Conflict and Development—Lessons from South Asia€¦ · little attention is that of conflict...

8
1 POVERTY REDUCTION AND ECONOMIC MANAGEMENT (PREM) NETWORK www.worldbank.org/economicpremise SEPTEMBER 2010 • Number 31 Economic Premise POVERTY REDUCTION AND ECONOMIC MANAGEMENT NETWORK (PREM) THE WORLD BANK Conflict and Development—Lessons from South Asia Ejaz Ghani and Lakshmi Iyer South Asia is the second most violent place on earth after Iraq. Conflicts in Afghanistan and Pakistan have attracted global attention. Parts of India, Sri Lanka, and Nepal have experienced long-running conflict. Conflicts result in death, misery, social trauma, destruction of infrastructure, and have huge spillover effects. What is conflict? Where is it concentrated? Is conflict a problem for development, or a failure of development? What should policy makers do? What Is Conflict? Conflict is a clash between two opposing groups, and can be external or internal to the country. An example of external clash is state-to-state conflict (interstate war). This kind of con- flict has declined. But internal conflict is on the rise. Indeed, internal conflicts have resulted in three times as many deaths as external conflicts, or interstate wars, since World War II (Fearon and Laitin 2003). Internal conflict is a loose term. It can be classified into two broad categories (Ghani and Iyer 2010). The first category is conflict against the state. Examples of this are civil war, separat- ist movements, and suicide bombings. Suicide bombings are an extreme manifestation of conflict carried out by a relatively organized group of nonstate actors, and their goal is the desta- bilization of the state; all such incidents will be referred to here as terrorism. The second category is people-to-people conflict. Examples of this include conflicts between ethnic and social groups, localized land conflicts, religious riots, homicides, do- mestic violence, common violence, or other crimes. Ethnic and religious violence stand out in people-to-people conflict (Stew- art 2010; Varshney 2002). The two types of internal conflicts have evolved differently in South Asia. People-to-people conflict has declined: in India, clashes between Hindus and Muslims have not increased over the past decade, and homicide rates have declined substantial- ly. But conflict against the state has increased. Researchers tend to focus on conflict against the state, because it has greater im- plications for the stability of the state itself, and therefore im- pacts states’ abilities to implement developmental policy. The impact of people-to-people conflict is less severe compared to conflict against the state. These two categories of conflict make it easier to explore po- tential relationships between conflict and development. Such an approach is also better aligned with the economic literature on institutions and economic growth (Acemoglu, Johnson, and Robinson 2001). Of the different types of institutions which have been identified as important to development—market- creating institutions, market-regulating institutions, market substituting institutions—the type that has received relatively little attention is that of conflict management or market-legiti- mizing institutions. Yet political stability is a prerequisite for implementing changes to any of the other types of institutions. Even in a best-case scenario, the presence of even low-level con- flict places constraints on the kinds of policies governments can implement. Is Conflict a Problem for Development, or a Failure of Development? Figure 1 plots the internal conflict rate and real per capita in- come for a large group of countries. The vertical axis reports the number of people killed in terrorist incidents (normalized by population) as a measure of conflict rate (it excludes state-to- Public Disclosure Authorized Public Disclosure Authorized Public Disclosure Authorized Public Disclosure Authorized Public Disclosure Authorized Public Disclosure Authorized Public Disclosure Authorized Public Disclosure Authorized

Transcript of Conflict and Development—Lessons from South Asia€¦ · little attention is that of conflict...

Page 1: Conflict and Development—Lessons from South Asia€¦ · little attention is that of conflict management or market-legiti-mizing institutions. Yet political stability is a prerequisite

1 POVERTY REDUCTION AND ECONOMIC MANAGEMENT (PREM) NETWORK www.worldbank.org/economicpremise

SEPTEMBER 2010 • Number 31

1 POVERTY REDUCTION AND ECONOMIC MANAGEMENT (PREM) NETWORK www.worldbank.org/economicpremise

JUNE 2010 • Number 18

Economic Premise

POVERTYREDUCTION

AND ECONOMICMANAGEMENT

NETWORK (PREM)

THE WORLD BANK

Trade and the Competitiveness AgendaJosé Guilherme Reis and Thomas Farole

Export-Led Growth, the Crisis, and the End of an Era

The dramatic expansion in global trade over recent decadeshas contributed significantly to diversification, growth, andpoverty reduction in many developing countries. This periodof rapid export growth has been enabled by two criticalstructural changes in global trade: (1) the vertical and spatialfragmentation of manufacturing into highly integrated“global production networks,” and (2) the rise of servicestrade and the growth of “offshoring.” Both of these, in turn,were made possible by major technological revolutions; andthey were supported by multilateral trade policy reformsand broad liberalizations in domestic trade and investmentenvironments worldwide.

The global economic crisis came crashing into the middleof this long-running export-led growth party during 2008and 2009. Between the last quarter of 2007 and the secondquarter of 2009, global trade contracted by 36 percent. Butas the recovery started to strengthen in 2010 (at least untilthe clouds began to form over Europe), the longer-term im-

pacts of the crisis on the policy environment regarding tradeand growth were becoming more apparent. Indeed, in addi-tion to raising concerns over the global commitment to tradeliberalization, the crisis has also led to some serious rethink-ing of some of the conventional wisdom regarding thegrowth agenda—the most important result of which is thelikelihood that governments will play a much more activistrole in the coming years. There are three principal reasonswhy governments are likely to be more actively involved inindustrial and trade policy in the coming years.

First, the crisis has undone faith in markets and discred-ited laissez-faire approaches that rely simply on trade policyliberalization. Instead, governments and local markets havebeen “rediscovered.” In this sense, the demand for activistgovernment is likely to go well beyond financial markets andregulation, and it will affect the policy environment in whichtrade and industrial strategies are designed.

Second, the crisis has highlighted the critical importanceof diversification (of sectors, products, and trading partners)in reducing the risks of growth volatility. The recent era ofglobalization contributed to substantial specialization of

The global economic crisis has forced a major rethinking of the respective roles of governments and markets in theprocesses of trade and growth. Indeed, industrial policy seems to be back in fashion—or, at least, talking about it is.But a renewed “activism” by government in the trade and growth agenda need not mean a return to old-stylepolicies of import substitution and “picking winners.” Instead, it may mean a stronger focus on competitiveness byunlocking the constraints to private sector–led growth. This note discusses the renewed role of government in tradeand growth policy from the competitiveness angle, and it suggests some priorities for the new competitiveness agenda.

Conflict and Development—Lessons from South AsiaEjaz Ghani and Lakshmi Iyer

South Asia is the second most violent place on earth after Iraq. Conflicts in Afghanistan and Pakistan have attracted global attention. Parts of India, Sri Lanka, and Nepal have experienced long-running conflict. Conflicts result in death, misery, social trauma, destruction of infrastructure, and have huge spillover effects. What is conflict? Where is it concentrated? Is conflict a problem for development, or a failure of development? What should policy makers do?

What Is Conflict?

Conflict is a clash between two opposing groups, and can be external or internal to the country. An example of external clash is state-to-state conflict (interstate war). This kind of con-flict has declined. But internal conflict is on the rise. Indeed, internal conflicts have resulted in three times as many deaths as external conflicts, or interstate wars, since World War II (Fearon and Laitin 2003).

Internal conflict is a loose term. It can be classified into two broad categories (Ghani and Iyer 2010). The first category is conflict against the state. Examples of this are civil war, separat-ist movements, and suicide bombings. Suicide bombings are an extreme manifestation of conflict carried out by a relatively organized group of nonstate actors, and their goal is the desta-bilization of the state; all such incidents will be referred to here as terrorism. The second category is people-to-people conflict. Examples of this include conflicts between ethnic and social groups, localized land conflicts, religious riots, homicides, do-mestic violence, common violence, or other crimes. Ethnic and religious violence stand out in people-to-people conflict (Stew-art 2010; Varshney 2002).

The two types of internal conflicts have evolved differently in South Asia. People-to-people conflict has declined: in India, clashes between Hindus and Muslims have not increased over the past decade, and homicide rates have declined substantial-ly. But conflict against the state has increased. Researchers tend

to focus on conflict against the state, because it has greater im-plications for the stability of the state itself, and therefore im-pacts states’ abilities to implement developmental policy. The impact of people-to-people conflict is less severe compared to conflict against the state.

These two categories of conflict make it easier to explore po-tential relationships between conflict and development. Such an approach is also better aligned with the economic literature on institutions and economic growth (Acemoglu, Johnson, and Robinson 2001). Of the different types of institutions which have been identified as important to development—market-creating institutions, market-regulating institutions, market substituting institutions—the type that has received relatively little attention is that of conflict management or market-legiti-mizing institutions. Yet political stability is a prerequisite for implementing changes to any of the other types of institutions. Even in a best-case scenario, the presence of even low-level con-flict places constraints on the kinds of policies governments can implement.

Is Conflict a Problem for Development, or a Failure of Development?

Figure 1 plots the internal conflict rate and real per capita in-come for a large group of countries. The vertical axis reports the number of people killed in terrorist incidents (normalized by population) as a measure of conflict rate (it excludes state-to-

Pub

lic D

iscl

osur

e A

utho

rized

Pub

lic D

iscl

osur

e A

utho

rized

Pub

lic D

iscl

osur

e A

utho

rized

Pub

lic D

iscl

osur

e A

utho

rized

Pub

lic D

iscl

osur

e A

utho

rized

Pub

lic D

iscl

osur

e A

utho

rized

Pub

lic D

iscl

osur

e A

utho

rized

Pub

lic D

iscl

osur

e A

utho

rized

wb350881
Typewritten Text
56610
Page 2: Conflict and Development—Lessons from South Asia€¦ · little attention is that of conflict management or market-legiti-mizing institutions. Yet political stability is a prerequisite

2 POVERTY REDUCTION AND ECONOMIC MANAGEMENT (PREM) NETWORK www.worldbank.org/economicpremise

state conflict and common crime). The horizontal axis plots real GDP per capita. The downward sloping line suggests that countries that have low per capita income have a higher conflict rate. This is consistent with other findings in the literature that report higher conflict rates in low-income countries (Collier et al. 2003).

However, the relationship between conflict and per capita income is not very tight. High income can’t guarantee peace and stability. There are many countries that are outliers. It is quite striking that many South Asian countries are outliers: In-dia, Pakistan, Sri Lanka, and Nepal all have much higher con-flict rates than expected for their stage of development.

One cannot infer causality from figure 1. Conflict may be contributing to low per capita income, or low income may be contributing to conflict. The poverty-conflict link is a two-way relationship. A better understanding of causality has big poli-cy implications. If it is conflict that holds back growth, then policy makers should focus on controlling conflict, perhaps by increasing military and police interventions to reduce con-flict. But if it is low income and high poverty that cause con-flict, then the focus should be on direct policy interventions to reduce poverty and human misery. In India, there is some evi-dence that states that had more welfare and less police had less

violence than states that had more police and less welfare (Jus-tino 2009).

If cross-country data suggest an inverse association between conflict incidents and per capita income, would subnational data also show that conflict rates are higher in lagging regions compared to leading regions within countries (lagging regions have lower per capita income compared to national average)? Indeed, this is exactly the situation in South Asia.

Figure 2 shows that in India, Bangladesh, Nepal, Pakistan, and Sri Lanka, conflict is concentrated in the lagging regions. The lagging regions of Pakistan (Balochistan, Federally Admin-istered Tribal Areas [FATA], and North-West Frontier Province [NWFP]), India (Maoist insurgency in Bihar, Chhattisgarh, Jharkhand, and Orissa), and Sri Lanka (northern province), have high conflict rates. Nepal appears to be an exception in terms of showing greater conflict in leading regions (figure 3).

The differences in conflict intensity across leading and lag-ging regions are statistically significant, as shown by formal t-tests (table 1). In South Asia as a whole, lagging regions experi-enced more than three times the number of terrorist incidents per capita, compared with leading regions, and almost twice as many deaths per capita in such incidents (see table 1, panel A, first two rows). This is a large difference and remains statisti-

Figure 1. Conflict and Violence (1998–2004)

Source: LaFree and Dugan (2008).Note: The figure takes the arithmetic mean for fatalities and income per capita for the period 1998–2004. Fatality is the number of total confirmed fatalities for the incident. The number includes all victims and attackers who died as a direct result of the incident.

6 7 111098

GDP per capita, PPP (in logs)

log

(num

ber

of d

eath

s pe

r ca

pita

)

2

4

0

1

3 NepalRwanda

Sierra LeoneBurundi

Congo, Rep. of

Liberia

Ethiopia

Guinea

Kenya

Uganda

Tanzania

Pakistan

Bangladesh

Sudan

UzbekistanNigeria

Vietnam

HaitiSenegalTajikistan

Cambodia

India

Angola

Saudi Arabia

Philippines

Sri Lanka

Spain

IsraelRussian Federation

Algeria

Colombia

Switzerland

Turkey

Morocco

Georgia

Honduras

Yemen, Rep. of

Indonesia

Egypt, Arab Rep. of

Namibia

ThailandPeru

Lebanon

Macedonia

Finland

United States

Taiwan

Germany

United KingdomParaguay Serbia and

Montenegro

MexicoCongo, Dem. Rep. of Iran, Islamic Rep. of

Syrian Arab Rep.

Page 3: Conflict and Development—Lessons from South Asia€¦ · little attention is that of conflict management or market-legiti-mizing institutions. Yet political stability is a prerequisite

3 POVERTY REDUCTION AND ECONOMIC MANAGEMENT (PREM) NETWORK www.worldbank.org/economicpremise

cally significant even after controlling for changes that affected the whole region in any given year.

Some of this difference is attributable to cross-country dif-ferences: Afghanistan and Nepal are both much poorer than rest of South Asia, and have suffered high levels of conflict. But, consistent with the results in figure 3, the difference between lagging and leading regions is present within individual coun-tries as well: lagging regions within Bangladesh, India, Pakistan, and Sri Lanka have more than twice the levels of per capita con-flict than leading regions within the same countries.

What Explains Higher Concentration of Con-flict in Poor Regions?

That conflict is higher in lagging regions is consistent with the cross-country literature on the incidence of civil war, which shows that poor countries are at greater risk of internal conflict (Collier and Hoeffler 2004); Fearon and Laitin 2003). Time-series studies of conflict find that poor economic circumstanc-es are more likely to result in conflict: Miguel, Satyanath, and Sergenti (2004) find that civil war is more likely to begin in Af-

Figure 2. South Asia Conflict Intensity Map

Source: Conflict categories created by authors based on data from the RAND-MIPT Terrorism Incident Database for the period 1998–2007.

Haryana

Madhya Pradesh

Rajasthan

Bihar

Chhattisgarh

Orissa

AndhraPradesh

WestBengal

Jharkhand

PunjabUttarakhand

FarWestern

MidWestern

WesternCentralEastern

HimachalPradesh

UttarPradesh

Delhi

Nagaland

Manipur

Meghalaya

Sikkim

Assam

MizoramTripura

Punjab

Northern

NorthCentral

Western

SabaragamuwaSouthern

Uva

Central

Eastern

RajshahiDhaka

Sylhet

Chittagong

BarisalKhulna

Nepal

N.W.F.P.

FarWestern

Sikkim

Northern

NorthCentral

North Western

Western

SabaragamuwaSouthern

Uva

Central

Eastern

Chittagong

Afghanistan

BhutanBangladesh

This map was produced by the Map Design Unitof The World Bank. The boundaries, colors,denominations and any other informationshown on this map do not imply, on the part of The World Bank Group, any judgment on the legal status of any territory, or any endorsement or acceptance of such boundaries.

IBRD 37114APRIL 2010

Low

Medium

High

No data

Pakistan

India

Balochistan

Sindh

Gujarat

Maldives

Sri Lanka

Maharashtra

Goa

Karnataka

KeralaTamilNadu

Page 4: Conflict and Development—Lessons from South Asia€¦ · little attention is that of conflict management or market-legiti-mizing institutions. Yet political stability is a prerequisite

4 POVERTY REDUCTION AND ECONOMIC MANAGEMENT (PREM) NETWORK www.worldbank.org/economicpremise

Source: RAND-MIPT Terrorism Incident Database. Note: In the interests of showing the within country details, the per capita figures are per million population for Bangladesh and India, and per 100,000 for Pakistan, Sri Lanka, and Nepal. The latter three countries experienced significantly higher levels of overall conflict per capita over this period. The MIPT data for Nepal are not of high quality.

Bangladesh India NepalSri LankaPakistan0

0.5

1.0

1.5

2.0

2.5

leading regions lagging regions

terr

oris

t inc

iden

ts p

er c

apita

Figure 3. Comparing Terrorist Incidents across Leading and Lagging Regions within Countries

Source: LaFree and Dugan (2008); RAND-MIPT Terrorism Incident Database.Note: Regression differences are calculated by regressing the conflict intensity on a dummy for lagging region and year fixed effects. GTD2 = Global Terrorism Database II. *** Represents significance at 1 percent, ** represents significance at 5 percent, and * represents significance at 10 percent.

Table 1. Are Conflict Differences between Leading and Lagging Regions Statistically Significant?

Variable PlaceLeading regions

Lagging regions Difference

Regression difference

Panel A: MIPT data, 1998–2007

# terrorist incidents per million population

South Asia 0.399 1.195 0.796 0.796***

# fatalities per million population

South Asia 0.521 1.738 1.217 1.217**

# terrorist incidents per million population

Bangladesh 0.115 0.105 -0.011

India 0.165 0.363 0.198

Nepal 2.056 1.511 -0.545

Pakistan 0.249 2.509 2.260

Sri Lanka 0.858 2.495 1.637

Panel B: GTD2 data, 1998–2004

# terrorist incidents per million population

South Asia 0.269 0.559 0.290 0.290**

# fatalities per million population

South Asia 4.045 11.963 7.918 7.918**

# terrorist incidents per million population

Bangladesh 0.096 0.050 0.047

India 0.159 0.129 -0.030

Nepal 0.864 0.698 -0.166

Pakistan 0.204 0.254 0.050

Sri Lanka 1.039 1.641 0.602

Page 5: Conflict and Development—Lessons from South Asia€¦ · little attention is that of conflict management or market-legiti-mizing institutions. Yet political stability is a prerequisite

5 POVERTY REDUCTION AND ECONOMIC MANAGEMENT (PREM) NETWORK www.worldbank.org/economicpremise

rican countries in years following poor rainfall; Hidalgo et al. (2008) find that poor rainfall is associated with an increased incidence of land invasions in Brazil; and Dube and Vargas (2009) document a robust association between reduced coffee prices and the incidence of terrorism in Columbia. Do and Iyer (2010) find similar results in an analysis of conflict intensity across the districts of Nepal.

Figure 4 shows the distribution of poverty rates across the regions of South Asia, measured by the head-count ratio. The

head-count ratio measures the percentage of population in a given area whose consumption is below the poverty line for that region. The head-count ratio here has been calculated with re-spect to national poverty lines for the different countries.

Does poverty incidence match with the incidence of con-flict? The analysis does show a higher incidence of conflict in poor and landlocked regions. Furthermore, there is a close rela-tionship between higher poverty rates and greater conflict. One can easily see that western Pakistan, Afghanistan, Nepal, and

Source: Ghani (2010).

Figure 4. Map of Poverty Head-Count Ratio in South Asia

Haryana

Madhya Pradesh

Maharashtra

Karnataka

TamilNaduKerala

Rajasthan

Gujarat

Bihar

Chhattisgarh

Orissa

AndhraPradesh

WestBengal

Jharkhand

PunjabUttarakhand

FarWestern

MidWestern

WesternCentralEastern

HimachalPradesh

UttarPradesh Assam

Punjab

Sindh

Balochistan

NorthCentral

North Western

Western

SabaragamuwaSouthern

Uva

Central

RajshahiDhaka

Sylhet

BarisalKhulna

Pakistan

India

NEPAL

N.W.F.P.

Chittagong

Kerala

FarWestern

NorthCentral

North Western

Western

SabaragamuwaSouthern

Uva

Central

Chittagong

Afghanistan

SriLanka

Maldives

Bangladesh

This map was produced by the Map Design Unitof The World Bank. The boundaries, colors,denominations and any other informationshown on this map do not imply, on the part of The World Bank Group, any judgment on the legal status of any territory, or any endorsement or acceptance of such boundaries.

IBRD 37361FEBRUARY 2010

8%–23%

23.1%–38%

38.1%–52%

No data

Bhutan

Page 6: Conflict and Development—Lessons from South Asia€¦ · little attention is that of conflict management or market-legiti-mizing institutions. Yet political stability is a prerequisite

6 POVERTY REDUCTION AND ECONOMIC MANAGEMENT (PREM) NETWORK www.worldbank.org/economicpremise

some parts of eastern India have both high levels of poverty and high levels of conflict.

This relationship is visible in figure 5, where we see higher levels of conflict in poorer regions of South Asia. This relation-ship is not uniform within each country; in particular, it is much less strong across regions of Bangladesh. Indeed, this is not a tight relationship. Poverty figures may reflect the effect of any conflict in that region as well, and thus these figures cannot be used to make a causal statement. Furthermore, the existence of conflict complicates the collection of detailed data. In par-ticular, poverty figures are not available for the northern and eastern provinces of Sri Lanka, which had the highest levels of conflict in the whole of South Asia.

Several different interpretations can be made for any ob-served relationship with poverty. It might be easier for rebels to recruit people to their cause in poorer areas, because their op-portunity cost of conflict is relatively low. This “opportunity cost” hypothesis means that the relationship between poverty and conflict will be different for an ethnically based or separat-ist conflict, because recruitment will be made on the basis of ethnicity or regional affiliation, rather than the lowest cost of recruitment. However, another potential interpretation is that poorer regions have poorer state capacity, and hence the govern-

ment is not able to deal with the rebels effectively. In fact, sepa-ratist or ethnic conflicts are often driven by the perception of a specific region or group being discriminated against by the state.

The cross-country literature on civil wars has documented several other features that appear to be important. For instance, Fearon and Laitin (2003) show that geographic conditions that favor insurgency, such as the presence of forest cover, are signifi-cantly associated with the incidence of conflict. How far does this matter for the South Asian context? States in India that have a higher forest cover have higher conflict intensity (see fig-ure 6). This is consistent with numerous accounts of Naxalites using forest cover to hide effectively from law enforcement forc-es. Data from Sri Lanka and Nepal show a similar relationship.

In addition to economic and geographic circumstances, so-cial divisions are often cited as a driver of conflict. For instance, the separatist movement in Sri Lanka began with the demands of ethnic Tamils for greater autonomy. Similarly, the Maoist rebels in Nepal often claim to be fighting on behalf of marginal-ized sections of society, such as members of the lower castes. India’s northeastern states, which are the scene of long-running separatist movements, are socially and ethnically different from the majority of the states in India.

Figure 5. Relationship between Conflict Intensity and Poverty Rates

Source: RAND-MIPT Terrorism Incident Database. Poverty numbers are computed by World Bank staff from individual country data sources. Note: MIPT data are at region level. Figure excludes Balochistan and Central Province in Nepal, which are large outliers. Data on poverty levels are not available for northern and eastern provinces of Sri Lanka.

10 20 4030

poverty rate 2005

num

ber

of te

rror

ist i

ncid

ents

per

mill

ion

popu

latio

n

10

20

0

5

15

incidents per million population fitted values

50

SWes

GujSCen

TNRAJ

PPun

KER

AP

HARHPPUN Mah

BKhu

NFarW

NMidW

BRsh

Asm

PSin

WBKAR

SSou

Jha

MPBih BBarOri

NEas

BDha

SNC

NWes

SNW SUvaCtg

PNWFP

BSylBChiUtc

SSabUP

Page 7: Conflict and Development—Lessons from South Asia€¦ · little attention is that of conflict management or market-legiti-mizing institutions. Yet political stability is a prerequisite

7 POVERTY REDUCTION AND ECONOMIC MANAGEMENT (PREM) NETWORK www.worldbank.org/economicpremise

Conflicts can be triggered by low economic growth (a lower economic opportunity cost of rebellion against the state in poor areas), unequal distribution in gains from development, and political marginalization. Or conflict can result from shocks such as natural calamities or commodity price shocks. The lag-ging regions of South Asia suffer from both types of problems—low economic growth and higher vulnerability to natural ca-lamities (Ghani 2010; Ahmed, Kalegama, and Ghani 2010).

The consequences of conflict on development are more se-vere in lagging regions due to weak institutions, poor geogra-phy, and weak integration with global markets. These are also the characteristics that limit economic growth in lagging re-gions. Leading regions also suffer from conflict but are better able to contain and manage them because of administrative and economic dynamism (which includes job creation capacity and effective safety net programs).

What Should Policy Makers Do to Reduce Conflict?

A speech given by the Prime Minister of India, Dr. Manmohan Singh, to a conference on Internal Security and Law and Order in 2005, sums up the story of conflict and development:

Whatever be the cause, it is difficult to deny that extremism has huge societal costs. Investments are unlikely to fructify, em-ployment is not likely to grow and educational facilities may be impaired…the threat of Naxalism is geographically spread out to the more backward regions and districts of our country.

Reducing conflict is a prerequisite to political stability, which, in turn, is the prerequisite for implementing pro-growth policies. Even in a best-case scenario, the presence of low-level conflict constrains the policies governments can implement to promote growth.

Source: RAND-MIPT Terrorism Incident Database on conflict for Indian states.

Policy makers in South Asia have tried various policies to re-duce conflict. The most common approach is to use police forc-es to establish law and order in the affected areas. The police forces in South Asian countries, however, tend to be under-staffed and underequipped. In cases in which police forces are insufficient, the armed forces are called in to deal with the insur-gency. In most cases, this has not been a successful strategy. Even when successful in defeating the insurgents, as in Sri Lanka, the human cost associated with military operations is very high.

A different approach to dealing with insurgencies is to con-duct negotiations and sign peace agreements with the insur-gents. To be effective, this approach needs two requirements: (1) the government must conduct coordinated negotiations and fulfill at least some of the insurgents’ demands; and (2) the insurgent group must be genuinely interested in joining the po-litical mainstream. This approach has been tried in some areas of South Asia. For instance, the Indian government has signed peace deals with several separatist groups in the northeastern states, granting them a higher degree of local autonomy in some cases. Similarly, negotiations with some Tamil groups in Sri Lanka, such as the EPRLF, have resulted in their integration into mainstream politics.

Complementary to the security-based solution is an eco-nomic solution, whereby the government expands welfare pro-grams and reduces poverty in the conflict-affected areas to un-dercut the support for the insurgency. This approach is consistent with economic backwardness as a cause of conflict. This approach has been tried in some conflicts in South Asia, but it has failed because of poor economic policy selection and poor implementation in conflict regions.

Policy choices and their implementation are critical in pre-venting an escalation of conflict and in postconflict reconstruc-

Figure 6. Forest Cover and Conflict Intensity in South Asia

AP ArP

Asm

BihCdg

C tgDel

G oa G ujHar

HP

Jha

Kar Ker

MPMah

Man

Meg M iz

Nag

O riPun

Raj S ik TN

Tri

UP

U tc

W B0

10

20

30

0 20 40 60 80

#incidents per m illion population fitted values percentage of area under forest over

num

ber

of te

rror

ist i

ncid

ents

pe

r m

illio

n po

pula

tion

Page 8: Conflict and Development—Lessons from South Asia€¦ · little attention is that of conflict management or market-legiti-mizing institutions. Yet political stability is a prerequisite

8 POVERTY REDUCTION AND ECONOMIC MANAGEMENT (PREM) NETWORK www.worldbank.org/economicpremise

tion. Economic policies should be geared not just to maximize growth, which would take time, but also to address the distri-butional or political factors that led to the conflict. Policy choic-es must be structured to reduce real or perceived inequities. Aid agencies should work through the existing government in-stitutions, be practical to create jobs quickly, and in most cases, work on short-term economic goals first and address medium- and longer-term efficiency considerations later. This approach calls for humanitarian treatment for conflict-affected people, closure of refugee camps, and reintegration of refugees within society.

Cross-border cooperation between countries should be an integral part of any strategy to reduce conflict. Many of the in-ternal conflicts in South Asia have cross-border dimensions. The Taliban in Afghanistan obtain significant support from Pakistan’s border areas. The Maoists in Nepal formed close links with the Maoist movements in India. Many separatist groups in India’s northeastern states had training camps and cells in neighboring countries such as Bangladesh and Bhutan. The Liberation Tigers of Tamil Eelam (LTTE) and other Tamil separatist groups in Sri Lanka have traditionally enjoyed sup-port from the Tamil diaspora in India and other countries. In such a context, regional cross-border cooperation is an essential part of any counterinsurgency strategy. Considerable potential exists for regional cooperation in reducing conflict, but this has been an underutilized strategy in combating terrorism in South Asia.

South Asian governments have taken a variety of different approaches to counter terrorism. Reviewing these approaches in the South Asian and global context, it appears that the armed forces or local militias have not been overly effective in combat-ing terrorism. Strengthening police forces or conducting nego-tiations to induce insurgents to join the political mainstream appear to be more effective approaches. Regional cooperation initiatives, which have been underutilized so far, are likely to be important in countering terrorism. The challenge is to find the right combination of these different approaches toward coun-tering conflict, as well as the optimal economic policies to be adopted in postconflict environments.

About the Authors

Ejaz Ghani is economic advisor at the World Bank. Lakshmi Iyer is associate professor at Harvard Business School. A summary of this article appeared in the World Bank Ending Poverty in South Asia Blog and VOX EU. The views expressed here are those of the authors and not of World Bank or Harvard Busi-ness School.

ReferencesAcemoglu, Daron, Simon Johnson, and James A. Robinson. 2001. “The Colo-

nial Origins of Comparative Development: An Empirical Investigation.” American Economic Review 91 (5): 1369–1401.

Ahmed, Sadiq, Saman Kalegama, and Ejaz Ghani, eds. 2010. Promoting Eco-nomic Cooperation in South Asia: Beyond SAFTA. New Delhi, India: SAGE Publications.

Collier, Paul, V. L. Elliott, Havard Hegre, et al. 2003. Breaking the Conflict Trap: Civil War and Development Policy. Washington, DC: World Bank and Ox-ford University Press.

Collier, Paul, and Anke Hoeffler. 2004. “Greed and Grievance in Civil War.” Oxford Economic Papers 56: 563–95.

Do, Quy-Toan, and Lakshmi Iyer. Forthcoming. “Geography, Poverty and Con-flict in Nepal.” Journal of Peace Research.

Fearon, James, and David Laitin. 2003. “Ethnicity, Insurgency, and Civil War.” American Political Science Review 97 75–90.

Ghani, Ejaz, ed. 2010. The Poor Half Billion in South Asia: What Is Holding Back Lagging Regions? Oxford University Press India, http://www.oup.co.in/cat-egory.php?cat_id=54.

Ghani, Ejaz, and Sadiq Ahmed, eds. 2009. Accelerating Growth and Job Cre-ation in South Asia. Oxford University Press, India.

Ghani, Ejaz, and Lakshmi Iyer. 2010. “Conflict and Development: Lessons from South Asia.” VOX EU, March 23, http://www.voxeu.org/index.php?q=node/4794.

Hidalgo, F. Daniel, Suresh Naidu, Simeon Nichter, and Neal Richardson. Forth-coming. “Occupational Choices: Economic Determinants of Land Inva-sions.” Review of Economics and Statistics.

Justino, Patricia. 2009. “The Impact of Armed Civil Conflict on Household Welfare and Policy Responses.” Research Working Papers 12, MICRO-CON—A Micro Level Analysis of Violent Conflict.

LaFree, G., and L. Dugan. 2008. Global Terrorism Database II, 1998–2004. Study #22600, Interuniversity Consortium for Political and Social Re-search.

Miguel, Edward, Shanker Satyanath, and Ernest Sergenti. 2004. “Economic Shocks and Civil Conflict: An Instrumental Variables Approach.” Journal of Political Economy 112 (4): 725–53.

Stewart, Frances, ed. 2010. Horizontal Inequalities and Conflict: Understanding Group Violence in Multiethnic Societies. Palgrave Macmillan, http://us.mac-millan.com/Palgrave.aspx.

Varshney, Ashutosh. 2002. Ethnic Conflict and Civic Life: Hindus and Muslims in India, First Edition. New Haven and London: Yale University Press.

The Economic Premise note series is intended to summarize good practices and key policy findings on topics related to economic policy. They are produced by the Poverty Reduction and Economic Management (PREM) Network Vice-Presidency of the World Bank. The views expressed here are those of the authors and do not necessarily reflect those of the World Bank. The notes are available at: www.worldbank.org/economicpremise.