie Bge

    1/41

    IntroductionFreight transport on roads has increased greatly over thelast few decades. But in genera l, the volume of roadfreight expressed in tonnes is stagnat ing, whereas freighttransport activity (the product of weight and distance) isincreasing. This means that products are transportedover longer distances. Only the freight transport activityfollows the mainstream of economic development, and isnot the result of more production. It is the spatialspreading and the intensity of exchange in the economythat has g rown, the quantity which is shipped has not

    increased in the same manner as the distances (Hesse,1991, p. 3).

    Such structural changes, as shown here for the case ofthe growth of road freight transportation, are alsodecisive determinants of the environmental and socialimpacts. Even today there are capacity limits whichbecome evident in the environmental field in thedestruction of natural resources and in the social field indecreasing quality of life. Particularly environmentallysensitive nat ural areas (e.g. the Alps), or towns andconurbations suffer the main burdens of traffic and its

    consequences.

    At the same time the activity of road freight traffic willincrease dramatically: according to some forecasts, thetotal volume will increase by more than 70 per cent inGermany. The transfrontier volume, which depends onfreight transport in the Single European Market, isexpected to increase by even more than 100 per cent(Whitelegg, 1990, p. 26).

    But this forecasted growth, towards which all trendspoint, is insupportable because there are physical limits.In the economic sphere this is mainly the impossibility ofoverburdening the infrastructure even more. Production

    concepts such as just -in-time product ion (in whichproduction-synchronized transportation takes place inorder to synchronize the production process) do not workany more, because there is no longer any reliability inroad transport.

    One suggest ion to solve the problem in road freighttransport is to include the true costs in the transportat ioncosts. Today, large parts of transportation costsare externalized. This means they are transferred tothe public infrastructure and natural environment.

    These costs have to be paid by todays society and bythose which follow. An adequate use of scarce meansof production (in this case the natural and humanenvironments) can only be achieved if all costs are takeninto consideration and if all these costs are included in thesupply prices. (Teufel, 1989; 1991, has es timated theexternal costs of freight transport.)

    As a result of the Single European Market and thederegulation of transportation, the need to externalizeinternal costs has become urgent. In Germany inparticular, the prices will mirror the actual costs less and

    less. As a result, environmental and social impacts aregrowing more and more. Even on straightforwardeconomic grounds, there are signs that the current systemis highly inefficient.

    An environmentally sound and socially equitableeconomy (including the transportation of goods) canbe realized only by the manufacturers themselves.A prerequisite to this is the knowledge of the effects andconnections of production processes internal and externalto manufacturing as implemented by freight transport.

    In this article, I shall describe how manufacturers candocument and evaluate the freight transpor tat ion ofgoods. This meth odology demonstr ates how freighttransport can be organized in a way which iseconomically efficient, environmentally responsible andkind to human lifestyles.

    7THE WELL-TRAVELLED YOGURT POT

    The well-travelled yogurt pot:lessons for new freight transport policies and regionalproductionStefanie Bge

    Investigates what can be done to cater for the increase in freight transport on roads

    World Transport Policy & Practice, Vol. 1 No. 1, 1995, pp. 7-11 MCB University Press Limited, 1352-7614

  • 8/2/2019 The well-travelled yogurt pot_lessons for new freight transport policies and regional production_Stefanie Bge

    2/41

    Product- related transportation analysisA detailed analysis technique addressing transportation

    processes at the microeconomic level still does not exist.In a general environmental analysis or eco-balance of aproduction method (or single product), transportationprocesses as the basis of any production have to beanalysed. Their effects on the natural and socialenvironment are large and growing and call for specialattention.

    The aim of the transportation analysis is to model, as faras possible, all transportat ion processes in the life cycle ofa product, concentrating on the activities of themanufacturer. The result shows how far one unit productwas transported (by a lorry) and the conditions and

    impacts of this products specific transportation processin a quantitative or descriptive way (e.g. transportationcosts, the reliability of transportation, the quality of theproduct, environmental and social impacts). Only then isit guaranteed that the manufacturer can react to futuredevelopments in the tr ansp ort s ector, and do so in apreventive way for the environment.

    At the same time, this analysis is oriented towards theconsumer, as this can show the implications of theproduction and consumption of products. Only then canthe consumers develop an environmentally sound

    consumption behaviour. This concept of a product-relatedtranspor tation analysis has been realized for the firsttime by a milk manufacturer in southern Germany.

    The results of the transportati on analysisIn this analysis, a number of milk products includingstrawberry yogurt weighing 150g in a recyclable glass jarwere examined. In this examination all ingredients of theproduct are included, e.g. milk, jam, sugar and thepackaging, e.g. the glass container, paper label,aluminium cover, cardboard box and cardboard sheets,

    glue and foil.

    The product does not have unusual transportrequirements and may be regarded as typical of the foodsector. The results are summarized under the headings:space-specific, product-specific and vehicle-specific.

    Space-specifi c resultsFigure 1 shows the transportation relations of theingredients (including the main ingredients of thesubcontractors) and of the whole product to distributionoutlets in southern Germany.

    Product-specific resultsIn the following analysis, trip segments per product inmetres (transport intensity) are used. The total distancetravelled by all the components is related to the number ofunits moved and the different segments of the total trip to

    reveal an average distance in metres per trip segment perunit (i.e. 1 150g pot of strawberry yogurt). The resultsare shown in Table I.

    If one 150g strawberry yogurt is purchased in asupermarket in southern Germany, one of the ingredientswhich could be listed on the container is 9.2m of lorrymovement.

    Vehicle-specific resultsTo bring one truckload of product to a distribution outletin southern Germany, one theoretical truck (includingall examined r elationships ) must be moved 1,005km.In 1992, theoretically, 24 fully packed lorries with 150gpots of strawberry yogurt had to be moved each over this

    distance to supply the southern German area with thisproduct.

    Effects of product- related distanceObviously large trip segments are problematic notonly for the futu re manufactu rer, but also for todaysnatu ral and social environment, par ticularly in cities.Simultaneously the behaviour of consumers supports thetrend towards increasing freight transport on roads.

    The reliability and r apidity with which the necessarygoods for production are transported on roads alsodepends on the motor vehicle density on the roads used.Long distances represent additional risk factors forreliable and punctual supplies and deliveries of theinputs. These risks are likely to increase in the futurebecause vehicle density is increasing. In peak times, theroads are continuously overloaded.

    Higher tr ansportat ion costs, which depend largely onhigher petrol or diesel costs, have considerable impactson the internal cost structures of manufacturers. With theincrease of diesel costs in which the external costs areinternalized so far as possible, the total transport costs ofthe yogurt manufacturer would increase by about 21-65

    per cent.

    The energy consumption, pollutant emissions and theeffects on the natural environment from road freighttraffic entail the increasing use of natural resources andincreasing environmental degradation. The calculatedtrip segments in this transportation analysis give a clueas to how a daily product contributes to the increasingenvironmental pollution with its transportation process.

    On the basis of the specific distance covered, one 150gstr awberry yogurt has used 0.004 litres diesel, if it is

    distributed in southern Germany. To sell the salesquantities for 1992, 24 lorries had to be used and for them10,200 litres diesel.

    Of course, the examined product has only a low share ofthe pollutant emissions caused by all freight traffic. Since

    8 WORLD TRANSPORT POLICY & PRACTICE 1,1

  • 8/2/2019 The well-travelled yogurt pot_lessons for new freight transport policies and regional production_Stefanie Bge

    3/41

    all products moved around over increasingly longerdistances have a negative environmental impact, thepollution caused is still serious, e.g. with 22.8g/tkm NOx,1.9g/tkm sulphur dioxide and 1.52g/tkm dust. The totalpollution associated with a shopping trolley full ofpurchases at a supermarket checkout is a large

    component of total pollution when all such events arecalculated over the whole population and the whole year.

    Emissions from the traffic sector have negative effects onhuman health, especially for children (Holzapfel, 1991,p. 239). These emissions are carcinogenic, they cause

    9THE WELL-TRAVELLED YOGURT POT

    Key:

    Niebll

    Uetersen

    LneburgHamburgVarel

    Berlin

    AachenFrechen

    Dsseldorf

    Amsterdam

    NeuburgStuttgart

    Kulmbach

    Weiden

    Cologne

    Resin

    Pa

    per

    Y o

    g u

    r t c u

    l t u r e s

    Strawbe

    rriesCorn/w

    heatpo

    wder

    Glu

    efo

    rcar

    db

    oard

    box

    Aluminium

    Alumi

    nium

    cove

    r

    PaperGlass jarM

    ilk

    Plastic

    grains

    Corn

    /wh

    eatp

    owd

    er

    Corn/

    wheatpow

    der

    Cardboardbox

    Quartzsand

    paper

    Gluefor

    label

    Plasticgrains

    Jam

    Subcontractor to manufacturer Inputs fromcatchment area

    Subcontractor to subcontractor Manufacturer, distributionoutlets (southern Germany)

    Source: Stefanie Bge, Wuppertal Institut 1993

    Sugar 7.8 per cent

    Yogurt cultures 0.03 per cent

    Jam 13.3 per cent

    Milk 78.9 per centGlass jar 90.1 per cent

    Cardboard sheets6.6 per cent

    Cardboard 2 per cent

    Label 0.5 per centAluminum cover0.4 per cent

    Plastic foil 0.1 per cent

    Glue for cardboard box0.1 per cent

    Glue for label 0.2 per cent

    PackagingProduct

    Poland

    Sugar beat

    Offenau

    Figure 1. Transportation relationships

  • 8/2/2019 The well-travelled yogurt pot_lessons for new freight transport policies and regional production_Stefanie Bge

    4/41

    respiratory diseases and circulatory disorders. Some react

    with each other and form secondary air pollutants such asozone and smog. They also have adverse health effects.

    Adverse affects on human living space caused by freightshipments become clear mainly in cities and con-urba tions. Space used by motorized traffic can not beused for parks, playgrounds, pedestrian or bicycle traffic.Urban planning depends on the demand of traffic,especially on freight traffic. The width of roads has beenplanned according to their demands.

    Also the recreation areas are affected by the land use of

    (freight) traffic. Urban recreation and recreation areas inthe immediate vicinity of cities are affected because ofpollutant emissions, noise and monotonous planning ofthe urban structure. If the recreation value decreases inand around cities, human beings drive out and use distantrecreation areas. And as a result, in these areas, noise alsoincreases, visual impairments by road building increasesand destroys the landscape.

    Healthy food, a calm environment and fresh air areimportant aspects for a healthy lifestyle, as impressivelyillustrated by the advertising pictures. But in reality the

    facts of transportation of each product give quite adifferent picture.

    But at the sa me time it is remarkable, that so-calledenvironmental products are not environmental, if thedistances travelled are included. Specifically, the greaterdistances are from the manufacturer to the supermarket.The longer the dist ances are for a product, the moreenvironmental impacts result. The demand of theconsumers to buy everything everywhere and at any timehas direct consequences on freight shipment. Increasingdemands in th is direction increase the effects on t he

    environment and on lifestyle. The existing productionsystem based on the externalization of costs is supported.Consumer behaviour plays a part in forming productionsand distr ibution systems. Last but not least, there is nodetailed information for consumers on the connectionsbetween production and consumption.

    ConclusionProduct-related transportation analysis is aimed at themanufacturing and distribution system and is intendedto reveal the import ance of distance intensity in thesystem of production, distribution and consumption. Thisin turn identifies possibilities for reorganizing productionsystems to reduce their impact on the social and naturalenvironment.

    One cannot suppose that only the manufacturer shouldshow good will in realizing an environmental economy bytaking the transportation procedures into account. It is afact that policy has to dictate other general conditionswhich motivate environmentally and socially responsibleproduction and transportation. The consumers, on the

    basis of appropriate information and changed behaviourin consumption, can contribute only to a certain extent, tocreate a better environment.

    In general, there are three basic options for manufac-turers:

    (1) Use inputs from nearer subcontractors.

    (2) Improve existing transportation vehicles.

    (3) Shift to more environmentally s ound freightshipment vehicles.

    To reduce distribution shipments fundamentally, there is

    the possibility to create decentralized or regionalproduction structures. To reduce distances intransportat ion processes from manufacturing to trademeans in the end a reduction of transport costs for themanufacturer. The more decentralized the productionstructures, the faster an environmentally sound andeconomically efficient freight transport system can beimplemented. This will also st imulate greater levels ofsocial equity in reinvigorated regional economies. Thiscannot be achieved by technical optimization of vehiclesalone, although that is a desirable contribution.

    In addition, policy has to develop and put in to effectmeasures to create appropriate general conditions. Tolimit freight traffic growth and organize it in anenvironmental and social way, there is a debate based onthree points:

    (1) reduction of trips in business/commercial traffic;

    (2) improvement of vehicles and infrastructure;

    (3) shift to other modes of transport.

    It is profitable to build small freight traffic anddistr ibution centres a llowing bett er co-ordination offreight movements and avoidance of unnecessary

    shipments. In general, measures such as the inter-nalization of external costs in freight shipment with achange in fuel and motor vehicle taxes as well asfreight taxes for certain goods, are necessary.Fundamental, far-reaching measures, such as therealization of decentralized urban settlement and

    10 WORLD TRANSPORT POLICY & PRACTICE 1,1

    Trip segment Metres

    Subcontractor 5.1

    Manufacturer 3.1

    Trade 1.0

    Total distance 9.2

    Table I. Distance in metres per trip segment per unit (1 150g pot of strawberry yogurt)

  • 8/2/2019 The well-travelled yogurt pot_lessons for new freight transport policies and regional production_Stefanie Bge

    5/41

    economic structures with short distances should,however, receive priority.

    At the same time the information of consumers has to beimproved in the direction of comprehensive productinformation, which includes the transportation processesof a product. Manufacturers should be encouraged to givetheir products a regional label, issued by a governmentorganization. This label can prove that the ingredients ofa product come are locally or regionally sourced, e.g. 80per cent from a particular region. Product-relatedtrans porta tion analysis can give the basis for such ascheme. With such a label, the consumer can see whetherhe/she is buying a product with less distance or moredistance.

    Many consumers also have the intention of doingsomething to create a better environment. But thisbetter behaviour must first be assessed critically,because consumption always has an effect on theenvironment and is concerned with the ways ofmanufacturing products. Only with direct changes in thebehaviour and basic changes in attitudes can anenvironmentally sound consumption really be practised.

    The strawberry yogurt included a new ingredient:a distance of approximately 10m of lorry movement. This

    does not seem a lot, but it is enough to make looking inyour own trolley or refrigerator worthwhile. In it there isa great sum of distances, which mostly result fromdistant manufacturing of these products. Besides theconsumption of these products, distances are consumed,which have, because of the means of transportation (thelorry), considerable effects on the natura l and humanenvironment.

    Those negative effects of products which are the result oftheir transportation processes can be reduced by payingattention to buying regional and seasonal products.Ecological products a re regionally and seasonallydifferentiated products. If the food is purchased whichhas been grown in the neighbourhood and in theappropriate season, long distances of freight shipmentare also avoided.

    The existing and impending environmental disast er,which depends also on road freight shipment, has

    meanwhile been realized by every person with anydegree of awareness. The situation is becoming worse,because of an outdated at titude towards t he existing

    standard of life or prosperity predominates whichdepends on mass production and mass consumption.

    The direction for a changed awareness leading to alifestyle which does not make future generations livesuntenable, has to be found. This analysis contributes tothis aim by showing connections between freighttransportation, economy and consumer behaviour andthe resulting effects on the natural and humanenvironment. It is clear that these effects contribute to aprogressive destruction of space and with that, to adestruction of the foundation of life and of its quality.

    References

    Hesse, M. (1991), Umweltbelastung durch strukturellen Wandel Die Entwicklung des Wirtschaftsverkehrs aus kologisch konomischer Sicht (Environmental Impacts of StructuralChange An Ecological/Economical Perspective onDevelopment of Industrial Transport), Institut frkologische Wirts chaftsforschung (IW), Diskussions-papier 6/91 des IW, Berlin.

    Holzapfel, H. (1991), Europischer Binnenmarkt:

    Auswirkungen auf den Gterverkehr (The Europeaninternal market: impacts on freight transportation), inkologie, J. (1992), Environmental Yearbook 1992, Munich.

    Teufel, D. (1989), Gesellschaftliche Kosten des Straen-gterverkehrs (The Social Costs of Road Freight Transport),Umwelt- und Pr ognose-Institu t Heidelberg (UPI), UPI-Bericht Nr. 14, Heidelberg, May.

    Teufel, D. (1991),Umweltwirkungen von Finanzinstrumenten imVerkehrsbereich (Environmental Impacts of FinancialInstruments in the Transport Sector), Umwelt- undPrognose-Institut Heidelberg (UPI), UPI-Bericht Nr. 21,Heidelberg, January.

    Whitelegg, J. (1990), Auswirkungen der EG-Politik auf denGtertransport und die Folgen fr Nordrhein-Westfalen(Impacts of EC Policy on Freight Transport and theConsequences for the German Land of North Rhine-Westphaliae). Im Auftrag des Instituts fr Landes- undStadtentwicklungsforschung des Landes Nordrhein-Westfalen, Dortmund.

    11THE WELL-TRAVELLED YOGURT POT

    Stefanie Bge is based at the Wuppertal Institute for Climate, Environment and Energy, Wuppertal, Germany.

  • 8/2/2019 The well-travelled yogurt pot_lessons for new freight transport policies and regional production_Stefanie Bge

    6/41

    The collapse of the Los Angeles freeways could be asymbol of the end of this technology as the basis of citytransport. Some of the 13 LA freeways which lie in ruinsfrom the recent earthquake are being rebuilt, but the mostdamaged could be removed forever. The two in SanFrancisco which collapsed five years ago have not beenrebuilt. The community has demanded somethingdifferent.

    Since Hitler bu ilt the first autobahn in the 1930s, thefreeway has been controversial. The gigantism of thearchitecture appeals to macho empire builders only thehigh-rise building has similar massive proportions.Nature has tended to level such gigantism throughouthistory. It has now revealed the limits of the highwayengineer and in doing so makes us look again at how weshould build cities.

    Even before the earthquake in Los Angeles, the freewaywas receiving substantial criticism. 1993 saw the openingof the last new freeway in Los Angeles. The CenturyFreeway, costing some US$200 million per km to build,revealed that such structures had exhausted the politicaland financial will of citizens. Only 18 per cent of people ina Californian s urvey believe that freeways solve thetraffic congestion problem (Franz, 1989). Robert Reinholdconcluded a story on the Century Freeway in the NewYork Timesby saying: few cities will soon try again tobuild highways through their urban cores. Some of theLA freeways will no doubt be rebuilt and reopened, butthe back of the urban freeway is now broken figurativelyas well as literally.

    This article will examine some of the trends in providingalternatives to the urban freeway in the UK, USA andAustralia where there appears to be the acceptance(perhaps a little reluctan tly) that a new paradigm isemerging on how to build cities. These countries aresignificant as they are probably the ones which in thepast, have shown the greatest commitment to the freeway.

    Little reference is made to European and Asian cities asthe majority of these moved some decades ago to thisdifferent p aradigm though exceptions can always be

    found.

    What is the alternative?In San Francisco, the Embarcadero Freeway and theCypress Freeway have not been rebuilt because thecommunity has revolted against their impact and becausealternative approaches do exist. Traffic demandmanagement is now seen as necessary and, together withinnovative public transport, is providing access in wayswhich are much more in tune with community ideals,particularly when it is provided in close association withsensitive land development that promotes pedestrian andbicycle access. T his t hree-sided approach demandmanagement, upgraded tr ansit and non-car-based landdevelopment is the basic alternative to the urbanfreeway.

    Business interests in San Francisco were desperatelydemanding the Embarcadero Freeway was rebuilt after itwas damaged five years ago. After a few years, however,they found their trade was not diminished and could infact be improved, along with the whole city, if thewaterfront freeway was removed. The role of public

    transport in a city is usually underestimated as is theability of land uses to adjust to new constraints.

    Los Angeles once had the most extensive and efficientpublic transport in the world. In the 1930s, the famous redtrolleys (along with the transit systems in 44 other cities)were bought up by General Motors, Firestone Tyres andStandard Oil and closed down. The LA freeway era wasborn in the wake of this decision. It was not however acommunity decision but a commercial one and illegal atthat. The consortium was found to have broken anti-trustlaws and was fined $5,000.

    Public transport once worked well in LA and continues toprovide a softer and more sustainable solution to a citysaccessibility. In particular, modern light rail can providethe city centre and cross-city destinations that arerequired. European cities such as Zurich and Stockholm

    12 WORLD TRANSPORT POLICY & PRACTICE 1,1

    The end of the urban freewayPeter NewmanSupport for the construction and maintenance of freeways has decreased

    World Transport Policy & Practice, Vol. 1 No. 1, 1995, pp. 12-19 MCB University Press Limited, 1352-7614

  • 8/2/2019 The well-travelled yogurt pot_lessons for new freight transport policies and regional production_Stefanie Bge

    7/41

    and Asian cities such as Singapore and Hong Kong haveshown that there is no shame in showing a preference forpublic transport other than freeways.

    For freight, these cities (particularly in Europe) do havegood roads, though rarely do they have freeways passingthrough their cities. In The Netherlands, there is a strongemphasis on limiting car use so that freight can havebetter access, and limiting freight movements byensuring that high freight intensity land uses are kept toareas with good road access rather than having to buildmore roads. At the same time, they have strong land useplanning regulations which ensure high people-intensityuses are built around good transit. This process is calledThe right business in the right place (Ministry of

    Housing et al., 1991). Dutch cities are wealthy, yet theyhave much fewer cars in use than most cities and have noplans to build a massive freeway network in their much-loved cities. Such a concept would be seen as destroyingtheir major economic asset. Instead there are a number ofDutch cities which see their future as so far away fromthe urban freeway scenario that they are leadingmembers of the Car Free City movement.

    Even in Los Angeles today the new order is under way.At the same time that it had begun to see the imposs-ibility of building ever-greater capacity for automobiles,

    the first evidence of the new paradigm was appearing. In1993, its new subway opened, light rail is being builtagain along old trolley routes and heavy rail passengertrains are being introduced onto freight lines. When thefreeways came down, the new rail systems (all of whichsurvived) were flooded with passengers, many of whomthe LA transit operators believe are there to stay.Tollways and parking controls are being phased in toreduce traffic, together with other demand managementand the first plans for transit-supportive land use areappearing. As the new order gains momentum, therationale for the urban freeway is losing its last shreds of

    credibility, particularly in the light of new economicanalyses.

    New economic awarenessThere has always been an awareness that urban freewayscause environmental and s ocial dama ge (with s omeconfusion about their role in causing more emissions andfuel use, see Newman and Kenworthy, 1988). But this hasbeen acceptably traded off by decision makers who sawthe economic gains of the extra mobility. Now there aresignificant questions about the economic benefits to be

    gained from urban freeways, even if a government is ableto find the huge capital like that as sociated with t heCentury Freeway.

    The accepted myth for most governments, at least in theEnglish-speaking world, has been that transit systems

    are inherently a waste of money, while road funding feedsthe economy. The reality appears to be the opposite, atleast in cities. Yet it appears that in most countries, the

    acceptance of this myth has not come about from analysisor evaluation but merely from assertions, often dressedup in scientific form in the guise of a model par ticularlyin the UK, USA and Australia.

    In the UK, Oliver Tickell tried to find the economic basisof the Governments Roads for Prosperity programme(Tickell, 1993). He examined the direct employment andthe economic flow-ons. He found very poor value formoney as a job creator compared with other investments 66,000-80,000 was needed to employ one person inroad building compared with 30,000-50,000 for railways

    and 20,000-40,000 for building houses and just 9,000-18,000 for installing domestic insulation. Roads are builtby machines not men was the comment from theemployment secretary Lord Young.

    Even with a poor record in employment, roads may stilllead to prosperity through improving economic activity.Unfortunately the economic flow-ons are not so obviouseither. Tickell (1993) examined the claim that congestionis costing UK business 15 billion a year (similar claimsare made in the Industry Commission report inAustralia). He found only anecdotal support for the

    claim, and the Department of Transport was equallyshort on hard data to back up its view that prosperityfollows where roads lead. For example, no part ofBirmingham is more than five miles from a motorway butas Tickell says: If access by road is the key to economicprosperity then Birmingham should be the wealthiestcity in Britain. It is not. You can go even further and seethat Liverpool, Britains most advanced economic basketcase, is well served by roads. The UK Depar tment ofTransport are now saying: the effectiveness of transportpolicy in stimulating regional growth may be somewhatlimited. This very guarded comment is not the

    conclusion of most roads-based recovery approacheswhich have been standard fare from this Department forthe past 40 years.

    Whitelegg (1993) examined a series of major UK roadbuilding projects (M58 and M62 in particular) which havefailed to materialize economic benefits and concluded:There is simply no evidence of the claimed link betweenaccess and employment or economic prosperity. Theemperor has no clothes.

    Whitelegg concludes that the factor which most attracts

    businesses to a locality is a high quality environment.He says:

    My advice to local authorities is to go for clean air, protectedcountryside and quiet residential areas. These are the assetsthat stimulate economic development. Unfortunately, toomany authorities are providing the opposite: an area with

    13THE END OF THE URBAN FREEWAY

  • 8/2/2019 The well-travelled yogurt pot_lessons for new freight transport policies and regional production_Stefanie Bge

    8/41

    terrific accessibility, but which is noisy, polluted, and criss-crossed with motorways.

    He points out that areas such as Covent Garden inLondon or York are thriving economically but have verypoor road access. The same experience has been wellknown in Europe for some time. Roberts (1989) found thatthose European cities which had slowed their roadsystems and not expanded capacity had all benefitedeconomically. Cities, says Roberts, must be user friendlyand users in the end are pedestrians. In Australia, thislink between controlling the automobile and economicsuccess can now be seen in many cities, for example therevival of Fremantle owes as much to the s topping ofmajor road proposals as anything, because several roadswere planned which would have destroyed its unique

    heritage and character.

    The mechanism for how improving the urbanenvironment rather than building roads leads to a bettereconomy is not difficult to understand. Road constructionleads to dispersal of land uses and, together with thegreater road capacity, facilitates a rapid growth in caruse. The resulting congestion sets up a never-endingspiral in demand for road space. As Phil Goodwin fromOxfords Transport Studies Unit says, to try and buildour way out of congestion is impossible, since the rate atwhich traffic levels are likely to increase will far outpaceany realistic construction programme. But even beforethe limits t o const ruction are met, the city will haveexperienced significant reductions in the quality of itsurban environment, which today translate directly intoreduced economic performance.

    The situation in Los Angeles illustrates this well, with themost extensive set of freeways the world has ever seenand yet the city has huge problems with traffic. It is alsonow facing serious economic decline as it s militar yspending is cut back and a middle class flight from thecity over the past decade is now apparent, owing to itspoor environment (Gobor, 1993).

    In a post-industrial city, the quality of the environment iscritical to a citys success and t he role of transport iscrucial to this an overemphasis on road building and anunder emphasis on public transport and a pedestrianenvironment, can spin a city into a decline phase, whetherit be Bangkok, Los Angeles or Sydney.

    For Britain, the conclusion to this debate on how trans-port impacts on the economy was a new Governmentapproach summarized by Tickell (1993) as:

    a transport s trategy that restrains traffic, that reduces the

    need for travel and provides high quality transportalternatives.

    Such s tatements are not a lways appearing from UKpublic servants and politicians but it is obvious frommajor reports such as Sustainable Development: The UKStrategy(Secretary of State for the Environment, 1994)

    and the abandonment of most of Londons controversialmotorways, that the paradigm has substantially shifted.

    Similar economic work to that in the UK has been goingon in the USA. Aschauer (1989) has calculated that forevery $1 million invested in road funding, private sectorcapital productivity increases 0.24 per cent and privatesector total factor productivity increases by 0.27 per cent.This has been highlighted by the road lobby groupAustralian Automobile Association in its recent report onroad funding (AAA, 1994). However they do not recordAschauers (Aschauer and Campbell, 1991) later study ontransit investment where he concludes:

    Within the broad category of transportation spending, theevidence indicates that public transit spending carries more

    potential to stimulate long run economic growth than doeshighway spending.

    The major findings of Aschauer and Campbells s tudywere:

    q Transit spending has more than twice thepotential to improve worker productivity thandoes highway spending:

    A ten-year, $100 billion increase in transitinvestment would yield improved workeroutput valued at $52l billion; a comparableexpenditure on highways would yield $237billion.

    The highest annual level of net benefits fromsuch an increase in transit would be $15 billionin the year 2000; the highest annual level of netbenefits for highway spending would be $7billion, also in the year 2000.

    In the peak year, the productivity of eachAmerican worker would be increased by $185from transit spending versus $87 fromhighway spending.

    q Net economic benefits from transit expendituresoccur sooner for the economy as a whole than do

    net benefits from highway expenditures.As well as these critical assessments of road fundingthere is a growing movement to account more correctlyfor t he total costs of transport , in pa rticular how toaccount for the full costs of feeding government moneyinto the increased use of private motor vehicles. Table I isa summary of the studies we have collected, mostly fromUS cities but also from Europe.

    Our own calculations on a comparison of the total costs oftransport also reveal a very different story to the abovemyth concerning transits inherent economic problems.Table II shows how car, bus and rail costs vary when

    their total costs are considered.

    These costs do not consider the added benefits due toland development which is inherently more concentratedaround transit rather than road systems. There are somewho do not accept that road developments lead to more

    14 WORLD TRANSPORT POLICY & PRACTICE 1,1

  • 8/2/2019 The well-travelled yogurt pot_lessons for new freight transport policies and regional production_Stefanie Bge

    9/41

    dispersed cities, though the evidence is very suggestive ofthis in historical studies and in correlations betweenlevels of road provision, levels of road use and levels ofurban dispersal as well as urban concentration related togood transit levels (Naess, 1993; Newman and Kenworthy,1989, Newman et al., 1992). The study by Naess (1993)confirms all the patterns of our global cities comparison

    through a study of 22 Nordic cities.

    The first outlines of theory showing how transit helps toslow urban dispersal and thus make the city moreeconomically efficient, or on the other hand, howextensive road systems lead to dispersed cities which arenot so economically efficient, has been suggest ed byJacobs (1984) and Frost (1991). They suggest this is due toexcessive commitment to suburban infrastructure whichis a significant opportunity cost a s well as the costsoutlined above. We have summarized the possiblemechanisms in Figure 1.

    The role of public transport (particularly rail) in helpingto reverse this process is strongly supported by Cervero(1992), who concludes t hat rail s yst ems provide themarket incentive for concentrating land use so oftendesired by cities. He suggests that car-based cities arehaving to move to extraordinary levels of control overprivate enterprise to try to minimize the impacts of thecar (e.g. forcing firms to introduce ride sharing or risksubstant ial fines) but rail-oriented development can beleft to the market t o produce the necessa ry land u seintegration that reduces travel needs.

    In Portland, Oregon the new light rail system has not onlybeen successful in transport terms (doubling tra nsitshare in the city) but also it has been the catalyst for arejuvenation of the Downtown (from 5 per cent to 30 percent of retail trade), the development of subcentres (most

    15THE END OF THE URBAN FREEWAY

    Estimate per carCountry in US$ per year Source

    USA 4,220 Ketcham and Komanoff,1992

    USA 2,965 Litman, 1993USA 2,312 MacKenzie et al., 1992USA 2,1850-3,636 Moffet, 1991USA 3,647 Voorhees, 1992Switzerland 2,813 VCS, 1991Germany 3,376 UPI, 1991Australia 3,868 Laube and Lynch, 1994

    Note:Costs include all public and external costs

    Table I. Costs of the automobile from various studies

    Cost item Rail Bus Car

    Capital and operating 27.06 21.51 26.65Depots/car parking 1.09 3.42Roads 8.89Road maintenance 0.03 0.00Fatalities 0.12 0.03 0.35Injuries 0.00 0.00 0.11Property damage 0.01 0.00 0.18Air pollution 0.00 0.25 0.43

    Noise pollution 0.00 0.20 0.08Total 27.19 23.11 40.11

    Notes:

    1. The data represent the costs for any additionalpassenger kms of travel added to the Australian urbantransport system.

    2. The data are mostly Australia-wide averages for thefive main Australian capital cities (excludingCanberra), based on information from the BTCE andRail Industr y Council adjusted b y McGlynn a ndAndrews (1991) for inflation and other factors such aspetrol tax and insurance for cars.

    3. Capital and operating costs for urban rail show arange of 21.24 cents per passenger km to 50.35 centsper passenger km. The low figure is based on theincremental or marginal costs of adding newpassengers to existing rail systems, while the highfigure is for new light-rail syst ems for which theincremental costs equal the average costs becauseentirely new systems must be built. The figure usedhere is based on 80 per cent conventional rail and 20per cent light rail to recognize the increasing interestin light rail and prevalence of LRT proposals aroundAustralia and the likelihood that at least some new railsystems in the near future will be light rail.

    4. The bus data in McGlynn and Andrews (1991) show afigure of 18.17 cents per passenger km for busways (inline with the Rail Industry Councils work). However,this cost dominates the bus data and seemsexcessively large. It has been eliminated here sincebusways are relatively uncommon in Australian citiescompared with the great bulk of services whichoperate in normal traffic.

    5. Air pollution and noise costs are based primarily onhealth impacts and are likely to be underestimatedowing to inadequate data in these areas. Also, there isthe wider, and as yet mostly unquantified damage,from air and noise pollution (e.g. materials and cropdamage from air pollution, psychological/socialimpacts of noise and reduced real-estate values owingto traffic intrusion).

    Source:Modified from McGlynn and Andrews (1991)

    Table II. Capital, operating and external costs of rail, busand car modes in Australian cities (cents per passenger km,1991)

  • 8/2/2019 The well-travelled yogurt pot_lessons for new freight transport policies and regional production_Stefanie Bge

    10/41

    development has been attracted to station areas, over US$900 million in five years) and the prevention of urbansprawl (a green belt has now been possible to impose onthe urban fringe) (Arrington, 1993).

    It is these kinds of results that are beginning to showgovernments in UK, Australian a nd US cities tha t torevamp their urban public transport systems, link themto land development and move towards demandmanagement, may be the basis of achieving sustainableeconomic development. This is now apparent in threegovernment progr ammes in each of these countr ies,which will be briefly outlined.

    US ISTEA legislat ionThe most significant transport and land use legislation inrecent US history is the Inter Surface TransportationEfficiency Act (ISTEA) which was passed in the last yearof the Bush Administration and now has the full supportof Clinton. The key components of ISTEA are:

    q a renewed Federal involvement in transit(including the funding of capital works for transit);

    q increased funding;

    q great er flexibility in use of funds for transit orhighways (but subject to the provisions below) ordemand management programmes;

    q insistence on the use of planning processesinvolving the community to be adopted in citiesbefore any funding for projects is allowed (i.e. nogun at the head of states to either accept the fundsfor a major highway or lose it altogether);

    q tying of funding to achievement of Clean Air Actinitiatives (i.e. no funds if smog levels areincreased).

    It is no wonder that with these provisions the balance ofFederal funds is swinging towards transit. Many citieshave been slow to catch on to the new order, but it isfirmly in place and communities are beginning to see thatit provides the opportunities to rebuild American cities ina more sustainable way.

    The key component of having land development that ispedestrian friendly and transit oriented instead ofautomobile dependent has been t he major problem inrecent US urban h istory. ISTEA provides a chance tobreak that tradition but it requires local land use laws to

    be developed that are able to facilitate this. In California,there is a set of initiatives which is establishing the legalbasis of transit-oriented development: the Transit VillageDevelopment Act of 1994 would establish all land withina quarter mile of rail transit stations as a transit-villagedevelopment district if applied for by a local authority.The area would then be given the powers of aredevelopment agency and staffed to facilitate itstransition into a mixed use, high density pedestrian scaleurban environment. The district would have first priorityfor funding from state and Federal innovative transport-land use programmes. The Bill is in response to the

    US$10 billion worth of planned transit investment inCalifornia due to ISTEA; as well as this there could beeven fur ther t ransit investment if a new citizens bill ispassed to take a 4c/gallon fuel tax and direct itspecifically into transit.

    Transit/ land-use linkage in the UKA central concept in the new paradigm of city building isthat transit funding should only be used as pa rt of atotally integrated land use package. Thus any new line tobe built or any old line upgraded can only go ahead if

    there is a coherent policy that increases housing, jobs andservices in transit station precincts. This is the kind ofprocess successfully undergone by the Toronto TransitCommission on their new lines and also on the VancouverSky Train. It is more or less standard practice in Europe,with Stockholm being one of the best examples of

    16 WORLD TRANSPORT POLICY & PRACTICE 1,1

    Waste of publicinvestment

    Suburbsover-capitalized

    Subsidized roadprovision

    Subsidized water/sewerage provision

    Tax incentives onhouse andland package

    Othersubsidizedinfrastructure

    Regulations and planning processes that shape the city

    Sprawl

    Wasted urban space

    Waste of privateinvestment

    Suburbsover-capitalized

    Ongoing cost

    High maintenanceof infrastructure

    External costs

    Road accidents,smog, noise,physical damage,loss of land

    Wasteof travel time

    Distances longerthan they needto be

    Less public capitalfor productivepurposes

    Less private capitalfor productivepurposes

    Less productiveeconomy

    Inflation andunemployment

    Figure 1. Possible mechanisms linking excessive provision ofroads, urban sprawl and economic problems

  • 8/2/2019 The well-travelled yogurt pot_lessons for new freight transport policies and regional production_Stefanie Bge

    11/41

    planned land use/transit integration. However it has notbeen a feature of UK planning which opted for NewTowns often without good transit links and with other

    development only loosely connected to transit.

    Th is is now set to change with t he UK Governmentsmuch applauded Planning Policy Guideline PPG 13Department of Environment and Department ofTransport, 1994, which seeks to:

    q reduce growth in the length and number ofmotorized journeys;

    q encourage alternative means of travel which haveless environmental impact, and hence;

    q reduce reliance on the private car.

    The new regulations require housing to be located inpresent urban areas near to work and services especiallygood public transport, rather than incremental expansionof villages and small towns outside the main cities, orsporadic housing in the countryside that is likely toresult in car commuting to urban centres(Department ofEnvironment and Department of Transport, 1994, 3.2).They also require rail stations and light-rail stops to bethe preferred location for travel-intensive development(Department of Environment and Department ofTransport, 1994, 4.24). The transit/land-use package isdesigned to not only overcome deficiencies in the

    transport area but also to help overcome some of thespatial inefficiencies in cities and make them moreatt ractive places for living, working, recreating andmoving around. The paradigm shift is in seeing that thisrequires tr ansit -oriented development not car-baseddevelopment. As Robert Cervero (1992) says:

    Creating transit-oriented pedestrian-friendly environmentswould reduce auto dependency and cleanse the air, not tomention enliven cities and bring people from all walks of lifeinto daily contact. Those previously isolated by the autosociety the elderly, the wheel-chair bound, the poor couldfully par ticipate in societys offerings in a transit-oriented

    city.

    Australi an better cit ies programIn each Australian city, there are transport planningstrategies that are recommending the new order. Eachcity has shown that they understand the new policyenvironment, that they must upgrade t ransit, createbetter land use linkages thus reducing the need to travel,create more pedestrian-friendly environments andimplement demand management (summarized inNewman et al., 1992). However the old order continues

    relatively unabated because they have the funds andthe bureaucracy in place. There is considerabledisenchantment being expressed at grass-roots level withsophisticated alternative proposals being developed, evenlinking up the isolated alternatives from across Sydneyinto a coherent, integrated a lternative plan (Link Up,

    1994). When imaginative, future-oriented exercises areundertaken, the results show a much reduced level ofautomobile dependence, for example the Greenpeace

    winning concept for the Sydney 2000 Olympic Village is atransit-oriented, pedestrian-friendly urban village. Thisall seems to suggest that the Australian city is ready forsome legislative changes like those outlined above in theUSA and UK (Newman, 1994).

    There is a major initiative from the Federal Governmentthat is putt ing demonstration projects into place designedto help Australians envisage an alternat ive, less car-dependent city. This is the Better Cities Program and it isa five-year A$850 million exercise which is alreadybeginning to bear fruit. Although few of the projects are

    complete, the state and local Government bureaucraciesinvolved have begun to apply the principles of transit-oriented, denser, more mixed land use to other areas.There are also two cities, Sydney and Brisbane, which aredeveloping small light-rail systems that are likely to setthe standard for new transit options in Australian cities.

    Several Better Cities projects in Perth are building transit-supportive urban villages around the newly electrifiedand extended urban ra il system. The new service hasbeen a spectacular success, in particular the newNorthern Suburbs line has attracted 40 per cent higherpatronage than the previous bus-only service and 25 percent of patrons have switched from cars. Now that landuses are moving to intensify around the stat ions and thatcross-city bus services are occurring through theintegrated feeder links, the basis for a lifestyle that ismuch lower in its aut o dependence is now apparent.This is quite an achievement for such a car-dominatedcity but like all changes that involve a substantial elementof paradigm shift, the upgrading of the Perth rail systemcame about because of political intervent ion throughgrass roots processes rather than the transportprofessionals (Newman, 1993). The professionalspreferred choice was a low-key bus option that essentially

    admitted the task of overcoming auto dependence wasnot winnable. Once given the direction, the professionalschanged and produced an award winning railway, on timeand on budget.

    This is the great hope as the urban freeway era is ended,that the combination of political commitment andprofessional expertise can be harnessed quickly toimplement the necessary package of transport and landuse policies. The global information system can providethe expertise and the evidence is pointing to a rapid risein the political will to move away from the urbanfreeway.

    The urban freeway protest movementA recent article in The Economist(19 February 1994)says t hat protesting about new roads in the UK has

    17THE END OF THE URBAN FREEWAY

  • 8/2/2019 The well-travelled yogurt pot_lessons for new freight transport policies and regional production_Stefanie Bge

    12/41

    become a truly populist movement drawing supportersfrom all walks of life. The movement has strong supportfrom the Tory Party, NIMBY groups and wider

    environmental g roups. Their concerns are for the localcountryside, the citys environment and the globalenvironment. The Department of Transpor t recentlyreceived 10,000 submissions on the M25 only eight werein favour. The Economistarticle went on to say that thepro-roads lobby, by contrast, draws upon a muchnarrower constituency mostly road builders and carmakers. The alternative of shifting public money fromhigh capacity roads into public trans port is almostuniversally accepted.

    In the USA, the movement to change priorities from road

    building to transit is very active. The Surface TransportPolicy Project co-ordinates hundreds of organizationsacross the country and was a major force behind ISTEA.In California, the home of the freeway, only 18 per cent ofthe community believe that freeways help solve trafficproblems, whereas 36 per cent believe in rail transit (seeFigure 2).

    In Norway a very revealing survey found a similar levelof anti-freeway/pro-transit sentiment and when askedwhether people believed their politicians had correctly

    judged the feeling of people towards private cars, theirresponses were: Yes, 19 per cent; No, 53 per cent; Do NotKnow, 18 per cent (INRA Europe, 1991).

    In Austra lia the tide is moving in this direction. TheCommunit y and Fa mily Commiss ion (1992), in theirsurvey of attitudes in Perth, found a strong dislike forfreeways, support for transit, and interestingly apowerful desire to try to create more diverse, village-stylecommunities with close access to services. AcrossAustr alia there are many groups producing creativealternatives to large roads as well as opposingfreeways. The Link-Up Conference brought together over100 such groups just in Sydney. These groups have all the

    energy, vision and commitment of the earlyenvironmental movement. The one characteristic whichthey a ll express is t hat they receive little help from

    government in their work, that government is seen astheir enemy, too closely allied to the road lobby and withvirtually all government planners, engineers andadministrators facilitating the problem, not the solution.Th is movement is now calling for a Commonwealthinitiative on transit (similar to the US ISTEA approach)as it called for such action on the natural environment inthe 1980s.

    ConclusionThe kind of modernist thinking that produced the

    urban freeway with its grandiosity, its simplicity in themidst of complexity, its neglect of the social andenvironmental, its machismo, is now easily parodied bycommentators. But the post-modern world in many otherareas of human endeavour is still very confused aboutwhether any alternative future can exist. With the urbanfreeway, it is now clear that the economic basis for itscontinuance is as shaky as its moral basis andalternatives do exist and are well-demonstrated inEuropean and Asian cities. The English-speaking worldhave been slower to adopt the new paradigm but theevidence presented here suggests that the last days of the

    old paradigm are appearing in the UK, USA andAustralia. This is not to say that the old way does nothave some momentum left or that the political battles areover. What it does mean is that the tide has changed andcities which now build freeways will probably regret it.

    References

    Arrington, G.B. (1993), Transportation and land use a sharedvision, Passenger Transport, Vol. 2 No. 3, pp. 4-14.

    Aschauer, D.A. (1989), Is public expenditure productive?,Journal of Monetary Economics, No. 23.

    Aschauer, D.A. and Campbell, E.J. (1991), Transport ationspending and economic growth, Bates College, September,reported in Earthword, Vol. 4 No. 38.

    Australian Automobile Association (AAA) (1994), LandTransport Infrastructure Maximising the Contribution toEconomic Growth, The Allen Consu lting Group, AAA,Canberra.

    Cervero, R. (1992), Transp ortation shap es the city, PerthBeyond 2000, Proceedings of City Challenge Conference,Challenge Bank, Perth.

    Community and Family Commission (1992), Speaking Out,Taking Part, Community and Family Commission, Perth.

    Depar tment of Environment and Depart ment of Transport

    (1994), Reducing the Need to Travel, Planning PolicyGuidance PPG 13, Depar tment of Environment, London.The Economist(1994), 19 Febr uary.Franz, J.D. (1989), Views of Bay Area Residents on Traffic and

    Growth Issues, Metropolitan Transit Commission, July, SanFrancisco, CA.

    18 WORLD TRANSPORT POLICY & PRACTICE 1,1

    40

    30

    20

    10

    0

    Percentage ofrespondents

    Rail Car pool Freeway Limit growth

    Key:

    Support Oppose

    Figure 2. California support and opposition for options tosolve traffic problems

  • 8/2/2019 The well-travelled yogurt pot_lessons for new freight transport policies and regional production_Stefanie Bge

    13/41

    Frost, L. (1991), The New Urban Frontier: Urbanization andCity Building in Australasia and the American West,University of New South Wales Press, Sydney.

    Gobor, P. (1993), Americans on the move, Population Bulletin,Vol. 48 No. 3, pp. 1-40.

    INRA Europe (1991), European at titud es to ur ban trafficproblems and public transport, survey for ECG and IUTP,INRA Brussels, July.

    Jacobs, J. (1984), Cities and the Wealth of Nations, Penguin,Harmondsworth.

    Ketcham, B. and Komanoff, C. (1992), Win-Win Transportation:A No-losers Approach to Financing Transport in the NewYork City and the Region, Draft, New York, NY.

    Laube, F. and Lynch, M. (1993), The Costs of the Motor Vehiclein WA, Institute for Science & Technology Policy (ISTP),Murdoch University, Perth.

    Laube, F. and Lynch, M. (1994), Costs and Benefits of MotorVehicle Traffic in Western Australia, Institute for Scienceand Technology, Murdoch University, Perth.

    Laube, F., Marinova, D. and Lynch, M. (1993), Land TransportInfrastructure: Maximising the Contribution to EconomicGrowth; A Response to the AAA Report, Institute forScience & Technology Policy (ISTP), Murdoch University,Perth.

    Link Up (1994), Livable City Times, Link Up, Darlinghurst, NewSouth Wales.

    Litman, T. (1993), Transportation efficiency and equity: aneconomic analysis, draft of mas ters d isserta tion, TESC

    Victoria, BC.MacKenzie, J., Dower, R. and Cheng, P. (1992), The Going Rate:

    What It Really Costs to Drive, World Resources Institute,Washington, DC.

    McGlynn, G. and Andrews, J. (1991), The economic costs andbenefits of urban scenarios that support ecologicallysustainable development, internal ISTP report, September.

    Ministry of Housing, Ministry of Transport and Public Works,Ministry of Economic Affairs (1991), The Right Business inthe Right Place: Towards a Location Policy for Business andServices in the Interests of Accessibility and theEnvironment, The Netherlands Government, The Hague.

    Moffet, J. (1991), The price of mobility, Draft, NationalResources Defense Council, San Francisco, CA.

    Naess, P. (1993), Energy use for transport in 22 Nordic towns,

    NIBR Report No. 2, Norwegian Institu te for Urban andRegional Research, Oslo.

    Newman, P.W.G. (1993), The rebirth of Perths suburbanrailways, in Hedgcock, D. and Yiftachel, O. (Eds), Urbanand Regional Planning in Western Australia, ParadigmPress, Perth.

    Newman, P.W.G. (1994), The rationale for a commonwealthrole in public transport, seminar on Urban publictransport futures by Australian Urban and RegionalDevelopment Review, Depart ment of Housing and LocalGovernment, Canberra, April.

    Newman, P.W.G. and Kenworthy, J.R. (1988), The transportenergy tradeoff: fuel efficient traffic versus fuel efficient

    cities, Transportation Research, Vol. 22A No. 3, pp. 163-74.Newman, P.W.G. and Kenworthy, J.R. (1989), Cities and

    Automobile Dependence, Gower, Aldershot.Newman, P.W.G., Kenworthy, J.R. and Vintila, P. (1992),

    Housing, Transport and Urban Form, National HousingStrategy, Background Paper 15, Australian GovernmentPublishing Service, Canberra.

    Roberts, J. (1989), User-friendly Cities: What Britain Can Learnfrom Mainland Europe, TEST, London.

    Secretary of State for the Environment (1994), SustainableDevelopment: The UK Strategy, Cm2426, HMSO, London.

    Tickell, O. (1993), Driven by dogma, Geographical, October,

    pp. 20-4.UPI (1991), Umweltwirkungen von Finanzinstrumenten imVerkehrsbereich, Umwelt- und Prognose-Institut/D. Teufel etal., Heidelberg/Germany.

    Voorhees, M. (1992), The True Costs of the Automobile toSociety, Boulder, CO.

    VCS (1991), Umwelt Verkehr Umkehr UmweltgerechtesVerkehrsleitbild fr die Schweiz, Verkehrsclub der Schweiz/Association des transports et environment/Associazionetraffico e embiente, Herzogenbuchsee, p. 304.

    Whitelegg, J. (1993), Transport for a Sustainable Future: TheCase for Europe, Belhaven Press, London.

    19THE END OF THE URBAN FREEWAY

    Peter Newman is Associate Professor in City Policy and Director of the Institute for Science & Technology Policy, MurdochUniversity, Perth, Western Australia.

  • 8/2/2019 The well-travelled yogurt pot_lessons for new freight transport policies and regional production_Stefanie Bge

    14/41

    Summer of discontentApril 1994 brought an Indian Summer to Melbourne, afortnight of unseasonably fine Autumn weather. Whatshould have been an occasion for enjoyment soon turnedsour, as the build-up of car exhausts produced the citysworst ever bout of photochemical smog. Instead ofsunning themselves, the three million residents of the citydesignated the worlds most livable by the WashingtonResearch Institute were coping with irritations to the eyesand respiratory system.

    The smog episode refocused concern on the poor state ofMelbournes public transport . Despite possess ing theEnglish-speaking worlds largest tram/light-rail networkand an electrified urban rail system the size of the LondonUnderground with a fleet of modern tra ins (none morethan 20 years old), Melbourne has lost public transportpassengers at a world-beating rate since wartime petrolrationing was lifted in February 1950. A LabourGovernment which held office from 1982 to 1992 and wascommitt ed to reversing decades of neglect of publictransport could do no more than slow the rate of decline:current modal share is about 8 per cent of total travel and

    15 per cent of work trips (Moriarty and Beed, 1992). Therail system operates at only a fraction of capacity, even inpeak period (Mees, 1993) and occupancies are now so lowthat rail transport actually produces similar greenhousegas emissions per passenger-kilometre to the car(Richardson, 1993).

    The conservative Victorian State Government elected inNovember 1992 is responding with a reform programmecomprising service reductions, fare increases, produc-tivity improvements and privatization (urban transport isa state responsibility). The Government has alsoannounced an accelerated urban freeway programmecalled Linking Melbourne (VicRoads, 1994). These

    policies have the support of most transport academicsand other experts, although some believe the Governmentshould go further. Their reasoning is:

    q Urban public transport requires a large publicsubsidy, but returns little benefit, because so fewpeople use it.

    q Little can be done to improve patronage, sadly,because social change and post-war developmenthave made the radial rail and tram systems, andeven conventional route bus services, irrelevant tomost peoples travel needs.

    q The only logical response is to cut costs ruthlesslyand bring the subsidy to an acceptable level, and toprivatize and deregulate as much of the system aspossible.

    q Since most travel is going to be by road, anexpanded freeway network is needed.

    But transport policy is not just about moving people andgoods around. Transport is one of the major influences onthe form of cities. Los Angeles and Barcelona both didmost of their growing in the last 120 years. They look

    very different largely because of differing t ranspor thistories. If Melbourne is to be sur rendered entirely to thecar, we must expect a city more and more like Detroit,Dallas or LA, and more smog epidemics. If, as LinkingMelbourne proposes, a ring-freeway is built, we canexpect a shapeless sprawl of drive-in shopping centresand office parks around the interchanges, uncontrollablesuburban traffic congestion and pollution, as can be seenaround most US cities and along Londons M25 orbitalfreeway.

    Few planners even those who support ring-freeways orpublic transport cuts want this future for Melbourne,but the policies they advocate amount to a return to the1960s and 1970s, when Thomson noted that Melbournewas gradually being transformed from a strong-centreto a weak-centre structure (Thomson, 1977, p. 136).

    20 WORLD TRANSPORT POLICY & PRACTICE 1,1

    Urban transport policy paradoxesin AustraliaPaul Mees

    A period of smog highlights Melbournes inadequate public transport

    World Transport Policy & Practice, Vol. 1 No. 1, 1995, pp. 20-24 MCB University Press Limited, 1352-7614

  • 8/2/2019 The well-travelled yogurt pot_lessons for new freight transport policies and regional production_Stefanie Bge

    15/41

    The dispersed cityThe argument that low-density, decentralized post-war

    development makes conventional public transport non-viable is not new. As early as 1960, the authors of theChicago Area Transportation Study confidently claimed:

    The conditions of land use and densityare the majordeterminants of the travel market. If demand is constrainedby these factors, it is unlikely that changes in supply willhave any great impact on the number of users (CATS, 1960,p. 52).

    The argument was presented more thoroughly in Meyer,et al., (1965) and has not been improved on since.

    A 1985 study for the European Conference of Ministers of

    Transport noted extremely low levels of public transportuse in Australia (as well as New Zealand and the USA),which was attributed to high levels of car ownershipand extensive low-density suburbs, which are difficult toserve adequately by public transport (Webster et al.,1985, p. 43).

    This is the conventional explanation for the decline ofpublic transport in Melbourne and other Australiancities. A local road engineering text observes:

    Although every effort should be made to encourage theefficient use of public transport. Current land use trends

    in Australian cities are towards continued low-densitydevelopment that cannot be effectively or economicallyserved by public transport (Underwood, 1990, p. 162).

    Underwood discusses a series of flexible and demand-responsive alternatives, such as shared taxis andneighbourhood car co-operatives. This is also a commontheme: in a dispersed, low-density city, innovative,flexible, car-like (and consequently, highly p olluting)forms of public transport are the only viable options.Traditional modes such as rail have a declining role, andpublic transp ort is for niche markets such as schoolchildren and other people without cars (Hensher, 1994).

    An additional form of dispersion is movement ofemployment, retailing and other activity from the CentralBusiness District to the suburbs, a result of the flexibilitycreated by the car and the truck and of technologicalchange, particularly electronic communications(Brotchie, 1992). This process, noted in the USA by Meyeret al. (1965), has produced a diffuse pattern of tripmaking, which Hall (1990, p. 5) describes as a generalfeature of Western cities:

    The traditional downtown is now only the leadingcommercial centre among a number of others, some of which

    may compete strongly with it. Thus the traditional patternof movement radially inward during the morning peak,outward during the late afternoon has increasingly beenoverlain by other movements, both reverse commuting andcriss-cross commuting... [like] a box of matches thrownalmost randomly onto a table.

    This dispersed journey patt ern does not produce theconcentrated flows of passengers required to supportpublic transport (Brotchie, 1992). Much of the new

    suburban travel is cross-suburban, and cannot beconveniently served by the radial fixed-rail system. Evenwhere suburban jobs are concentrated in centres, theseare too small, and attract trips from too many directions,to support much in the way of public transport. Hall,however, is less eager to write off public transport: inmetro areas where suburban jobs are clustered aroundtransit interchanges, for instance, it may not be tr ue atall (Hall, 1990, p. 6).

    Canadian contrasts

    The 1985 ECMT study (Webster et al., 1985, p. 43) notedthat Canadian cities have been much more successfulthan their Australian and US counterparts at retainingpublic transport patronage:

    The situation in Canada is particularly interesting, sincesuburban development is very much in the NorthAmerican, car-oriented pattern, yet public transport use isat European levels, and the trend is strongly upwards (p. 43).

    The report suggests that this may be due to Governmentpolicies which have concentrated employment and othertrip destinations in central business districts. Newmanand Kenwort hy (1989) have spa rked controversy in

    Australian tr ansport planning circles by presentingToronto as an example of the successful integration oftransport and land-use planning, emphasizing the sitingof high-density housing near rapid transit stations.

    Critics of this approach argue that large increases indensity are neither feasible nor desirable (e.g. Hensher,1994). Public transport will continue to decline or at bestplay a minor role, because densities cannot or should notbe increased substantially nor jobs recentralized. Thisagain echoes the reasoning of the Chicago AreaTransport at ion Study (e.g. CATS, 1959, p. 90; 1960,

    p. 54). But some planners argue that the environmentaldamage created by over reliance on the car makesincreased densities imperative. They point to successfulexamples urban villages of residents of affluentcities happily accepting high-density lifestyles. Even theproponents of increased densities, however, are generallyat a loss to deal with employment decentralization, exceptto argue that existing levels of centralization should beprotected.

    Looked at in very simplistic terms, the solution to the publictransport dilemma is to alter the way in which Melbourne isdeveloping, to induce a form and density t hat creates

    favourable conditions for public transport to operate under(Kohut, 1991, p. 15).

    There are, however, other explanations for the apparentsuccess of Canadian urban transit. Vuchic (1981) alsoregards Toronto as a model, but not primarily of land-useplanning:

    21URBAN TRANSPORT POLICY PARADOXES IN AUSTRALIA

  • 8/2/2019 The well-travelled yogurt pot_lessons for new freight transport policies and regional production_Stefanie Bge

    16/41

    Another interesting comparison is between several US citiesand Toronto. In 1950, Toronto had a similar transit service tothat in US cities; it had a simultaneous increase in auto

    ownership, it experienced urban sprawl (it has even fewerspace limitations), and it constructed some of the widestfreeways in the world. The drastic difference is that, unlikemost US cities, Toronto made a serious commitment tocontinuous improvement of transit. It constructed a rapidtransit system and introduced numerous operationalinnovations. The consequences of this p olicy are clear :between 1961 and 1976 transit ridership in Torontoincreased by 46 per cent. During the same period ridershipin most US cities continued to decline (Vuchic, 1981,p. 110).

    Cervero (1986, p. 296), comparing Canadian and US publictransport , concludes:

    the overriding factor behind transits success in Canada is,plainly and simply, the superior levels of service, combinedwith the careful integration of transit and land-use planning.

    Another possible explanation for Melbournes publictransport decline thus emerges. Melbourne, like Canadiancities, had a choice about the kind of transport system itwas to have; policy-makers chose the path of decliningpublic transport and car dominance. This contrasts withthe urban form explanation, which is more deterministic,portraying transport changes as the outcome of naturalprocesses of city growth and technological change.

    Toronto stands out even in Canada as having achievedthe apparently impossible task of providing high quality,cost-effective public transport in a sprawling city. Thesecret of success is service and integration. Trains arefast, safe and clean, running every few minutes until 1.30a.m. Buses and trams operate as feeders to the railsystem, with frequent services and 24-hour coverage ontrunk routes, and changing modes is easy. The excellenceof the rail system draws passengers to the feeder buses,which also serve local and cross-suburban travel. Thebuses generate patrons for the rail system, completingthe virtuous circle. Public transport has been supported

    by a two-decade moratorium on freeway construction,except in outer areas, limits on downtown car parkingand supportive land-use policies (although the latter mayhave been honoured more in the breach than theobservance (Frisken, 1990).

    Canada should be able to provide lessons for Australia,particularly since the two nations share many featureswhich distinguish them from the USA, such as theabsence of urban race tensions. In many respects, theAustralian s ituation is actually more favourable topublic transport: Toronto opened its first rail line in 1954,

    and must build each addition to its small networkunderground, while the Melbourne rail and tram systemshave been in place for over a century, and have shaped thecitys development. Less than 10 per cent of Melbournespopulation lives more than 5 km from a rapid transitstation, compared with 60 per cent in Toronto; 17 of the 25

    largest suburban shopping centres (ABS, 1986) areadjacent to rail stations, to only five in Toronto(Metropolitan Toronto Planning Department, 1992).

    But public transp ort servicein Melbour ne has beendeteriorating for decades. Frequencies have been cut andtrains are no faster than when the first electric servicescommenced in the 1920s (see Table I). Even the currentState Government acknowledges that service reliability ispoor (Brown, 1994). New trams and buses have hardlyaffected operating speeds, which are determined mainlyby traffic conditions. Buses are not timetabled to connectwith trains or trams, despite scheduling having beenunder the control of a single authority since 1982, sonothing has changed since 1953, when Melbournes

    planning authority lamented:A few buses run to and from the city, but in most casesthey act as feeders to the r ail and tr am services Onaccount of infrequent service and poor co-ordination there are relatively few who can save much time by usingthese services (MMBW, 1953, p. 184).

    Torontos approach to service has received little attentionfrom transport planners in Melbourne, as both sides ofthe local transport debate accept the urban formexplanat ion for the decline of public transport . Littleattention has been paid to learning what makes public

    transport successful, because the conventionalexplanation for its decline has acted as a self-denyingordinance closing off debate.

    Developments in the westMeanwhile, on the West Coast of Australia, a newapproach has emerged. Perth, a sprawling, car-dominatedcity, compared with which Melbourne seems almostEuropean, is following the Canadian model. Newman(1991) comments that other Australians view Perths rail

    22 WORLD TRANSPORT POLICY & PRACTICE 1,1

    1929 1994

    Service frequency (min)Peak 3-4 15Shoulder 7-8 15Interpeak 15 15Evening and Saturdays 15 20Sundays 15 40

    Fastest service (min) 26 27

    Line length (km) 18

    Number of stations 14 14

    Population in lines catchment area 80,000 120,000

    Table I. Decline in train service on MelbournesSandringham line

  • 8/2/2019 The well-travelled yogurt pot_lessons for new freight transport policies and regional production_Stefanie Bge

    17/41

    revival with some amazement: the reactions ofconventional transport planners on the East Coast couldbe more appropriately described as hostility (e.g. Industry

    Commission, 1993).

    Perth sp ent heavily on rail upg rading over t he lastdecade. The line to Freman tle, closed in 1979, wasreopened in 1983 by a new State Government, the railsystem was electrified and modernized. The effect onperformance was dramatic. Trains are faster, morefrequent and cheaper to run; many bus routes now act asrail feeders, giving a better service at lower cost. Cost-recovery is improving as patronage grows, with the newNorthern suburbs line, built along a freeway median,recovering 49 per cent of operating costs from the farebox

    (Ministry of Transport, WA, 1994).

    Newman (1991) claims Perths improvements were foughtat every tu rn by the transport bureaucracy and otherexperts, a claim corroborated by the views of unnamedofficials cited approvingly by a more orthodox author:

    Railway officials commented somewhat ruefully after thisepisode [the reopening of the Fremant le line] that t he[previous] government should have waited a little longer,ended freight and passenger service simultaneously, andtorn up the line so that the restoration of passenger trainswould have been impossible (Stevenson, 1987, p. 108).

    Their thinking was trapped in paradigms from the 1960s:public transport can never compete with cars in a low-density city, so there is little point improving it (e.g.Director-General of Transport, WA, 1982). TheGovernment used Newman (1991) and Vuchic (1981) asconsultants to break the impasse.

    In Melbourne, the old thinking dominated decisionmaking. The transport bureaucracy advised theincoming Labour Tr ansport Minister that only minorincreases in patronage could be achieved, and even thiswould create a deficit blowout (Ministry of Transport ,

    Victoria, 1982). When Labour insist ed on s pendingmoney on public transport, the experts responded with aprogramme of indiscriminate modernization, rather thana strategy for expanding, co-ordinating and improvingservice. Meanwhile, the construction of freewayscontinued.

    From the mid-1980s, the Victorian Governmentsattention returned to cost-cutting. Rail stations werede-staffed at night just as a series of films about New Yorksubway graffiti hit the cinemas: the resulting outbreak ofvandalism afflicts the system to this day. The

    Government met its nemesis in a 1990 industrial disputesparked by a proposal to eliminate tr am conductors.Lines of trams were parked in city streets for weeks, andthe lottery-style self-scratch tickets introduced to savethe cost of vending machines were ridiculed by the publicand media. The Government backed down.

    The new conservative State Government has returned tothe remedies of previous decades: service cuts, fare risesand new technology for public transport, coupled with an

    accelerated programme of freeway constr uction. Thereform programme has received the full support ofmainstream transport planners and Thatcheriteeconomists (e.g. Hensher, 1993; Industry Commission,1993), despite having produced a 10 per cent fall inpatronage in only 18 months. The magic wand ofcompetition will create the flexibility needed for publictra nsport to serve marginal niche markets in a car-dominated city. British bus deregulation is citedglowingly as a success story, a fact which may surpriseEnglish readers.

    ConclusionMelbournes land-use planners continue their four-decadestr uggle to preserve the public transport-oriented land-use pattern inherited from the pre-War city. TheMelbourne & Metropolitan Board of Works 1954metropolitan plan emphasized containment of urbansprawl and the creation of rail-based suburban districtbusiness centres. The most recent update (Ministry ofPlanning, Victoria, 1987) continues the tradition,prescribing rail-based development corridors and districtcentres, and urban consolidation (redevelopment ofestablished areas at h igher densities). Melbour ne has

    recently emerged as a world leader in traditionalneighbourhood design. I have argued elsewhere (Mees,1994) that the land-use planners have been largelysuccessful.

    Meanwhile, transport planners continue their long-established approach of discouraging public transportuse through declining service quality and expanding theroad network, paradoxically claiming that they haveno choice but to do so because Melbournes urban form isso car-oriented. Unfortunately, they have a lso beensuccessful.

    Urban form is not Melbournes major transport problem;rather it is an excuse used to perpetuate the real malaise,which is a refusal by transport planners to treat seriouslytransport modes other than the car.

    References

    Australian Bureau of Statistics (ABS) (1986), Retail Census,Small Area Statistics, Victoria, ABS, Canberra.

    Brotchie, J. (1992), The changing structure of cities, UrbanFutures, Special Issue, No. 5, February, pp. 13-26.

    Brown, A. (1994), Ministerial Statement on Stage 2 of PublicTransport Reform, Victorian Government Printer,

    Melbourne.Cervero, R. (1986), Urban transit in Canada: integration and

    innovation at its best, Transportation Quarterly, Vol. 40 No.3, pp. 293-316.

    Chicago Ar ea Tr anspor tat ion Study 1956 (CATS) (1959),Volume 1 Survey Findings, Chicago, IL.

    23URBAN TRANSPORT POLICY PARADOXES IN AUSTRALIA

  • 8/2/2019 The well-travelled yogurt pot_lessons for new freight transport policies and regional production_Stefanie Bge

    18/41

    Chicago Area Transp ort ation Study 1956 (CATS) (1960),Volume 2 Data Analysis, Chicago, IL.

    Director-General of Transport, Western Australia (1982),

    Transport 2000: A Perth Study, WA Government Printer,Perth.

    Frisken, F. (1990), Planning and servicing the greater Torontoarea: the interplay of provincial and municipal interests,Urban Studies Working Pap er No. 12, York University,Toronto.

    Hall, P. (1990), Managing growth in the worlds cities,Planning the Toronto Region: Lessons from Other Places,Canadian Urban Institute, Toronto.

    Hensher, D.A. (1993), The transportation sector in Australia:economic issues and challenges, Transport Policy, Vol. 1No. 1, pp. 49-67.

    Hensher, D.A. (1994), Technology, pricing and managementsystems futures for urban public transport, Urban PublicTransport Futures, Australian Urban and RegionalDevelopment Review, Canberra.

    Industry Commission (1993), Urban Transport Draft Report,Australian Government Printer, Canberra.

    Kohut, R. (1991), Shaping Public Transports Future, PublicTransport Corporation, Melbourne.

    Mees, P. (1993), The capacity of the Melbourne rail system,Road and Transport Research, Vol. 2 No. 2, pp. 105-7.

    Mees, P. (1994), Continuity and change in marvellousMelbourne, Urban Futures, Vol. 4 No. 1, pp. 1-11.

    Melbourne & Metropolitan Board of Works (MMBW) (1953),Melbourne Metropolitan Planning Scheme 1954: Surveysand Analysis, Victorian Government Printer, Melbourne.

    Metropolitan Toronto Planning Department (1992), Retail FloorSpace and Employment Characteristics in the GreaterToronto Area, Toronto.

    Meyer, J., Kain, J. and Wohl, M. (1965), The UrbanTransportation Problem, Harvard University Press,Cambridge, MA.

    Ministry of Planning, Victoria (1987), Shaping MelbournesFuture: The Governments Metropolitan Policy, Melbourne.

    Ministry of Transport, Victoria (1982), Future Context for

    Transport: Metropolitan Transit Authority, Melbourne.Ministry of Transport, Western Australia (1994), unpublished

    data on Northern Suburbs Transit System.

    Moriarty, P. and Beed, C. (1992), Explanat ion of personal travelincreases in Australian cities, Papers of AustralasianTransport Research Forum, Vol. 17 Part 2, Canberra, pp. 259-70.

    Newman, P. (1991), The rebirth of the Perth suburbanrailways: a personal and policy perspective, Institute forScience and Technology Policy Working Paper 4/91,Murdoch University, Perth.

    Newman, P. and Kenworthy, J. (1989), Cities and Automobile

    Dependence: An International Sourcebook, Gower,Aldershot.Richardson, A.J. (1993), Environmental impacts of urban

    villages, Transport Research Centre, University ofMelbourne.

    Stevenson, G. (1987), Rail Transport and AustralianFederalism, Research Monograph 48, Centre for Research onFederal Financial Relations, Australian National University,Canberra.

    Thomson, J.M. (1977), Great Cities and Their Traffic, VictorGollancz, London.

    Underwood, R.T. (1990), Traffic Management: An Introduction,

    Hargreen Publishing, Melbourne.VicRoads (1994), Linking Melbourne: A Strategy for ManagingMelbournes Traffic, VicRoads Special Report 93-1,Melbourne.

    Vuchic, V.R. (1981), Urban Public Transportation: Systems andTechnology, Prentice-Hall, Englewood Cliffs, NJ.

    Webster, F.V., Bly, P.H., Johnston, R.H., Paulley, N. andDasgupta, M. (1985), Changing Patterns of Urban Travel,OECD Publications Office, Paris.

    24 WORLD TRANSPORT POLICY & PRACTICE 1,1

    Paul Mees is a Tutor and Postgraduate Research Student at the School of Environmental Planning, University ofMelbourne, Australia. He is also President of the Public Transport Users Association, a community transport lobby group.

  • 8/2/2019 The well-travelled yogurt pot_lessons for new freight transport policies and regional production_Stefanie Bge

    19/41

    BackgroundThe city of Amsterdam has one of the largest and mostintensely used historic centres in Europe. This centre,designed in the seventeenth century, was of course notbuilt for cars.

    The increasing number of cars has been causingproblems for a few decades already. There is not enoughroom for all types of traffic in one narrow st reet. Thecitys canal structure has long been used intensively to

    transport cargo of all kinds aboard boats of all kinds. Atthe turn of the twentieth century, the city was forced toadapt to automobile traffic and several canals werefilled in. The main canals, however, remained largelyintact, and today no one would dare to propose adaptingthe historic city centre structure to the needs of the motorcar.

    The centre is not an open air museum of the seventeenthcentury. It covers an area of some seven square kilometresand accommodates a t otal of 80,000 residents and afurther 80,000 employees. There is also a wide variety of

    functions which are supposed to belong in a city centre.The citys policy is to retain and preferably strengthen theeconomic importance of the centre. The level ofaccessibility therefore needs to be adequate for a healthyand multifunctional city centre.

    There is also general agreement on the following points:

    q Pollution and noise, largely caused by cars, shouldbe reduced.

    q Traffic safety should be increased.

    q Quality of public space should be improved.

    Why make a plan to reduce car traf fi c?The fact that a plan to reduce car traffic in Amsterdamscity centre was developed was more or less coincidental.It had a political background that had very little to dowith traffic or environmental concerns but was rather aresponse to the complaint that there was an ever-widening communication gap between the cityspoliticians and their constituents.

    Especially after the local elections of 1990, when therewas both a very low level of tur nout and a landslidedefeat for the ruling parties, politicians were looking fornew ways to improve the publics involvement. Areferendum the first ever held in Amsterdam seemedan a ttr active way of experimenting with more directpublic influence on decision making.

    Many subjects for a referendum were suggested butfinally the question chosen was how far should we gowith reducing car traffic in the city centre?. Twoscenarios were developed: one representing acontinuation of the exist ing t raffic policy, the otheraiming at a more drastic reduction of car traffic; 50 percent was a number that was frequently mentioned.

    Eventually the referendum was held in March 1992. Theresult was a narrow victory for the supporters of themore dr