INEQUALITIES, AGEING SOCIETIES AND SECULAR STAGNATION:...

20
INEQUALITIES, AGEING SOCIETIES AND SECULAR STAGNATION: AN OECD VIEW Secular Stagnation in Europe and Japan Bruegel-Kobe University 5 October 2015 Paul Swaim Senior Economist Directorate for Employment, Labour and Social Affairs OECD

Transcript of INEQUALITIES, AGEING SOCIETIES AND SECULAR STAGNATION:...

  • INEQUALITIES, AGEING SOCIETIES

    AND SECULAR STAGNATION:

    AN OECD VIEW

    Secular Stagnation in Europe

    and Japan Bruegel-Kobe University

    5 October 2015

    Paul Swaim

    Senior Economist

    Directorate for Employment, Labour and Social Affairs

    OECD

  • Outline of my talk

    1. What does secular stagnation have to do with inequalities and ageing

    populations?

    o Demand versus supply-side aspects of secular stagnation

    o (Mostly) on the supply-side

    2. How did the global financial crisis affect potential growth?

    o OECD estimates of the “hit” on potential output

    o Possible channels underlying lasting impacts from recessions/banking crisis

    3. How rising inequality and population ageing fit into the picture

    o Inequality trends and their impacts on potential growth rates

    o Population ageing/stagnation reduces the size of the labour force and thus potential

    growth, while also reinforcing the rise in inequality

    4. What should governments do?

    o Raise participation rates and the earnings of low-paid workers

    o Use the tax-benefit system to redistribute income

    o Much else

  • Part 1 – What does secular stagnation have to do with

    inequalities and ageing populations?

    • Demand versus supply-side aspects of secular stagnation

    • Inequalities and ageing affect both demand and supply, but

    I will focus largely on supply-side channels

  • Demand versus supply-side theories

    of secular stagnation

    • Chronically deficient aggregate demand is classic focus, at least

    in North America

    o Alvin Hansen’s 1938 Presidential address to the AEA forecast chronic

    low demand (very wrong, as did not predict World War II)

    o Slow recoveries from the bursting of Japan’s bubble economy in the

    early 1990s and, more recently, the GFC in the US much of Europe is

    reviving interest in secular stagnation theory

    • Chronic slow/no growth can also reflect low potential growth

    rates due to supply-side factors:

    o Slow input growth (quantity or quality)

    o Slow productivity growth

  • Population ageing and rising inequality probably have

    their strongest impacts on the supply side

    • Stagnant/ageing population reduces the growth of labour input

    o Clearly true with respect to the quantity of labour, unless participation

    rates rise

    o Impact on the quality of labour is less clear

    • Rising inequality most strongly effects who benefits from growth,

    but may also contribute to slowing growth by impeding human

    capital development

    • Both factors can also have demand-side effects

    o Hansen cited slower population growth as a factor leading to low

    investment spending

    o Rising inequality may lower consumer spending or lead to unsustainable

    debt levels

  • Part 2 – How did the GFC affect potential growth?

    • Recent OECD estimates of the “hit” on potential output

    • Possible channels from a recession/banking crisis to lower

    potential growth rates

  • OECD GDP per capita compared with various pre-crisis trends

    In 2010 PPP US dollars

    Note: OECD GDP per capita over the period 2014-16 is based on November 2014 OECD Economic Outlook projections.

    Source: OECD calculations based on OECD Economic Outlook, November 2014 long-term database.

    24,000

    26,000

    28,000

    30,000

    32,000

    34,000

    36,000

    38,000

    40,000

    42,000

    44,000

    1991 1993 1995 1997 1999 2001 2003 2005 2007 2009 2011 2013 2015

    Actual GDP per capita

    Pre-crisis trend GDP per capita, 2000-07

    Potential GDP per capita

    Pre-crisis trend potential GDP per capita, 2000-07

  • Estimated effects of the crisis on the potential output of

    OECD countries Percentage reduction in potential output relative to a pre-crisis counter-factual scenario

    Note: Estimated effects of the crisis are measured relative to a counter-factual scenario in which trend productivity continues at its pre-crisis

    (2000-7) trend growth rate, structural unemployment rates remain at their pre-crisis (2007) levels and trend participation rates are projected to

    allow for evolving demographics by holding labour force entry and exit rates constant at pre-crisis levels.

    Source: OECD calculations based on OECD Economic Outlook, November 2014 long-term database.

    -12

    -10

    -8

    -6

    -4

    -2

    0

    2

    2007 2008 2009 2010 2011 2012 2013 2014 2015

    %

    OECD aggregate

    Median

    Upper/Lower quartile

  • Contributions to the effect of the crisis on the potential

    output for individual OECD countries Percentage-point differences in 2014, relative to a pre-crisis counter-factual scenario

    Note: An asterisk (*) denotes that country is judged to have experienced a banking crisis between 2007 and 2011 based on Laeven and

    Valencia (2012). Estimated effects of the crisis are measured relative to a counter-factual scenario in which trend productivity continues at its

    pre-crisis (2000-7) trend growth rate, structural unemployment rates remain at their pre-crisis (2007) levels and trend participation rates are

    projected to allow for evolving demographics by holding labour force entry and exit rates constant at pre-crisis levels.

    Source: OECD calculations based on OECD Economic Outlook, November 2014 long-term database.

    -25

    -20

    -15

    -10

    -5

    0

    5

    DEU* JPN USA* OECD GBR* FIN IRL* GRC*

    %

    Nairu

    Participation rate

    TFP

    Capital per worker

    Total

  • Part 3 – How do inequalities and

    population ageing fit into the picture?

    • Inequality trends and their impacts on potential growth rates

    • Population ageing/stagnation reduces the size of the labour

    force and thus potential growth, while also reinforcing the

    rise in inequality

  • Income inequality increased in good times, and it

    continued increasing in bad times Long-term trends in inequality of disposable income (Gini coefficient)

    Source: OECD Income Distribution Database, www.oecd.org/social/income-distribution-database.htm.

    Note: Income refers to disposable income adjusted for household size.

    0.18

    0.2

    0.22

    0.24

    0.26

    0.28

    0.3

    0.32

    0.34

    0.36

    0.38

    0.4

    http://www.oecd.org/social/income-distribution-database.htmhttp://www.oecd.org/social/income-distribution-database.htmhttp://www.oecd.org/social/income-distribution-database.htmhttp://www.oecd.org/social/income-distribution-database.htmhttp://www.oecd.org/social/income-distribution-database.htm

  • Inequality drags down economic growth and harms opportunities

    Note: The graph plots the average predicted numeracy score for individuals from low, medium and high family (educational) backgrounds, as a function

    of the degree of inequality (Gini points) in the country at the time they were around 14 years old. Marginal effects obtained using estimates are shown in

    Table 2.A1.2, column 7 (i.e. conditioning the degree of formal education). The dotted blue line replicates the results reported in Figure 2.4 in the case of

    low PEB individuals. Low PEB: neither parent has attained upper secondary education; medium PEB: at least one parent has attained secondary and

    post-secondary, non-tertiary education; high PEB: at least one parent has attained tertiary education. Dotted lines represent baseline probabilities for

    each group. The bars indicate 95% confidence intervals. The vertical dashed lines indicate the 25th, the median and the 75th percentiles of the

    underlying distribution of inequality.

    Source: OECD Secretariat calculations based on PIAAC data.

    Average numeracy score conditional on parental educational background (PEB) and inequality

    250

    260

    270

    280

    290

    300

    18 20 22 24 26 28 30 32 34 36 38

    Num

    erac

    y S

    core

    Inequality (Gini coefficient)

    Low PEB Medium PEB High PEB

  • Ageing and slowing growth mean that generational improvements in

    living standards are slowing in many countries, especially for the less

    educated (further raising inequality)

  • Part 4 – What should governments do?

    • A comprehensive strategy that works on multiple fronts is

    needed, including measures to:

    o Raise participation rates (especially of women and older workers)

    o Raise the earnings of low-paid workers

    o Redistribute income via the tax-benefit system

    o And much else (e.g. better macroeconomic policy, immigration,

    innovation policy, ….)

  • Activation measures, targeted to under-represented

    groups could play a key role

    Note: OECD is the weighted average of the 31 OECD countries reported in this figure (excluding Greece, Iceland and Turkey).

    a) 2008-13 for Chile; 2007-11 for Israel and the United Kingdom; 2007-12 for France, Korea, New Zealand, Poland and Spain. Fiscal years for

    Australia (starting on 1 July), Canada (starting on 1 April), Japan (starting on 1 April), New Zealand (starting on 1 July), the United Kingdom (starting

    on 1 April), and the United States (starting on 1 October).

    b) Short-time work schemes (Employment Adjustment Subsidies and Employment Continuation Benefit of the Employment Insurance) are included

    in the active labour market spendings for Japan.

    c) Data on unemployment for Israel have been adjusted to be consistent with the data published since 2012 using the chaining coefficient provided

    by the National Authorities.

    Source: OECD estimates based on the OECD Labour Market Programmes, Eurostat Labour Market Policy and OECD Short-Term Labour Market

    Statistics Database.

    Evolution of ALMP expenditures per unemployed: Annualised average percentage change, 2007-13a

    -25

    -20

    -15

    -10

    -5

    0

    5

    10

    15

    20

    25

    %

  • Building relevant skills is key, but also using them in the labour

    market

    a) The Survey of Adult Skills only covered Flanders (Belgium) and England/Northern Ireland (United Kingdom).

    Source: OECD Employment Outlook 2015, Chapter 2.

    Average numeracy scores and average skill use levels

    2

    2.1

    2.2

    2.3

    2.4

    2.5

    2.6

    2.7

    2.8

    2.9

    250

    255

    260

    265

    270

    275

    280

    285

    290

    295

    Numeracy proficiency scores (left axis) Numeracy use (right axis)

  • Promoting access to skills in high demand is essential, but also

    rewarding them equally: the case of gender pay gaps

    a) OECD calculated as the simple, unweighted country average. Wage gaps are expressed as the log of the D9/D1 ratio.

    b) The Survey of Adult Skills only covered Flanders (Belgium) and England/Northern Ireland (United Kingdom).

    Source: OECD Employment Outlook 2015, Chapter 2.

    Male-female wage ratio before and after controlling for skills distribution and price effectsa

    0.9

    1

    1.1

    1.2

    1.3

    1.4

    1.5

    1.6

    Raw

    Skills distribution

    Skills prices

  • The minimum wage can be a useful tool to combat

    in-work poverty Minimum wages as a percent of median and average wages of full-time employees, 2007 and 2013

    Note: Germany: the minimum-wage level in 2015 is expressed as proportion of the projected 2015 median wage. Projections are based on earnings data

    from the OECD Economic Outlook Database.

    Source: OECD Employment Outlook 2015, Chapter 1.

    30

    40

    50

    60

    70

    80

    %

    2007 2013

  • Redistribution through taxes and benefits plays an important role for

    decreasing inequality

    Note: Data for 2007 refer to 2006 for Chile and Japan; and 2008 for Australia, France, Germany, Israel, Mexico, Norway, New Zealand, Sweden, and the

    United States. Data for 2011 refer to 2009 for Japan; 2010 for Austria and Belgium; and 2012 for Australia, Finland, Hungary, Korea, Mexico, the

    Netherlands and the United States. For Hungary, Mexico and Turkey data on market income inequality are not available. There is a break in the series in

    2011 for the United Kingdom, and results are not strictly comparable. 2011 data for Ireland and the United Kingdom are provisional. OECD-30 average

    excludes Hungary, Mexico, Switzerland and Turkey.

    Inequality of (gross) market and disposable (net) income, working-age population, 2011

    20

    25

    30

    35

    40

    45

    50

    55

    60

    Market income inequality (↗) Disposable income inequality

  • 20

    Thank you Contact: [email protected]

    OECD Directorate for Employment, Labour and Social Affairs, via www.oecd.org/els

    Follow us on Twitter, via @OECD_Social

    OECD Employment Outlook, via www.oecd.org/employment/outlook

    OECD Employment database, via www.oecd.org/employment/database

    https://twitter.com/OECD_Social