Ch. 17 International Trade and Comparative Advantage: Understanding Trade Flows

26
17.1 Ch. 17 International Trade and Comparative Advantage: Understanding Trade Flows All economies, regardless of their size, depend to some extent on other economies and are affected by events outside their borders. The “internationalization” or “globalization” of the U.S. economy has occurred in the private and public sectors, in input and output markets, and in business firms and households.

description

Ch. 17 International Trade and Comparative Advantage: Understanding Trade Flows. All economies, regardless of their size, depend to some extent on other economies and are affected by events outside their borders. - PowerPoint PPT Presentation

Transcript of Ch. 17 International Trade and Comparative Advantage: Understanding Trade Flows

Page 1: Ch. 17 International Trade and Comparative Advantage: Understanding Trade Flows

17.1Ch. 17 International Trade and Comparative Advantage: Understanding Trade Flows

• All economies, regardless of their size, depend to some extent on other economies and are affected by events outside their borders.

• The “internationalization” or “globalization” of the U.S. economy has occurred in the private and public sectors, in input and output markets, and in business firms and households.

Page 2: Ch. 17 International Trade and Comparative Advantage: Understanding Trade Flows

17.2Trade Surpluses and Deficits

U.S. Balance of Trade (Exports Minus Imports), 1929 – 1999 (Billions of Dollars)

EXPORTS MINUS IMPORTS EXPORTS MINUS IMPORTS

1929 + 0.4 1984 – 102.0

1933 + 0.1 1985 – 114.2

1945 – 0.9 1986 – 131.9

1955 + 0.4 1987 – 142.3

1960 + 2.4 1988 – 106.3

1965 + 3.9 1989 – 80.7

1970 + 1.2 1990 – 71.4

1975 + 13.6 1991 – 20.7

1976 – 2.3 1992 – 27.9

1977 – 23.7 1993 – 60.5

1978 – 26.1 1994 – 87.1

1979 – 24.0 1995 – 84.3

1980 – 14.9 1996 – 89.0

1981 – 15.0 1997 – 89.3

1982 – 20.5 1998 – 151.5

1983 – 51.7 1999 – 254.0

Page 3: Ch. 17 International Trade and Comparative Advantage: Understanding Trade Flows

17.3The Economic Basis for Trade: Comparative Advantage

• Corn Laws were the tariffs, subsidies, and restrictions enacted by the British Parliament in the early nineteenth century to discourage imports and encourage exports of grain.

• David Ricardo’s theory of comparative advantage , which he used to argue against the corn laws, states that specialization and free trade will benefit all trading partners (real wages will rise), even those that may be absolutely less efficient producers.

• A country enjoys an absolute advantage over another country in the production of a product if it uses fewer resources to produce that product than the other country does.

• A country enjoys a comparative advantage in the production of a good if that good can be produced at a lower cost in terms of other goods.

Page 4: Ch. 17 International Trade and Comparative Advantage: Understanding Trade Flows

17.4Mutual Absolute Advantage

YIELD PER ACRE OF WHEAT AND COTTONNEW ZEALAND AUSTRALIA

Wheat 6 bushels 2 bushels

Cotton 2 bales 6 bales

New Zealand has an absolute advantage in Wheat because one acre of land in New Zealand can produce 6 bushels of wheat whereas an acre in Australia can produce only 2 bushels of wheat.

Australia has an absolute advantage in Cotton because one acre of land in Australia can produce 6 bales of cotton whereas an acre in New Zealand can produce only 2 bales of cotton.

Since each country has an absolute advantage, we say it is mutual.

Page 5: Ch. 17 International Trade and Comparative Advantage: Understanding Trade Flows

17.5Mutual Absolute Advantage with No Trading

TOTAL PRODUCTION OF WHEAT AND COTTON ASSUMING NO TRADE, MUTUAL ABSOLUTE ADVANTAGE, AND 100 AVAILABLE ACRES

NEW ZEALAND AUSTRALIA

Wheat 25 acres x 6 bushels/acre150 bushels

75 acres x 2 bushels/acre150 bushels

Cotton 75 acres x 2 bales/acre150 bales

25 acres x 6 bales/acre150 bales

Suppose that each country has 100 acres of land and divides its land to obtain equal units of cotton and wheat production. (An assumption about preferences)

Page 6: Ch. 17 International Trade and Comparative Advantage: Understanding Trade Flows

17.6Production Possibility Frontiers for Australia and New Zealand with No Trading

Because both countries have an absolute advantage in the production of one product, specialization and trade will benefit both.

Page 7: Ch. 17 International Trade and Comparative Advantage: Understanding Trade Flows

17.7With Trade: The Gains from Specialization

With Trade: each country uses all of its land to produce the good for which it has an absolute advantage. An agreement to trade 300 bushels of wheat for 300 bales of cotton would double both wheat and cotton consumption in both countries.

PRODUCTION AND CONSUMPTION OF WHEATAFTER SPECIALIZATION

PRODUCTION CONSUMPTION

NEW ZEALAND AUSTRALIA NEW ZEALAND AUSTRALIA

Wheat 100 acres x 6 bu/acre600 bushels

75 acres x 2 bu/acre150 bushels

300 bushels 300 bushels

Cotton 0 acres0

100 acres x 6 bales/acre600 bales

300 bales 300 bales

Page 8: Ch. 17 International Trade and Comparative Advantage: Understanding Trade Flows

17.8With Trade: The Gains from Specialization

Each country can consume beyond its PPF due to specialization and trade. “Trade is good for all parties involved”

Page 9: Ch. 17 International Trade and Comparative Advantage: Understanding Trade Flows

17.9What If There is No Mutual Absolute Advantage: Gains from Comparative Advantage

• Sometimes, resources and abilities aren’t as evenly balanced as in the previous example.

• Suppose a country had a considerable absolute advantage in the production of both goods; Ricardo would argue that specialization and trade are still mutually beneficial.

• Countries should specialize in producing the goods in which they have a comparative advantage. We will see that they maximize their combined output and allocate their resources more efficiently when they do so.

Page 10: Ch. 17 International Trade and Comparative Advantage: Understanding Trade Flows

17.10Gains from Comparative Advantage

Comparative Advantage uses the idea of opportunity cost

• The real (opportunity) cost of producing cotton is the wheat that must be sacrificed to produce it.

• The real (opportunity) cost of producing wheat is the cotton that must be sacrificed to produce it.

A country has a comparative advantage in cotton production if its opportunity cost of cotton, in terms of wheat, is lower than the other country.

A country has a comparative advantage in wheat production if its opportunity cost of wheat, in terms of cotton, is lower than the other country.

Page 11: Ch. 17 International Trade and Comparative Advantage: Understanding Trade Flows

17.11Gains from Comparative Advantage

YIELD PER ACRE OF WHEAT AND COTTONNEW ZEALAND AUSTRALIA

Wheat 6 bushels 1 bushel

Cotton 6 bales 3 bales

Here, Australia’s land is less productive than New Zealand’s in the production of both goods:

For Wheat: one acre of land in NZ produces 6 bushes, whereas one acre of land in AUS produces only 1 bushel.

For Cotton: one acre of land in NZ produces 6 bales, whereas one acre of land in AUS produces only 3 bales.

NZ has an absolute advantage in the production of both goods.

We will see that the countries can still gain from specialization and trade.

Page 12: Ch. 17 International Trade and Comparative Advantage: Understanding Trade Flows

17.12Gains from Comparative Advantage: Calculating Opportunity Cost

To illustrate the gains from comparative advantage, assume (again) that in each country people want to consume equal amounts of cotton and wheat.

YIELD PER ACRE OF WHEAT AND COTTONNEW ZEALAND AUSTRALIA

Wheat 6 bushels 1 bushelCotton 6 bales 3 bales

Wheat:NZ: 6 bushels “cost” 6 bales of cotton 1 bushel costs 1 baleAUS: 1 bushels “cost” 3 bales of cotton 1 bushel costs 3 bale

Cotton:NZ: 6 bales “cost” 6 bushels of wheat 1 bale costs 1 bushelAUS: 3 bales “cost” 1 bushel of wheat 1 bale costs 1/3 bale

Page 13: Ch. 17 International Trade and Comparative Advantage: Understanding Trade Flows

17.13Before Trade

In the next few slides, we will show that both countries can be better off by specializing and then trading with each other

TOTAL PRODUCTION OF WHEAT AND COTTON ASSUMING NO TRADE AND 100 AVAILABLE ACRES

NEW ZEALAND AUSTRALIA

Wheat 50 acres x 6 bushels/acre300 bushels

75 acres x 1 bushels/acre75 bushels

Cotton 50 acres x 6 bales/acre300 bales

25 acres x 3 bales/acre75 bales

Page 14: Ch. 17 International Trade and Comparative Advantage: Understanding Trade Flows

17.14Terms of Trade

Terms of Trade: the ratio at which a country can trade domestic products for imported products

NZ and AUS need to decide the terms of their trade.AUS is going to sell cotton to NZ. In return, NZ is going to sell wheat to AUS, but how much cotton for how much wheat?

As the “buyer” of cotton, NZ won’t offer more than 1 wheat for 1 cotton. As the “seller” of cotton, AUS won’t accept less than 1/3 of a wheat for 1 cotton

They will agree to a ratio between 1 and 1/3.

As the “buyer” of wheat, AUS won’t offer more than 3 cottons for 1 wheat. As the “seller” of wheat, NZ won’t accept less than 1 of cotton for 1 wheat

They will agree to a ratio between 1 and 3.

Let’s pick ½ of a wheat for 1 cotton (or 2 cottons for 1 wheat) as the terms of trade.

Page 15: Ch. 17 International Trade and Comparative Advantage: Understanding Trade Flows

17.15With Trade: Gains from Comparative Advantage

Stage 1: Australia transfers all its land into cotton production. New Zealand cannot completely specialize in wheat because it needs 300 bales of cotton and will not be able to get enough cotton from Australia (if countries are to consume equal amounts of cotton and wheat).

REALIZING A GAIN FROM TRADE WHEN ONE COUNTRY HAS A DOUBLE ABSOLUTE ADVANTAGE

STAGE 1

NEW ZEALAND AUSTRALIA

Wheat 50 acres x 6 bushels/acre300 bushels

0 acres0 bushels

Cotton 50 acres x 6 bales/acre300 bales

100 acres x 3 bales/acre300 bales

Page 16: Ch. 17 International Trade and Comparative Advantage: Understanding Trade Flows

17.16Gains from Comparative Advantage

Stage 2: New Zealand transfers 25 acres out of cotton and into wheat.

REALIZING A GAIN FROM TRADE WHEN ONE COUNTRY HAS A DOUBLE ABSOLUTE ADVANTAGE

STAGE 2

NEW ZEALAND AUSTRALIA

Wheat 75 acres x 6 bushels/acre450 bushels

0 acres0

Cotton 25 acres x 6 bales/acre150 bales

100 acres x 3 bales/acre300 bales

Page 17: Ch. 17 International Trade and Comparative Advantage: Understanding Trade Flows

17.17Gains from Comparative Advantage

Stage 3: Countries trade

REALIZING A GAIN FROM TRADE WHEN ONE COUNTRY HAS A DOUBLE ABSOLUTE ADVANTAGE

STAGE 3

NEW ZEALAND AUSTRALIA

Wheat 450 Bushels (before) 100 bushels (trade)

350 bushels (after)

0 Bushels (before)

100 bushels (after)

Cotton 150 bales (before)

350 bales (after)

300 bales (before)200 bushels (trade)

100 bales (after)

Page 18: Ch. 17 International Trade and Comparative Advantage: Understanding Trade Flows

17.18Gains from Comparative Advantage

Both countries are better off than they were before trade. Both have moved beyond their own production possibility frontiers.

Page 19: Ch. 17 International Trade and Comparative Advantage: Understanding Trade Flows

17.19The Sources ofComparative Advantage

• Factor endowments refer to the quantity and quality of labor, land, and natural resources of a country.

• Factor endowments seem to explain a significant portion of actual world trade patterns.

• The Heckscher-Ohlin theorem is a theory that explains the existence of a country’s comparative advantage by its factor endowments.

• According to the theorem, a country has a comparative advantage in the production of a product if that country is relatively well endowed with inputs used intensively in the production of that product

Page 20: Ch. 17 International Trade and Comparative Advantage: Understanding Trade Flows

17.20Trade Barriers: Tariffs,Export Subsidies, and Quotas

• Protection is the practice of shielding a sector of the economy from foreign competition.

• A tariff is a tax on imports.• Export subsidies are government payments made to domestic firms to

encourage exports. Closely related to subsidies is dumping. A firm or industry sells products on the world market at prices below the cost of production.

• A quota is a limit on the quantity of imports.

• The Smoot-Hawley tariff was the U.S. tariff law of the 1930s, which set the highest tariff in U.S. history (60 percent). It set off an international trade war and caused the decline in trade that is often considered a cause of the worldwide depression of the 1930s.

• The General Agreement on Tariffs and Trade (GATT) is an international agreement singed by the United States and 22 other countries in 1947 to promote the liberalization of foreign trade.

Page 21: Ch. 17 International Trade and Comparative Advantage: Understanding Trade Flows

17.21Economic Integration

• Economic integration occurs when two or more nations join to form a free-trade zone.

• The European Union (EU) is the European trading bloc composed of Austria, Belgium, Denmark, Finland, France, Germany, Greece, Ireland, Italy, Luxembourg, the Netherlands, Portugal, Spain, Sweden, and the United Kingdom.

• The U.S.-Canadian Free-Trade Agreement is an agreement in which the United States and Canada agreed to eliminate all barriers to trade between the two countries by 1988.

• The North American Free-Trade Agreement (NAFTA) is an agreement signed by the United States, Mexico, and Canada in which the three countries agreed to establish all of North America as a free-trade zone.

Page 22: Ch. 17 International Trade and Comparative Advantage: Understanding Trade Flows

17.22The North American Free-Trade Agreement (NAFTA)

• The U.S. Department of Commerce has estimated that as a result of NAFTA trade between the United States and Mexico increased by nearly $16 billion in 1994.

• In addition, exports from the United States to Mexico outpaced imports from Mexico.

• By 1998, a general consensus emerged among economists that NAFTA had led to expanded employment opportunities on both sides of the border.

Page 23: Ch. 17 International Trade and Comparative Advantage: Understanding Trade Flows

17.23The Case for Free Trade

• The case for free trade is based on the theory of comparative advantage. When countries specialize and trade based on comparative advantage, consumers pay less and consume more, and resources are used more efficiently.

• When tariffs and quotas are imposed, some of the gains from trade are lost.

Page 24: Ch. 17 International Trade and Comparative Advantage: Understanding Trade Flows

17.24The Gains from Trade

When world price is $2, domestic quantity demanded rises, and quantity supplied falls. U.S. supply drops and resources are transferred to other sectors.

Page 25: Ch. 17 International Trade and Comparative Advantage: Understanding Trade Flows

17.25The Losses from theImposition of a Tariff

The loss of efficiency from a $1 tariff has two components:1. Consumers must pay a higher

price for goods that could be produced at a lower cost.

2. Marginal producers are drawn into textiles and away from other goods, resulting in inefficient domestic production.

Government revenue equals the shaded area.

Page 26: Ch. 17 International Trade and Comparative Advantage: Understanding Trade Flows

17.26The Case for Protection

• Protection saves jobs• Some countries engage in unfair trade practices• Cheap foreign labor makes competition unfair• Protection safeguards national security• Protection discourages dependency• Protection safeguards infant industries