Entropy, pricing and macroeconomics of pumped-storage systems · 6. Pumped-storage for optimal...

1
Fuel depletion conditions Entropy, pricing and macroeconomics of pumped-storage systems Georgios Karakatsanis, Nikos Mamassis, Demetris Koutsoyiannis and Andreas Efstratiades Department of Water Resources and Environmental Engineering, School of Civil Engineering National Technical University of Athens (NTUA), “ITIA” Research Team (www.itia.ntua.gr ) Abstract We propose a pricing scheme for the optimization of macroeconomic performance of pumped-storage systems, based on the statistical properties of both geophysical and economic processes. The argument consists in the need for identification of economic values concerning the hub energy resource; defined as the resource that comprises a reference energy currency for all involved renewable energy sources (RES) and discounts related uncertainty. In the case of pumped-storage systems the hub resource is the reservoir’s water, as an energy benchmark for connected intermittent RESs. The uncertainty of related natural and economic processes is statistically quantifiable by entropy. It is the relation between the entropies of involved RESs that shapes total energy value added; thus the macroeconomic state of the integrated pumped-storage system. Consequently, there must be consideration not only on the entropy of wind, solar and precipitation patterns, but on the entropy of economic processes as well such as demand preferences on either immediate energy use or storage for future availability. For pumped- storage macroeconomics, a price on the reservoir’s capacity scarcity should also be imposed in order to shape a coherent pricing field with upper and lower bounds for the long-term stability of the pricing range and significant energy value added; which are the primary issues of generalized pumped-storage technology deployment. Keywords: Entropy, pricing, macroeconomics, hub energy resource, RES, uncertainty, energy value added, energy storage, capacity scarcity Bibliography and References 1. Crampes, Claude and Michel Moreaux (2010), Pumped storage and cost saving, Energy Economics 32, 325-333 2. Horsley, Antony and Andrew J. Wrobel (2002), Efficiency rents for pumped storage plants and their use for operation and investment decisions, Journal of Economic Dynamics and Control 27, 109-142 3. Jaynes, E.T. (1991), How Should We Use Entropy in Economics?, St. John’s College, Cambridge, England 4. Kapsali M. and J.K. Kaldelis (2010), Combining hydro and variable wind power generation by means of pumped-storage under economically viable terms, Applied Energy 87, 3475-3485 5. Karakatsanis, Georgios et al. (2013), Entropy and reliability of water use via a statistical approach of scarcity, 5th EGU Leonardo Conference Hydrofractals 2013 STAHY 13, Kos Island, Greece, European Geosciences Union, International Association of Hydrological Sciences, International Union of Geodesy and Geophysics 6. Karakatsanis, Georgios (2012), An energy R&D fund for energy paradigm transitions: micro and macro scale analysis, 12 th Biennial Conference of the International Society for Ecological Economics (ISEE), Rio de Janeiro, Brazil 7. Rippi, Aikaterini (2013), Mathematical simulation of hybrid systems: The system of Ikaria, Diploma Thesis (135p.), Department of Water Resources and Environmental Engineering, National Technical University of Athens (NTUA) 8. Roegen-Georgescu, Nicholas (1971), The Entropy Law and the Economic Process, Harvard University Press 9. Samuelson, Paul (1960), An Extension of the Lechatelier Principle, Econometrica 28, 368-379 10. Shannon, Claude E. (1948), A Mathematical Theory of Communication, The Bell System Technical Journal, Vol. 27, pp. 379- 423, 623-656 11. Zhao, Ghuanghzi and Matt Davison (2009), Optimal control of hydroelectric facility incorporating pumped storage, Renewable Energy 34, 1064-1077 1. Entropy and hydro-economic adaptability Shannon (1948) postulated a statistical mechanical definition of entropy, concerning the propagation complexity of a communication signal as a random variable (X) within a specific time-frame. We conceptualize processes of hydrological supply as signals that incorporate uncertainty; statistically quantified by entropy. Uncertainty may very well comprise a function of structured complexity. The connection of entropy to water resource economics lies in the effort of the economy to reconfigure its internal structure towards higher robustness against natural variability, via (a) charting an internal probability space of higher resolution (wider amplitude of technical capabilities to adequately meet a wider amplitude of natural events) and (b) and the use of an interpretation language of higher complexity (more options). Considering that for the economic system Shannon’s formula H(X) comprises a function of its own language complexity as well, we may write: The main difference of H(m;n) from the conventional conceptualization of H(X) is that it further comprises a function of the economic system’s language complexity to interpret hydrological processes with a better encoding than the dual (1,0). For pumped-storage deployment this is equivalent to more alternative options (structures) thus reduction of dependence from natural uncertainty (Fig. 1). The sophistication of each of the structures affect the entropy rate (Fig. 2) as it makes them flexible towards a wider amplitude of events. 3. Entropy and energy systems integration: Efficiency increase 3. Entropy of geophysical series and pumped-storage The optimization of a pumped-storage system primarily depends on its geophysical variables; the natural inputs of each connected intermittent Renewable Energy Source (RES), as their coordination or independence will affect the pumped-storage cycle (i.e. a heavy rainfall event that fills the reservoir, with high wind energy output and low energy demand is probable to lead to lower utility of the system’s main purpose due to failure to store wind energy excesses). Mutual Information is a scale-free measure of entropy decrease based on conditional probability of the two events’ joint frequency. European Geosciences Union (EGU) General Assembly 2014 “The Face of the Earth” HS 5.4 / CL 4.8 / ERE 1.16 Integrating hydropower with solar and wind related energies for sustainable future: Modelling, technology and management issues m i i n i P P n m H 1 log ; dx x f x f n x H X n X X ) ( log ) ( ; (X) (Y) 6. Pumped-storage for optimal energy resource composition The energy strategy of the system consists in satisfying electricity demand by minimizing the resource composition cost per unit time -including the depletion cost for each resource (Scarcity Rent, SR=μ). P-S hydropower is introduced to an initial mix of fuel and wind (upper figures). The system achieves 77,92% storage of total previous excesses; 80% of fuel output excesses that contributed by 80,92% to total excesses- and 69,1% of wind that contributed by 19,08% to total excesses (middle figures). Resource use optimization occurs for minimum depletion ratio per unit time (C it /S it , as the basis of the scarcity rent concept) for each resource. P-S hydropower reduces the fuel depletion ratio by 48,9% (lower figures) with fuel exhaustion assumed at cumulative output of 20MW and a constraint upon minimum reservoir volume. 5. Simulation of a simple pumped-storage system We model a simplified version of the Ikaria island pumped-storage system (Rippi 2013) that consists of: (1) a diesel fuel power station, (2) a wind park and (3) a hydropower station with an upper reservoir and a lower tank (by 400m) that gathers water after hydroelectricity output in order to store it for pumping. The basic energy deficit and supply excess characteristics of the system are presented below: For a discrete-time random variable For a continuous-time random variable 4. Entropy and energy systems pricing: The scarcity rent The scarcity rent derives as a shadow price imposed on the depletion of a biophysical surplus and has a strong link to the 2 nd Law of Thermodynamics (Karakatsanis 2012). According to Roegen (1971), macroscopically, entropy manifests as energy unavailability for further production of thermo- mechanical work. The scarcity rent was primary developed for fossil fuels depletion in order to represent rising scarcity due to the monotonic irreversibility of fuel degradation to heat, as an imposed cost on future availability and need for a transition to new technologies (left figure) with price (P St ). The notion of scarcity rent can be well expanded to any kind of surplus, such as reservoir capacity and available water electricity output. Scarcity rents for renewable surpluses such as water- represent only immediate unavailability (Karakatsanis et al. 2013); thus are fluctuating. For pumped-storage with fluctuating water scarcity- the optimal pricing path is defined from the minimum price per unit time. 7. Conclusions Pumped-storage is equivalent to an increase of the economic system’s complexity language towards a more sophisticated management of intermittent energy inputs. Maximization of intermittent renewables’ penetration and conservation of fuel reserves for future availability can lead to an optimal use path of non-renewable resources. Minimization of the scarcity rent may comprise a macroeconomic pricing target that is also in accordance to the 2 nd Law (via the imposing of shadow prices across fuel depletion). Mutual Information I(X;Y) Entropy, the complexity language and the economic macrostate (macroeconomics) Primary efforts by economist Paul Samuelson (1960) followed by Edward Jaynes (1991)- concerned the identification of how an economic system’s macrostate may be shaped by its internal micro-structure (microeconomy). Following a more classical approach, Roegen (1971) argued that the utility of a resource is reverse proportional to its entropy, as high entropy signifies a higher cost (in terms of production factors’ sacrifice) for its economic utilization. m i i P t s 1 1 . . 1 ) ( . . dx x f t s X A wits problem for Hermes... A master in economics and trade god asks himself: How to put into cooperation Aeolus (symbolizing the god of winds) with Achelous (symbolizing the rivers as the most famous ancient Greek river-god) and tame their variability in order to conserve the Earth’s energy resources for as long as possible? Wind Energy Output P Mutual Information Field Towards correlation maximization X x Y y y P x P y x P y x P Y X I ) ( ) ( ) , ( log ) , ( ) ; ( Time series (X) and (Y) share four (4) points of negative correlation (dark blue) and one (1) of positive (light blue) 0,00 1,00 2,00 3,00 4,00 5,00 6,00 7,00 8,00 1 301 601 901 1201 1501 1801 2101 2401 2701 3001 3301 3601 3901 4201 4501 4801 5101 5401 5701 6001 6301 6601 6901 7201 7501 7801 8101 8401 8701 Energy Demand Fuel energy supply (Min=0,6) Wind energy supply Hydro energy supply 0,00 0,20 0,40 0,60 0,80 1,00 1,20 1,40 1,60 1 301 601 901 1201 1501 1801 2101 2401 2701 3001 3301 3601 3901 4201 4501 4801 5101 5401 5701 6001 6301 6601 6901 7201 7501 7801 8101 8401 8701 Total energy rejections without P-S (Fuel+Wind) 0,00 0,10 0,20 0,30 0,40 0,50 0,60 0,70 0,80 0,90 1 301 601 901 1201 1501 1801 2101 2401 2701 3001 3301 3601 3901 4201 4501 4801 5101 5401 5701 6001 6301 6601 6901 7201 7501 7801 8101 8401 8701 Wind energy rejections (without P-S) 0 25 50 75 100 125 150 175 200 0,1 0,6 1,1 1,6 2,1 2,6 3,1 3,6 4,1 4,6 5,1 5,6 6,1 Distribution of Deficits (MW) without P-S Distribution of Excesses (MW) without P-S t t t D A A 1 0 / t t A D 0 / dt dA Non-stationarity of the Depletion Ratio (and Scarcity Rent) A rising trend of the fuel depletion ratio (lower right diagram) is obvious in both cases; however its evolution is more unstable in the first case. The depletion ratio C t /A t-1 is constantly pressured towards a monotonic increase due to the minimum depletion of the fuel reserve -equal to the quantity needed to produce 0,6MW/h. Observed drops -due to high substitution from wind and hydropower- are only temporary as the ratio is increasingly more sensitive towards A t-1 and unpredictable around a rising trend. The utility of renewables consists in the delay of this process. Although renewable, hydropower is affected by depleting fuel reserves, as the economy resorts more frequently to it; being increasingly depended on hydrological uncertainty (entropy) related to reservoir recharge. Optimal integration consists in increasing the statistical efficiency (subsets A 1 , B 1 ) of the system’s components (sets A, B) by: (a) minimizing the supply uncertainty of connected intermittent sources (i.e. wind) and (b) minimizing excessive output, via storage to a hub resource (water in the reservoir). The derivation of scarcity rent from an optimization problem The scarcity rent derives from the problem of optimizing a resource’s pricing path, whether it is a fossil resource or a biophysical capacity (i.e. the free capacity of a reservoir or the available water from the minimum volume) as a Net Present Value (NPV) maximization under quantity constraints: Independent energy systems A+B Efficiency: (A 1 +B 1 )/(A+B) Losses: (A 2 +B 2 )/(A+B), with [A 1 |B 2 ]=[B 1 |A 2 ]=Ø Integrated energy systems A+B Efficiency: (A 1 +B 1 )/(A+B) Losses: (A 2 +B 2 -A 2 B 1 )/(A+B) Efficiency increase due to system integration (A 2 +B 2 )/(A+B) > (A 2 +B 2 -A 2 B 1 )/(A+B) T t t I T t q t t t q A r dq C q P L t 0 0 0 1 ) ( T t q t t t t r dq C q P NPV 0 0 1 ) ( The Lagrange Multiplier μ is a dimensionless measure of constraint intensity on the economy across biophysical surplus depletion t C t , μ t , P Ft , P St Ps t C t P F t A 2 B 1 Optimal Price Path Scarcity Rent (SR) it it it C P t C t , μ t , P Ft , P St Ps t C t P F t μ t t S F t P P Min P ) , ( 0,00 0,10 0,20 0,30 0,40 0,50 0,60 0,70 0,80 0,90 1,00 0 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10 n=2;m=10 n=3;m=10 n=4;m=10 H=P 0,00 0,10 0,20 0,30 0,40 0,50 0,60 0,70 0,80 0,90 1,00 0 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10 n=2;m=8 n=2;m=6 n=2;m=4 H=P A : Fuel Reserve; C : Cost; P : Price; D : Demand; q : Extracted Quantity; μ : Scarcity Rent (Lagrange Multiplier); r : Discount Rate B 1 A 2 A 1 A 2 B 1 B 2 A 1 B 2 0,00 1,00 2,00 3,00 4,00 5,00 6,00 7,00 8,00 1 301 601 901 1201 1501 1801 2101 2401 2701 3001 3301 3601 3901 4201 4501 4801 5101 5401 5701 6001 6301 6601 6901 7201 7501 7801 8101 8401 8701 Energy Demand Fuel energy supply (Min=0,6) Wind energy supply 0 0,1 0,2 0,3 0,4 0,5 0,6 0,7 0,8 0,9 1 1,1 1 301 601 901 1201 1501 1801 2101 2401 2701 3001 3301 3601 3901 4201 4501 4801 5101 5401 5701 6001 6301 6601 6901 7201 7501 7801 8101 8401 8701 Ct/St Hydro Ct/St-1 Fuel 0 0,1 0,2 0,3 0,4 0,5 0,6 0,7 0,8 0,9 1 1,1 1 301 601 901 1201 1501 1801 2101 2401 2701 3001 3301 3601 3901 4201 4501 4801 5101 5401 5701 6001 6301 6601 6901 7201 7501 7801 8101 8401 8701 Ct/St-1 Fuel without P-S Ct/St-1 Fuel with P-S 0,00 0,10 0,20 0,30 0,40 0,50 0,60 0,70 1 301 601 901 1201 1501 1801 2101 2401 2701 3001 3301 3601 3901 4201 4501 4801 5101 5401 5701 6001 6301 6601 6901 7201 7501 7801 8101 8401 8701 Fuel energy rejections (without P-S) -7,00 -6,00 -5,00 -4,00 -3,00 -2,00 -1,00 0,00 1,00 2,00 3,00 1 301 601 901 1201 1501 1801 2101 2401 2701 3001 3301 3601 3901 4201 4501 4801 5101 5401 5701 6001 6301 6601 6901 7201 7501 7801 8101 8401 8701 Energy Output (Total) Energy Losses (Total after P-S) Energy Storage (Total) 0,00 0,15 0,30 0,45 0,60 0,75 0,90 1,05 1,20 1,35 1,50 1,65 1 301 601 901 1201 1501 1801 2101 2401 2701 3001 3301 3601 3901 4201 4501 4801 5101 5401 5701 6001 6301 6601 6901 7201 7501 7801 8101 8401 8701 Energy Storage (Total) Energy Storage (Fuel) Energy Storage (Wind)

Transcript of Entropy, pricing and macroeconomics of pumped-storage systems · 6. Pumped-storage for optimal...

Page 1: Entropy, pricing and macroeconomics of pumped-storage systems · 6. Pumped-storage for optimal energy resource composition The energy strategy of the system consists in satisfying

Fuel depletion conditions

Entropy, pricing and macroeconomics of pumped-storage systems Georgios Karakatsanis, Nikos Mamassis, Demetris Koutsoyiannis and Andreas Efstratiades

Department of Water Resources and Environmental Engineering, School of Civil Engineering

National Technical University of Athens (NTUA), “ITIA” Research Team (www.itia.ntua.gr)

Abstract We propose a pricing scheme for the optimization of macroeconomic performance of pumped-storage systems, based on the statistical properties of both geophysical and economic processes. The argument consists in the need for identification of economic values concerning the hub energy resource; defined as the resource that comprises a reference energy currency for all involved renewable energy sources (RES) and discounts related uncertainty. In the case of pumped-storage systems the hub resource is the reservoir’s water, as an energy benchmark for connected intermittent RESs. The uncertainty of related natural and economic processes is statistically quantifiable by entropy. It is the relation between the entropies of involved RESs that shapes total energy value added; thus the macroeconomic state of the integrated pumped-storage system. Consequently, there must be consideration not only on the entropy of wind, solar and precipitation patterns, but on the entropy of economic processes as well –such as demand preferences on either immediate energy use or storage for future availability. For pumped-storage macroeconomics, a price on the reservoir’s capacity scarcity should also be imposed in order to shape a coherent pricing field with upper and lower bounds for the long-term stability of the pricing range and significant energy value added; which are the primary issues of generalized pumped-storage technology deployment.

Keywords: Entropy, pricing, macroeconomics, hub energy resource, RES, uncertainty, energy value added, energy storage, capacity scarcity

Bibliography and References 1. Crampes, Claude and Michel Moreaux (2010), Pumped storage and cost saving, Energy Economics 32, 325-333

2. Horsley, Antony and Andrew J. Wrobel (2002), Efficiency rents for pumped storage plants and their use for operation and investment decisions, Journal of Economic Dynamics and Control 27, 109-142

3. Jaynes, E.T. (1991), How Should We Use Entropy in Economics?, St. John’s College, Cambridge, England

4. Kapsali M. and J.K. Kaldelis (2010), Combining hydro and variable wind power generation by means of pumped-storage under economically viable terms, Applied Energy 87, 3475-3485

5. Karakatsanis, Georgios et al. (2013), Entropy and reliability of water use via a statistical approach of scarcity, 5th EGU Leonardo Conference – Hydrofractals 2013 – STAHY ‘13, Kos Island, Greece, European Geosciences Union, International Association of Hydrological Sciences, International Union of Geodesy and Geophysics

6. Karakatsanis, Georgios (2012), An energy R&D fund for energy paradigm transitions: micro and macro scale analysis, 12th Biennial Conference of the International Society for Ecological Economics (ISEE), Rio de Janeiro, Brazil

7. Rippi, Aikaterini (2013), Mathematical simulation of hybrid systems: The system of Ikaria, Diploma Thesis (135p.), Department of Water Resources and Environmental Engineering, National Technical University of Athens (NTUA)

8. Roegen-Georgescu, Nicholas (1971), The Entropy Law and the Economic Process, Harvard University Press

9. Samuelson, Paul (1960), An Extension of the Lechatelier Principle, Econometrica 28, 368-379

10. Shannon, Claude E. (1948), A Mathematical Theory of Communication, The Bell System Technical Journal, Vol. 27, pp. 379-423, 623-656

11. Zhao, Ghuanghzi and Matt Davison (2009), Optimal control of hydroelectric facility incorporating pumped storage, Renewable Energy 34, 1064-1077

1. Entropy and hydro-economic adaptability

Shannon (1948) postulated a statistical mechanical definition of entropy, concerning the propagation complexity of a communication signal as a random variable (X) within a specific time-frame. We conceptualize processes of hydrological supply as signals that incorporate uncertainty; statistically quantified by entropy. Uncertainty may very well comprise a function of structured complexity. The connection of entropy to water resource economics lies in the effort of the economy to reconfigure its internal structure towards higher robustness against natural variability, via (a) charting an internal probability space of higher resolution (wider amplitude of technical capabilities to adequately meet a wider amplitude of natural events) and (b) and the use of an interpretation language of higher complexity (more options). Considering that for the economic system Shannon’s formula H(X) comprises a function of its own language complexity as well, we may write:

The main difference of H(m;n) from the conventional conceptualization of H(X) is that it

further comprises a function of the economic system’s language complexity to interpret hydrological processes with a better encoding than the dual (1,0). For pumped-storage deployment this is equivalent to more alternative options (structures) –thus reduction of dependence from natural uncertainty (Fig. 1). The sophistication of each of the structures affect the entropy rate (Fig. 2) as it makes them flexible towards a wider amplitude of events.

3. Entropy and energy systems integration: Efficiency increase

3. Entropy of geophysical series and pumped-storage

The optimization of a pumped-storage system primarily depends on its geophysical variables; the natural inputs of each connected intermittent Renewable Energy Source (RES), as their coordination or independence will affect the pumped-storage cycle (i.e. a heavy rainfall event that fills the reservoir, with high wind energy output and low energy demand is probable to lead to lower utility of the system’s main purpose due to failure to store wind energy excesses). Mutual Information is a scale-free measure of entropy decrease based on conditional probability of the two events’ joint frequency.

European Geosciences Union (EGU) General Assembly 2014

“The Face of the Earth” HS 5.4 / CL 4.8 / ERE 1.16

Integrating hydropower with solar and wind related energies for sustainable future: Modelling, technology and management issues

m

i

ini PPnmH1

log; dxxfxfnxH XnXX )(log)(;

(X)

(Y)

6. Pumped-storage for optimal energy resource composition

The energy strategy of the system consists in satisfying electricity demand by minimizing the resource composition cost per unit time -including the depletion cost for each resource (Scarcity Rent, SR=μ). P-S hydropower is introduced to an initial mix of fuel and wind (upper figures). The system achieves 77,92% storage of total previous excesses; 80% of fuel output excesses –that contributed by 80,92% to total excesses- and 69,1% of wind –that contributed by 19,08% to total excesses (middle figures). Resource use optimization occurs for minimum depletion ratio per unit time (Cit/Sit, as the basis of the scarcity rent concept) for each resource. P-S hydropower reduces the fuel depletion ratio by 48,9% (lower figures) –with fuel exhaustion assumed at cumulative output of 20MW and a constraint upon minimum reservoir volume.

5. Simulation of a simple pumped-storage system

We model a simplified version of the Ikaria island pumped-storage system (Rippi 2013) that consists of: (1) a diesel fuel power station, (2) a wind park and (3) a hydropower station with an upper reservoir and a lower tank (by 400m) that gathers water after hydroelectricity output in order to store it for pumping. The basic energy deficit and supply excess characteristics of the system are presented below:

For a discrete-time random variable For a continuous-time random variable

4. Entropy and energy systems pricing: The scarcity rent

The scarcity rent derives as a shadow price imposed on the depletion of a biophysical surplus and has a strong link to the 2nd Law of Thermodynamics (Karakatsanis 2012). According to Roegen (1971), macroscopically, entropy manifests as energy unavailability for further production of thermo-mechanical work. The scarcity rent was primary developed for fossil fuels depletion in order to represent rising scarcity due to the monotonic irreversibility of fuel degradation to heat, as an imposed cost on future availability and need for a transition to new technologies (left figure) with price (PSt). The notion of scarcity rent can be well expanded to any kind of surplus, such as reservoir capacity and available water electricity output. Scarcity rents for renewable surpluses –such as water- represent only immediate unavailability (Karakatsanis et al. 2013); thus are fluctuating. For pumped-storage –with fluctuating water scarcity- the optimal pricing path is defined from the minimum price per unit time.

7. Conclusions

Pumped-storage is equivalent to an increase of the economic system’s complexity language towards a more sophisticated management of intermittent energy inputs.

Maximization of intermittent renewables’ penetration and conservation of fuel reserves for future availability can lead to an optimal use path of non-renewable resources.

Minimization of the scarcity rent may comprise a macroeconomic pricing target that is also in accordance to the 2nd Law (via the imposing of shadow prices across fuel depletion).

Mutual Information I(X;Y)

Entropy, the complexity language and the economic macrostate (macroeconomics)

Primary efforts by economist Paul Samuelson (1960) –followed by Edward Jaynes (1991)- concerned the identification of how an economic system’s macrostate may be shaped by its internal micro-structure (microeconomy). Following a more classical approach, Roegen (1971) argued that the utility of a resource is reverse proportional to its entropy, as high entropy signifies a higher cost (in terms of production factors’ sacrifice) for its economic utilization.

m

i

iPts1

1.. 1)(.. dxxfts X

A wits problem for Hermes...

A master in economics and trade god asks himself: How to put into cooperation Aeolus (symbolizing the god of winds) with Achelous (symbolizing the rivers as the most famous ancient Greek river-god) and tame their variability in order to conserve the Earth’s energy resources for as long as possible?

Wind Energy Output

P

Mutual Information

Field

Towards correlation maximization

Xx Yy yPxP

yxPyxPYXI

)()(

),(log),();(

Time series (X) and (Y) share four (4) points of negative

correlation (dark blue) and one (1) of positive (light blue)

0,00

1,00

2,00

3,00

4,00

5,00

6,00

7,00

8,00

1

30

1

60

1

90

1

12

01

15

01

18

01

21

01

24

01

27

01

30

01

33

01

36

01

39

01

42

01

45

01

48

01

51

01

54

01

57

01

60

01

63

01

66

01

69

01

72

01

75

01

78

01

81

01

84

01

87

01

Energy Demand Fuel energy supply (Min=0,6)

Wind energy supply Hydro energy supply

0,00

0,20

0,40

0,60

0,80

1,00

1,20

1,40

1,60

1

30

1

60

1

90

1

12

01

15

01

18

01

21

01

24

01

27

01

30

01

33

01

36

01

39

01

42

01

45

01

48

01

51

01

54

01

57

01

60

01

63

01

66

01

69

01

72

01

75

01

78

01

81

01

84

01

87

01

Total energy rejections without P-S (Fuel+Wind)

0,00

0,10

0,20

0,30

0,40

0,50

0,60

0,70

0,80

0,90

1

30

1

60

1

90

1

12

01

15

01

18

01

21

01

24

01

27

01

30

01

33

01

36

01

39

01

42

01

45

01

48

01

51

01

54

01

57

01

60

01

63

01

66

01

69

01

72

01

75

01

78

01

81

01

84

01

87

01

Wind energy rejections (without P-S)

0

25

50

75

100

125

150

175

200

0,1 0,6 1,1 1,6 2,1 2,6 3,1 3,6 4,1 4,6 5,1 5,6 6,1

Distribution of Deficits (MW) without P-S

Distribution of Excesses (MW) without P-S

ttt DAA 1

0/ tt AD

0/ dtdA

Non-stationarity of the Depletion Ratio (and Scarcity Rent) A rising trend of the fuel depletion ratio (lower right diagram) is obvious in both cases; however its evolution is more unstable in the first case. The depletion ratio Ct/At-1 is constantly pressured towards a monotonic increase due to the minimum depletion of the fuel reserve -equal to the quantity needed to produce 0,6MW/h. Observed drops -due to high substitution from wind and hydropower- are only temporary as the ratio is increasingly more sensitive towards At-1 and unpredictable around a rising trend. The utility of renewables consists in the delay of this process. Although renewable, hydropower is affected by depleting fuel reserves, as the economy resorts more frequently to it; being increasingly depended on hydrological uncertainty (entropy) related to reservoir recharge.

Optimal integration consists in increasing the statistical efficiency (subsets A1, B1) of the system’s components (sets A, B) by: (a) minimizing the supply uncertainty of connected intermittent sources (i.e. wind) and (b) minimizing excessive output, via storage to a hub resource (water in the reservoir).

The derivation of scarcity rent from an optimization problem The scarcity rent derives from the problem of optimizing a resource’s pricing path, whether it is a fossil resource or a biophysical capacity (i.e. the free capacity of a reservoir or the available water from the minimum volume) as a Net Present Value (NPV) maximization under quantity constraints:

Independent energy systems A+B

Efficiency: (A1+B1)/(A+B) Losses: (A2+B2)/(A+B), with [A1|B2]=[B1|A2]=Ø

Integrated energy systems A+B

Efficiency: (A1+B1)/(A+B) Losses: (A2+B2-A2B1)/(A+B)

Efficiency increase due to system integration

(A2+B2)/(A+B) > (A2+B2-A2B1)/(A+B)

T

t

tI

T

t

q

t

tt qAr

dqCqPL

t

00 0 1

)(

T

t

q

t

tt

t

r

dqCqPNPV

0 0 1

)( The Lagrange Multiplier μ is a dimensionless measure of constraint intensity on the

economy across biophysical surplus depletion

t

Ct, μt, PFt, PSt Pst

Ct

PFt

A2B1

Optimal Price Path

Scarcity Rent (SR) ititit CP

t

Ct, μt, PFt, PSt

Pst

Ct

PFt μt

tSFt PPMinP ),(

0,00

0,10

0,20

0,30

0,40

0,50

0,60

0,70

0,80

0,90

1,00

0 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10

n=2;m=10 n=3;m=10 n=4;m=10 H=P

0,00

0,10

0,20

0,30

0,40

0,50

0,60

0,70

0,80

0,90

1,00

0 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10

n=2;m=8 n=2;m=6 n=2;m=4 H=P

A: Fuel Reserve; C: Cost; P: Price; D: Demand; q: Extracted Quantity; μ: Scarcity Rent (Lagrange Multiplier); r: Discount Rate

B1 A2

A1 A2 B1 B2

A1 B2

0,00

1,00

2,00

3,00

4,00

5,00

6,00

7,00

8,00

1

30

1

60

1

90

1

12

01

15

01

18

01

21

01

24

01

27

01

30

01

33

01

36

01

39

01

42

01

45

01

48

01

51

01

54

01

57

01

60

01

63

01

66

01

69

01

72

01

75

01

78

01

81

01

84

01

87

01

Energy Demand Fuel energy supply (Min=0,6) Wind energy supply

0

0,1

0,2

0,3

0,4

0,5

0,6

0,7

0,8

0,9

1

1,1

1

30

1

60

1

90

1

12

01

15

01

18

01

21

01

24

01

27

01

30

01

33

01

36

01

39

01

42

01

45

01

48

01

51

01

54

01

57

01

60

01

63

01

66

01

69

01

72

01

75

01

78

01

81

01

84

01

87

01

Ct/St Hydro Ct/St-1 Fuel

0

0,1

0,2

0,3

0,4

0,5

0,6

0,7

0,8

0,9

1

1,1

1

30

1

60

1

90

1

12

01

15

01

18

01

21

01

24

01

27

01

30

01

33

01

36

01

39

01

42

01

45

01

48

01

51

01

54

01

57

01

60

01

63

01

66

01

69

01

72

01

75

01

78

01

81

01

84

01

87

01

Ct/St-1 Fuel without P-S Ct/St-1 Fuel with P-S

0,00

0,10

0,20

0,30

0,40

0,50

0,60

0,70

1

30

1

60

1

90

1

12

01

15

01

18

01

21

01

24

01

27

01

30

01

33

01

36

01

39

01

42

01

45

01

48

01

51

01

54

01

57

01

60

01

63

01

66

01

69

01

72

01

75

01

78

01

81

01

84

01

87

01

Fuel energy rejections (without P-S)

-7,00

-6,00

-5,00

-4,00

-3,00

-2,00

-1,00

0,00

1,00

2,00

3,00

1

30

1

60

1

90

1

12

01

15

01

18

01

21

01

24

01

27

01

30

01

33

01

36

01

39

01

42

01

45

01

48

01

51

01

54

01

57

01

60

01

63

01

66

01

69

01

72

01

75

01

78

01

81

01

84

01

87

01

Energy Output (Total) Energy Losses (Total after P-S)

Energy Storage (Total)

0,00 0,15 0,30 0,45 0,60 0,75 0,90 1,05 1,20 1,35 1,50 1,65

1

30

1

60

1

90

1

12

01

15

01

18

01

21

01

24

01

27

01

30

01

33

01

36

01

39

01

42

01

45

01

48

01

51

01

54

01

57

01

60

01

63

01

66

01

69

01

72

01

75

01

78

01

81

01

84

01

87

01

Energy Storage (Total) Energy Storage (Fuel) Energy Storage (Wind)