Activist Short-Selling - University of Toronto T-Space · Activist short-selling – short-sellers...

132
Activist Short-Selling by Wuyang Zhao A thesis submitted in conformity with the requirements for the degree of Doctor of Philosophy Rotman School of Management University of Toronto © Copyright by Wuyang Zhao 2017

Transcript of Activist Short-Selling - University of Toronto T-Space · Activist short-selling – short-sellers...

Page 1: Activist Short-Selling - University of Toronto T-Space · Activist short-selling – short-sellers publicly talking down securities to benefit their short positions – attracts attentions

Activist Short-Selling

by

Wuyang Zhao

A thesis submitted in conformity with the requirements for the degree of Doctor of Philosophy

Rotman School of Management University of Toronto

© Copyright by Wuyang Zhao 2017

Page 2: Activist Short-Selling - University of Toronto T-Space · Activist short-selling – short-sellers publicly talking down securities to benefit their short positions – attracts attentions

ii

Activist Short-Selling

Wuyang Zhao

Doctor of Philosophy

Rotman School of Management

University of Toronto

2017

Abstract

Activist short-selling – short-sellers publicly talking down securities to benefit their short

positions – attracts attentions from a broad range of market participants, but is largely ignored by

the prior literature. Combining information from Seeking Alpha and Activist Shorts Research, I

collect more than 6,000 activist short-selling cases against listed companies from 2006 to 2015

and conduct two large-sample studies on this controversial phenomenon.

Chapter 1 examines the determinants and consequences of activist short-selling,

highlighting the critical roles of ex-ante available firm characteristics. I find that (1) activist short-

selling leads to much larger market reactions than comparable level of short-selling without public

talking-down, (2) activist short-sellers are more likely to target firms with severe overvaluation

and uncertainty features, (3) targets’ overvaluation (uncertainty) features are increasingly

(decreasingly) important in predicting returns from the short term to the long term, (4) their

overvaluation features predict short-selling allegations that focus on valuation issues such as

“bubble,” while their uncertainty features predict allegations that sound severe such as “fraud,”

and (5) uncertainty features also predict targets’ likelihood of responding to allegations.

Page 3: Activist Short-Selling - University of Toronto T-Space · Activist short-selling – short-sellers publicly talking down securities to benefit their short positions – attracts attentions

iii

Chapter 2 focuses on the consequences of activist short-selling on a specific group of

market players: sell-side analysts who cover target firms. Since the sell-side business model

discourages analysts from publishing negative opinions, the demand for negative information is

met by other sources, such as activist short-sellers who frequently accuse analysts’ talking-up as

the main driver of overvaluation. I find that analysts react to activist short-selling by revising their

target-price forecasts. The variation in the timeliness and direction of the reactions can be

explained by the ability and incentives of analysts as well as the initial impact of activist short-

selling. More importantly, analysts’ reputation can be severely damaged by activist short-sellers,

particularly when analysts talk-up too much previously, when short-sellers seem to be right, and

when analysts take too long to respond. However, the direction of analysts’ reactions (i.e., revising

up or down) seems unrelated to the reputation loss. Finally, analysts are more likely to move to

smaller brokerage houses if their covered firms are targeted by activist short-sellers.

Page 4: Activist Short-Selling - University of Toronto T-Space · Activist short-selling – short-sellers publicly talking down securities to benefit their short positions – attracts attentions

iv

Acknowledgments

Frequently I ask myself: what if I had not come to Rotman for this accounting PhD? I can

think of a lot of possibilities, but under no situation could I be as happy, optimistic, and self-

fulfilling as I am now – not even close. Now this Ph.D. is coming to its end; I have a lot of people

to thank.

First of all, I thank the Chair of my advising committee: Professor Ole-Kristian Hope. As

evidenced by the several thousand emails we had in the past four years, he had substantial impact

on every single important event I have had. Here are some examples. Attending his seminar in

Norway in the summer of 2012 led to my admission into the Rotman Accounting PhD program.

Reading a book given by him (i.e., Fooling Some of the People All of the Time) ignited my interest

in short-selling. He is also a key coauthor of my two published papers. As always, I have received

his incredible support and guidance in developing this dissertation. I have been and will always be

learning from him on how to become a successful scholar: hard-working, optimism, confidence,

and care for younger generations.

I also want to thank my four committee members for their valuable support in developing

the dissertation and hunting for a job: Alex Edwards, Partha Mohanram, Baohua Xin, and

Dushyant Vyas. Interacting with them helps me to be a better researcher and a better person.

Specifically, Alex was my mentor in the first year, and since then I have learned how to be a good

colleague from him. Partha’s seminar course on valuation prepared me for the research on activist

short-selling. Also, his broad knowledge about almost everything reminds me of the importance

of being an interesting person. Baohua’s theory seminar led me to think of my dissertation topic

in a deeper level, and I have learned from him how to strike a balance between being humble and

being confident. Dushyant was among the first who made me determined to focus on activist short-

selling, mostly because this is a topic that is highly relevant to practice. He has shaped my taste on

what constitutes good research.

I am grateful to my external examiner, Prof. Michael Welker from Queens’ University, for

his encouragements and highly constructive comments. I still remember that I was talking with

Michael about the attack by Citron Research against Valeant on Oct. 21, 2015 at PCAOB/JAR

conference in D.C. That case makes me to seriously consider to focus on activist short-selling.

Page 5: Activist Short-Selling - University of Toronto T-Space · Activist short-selling – short-sellers publicly talking down securities to benefit their short positions – attracts attentions

v

I wish to thank all the Rotman professors who helped me during the Ph.D. process. I have

discussed my dissertation with almost every faculty member individually, including Francesco

Bova, Jeff Callen, Feng Chen, Gus De Franco, Daehyun Kim, Nan Li, Scott Liao, Gord

Richardson, Christopher Small, Franco Wong, Aida Wahid, Minlei Ye, and Ping Zhang. I also

wish to thank all the fellow Ph.D. students who made my life easier during the four years, including

Muhammad Azim, Mahfuz Chy, Danqi Hu, Ross Lu, Barbara Su, Mingyue Zhang, and particularly

Stephanie Cheng, with whom I was very fortunate to start the program at Rotman.

I thank my coauthors and friends outside Rotman, especially Han Wu at HEC Paris and

Forester Wong at USC. They are always available for random chats, which not only makes the

research work less lonely but more enjoyable.

Finally, I am grateful to my family, especially to my wife and my best friend, Dr. Jessie

Yin Zhu. Equally well-educated and probably more talented, she contains her own aspiration and

ambition, but accompanies me wholeheartedly on an uncertain journey. I am grateful to her

dedication to love, her sacrifice to the family, and her unmatched trust and confidence in me. I

dedicate this doctorate thesis to her and our daughter Grace Shuman Zhao.

In addition, I want to thank people who provided comments on my dissertation, including

Pat Akey, Stefan Anchev, Karthik Balakrishnan, Mark Bradshaw, Wenjiao Cao, Shuping Chen,

Ted Christensen, Dain Donelson, Yiwei Dou, Fabrizio Ferri, Robert Freeman, Pingyang Gao,

Jonathan Glover, Amy Hutton, Ross Jennings, Alon Kalay, Bin Ke, Steve Kachelmeier, Mark Ma,

John McInnis, Stephen Penman, Shivaram Rajgopal, Scott Richardson, Sugata Roychowdhury,

Lakshmanan Shivakumar, Hun Tong Tan, Florin Vasvari, Brian White, Brady Williams, Eyub

Yegen, Yong Yu, Ronghuo Zheng, Emanuel Zur (FEA Discussant), and seminar participants at

Boston College, Columbia University, London Business School, Nanyang Technological

University, National University of Singapore, University of Texas at Austin, 2016 AAA Doctoral

Consortium, 2016 CMU Accounting Mini Conference, 2016 Conference on Financial Economics

and Accounting (FEA), and 2017 Financial Accounting and Reporting Section midyear meeting

(FARS) for comments. Last but not least, I thank Adam Kommel from Activist Shorts Research

for generously sharing his data, and Mingqi Li for Python assistance.

Page 6: Activist Short-Selling - University of Toronto T-Space · Activist short-selling – short-sellers publicly talking down securities to benefit their short positions – attracts attentions

vi

Table of Contents

Abstract ........................................................................................................................................... ii

Acknowledgments.......................................................................................................................... iv

Table of Contents ........................................................................................................................... vi

Introduction ......................................................................................................................................1

Chapter 1 Activist Short-Selling: A Large-Sample Study on the Determinants and

Consequences .............................................................................................................................3

1 Introduction .................................................................................................................................3

2 Related Literature and Hypotheses Development .......................................................................8

2.1 The Differences between Activist and Passive Short-Selling ...............................................9

2.1.1 Short-Selling Incentives ...........................................................................................9

2.1.2 Constraints in the Equity-Loan Market..................................................................10

2.1.3 Short-Selling Risk ..................................................................................................10

2.1.4 Activist Short-Selling as a Coordination Device ...................................................11

2.2 Market Reactions to Activist Short-Selling (H1) ................................................................12

2.3 Activist Short-Selling Strategies (H2 and H3) ....................................................................12

2.4 Overvaluation and Uncertainty Features and Short- and Long-Term Returns (H4) ...........13

3 Data ...........................................................................................................................................14

3.1 Seeking Alpha .....................................................................................................................14

3.2 Activist Shorts Research .....................................................................................................15

3.3 Sample-Construction Process .............................................................................................15

4 Does Activist Short-Selling Have Larger Market Reactions Than Passive Short-Selling? ......16

5 Determinants of Being Targeted by Activist Short-Selling ......................................................18

5.1 Variables and Models ..........................................................................................................18

Page 7: Activist Short-Selling - University of Toronto T-Space · Activist short-selling – short-sellers publicly talking down securities to benefit their short positions – attracts attentions

vii

5.1.1 Overvaluation Features ..........................................................................................18

5.1.2 Uncertainty Features ..............................................................................................19

5.1.3 The Model ..............................................................................................................19

5.2 Determinants Sample ..........................................................................................................20

5.3 Regression Results .............................................................................................................21

5.3.1 Overvaluation Features .............................................................................................21

5.3.2 Uncertainty Features ..............................................................................................21

5.3.3 Horseracing Variables and Including Both Features Together ..............................22

6 Overvaluation and Uncertainty Features and Short- and Long-Term Returns .........................23

6.1 Models and Variables ..........................................................................................................23

6.2 Sample and Regression Results ..........................................................................................23

6.3 An Ex-Ante Approach to Separate Winners vs. Losers among Activist Short-Selling ......24

7 Activist Short-Sellers’ Allegations and Firms’ Tendency to Respond .....................................25

7.1 Short-Sellers’ Allegations ...................................................................................................26

7.2 Firms’ Tendency to React to Short-Sellers’ Allegations ....................................................26

8 Supplemental Analyses and Robustness Tests ..........................................................................27

8.1 Separating ASR and SA Samples .......................................................................................27

8.2 Overvaluation and Uncertainty Features and Short-Interest ...............................................28

8.3 Overvaluation and Uncertainty Features and Analysts’ Recommendations .......................28

8.4 A Pseudo Test Using Peer Firms Matched on Firm Features .............................................29

8.5 The Interaction Effects of Overvaluation and Uncertainty Features ..................................29

8.6 The Role of Media and Short-Sellers’ Reputation ..............................................................30

8.7 Multiple Activist Short-Selling Events in the Same Firm-Quarter .....................................30

8.8 Other Robustness Checks ....................................................................................................31

9 Conclusion ................................................................................................................................31

Page 8: Activist Short-Selling - University of Toronto T-Space · Activist short-selling – short-sellers publicly talking down securities to benefit their short positions – attracts attentions

viii

References of Chapter 1 .................................................................................................................34

Appendices of Chapter 1 ................................................................................................................38

Appendix A: Activist Short-Selling in Seeking Alpha and Activist Shorts Research ..............38

Appendix B: The Activist Short-Selling Date and Financial Reporting Data ..........................40

Appendix C: Variable Definitions ............................................................................................41

Main Tables of Chapter 1 ..............................................................................................................45

Main Figures of Chapter 1 .............................................................................................................59

Additional Robustness Tests ..........................................................................................................60

Chapter 2 Selling Financial Analysts Short: The Impact of Activist Short-Selling on

Sell-Side Analysts ....................................................................................................................83

1 Introduction ...............................................................................................................................83

2 Related Literature ......................................................................................................................89

2.1 Sell-Side Optimism .............................................................................................................89

2.2 Activist Short-Sellers as a Source of Negative Research....................................................90

2.3 Prior Research on the Information Flows between Short-Sellers and Analysts .................91

3 Do Financial Analysts React to Activist Short-Selling? ...........................................................92

4 What Determines Financial Analysts’ Reactions to Activist Short-Selling? ............................94

5 Analysts’ Reputation Loss after Activist Short-Selling ............................................................96

5.1 Main Results .......................................................................................................................96

5.2 Cross-Sectional Variation: Analysts’ View Prior to Activist Short-Selling .......................98

5.3 Cross-Sectional Variation: The Market’s Initial Reactions ................................................98

5.4 Cross-Sectional Variation: What Analysts Can Do to Avoid Reputation Loss ..................99

6 The Impact of Activist Short-Selling on Analysts’ Careers......................................................99

7 Robustness Checks and Supplemental Analyses ....................................................................102

7.1 An Omitted-Variable Problem ..........................................................................................102

7.2 Analysts React by Revising EPS Forecasts ......................................................................102

Page 9: Activist Short-Selling - University of Toronto T-Space · Activist short-selling – short-sellers publicly talking down securities to benefit their short positions – attracts attentions

ix

7.3 Do Investors Become Less Responsive in General? .........................................................103

8 Conclusion ..............................................................................................................................104

References of Chapter 2 ...............................................................................................................105

Appendices of Chapter 2 ..............................................................................................................107

Appendix A: Variable Definitions ..........................................................................................107

Main Tables of Chapter 2 ............................................................................................................109

Main Figures of Chapter 2 ...........................................................................................................120

Page 10: Activist Short-Selling - University of Toronto T-Space · Activist short-selling – short-sellers publicly talking down securities to benefit their short positions – attracts attentions

1

Introduction

Recent years have witnessed a financial innovation where short-sellers publicly talk down

stocks to benefit their short positions (Ljungqvist and Qian 2016), a phenomenon commonly

referred to as “activist short-selling” in the investing community. On top of commenting on

popular media and at investing conferences, the rising popularity of social media platforms has

allowed short-sellers to disseminate their short-theses to a massive crowd. Prominent activist short-

selling cases such as Citron Research’s attack on Valeant attract tremendous attention from the

public, the media, and the regulators. However, due to the lack of easily available data, the prior

literature on short-selling mainly explores its “passive” dimension, focusing on short-interest,

realized short-sales, and market-wide short-selling regulations and largely ignoring the

possibilities of short-sellers as activists. This doctoral thesis seeks to fill the void in the literature

by conducting two large-sample studies on the roles of activist short-selling in capital markets.

Combining information from Seeking Alpha (SA) and Activist Shorts Research (ASR), I collect

more than 6,000 activist short-selling cases from 2006 to 2015 in the US equity market.

Chapter 1 illustrates the differences between activist short-selling and passive short-selling

(i.e., short-selling without public talking-down) and investigates the determinants and

consequences of activist short-selling. First, activist short-selling is expected to be more

informative than its passive counterpart because it is (1) based on profit incentives, (2) largely

unconstrained by the supply in the equity-loan market, and (3) riskier. Second, higher-order beliefs

– the fact that investors infer from short-sellers’ bearish public signals how other investors are

likely to behave – can encourage panic-selling among investors. Indeed, I do find that activist

short-selling leads to bigger market reactions than comparable passive short-selling does.

The core of Chapter 1 is to highlight the crucial roles of two ex-ante firm characteristics:

overvaluation and uncertainty. I find that activist short-sellers are more likely to target firms with

egregious overvaluation (as typical short-sellers do), and firms with high uncertainty (and therefore

with an investor base that could be easily influenced). Next, I examine the return implications of

these two features in the short and long term. I find that long-term returns depend on overvaluation

features more than short-term returns do, but depend on uncertainty features less than short-term

returns do. These results are consistent with the Higher-Order Beliefs view, because short-term

Page 11: Activist Short-Selling - University of Toronto T-Space · Activist short-selling – short-sellers publicly talking down securities to benefit their short positions – attracts attentions

2

returns are affected more by the panic of “lest everyone else get out first,” which relates to

uncertainty, but long-term returns reflect firm fundamentals captured by the overvaluation

features. These results also suggest an ex-ante way to separate winners vs. losers among activist

short-selling cases. Finally, with the rich information available in ASR, I find that overvaluation

features predict allegations on valuation issues (e.g., “bubble”), that uncertainty features predict

allegations that sound severe (e.g., “fraud”), and that firms with uncertainty features are more

likely to respond to allegations by accusing short-sellers of manipulation or by providing relevant

information to address their allegations.

Chapter 2 investigates the consequences of activist short-selling on a specific group of

market player: sell-side analysts. Note that the business model of sell-side research discourages

analysts to publish negative opinions. However, a healthy and efficient capital market requires

opinions from both positive and negative sides. Activist short-sellers are equipped with the right

incentive and abilities to publicly talk down stocks and to meet the market’s need for negative

opinions. Moreover, activist short-sellers frequently accuse analysts’ systematic talking-up as the

key driver of overvaluation. I find that analysts react to activist short-selling by revising their

target-price forecasts, and the variation in the timeliness and direction of the reactions can be

explained by the ability and incentives of analysts as well as the initial impact of activist short-

selling. When analysts’ talking-up meets with activist short-sellers’ talking-down, analysts’

reputation and future career prospects could possibly suffer. Following prior literature, I examine

how the market reacts to analysts’ EPS revisions differently after activist short-selling. I find that

analysts’ reputation can be severely damaged by activist short-sellers, particularly when analysts

talk-up too much previously, when short-sellers seem to be right, and when analysts take too long

to respond. However, the direction of analysts’ reactions (i.e., revising up or down) seems

unrelated to the reputation loss. Also, activist short-selling can influence analysts’ career prospects

such that they are more likely to move to smaller brokerage houses if their covered firms are

targeted by activist short-sellers.

Page 12: Activist Short-Selling - University of Toronto T-Space · Activist short-selling – short-sellers publicly talking down securities to benefit their short positions – attracts attentions

3

Chapter 1 Activist Short-Selling: A Large-Sample Study on the Determinants

and Consequences

Bloomberg TV: “How concerned are you that some short-sellers may be manipulating the market

and prices of certain stocks by either publishing research or making public comments that benefit

their positions?”

Mary Jo White: “… Short-selling has a legitimate positive purpose in the marketplace. That’s very

different, though, than if you manipulate by short-selling.… The whole topic of short-selling is

something that continually gets attention from the SEC, as it does in the marketplace.” 1

1 Introduction

More than 99% of U.S. publicly traded firms (as of the end of 2015 in Compustat) have

some shares being shorted, but most short sales are conducted without public awareness due to

lack of disclosure requirements at the short-seller level. However, in some cases, short-sellers

voluntarily announce their short theses (i.e., the rationale for short-selling) to the public, as

Bloomberg TV mentioned above: “publishing research or making public comments that benefit

their positions.” The investing community refers to such actions as “activist short-selling” and the

short-sellers identify themselves as activist short-sellers.2 These cases, such as Citron Research vs.

Valeant, often create market turmoil and capture the attention from a wide range of market

participants.3 Managers and shareholders are worried that their stocks are attacked by these short-

sellers, traders try to profit from the speculative opportunities created in the process, and regulators

and the public are concerned about the possibility that activist short-sellers are manipulating the

market by creating panic. Motivated by the attentions from those market participants, I conduct a

large-sample study on activist short-selling and highlight the role of ex-ante firm characteristics in

1 Mary Jo White, the SEC Chairwoman, was interviewed on Bloomberg TV on November 10, 2015. See

http://www.bloomberg.com/news/articles/2015-11-10/sec-s-white-says-short-selling-getting-her-intense-attention-. 2 See https://www.activistshorts.com/. These terms are also used in the law literature (e.g., Lee 2013). 3 Citron Research issued multiple short-selling reports on Valeant Pharmaceuticals (NYSE: VRX) from September to

November of 2015. The most influential one was published on October 21, 2015, calling Valeant “the Pharmaceutical

Enron.” The stock price plunged as much as 40% on that day. See more details at http://www.wsj.com/articles/the-

short-who-sank-valeant-stock-1445557157.

Page 13: Activist Short-Selling - University of Toronto T-Space · Activist short-selling – short-sellers publicly talking down securities to benefit their short positions – attracts attentions

4

attracting activist short-sellers, predicting the consequences after firms are targeted, and potentially

helping to separate manipulative short-selling from legitimate short-selling.

Prior literature on short-selling mainly explores its “passive” dimension, focusing on short-

interest, realized short-sales, and market-wide short-selling regulations (see the review by Reed

2013). Activist short-selling differs from passive short-selling in two important ways. First, activist

short-selling is likely to be more informative because (1) it is motivated by incentives betting on

price declines rather delaying tax payment or hedging risk of holding long positions, (2) it is largely

unconstrained by the supply in the equity-loan market, and (3) it is considerably riskier than

passive short-selling. Second, activist short-selling becomes a public signal when the short-seller

talks down stocks. According to Higher-Order Beliefs (HOB) theory (Morris and Shin 2002; Allen,

Morris, and Shin 2006; Gao 2008), a public signal can facilitate an investor in guessing how other

investors will behave. In the presence of an activist short-seller’s bearish public signal, an investor

will sell immediately if she is afraid that other investors will sell soon. Such panic-selling could

collapse stock prices in a stampede, and activist short-sellers are frequently accused of

manipulating stock prices in this way.4

Recognizing the above differences between passive short-selling studied in the prior

literature and activist short-selling, this paper examines the following related questions. First, does

activist short-selling lead to larger market reactions than comparable passive short-selling?

Second, what firm characteristics attract activist short-sellers? Third, how do these ex-ante

characteristics predict short-term and long-term returns for targeted firms? Fourth, do these

characteristics predict the types of allegations short-sellers make and the likelihood for targeted

firms to respond?

I construct a large sample of more than 6,000 activist short-selling cases by combining

information from Seeking Alpha (SA hereafter; www.seekingalpha.com) and Activist Shorts

4 For example, Mike Pearson, the then CEO of Valeant, accused the short-seller Andrew Left of Citron Research that

“(His) motivation is the same as one who runs into a crowded theatre and falsely yells fire. He wanted people to run.

He intentionally designed the report to frighten [emphasis added] our shareholders to drive down the price of our stock

so he could make money for his short selling.” See https://www.ft.com/content/41160372-7bf3-11e5-98fb-

5a6d4728f74e.

Page 14: Activist Short-Selling - University of Toronto T-Space · Activist short-selling – short-sellers publicly talking down securities to benefit their short positions – attracts attentions

5

Research (ASR hereafter; www.activistshorts.com). While SA is the largest crowdsourced

investing platform appealing to non-celebrity short-sellers, ASR tracks all influential activist short-

selling events, providing a complement to the SA sample.

I first report a rapidly increasing trend of activist short-selling in the past decade, echoing

the “intense attention” from the SEC and the marketplace as Chairwoman Mary Jo White

mentioned in the opening quote of this chapter. There are substantial market reactions to activist

short-selling. For example, on average the price drops 1.56% on day 0 (the date in which the short

thesis is announced) benchmarked on the Fama-French three-factor model. To assess whether

activist short-selling leads to larger market reactions than comparable passive short-selling (H1),

I construct five benchmarks based on market reactions to short-interest announcements of either

the targeted firms or their industry peers with the closest or highest level of short-interest ratio or

increase in short-interest. Despite the existence of spillover effects (i.e., peer firms’ prices could

also be adversely affected by activist short-selling), the results show that the market reaction to

activist short-selling is much more pronounced than that to passive short-selling benchmarks.

These results are consistent with both the information view that activist short-selling is more

informative than passive short-selling and the Higher-Order Beliefs view that the bearish public

signal creates a stampede of panic-selling.

My primary hypotheses (H2 – H4) focus on the determinants and consequences of activist

short-selling. The “short-selling” nature indicates that activist short-sellers would like to target

firms with egregious overvaluation, while the “activist” nature suggests that they would like to

target firms with high uncertainty (i.e., a representative investor is not sure how precise her

information is) and therefore with an investor base that could be easily influenced. For the 12

overvaluation features I examine, activist short-sellers target 10 of them, and seven still survive if

I horserace them in one regression, including previous price run-ups, high P/B ratio relative to peer

firms, high P/V ratio, high asset growth, high net operating assets, low recent earnings, and high

accounting-manipulation probability. For the nine uncertainty features I examine, activist short-

sellers target eight of them, and six survive in horseracing, including low accounting quality,

absence of blockholders, few dedicated institutional investors, high bid-ask spreads, non–Big Four

auditor, and internal control weaknesses. I construct two aggregate measures – Overvaluation and

Page 15: Activist Short-Selling - University of Toronto T-Space · Activist short-selling – short-sellers publicly talking down securities to benefit their short positions – attracts attentions

6

Uncertainty – by averaging the seven overvaluation features and six uncertainty features for

subsequent tests.

Next, I examine the return implications of these two features in the short and long term. I

find that overvaluation features affect long-term returns more than short-term returns, but

uncertainty features affect long-term returns less than short-term returns. These results are

inconsistent with the information view, which predicts no differential impact between the short

and long term by either overvaluation or uncertainty features. But they are consistent with the HOB

view, because long-term returns reflect firm fundamentals captured by the overvaluation features,

but short-term returns also reflect the panic of “lest everyone else get out first,” which corresponds

to uncertainty features.5 These results also suggest an ex-ante way to separate winners vs. losers

among activist short-selling cases. Specifically, target firms with overvaluation features higher

than the determinant-test sample median have a one-year cumulative abnormal return of about -

45%, while the remaining target firms do not underperform their risk-adjusted benchmark.

Finally, with the rich information available in ASR, I find that overvaluation features

predict allegations on valuation issues (e.g., “bubble”), that uncertainty features predict allegations

that sound severe (e.g., “fraud”), and that firms with uncertainty features are more likely to respond

to allegations by accusing short-sellers of manipulation or by providing relevant information to

address their allegations. These results are consistent with both the information and HOB views in

that short-sellers provide information about the actual overvaluation but they also try to create a

panic among investors facing higher uncertainty by using severe allegations.

In supplemental analyses, I first confirm that all inferences remain the same in either the

SA or the ASR sample, although ASR short-sellers, unsurprisingly, cause much larger market

reactions than SA short-sellers do. Second, I find that overvaluation and uncertainty features do

not predict short-interest ratio (or its increase), or analysts’ sell recommendations (or downgrades)

in the same way as they predict activist short-selling. Third, I conduct a pseudo test using industry

5 Christopher Cox, former Chairman of the SEC, wrote that “when an irrational panic is fueled by false rumors that

investors believe must be acted on immediately – lest everyone else get out first – market integrity is threatened.” See

Cox, “What the SEC Really Did on Short Selling.” Wall Street Journal, July 24, 2008. Available at

https://www.sec.gov/news/speech/2008/spch072408cc.htm.

Page 16: Activist Short-Selling - University of Toronto T-Space · Activist short-selling – short-sellers publicly talking down securities to benefit their short positions – attracts attentions

7

peer firms matched with the same aggregate Overvaluation and Uncertainty values with each

activist short-selling target and find that these two features do not predict matched firms’ returns

in the same way as they predict targets’ returns. Fourth, I find some evidence that overvaluation

and uncertainty features are substitutes in attracting activist short-selling, but complements in

affecting long-term returns. Fifth, I show that activist short-selling cases covered by media or

initiated by reputable short-sellers lead to more negative returns. Finally, I conduct several other

robustness checks, and all inferences remain unchanged.

To the best of my knowledge, this is the first large-sample study on activist short-selling,

complementing two recent small-sample studies that find substantial market reactions to short-

selling reports. Specifically, Ljungqvist and Qian (2016) use 358 short-seller reports from 2006 to

2011 and find that short-selling reports lead to immediate spikes in SEC filing views, volatility,

order imbalances, realized spreads, turnover, and selling by current shareholders. Chen (2016)

examines 443 short-seller reports on 87 U.S.-listed Chinese firms between 2007 and 2014 and also

documents substantial negative market reactions to the targeted firms and their peer firms sharing

the same non-Big 4 auditors.

There are clear differences between my study and these two. First, while all three studies

find negative reactions to activist short-selling, the key finding of my dissertation is about the vital

roles of firm characteristics – a dimension largely ignored by these two studies. Specifically, I

identify two ex-ante available characteristics (i.e., overvaluation and uncertainty) that predict the

probability of being targeted, the short- and long-term returns after being targeted, the types of

allegations, and firms’ tendency to respond after being attacked. Second, while these two studies

show the information role of short-selling reports, they do not consider the possible coordination

role through which a short-seller’s bearish public signal could create panic among investors – one

major concern the regulators and the public have over activist short-selling. This dissertation

explicitly discusses such a possibility and presents evidences consistent with it. Third, I combine

SA and ASR to construct a much larger (i.e., more than 13 times) sample of activist short-selling

over a longer period (i.e., 2006 to 2015). Such a large sample enables me to investigate the

determinants of being targeted by activist short-selling.

Page 17: Activist Short-Selling - University of Toronto T-Space · Activist short-selling – short-sellers publicly talking down securities to benefit their short positions – attracts attentions

8

This dissertation also has implications for practice. Managers can reduce firms’

attractiveness to activist short-sellers, for example, by reporting conservatively to avoid

overvaluation or improving transparency to reduce uncertainty. The takeaway for activist short-

sellers is that targeting firms with overvaluation (uncertainty) features is more profitable in the

long (short) term. Relatedly, investors with long positions and investors following short-selling

campaigns can benefit from the proposed trading strategy of separating winners vs. losers in

activist short-selling based on ex-ante available overvaluation and uncertainty characteristics.

Finally, this study can potentially inform policy debates over activist short-selling. First,

my findings suggest one approach to separate possible manipulative short-selling from legitimate

short-selling based on targets’ characteristics, which decide whether a target firm should be shorted

or should not have been shorted. In particular, regulators could pay more attention to short-selling

cases in which the target firms present few overvaluation features but many uncertainty features,

it is more likely that the short-seller is taking advantage of the high uncertainty and manipulating

the stock. Second, my findings echo the observation that “the biggest damage to stock prices is

almost always caused by the shorts who voice their thesis – those known as activist shorts,”

therefore casting doubts on the effectiveness of requiring short-position disclosure to stabilize the

market because activist shorts would not be affected as they disclose short theses voluntarily

anyway.6

2 Related Literature and Hypotheses Development

Short-sellers sell stocks that they do not own. First, they need to find a party to lend shares

to them with collateral (generally 102% of the loan’s value). After selling the shares borrowed

from the lender, they wait for the stock price to go down in order to buy shares back at a lower

price and return them to the lender. Finally, they get the collateral back from the lender. The most

frequently used matrix of short-selling activity is short-interest – the total shares sold short scaled

6 “Don’t Sell Short Sellers Short” by Michael Regan, Bloomberg Gadfly, November 16, 2015. See

https://www.bloomberg.com/gadfly/articles/2015-11-16/stop-treating-short-sellers-like-villains-despite-uproar.

Page 18: Activist Short-Selling - University of Toronto T-Space · Activist short-selling – short-sellers publicly talking down securities to benefit their short positions – attracts attentions

9

by the total shares outstanding. Please refer to Reed (2013) for more institutional details of the

short-selling process.

2.1 The Differences between Activist and Passive Short-Selling

In the investing community, activist short-selling refers to the phenomenon that short-

sellers publicly talk down securities to benefit their short-positions, rather than wait quietly for

price declines in passive short-selling. This feature dictates the major differences between activist

and passive short-selling.

2.1.1 Short-Selling Incentives

Short-selling is conducted because of profit incentives betting on the decline of stock prices

and other incentives such as tax and hedging (Brent, Morse, and Stice 1990).7 By definition,

activist short-selling is primarily motivated by the profit incentives – activist short-sellers publicly

disclose their short theses that explain why the targets’ prices should go down. In other words,

short-sellers whose motivation is tax or hedging would be unlikely to conduct activist short-selling.

The incentives are obscure for short-selling without the “activist” element because they are

unobservable in such passive cases. As a result, when researchers rely on short-selling metrics

such as short-interest, they pool profit incentives with tax and hedging incentives. This is likely a

reason why several studies fail to find negative relations between short-selling metrics and future

stock returns (e.g., Brent et al. 1990; Figlewski and Webb 1993; Woolridge and Dickinson 1994),

despite the overwhelming evidence on short-sellers’ sophistication of identifying trading

opportunities (e.g., Pownall and Simko 2005; Desai, Krishnamurthy, and Venkataraman 2006;

Karpoff and Lou 2010; Khan and Lu 2013). In the same vein, several studies find that the

predictability of short-selling metrics varies in the incentives. For example, Aitken, Frino,

McCorry, and Swan (1998) find that market reactions to short-sale disclosure in Australia are much

7 Tax incentive refers to the term “shorting against the box” – investors take a short position in a security that they

already hold long to defer taxable gains. Hedging incentive refers to the practice that investors hedge the risk of

holding long positions by taking short positions in related securities. For example, many hedge funds use a “pairs-

trading” strategy – long one stock but short another stock in the same industry. Speculation incentive pertains to short-

sellers betting on price declines, the incentive exemplifying the unique role of short-sellers in capital markets.

Page 19: Activist Short-Selling - University of Toronto T-Space · Activist short-selling – short-sellers publicly talking down securities to benefit their short positions – attracts attentions

10

less negative when it is related to hedging or tax incentives. Recently, Comerton-Forde, Jones, and

Putnins (2016) highlight the importance of separating two different types of short-sellers with

distinct incentives: market makers with no negative information and informed shorts with negative

information.

2.1.2 Constraints in the Equity-Loan Market

Another reason short-interest (as well as other short-selling metrics) represents a noisy

measure of profit incentives is the supply constraint in the equity-loan market (Reed 2015). If the

supply constraint is binding (not binding), short-interest reflects the supply of lendable shares

(demand of short-selling) (Beneish, Lee, and Nichols 2015).

By contrast, activist short-selling is largely unconstrained by the supply in the equity-loan

market. As Ljungqvist and Qian (2016) argue, if it is not feasible to take a large short position and

move the price by trading, activist short-sellers can move the price by disclosing their short theses

and thus encouraging long investors to sell the stock. In other words, activist short-selling reflects

the demand for short-selling rather than the supply in the equity-loan market.

2.1.3 Short-Selling Risk

Short-selling is risky mainly because of its capped upside but unlimited downside. In

addition, the equity-loan lender can recall the loan at any time or change the loan fees. These

features make both the fundamental risk and the noise trader risk substantial concerns to short-

sellers (De Long, Shleifer, Summers, and Waldmann 1990). According to Diamond and

Verrecchia (1987), short-selling is informative exactly because of its high risk – only investors

who expect short-selling profits and can compensate for the risk will decide to sell short. As

Engelberg, Reed, and Ringgenberg (2016) illustrate, stocks with more short-selling risk have lower

future returns, less price efficiency, and less short-selling.

Short-sellers can reduce such risk by taking short positions in a portfolio of stocks whose

prices are more likely to go down in the future (i.e., a valuation-based strategy). Indeed, Dechow,

Hutton, Meulbroek, and Sloan (2001) show that short-sellers target firms in stocks with low

fundamental-to-price ratios and cover their short positions as these ratios mean-revert. Another

Page 20: Activist Short-Selling - University of Toronto T-Space · Activist short-selling – short-sellers publicly talking down securities to benefit their short positions – attracts attentions

11

way to reduce the risk is to take short positions after the price has started to decline (i.e., a

momentum-based strategy). Lamont and Stein (2004) find that short-interest on the NASDAQ in

aggregate is positively associated with the prior month’s declines in the NASDAQ index. At an

individual stock level, Savor and Gamboa-Covazos (2011) also find that short-sellers increase their

positions following prior-month price declines.

The “activist” nature of activist short-selling substantially increases the already-high short-

selling risk.8 Targeted companies often “go down fighting” with the short-sellers using a variety

of approaches (Lamont 2012). Also, activist short-sellers receive “intense attention” from the SEC

as indicated in the opening quote. Further, a reputation loss ensues if a short-seller loses a bet

publicly.9 Finally, it is not clear whether a valuation- or momentum-based strategy can reduce

activist short-selling risk for two reasons. First, activist short-sellers usually target one stock each

time by providing in-depth analyses (93% in my sample). As the risk is not diversified, the cost of

a Type I error (i.e., being short a stock whose price subsequently goes up) is considerable. So they

need to be very confident in their short theses and the overvaluation should be egregious.10 Second,

by definition, activist short-sellers should “wake the market up” rather than “wait for the market

to wake up.” Thus, a momentum-based strategy is not designed for activist short-selling.

According to Diamond and Verrecchia (1987), the nontrivial extra risk of activist short-selling is

expected to increase its informativeness. Also, this idea is consistent with Grossman and Stiglitz

(1980) that the market rewards arbitrageurs who incur costs to identify arbitrage opportunities.

2.1.4 Activist Short-Selling as a Coordination Device

Finally and rather importantly, the “activist” element of activist short-selling makes it a

public signal, affecting investors in ways above and beyond its information content. According to

HOB theory, which is initiated from Keynes’s (1936) beauty-contest analogy and later formalized

by Morris and Shin (2002) and Gao (2008), among others, a public signal has two roles: the

8 It is possible, however, that short-sellers can reduce noise trader risk by publicly talking down stocks successfully. 9 Related, since short-sellers are often portrayed as unethical, criminal, and even “un-American” (e.g., The Economist

2008), an investor’s reputation at the personal level could be affected when her short-selling is known publicly. 10 Some well-known activist shorts, such as Manuel Asensio, make it clear that overvaluation is not the primary reason

for short-selling. According to Asensio, “an overvalued company is an opinion where someone has miscalculated

future earnings; valuation is a judgment.” See Page 41, “The Most Dangerous Trade” by Richard Teitelbaum.

Page 21: Activist Short-Selling - University of Toronto T-Space · Activist short-selling – short-sellers publicly talking down securities to benefit their short positions – attracts attentions

12

information role (e.g., the short thesis contains information regarding the target’s overvaluation

issues) and the coordination role (e.g., it creates an expectation or panic of “lest everyone else get

out first”). Indeed, the information role echoes why activist short-sellers have “a legitimate positive

purpose” (see the opening quote by Mary Jo White) in the capital market, but the coordination role

reflects the concerns that they may be manipulating the market by creating panic. The key HOB

insight is that investors tend to put too much weight on the public signal relative to the weight a

social planner would (i.e., weight based on the relative precision of the public signal and their own

private signals). In other words, investors would be affected excessively by activist short-sellers’

bearish public signal.

2.2 Market Reactions to Activist Short-Selling (H1)

The above differences between passive and activist short-selling have two major

implications. First, activist short-selling is expected to be more informative than its passive

counterpart because it is (1) based on profit incentives, (2) largely unconstrained by the supply in

the equity-loan market, and (3) riskier. Second, higher-order beliefs – the fact that investors infer

from short-sellers’ bearish public signals how other investors are likely to behave – can encourage

panic-selling among investors. Both the information view and the HOB view predict that activist

short-selling leads to larger market reactions than its passive counterpart does. Therefore, my first

hypothesis (stated in the alternative form) is as follows:

H1: Activist short-selling leads to larger market reactions than comparable passive

short-selling does.

2.3 Activist Short-Selling Strategies (H2 and H3)

Passive short-selling strategies documented in prior literature facilitate our understanding

of activist short-selling, even though they do not apply unconditionally. That is because activist

short-sellers are short-sellers in nature, therefore they benefit from declines in stock prices. If some

egregious overvaluation features identified by prior literature could reliably predict future

underperformance (i.e., small Type I error), we would expect that activist short-sellers, like passive

short-sellers with negative information, are more likely to target firms with these features.

Therefore, my second hypothesis is as follows (stated in the alternative form):

Page 22: Activist Short-Selling - University of Toronto T-Space · Activist short-selling – short-sellers publicly talking down securities to benefit their short positions – attracts attentions

13

H2: Activist short-sellers are more likely to target firms with overvaluation features.

Activist short-sellers publicly talk down stocks because they want to engage other

investors. They are more likely to succeed if investors can be easily influenced. Clearly, if investors

are faced with high uncertainty – they are uncertain about the precision of the existing information

signals – they would be easily convinced by the short thesis (i.e., the information view), and they

would also likely be afraid that others would sell first (i.e., the HOB view).11 Therefore, both these

views lead to the following hypothesis (stated in the alternative form):

H3: Activist short-sellers are more likely to target firms with uncertainty features.

2.4 Overvaluation and Uncertainty Features and Short- and Long-

Term Returns (H4)

The two features in the determinants hypotheses also have implications for short- and long-

term price consequences. Both overvaluation and uncertainty features should be associated with

negative market returns given the impact of activist short-selling, simply because stocks with more

overvaluation features have larger downside and investors of stocks with more uncertainty features

are easier for short-sellers to convince. But based on the information view, there is no obvious

reason that the relations between these features and short-term returns would differ from the

relations between these features and long-term returns. However, the HOB view predicts

differently because higher-order beliefs are more important in the short term than in the long

term.12 As a result, short-term returns should be affected more by uncertainty features because

investors facing uncertainty would worry how other people behave and such “worry” (or panic)

matters more for returns in the short term than in the long term. By contrast, no matter whether

panic dominates in the short term, fundamentals determine the price in the long term. As a result,

11 Sophisticated investors, such as insiders and activist short-sellers, are more likely to gain information advantages

over a representative investor under higher uncertainty. For example, Huddart and Ke (2007) find that insider trading

is more profitable under weaker information environment. 12 There are at least two reasons. First, short-term investors care more about the near-term price in other people’s view

than the fundamental value that the price would converge to in the long term. Second, in the short term, investors do

not have sufficient opportunities to communicate among themselves. As Qu’s (2013) experimental study shows,

communication among investors, even cheap talk, can help avoid coordination failures.

Page 23: Activist Short-Selling - University of Toronto T-Space · Activist short-selling – short-sellers publicly talking down securities to benefit their short positions – attracts attentions

14

to the extent overvaluation features capture fundamentals, the HOB view predicts that the

importance of overvaluation features relative to uncertainty features increases from the short term

to the long term. To facilitate interpretation, I list the null form (predicted by the information view)

and the alternative form (predicted by the HOB view) as two competing hypotheses – H4A and

H4B, respectively:

H4-A: For targeted firms, overvaluation (uncertainty) features are comparably

important in determining returns from the short term to the long term.

H4-B: For targeted firms, overvaluation (uncertainty) features are increasingly

(decreasingly) important in determining returns from the short term to the long term.

3 Data

I combine information from Seeking Alpha (SA) and Activist Shorts Research (ASR) to

construct a large sample of activist short-selling from 2006 to 2015. Whereas SA is an ideal

platform for non-celebrity shorts, ASR tracks short-selling campaigns waged by prominent traders.

3.1 Seeking Alpha

Founded in 2004 by former Wall Street analyst David Jackson, SA is the most popular

crowdsourced platform for investment research (Chen, De, Hu, and Hwang 2014), with broad

coverage of stocks, asset classes, ETFs, and investment strategies. According to the information

on the website as of December 30, 2015, SA has four million registered users (with a 48% annual

growth) and 18.5% of the audience are financial professionals.13 As a crowdsourced platform, the

articles on SA are written by contributors and reviewed by the editorial board.14 After acceptance,

the contributors can publish their articles and receive $35 per article plus further compensation

13 See http://seekingalpha.com/page/about_us. 14 The SA editorial team reviews submitted articles “for clarity, consistency and impact.” There are four main editorial

principles: (1) articles interest SA’s readership, (2) articles conform to SA’s standards of rigor and clarity, (3) articles

about a stock trading at less than $1 or with a market cap below $100 million will see extra scrutiny, and (4) authors

must agree in writing to SA’s disclosure standards. See http://seekingalpha.com/page/editorial_principles.

Page 24: Activist Short-Selling - University of Toronto T-Space · Activist short-selling – short-sellers publicly talking down securities to benefit their short positions – attracts attentions

15

based on page views. By the end of 2015, there were 12,354 contributors in total. In 2006 SA

opened a new section called “Short Ideas,” where contributors write articles illustrating why they

are short-selling or plan to short-sell certain securities. Critical to this study in identifying activist

short-sellers, SA “contractually requires all authors to disclose positions in stocks they write

about.”15

3.2 Activist Shorts Research

Founded in 2014 by Adam Kommel, a former analyst at FactSet SharkRepellent, ASR is

an independent database dedicated to tracking activist short-selling campaigns.16 Kommel and his

colleagues analyze campaigns by summarizing the returns, allegations, short-seller tactics,

company rebuts, and actions taken by regulators. ASR complements SA because it tracks celebrity

shorts who post research reports on their own well-known platforms (such as Muddy Waters) and

who disclose their short theses by appearing on business media (such as James Chanos) or

attending investing conferences (such as David Einhorn).

3.3 Sample-Construction Process

To compile the sample, I use Python to crawl all “Short Ideas” articles from the SA website

at http://seekingalpha.com/analysis/investing-ideas/short-ideas. For each SA article, I extract

information regarding the unique article identifier, article title, author name, author self-

descriptions, the stock(s) discussed in the article, the date of posting (I use the next day if an article

is posted after 4:00 p.m. EST – the time when the market closes), and most importantly, the text

of analyses, including the disclosure by the author on whether she is short the stock(s). Panel A of

Appendix A presents a typical SA article. In Panels B through D, I illustrate three scenarios

regarding the author’s relation with the analyzed stock: (1) the author is short the stock, (2) the

author has no position in the stock but may initiate a short position in the next 72 hours, and (3)

15 See http://seekingalpha.com/article/2389665-is-it-wrong-to-take-a-position-in-a-stock-and-then-write-about-it-on-

seeking-alpha. Relatedly, according to Section 17(b) of the Securities Act of 1933, it is unlawful to give trading advice

without disclosing one’s own interest. 16 Kommel generously gave me free access to ASR from November 2015 to June 2016. In July 2016, ASR was

acquired by Activist Insight.

Page 25: Activist Short-Selling - University of Toronto T-Space · Activist short-selling – short-sellers publicly talking down securities to benefit their short positions – attracts attentions

16

the author has no position in the stock and has no plan to initiate a short position in the next 72

hours. For about 2,000 SA articles without any statement among these three cases, I read them

through and manually check whether the authors explicitly mention their positions. I only focus

on the first case as I define activist short-selling as those SA articles in which authors have short

positions in the analyzed stocks.17 This leaves me with 5,716 articles out of 15,072 published from

February 13, 2006 to December 31, 2015, with 6,197 stock-article level observations.

By December 31, 2015, ASR had collected data on 773 campaigns by 98 short-sellers. The

campaign history of these 98 short-sellers is fully covered from 2011 onward but is only selectively

covered before 2010. I manually collected another 172 campaigns by these 98 short-sellers not

included in ASR. Out of these 945 activist short-selling cases (773 + 172), 341 are also available

on SA. For the combined 6,801 activist short-selling cases, 6,081 are matched with PERMNO and

GVKEY and comprise my final sample of activist short-selling. The detailed sample-construction

process is explained in Panel A of Table 1.

Panel B of Table 1 illustrates the distribution of activist short-selling cases by year and by

stock exchange. An increasing number of listed firms are targeted by activist short-sellers.

Specifically, the frequencies are steadily increasing but with clear surges in 2011 (50% more than

2010) and 2013 (90% more than 2012). Regarding the overall distribution across exchanges,

51.5% of the shorted stocks are listed on NASDAQ, 43.8% on NYSE, and the remaining 4.7% on

AMEX.

4 Does Activist Short-Selling Have Larger Market

Reactions Than Passive Short-Selling?

H1 hypothesizes that activist short-selling leads to larger market reactions than comparable

passive short-selling does because of its informativeness and its coordination role that could create

17 In untabulated analyses I find that other two cases (i.e., “May Short” and “No Plan”) have smaller market reactions.

Page 26: Activist Short-Selling - University of Toronto T-Space · Activist short-selling – short-sellers publicly talking down securities to benefit their short positions – attracts attentions

17

panic among other investors. I exploit the fact that short-interest is reported on a fixed schedule

and use the market reactions to short-interest announcements to mimic comparable passive short-

selling. Specifically, the Financial Industry Regulatory Authority (FINRA) collects short-interest

in individual securities on the settlement date twice per month (once per month before September

7, 2007) and the exchanges that list stocks publish the data at 4:00 p.m. eight business days later

(Senchack and Starks 1993; Hu 2016; Kahraman and Pachare 2016).

I use five types of announcements as benchmarks. The first (second) approach focuses on

the short-interest announcements of a firm in the same month, same market cap quintiles of the

same Fama–French 48 industry, and having the closest short-interest ratio (increase in short-

interest) with each targeted firm. The third (fourth) approach focuses on the short-interest

announcements of a firm in the same month, same market cap quintiles of the same Fama–French

48 industry, and having the highest short-interest ratio (increase in short-interest) with each

targeted firm. The final approach constructs a same-firm benchmark – the last short-interest

announcement of each targeted firm five days before the activist short-selling.

Table 2 reports the daily abnormal returns (adjusted by the Fama–French three-factor

model) from three days before to three days after the events (i.e., activist short-selling in Panel A

or short-interest announcements in Panels B to F). The market reacts strongly to activist short-

selling, with the mean (median) abnormal return on day 0 being -0.0156 (-0.058) and a t-value of

-16.64. Moreover, the negative abnormal returns continue to be significant through day 9 except

day 7 (untabulated). By contrast, the market reactions to the five benchmarks are much smaller.

The most negative one is in Panel E – to the short-interest announcement by industry peers with

the highest increase in short-interest, consistent with Diamond and Verrecchia’s (1987) prediction

that unexpected increase in short-interest is bad news. But its AR(0) is about one-tenth and CAR(-

1, 1) is one-quarter of its counterpart in Panel A. These results show that activist short-selling leads

to much larger market reactions than passive short-selling does, thus supporting H1.18

18 The inference remains unchanged if I use alternative market-reaction measures such as volatility and trading

volume. It is worth noting two caveats of using market reactions to short-interest announcements to proxy for market

reactions to passive short-selling. First, to the extent there are industry spillover effects (i.e., industry peers are also

adversely affected by activist short-selling), the above approach could overestimate the impact of passive short-selling.

Second, note that short-interest is announced with a delay (i.e., eight business days after being reported by FINRA

member firms). As a result, the above approach could underestimate the impact of passive short-selling. An alternative

Page 27: Activist Short-Selling - University of Toronto T-Space · Activist short-selling – short-sellers publicly talking down securities to benefit their short positions – attracts attentions

18

5 Determinants of Being Targeted by Activist Short-

Selling

5.1 Variables and Models

5.1.1 Overvaluation Features

Conceptually speaking, overvaluation exists when a security’s price (P) exceeds its

intrinsic value (V) and therefore the price is likely to go down in the future. I consider three broad

sets of features that are potentially associated with future underperformance. The first set only

focuses on the price. For example, Lakonishok, Shleifer, and Vishny (1994) show that the market

tends to overreact to past performance; as a result, a price run-up (PriceRunUp) is associated with

future underperformance. The second set considers both V and P using valuation multiples,

ranging from the simple P/B ratio (e.g., Liu, Nissim, and Thomas 2000) to the more complicated

P/V ratio (Frankel and Lee 1998; Li and Mohanram 2014). The third set focuses only on V by

employing nine anomaly variables from Beneish, Lee, and Nichols (2015): LowGrossProfit

(Novy-Marx 2010), AssetGrowth (Cooper, Gulen, and Schill 2008), Investment (Titman, Wei, and

Xie 2004), net operating assets (NOA) (Hirshleifer, Hou, Teoh, and Zhang 2004), Accruals (Sloan

1996), payout ratio (LowPayout%) (Daniel and Titman 2006), quarterly earnings (LowEarnings)

(Chen, Novy-Marx, and Zhang 2010), Ohlson Bankruptcy Score (OScore) (Ohlson 1980;

Stambaugh, Yu, and Yuan 2012), and the Beneish Manipulation Score (MScore) (Beneish, Lee,

and Nichols 2013). To focus on egregious overvaluation, I transform these continuous variables

into indicators equal to one if the according variables are in the top quintile of overvaluation, and

zero otherwise. Appendix C illustrates how to calculate these variables. A positive coefficient

indicates that the overvaluation feature attracts activist short-sellers, therefore supporting H2.

benchmark would be the market reactions to timely short-position disclosures, which are mandatory in several EU

countries after the recent financial crisis but are not mandatory in the US. However, as Jones, Reed, and Waller (2016)

report, the short-window reaction to large short-position disclosures in EU is very low, i.e. CAR(-1, 1) is an

insignificant -0.41%.

Page 28: Activist Short-Selling - University of Toronto T-Space · Activist short-selling – short-sellers publicly talking down securities to benefit their short positions – attracts attentions

19

5.1.2 Uncertainty Features

As discussed, I predict that activist short-sellers prefer targeting firms whose investors face

higher uncertainty and therefore are easier to influence. I consider three such scenarios. First,

investors are likely to feel uncertain when they are not sophisticated enough to process and analyze

relevant information. In particular, individual investors are likely to feel more uncertain than

institutional investors do (LowInstOwn). Second, in a weak information environment, investors

have insufficient knowledge about what is happening and are uncertain about the precision of

information they have. This could happen either because the internal information systems are not

functioning well, such as low accounting quality (LowAccQuality), internal control weakness

(ICW), or auditor switches (AuditSwitch), or because the disagreement in opinion is severe, such

as high information asymmetry among investors (BidAskSpread), or high analyst disagreement

(AnalystDisagree). Finally, investors are uncertain about the current valuation if they have few

credible information sources, such as blockholders (NonBlock), dedicated institutional investors

(LowDedicated), or Big Four auditors (NonBig4). For the five continuous variables, I transform

them into indicators equal to one if the according variables are in the top quintile of uncertainty,

and zero otherwise. No transformation is needed for ICW, AuditSwitch, NonBlock, and NonBig4

as they are already indicators with one indicating high uncertainty. Appendix C illustrates how to

calculate these variables. Again, a positive coefficient indicates that the uncertainty feature attracts

activist short-sellers, therefore supporting H3.

5.1.3 The Model

For the two determinants hypotheses, I estimate the following Logit model in the main

analyses at the firm-quarter level. I use alternative estimation methods (OLS and Negative

Binomial) in the supplemental section and all inferences remain.

, , , 0 1 , 2 , 3 ,

4 , 5 , 6 ,

(

)

i t j j i t i t i t i t

i t i t i t i t

Target f Determinant Size Leverage Illiquidity

Volatility LnAnalyst ShortInterest IND QTR

(1)

For a given fiscal quarter (labeled as “data quarter” – further illustrated in Appendix B),

Target is one if a firm is targeted by activist short-sellers from 45 days after the fiscal end of the

Page 29: Activist Short-Selling - University of Toronto T-Space · Activist short-selling – short-sellers publicly talking down securities to benefit their short positions – attracts attentions

20

quarter to 45 days after the fiscal end of the next quarter, and zero otherwise. Determinant refers

to one of the overvaluation or uncertainty features at the data quarter. In this way, all determinants

variables are available when activist short-sellers decide whether to target a firm or not.

I include several control variables measured at the data-quarter ends. First, I control for

two basic firm-level characteristics: firm size measured by the log of total assets (Size) and

leverage measured by the ratio of total liabilities to total assets (Leverage). Also, I control for two

market-based variables: illiquidity (Illiquidity) measured by the quarterly mean of Amihud’s

(2002) daily illiquidity measure and volatility measured by the quarterly standard deviation of

daily stock returns (Volatility). In addition, I include the log of one plus the number of analysts

forecasting earnings for the quarter (LnAnalyst). Finally, I include the short-interest ratio at the

end of the quarter to control for overall short-selling activities (ShortInterest). Fama–French 48

industry and quarter fixed effects are included to control for industry-wide and time-specific

factors. All t-statistics are based on standard errors clustered at the firm level. Appendix C provides

more detailed definitions of all variables.

5.2 Determinants Sample

Panel A of Table 3 presents the by-year distribution of the determinants sample. From

Quarter 4, 2005 to Quarter 4, 2015, 1.79% of the firm-quarter observations are targeted by activist

short-sellers. Panel B compares the firm-level characteristics between targeted and non-targeted

firm-quarters. Targeted firm-quarters have significantly larger size, higher leverage, lower

illiquidity, higher volatility, more analysts, and higher short-interest ratio. For overvaluation

features, targeted firm-quarters have higher means for all except NOA, Accruals, and

LowGrossProfit. The uncertainty features present a more mixed picture. Targeted firm-quarters

have higher means for LowAccQuality, AnalystDisagree, ICW, and BidAskSpread. These

univariate analyses are largely consistent with the bivariate correlations in Panel C. Specifically,

Target is positively correlated with all overvaluation variables except Accruals, and with all

uncertainty variables except LowInstOwn, NonBig4, and LowDedicated.

Page 30: Activist Short-Selling - University of Toronto T-Space · Activist short-selling – short-sellers publicly talking down securities to benefit their short positions – attracts attentions

21

5.3 Regression Results

5.3.1 Overvaluation Features

Table 4 shows that activist short-sellers target firms with overvaluation features, providing

broad support to H2. Specifically, 10 out of 12 overvaluation features (except LowGrossProfit and

Accruals) attract activist short-selling.19 As all features are indicator variables, I can also compare

the economic magnitudes of these features. The coefficients range from 0.166 (Investment) to

0.666 (P/V) and 0.781 (P/B). It is not surprising that P/V and P/B have the largest statistical and

economic significances, because these two consider both the current price and the intrinsic value

and therefore potentially better capture the actual overvaluation. In terms of marginal effects, given

all other variables at the mean values, the probability of being targeted by activist short-sellers

increases from 0.66% (0.78%) to 1.44% (0.95%) when we move from stocks in the bottom four

quintiles of P/B (Investment) to stocks in the top quintile of P/B (Investment). As a benchmark, the

unconditional probability that a firm-quarter gets targeted is 1.79%. The economic significances

of all other significant overvaluation features are between those of Investment and P/B. With

respect to control variables, across the 12 columns, activist shorts are more likely to target firms

that are more liquid, more volatile, covered by more analysts, and with higher levels of short-

interest ratio.

5.3.2 Uncertainty Features

Table 5 shows that activist short-sellers target firms with uncertainty features in general,

thus supporting H3. All uncertainty features, except AnalystDisagree, attract activist short-

selling.20 The coefficients range from 0.168 (LowInstOwn) to 0.379 (ICW) and 0.391 (NonBig4),

suggesting that activist short-sellers pay particular attention to auditing-related information. In

terms of marginal effects, given all other variables at the mean values, the probability of being

targeted by activist short-sellers increases from 0.73% (0.78%) to 1.07% (0.92%) when NonBig4

19 One possible reason for the insignificant coefficient on Accruals is that the accruals anomaly has decayed in recent

years (Green, Hand, and Soliman 2011; Mohanram 2014).

20 One possible reason for the insignificant coefficient on AnalystDisagree is related to the fact that activist short-

sellers are more likely to target stocks for which analysts are mostly optimistic (i.e., smaller disagreement).

Page 31: Activist Short-Selling - University of Toronto T-Space · Activist short-selling – short-sellers publicly talking down securities to benefit their short positions – attracts attentions

22

(LowInstOwn) increases from zero to one. These numbers indicate that the impact of uncertainty

features is smaller than that of overvaluation features. The coefficients on control variables are

similar to those in Table 4.

5.3.3 Horseracing Variables and Including Both Features Together

As Table 3, Panel C shows, many overvaluation (uncertainty) features are correlated with

each other. For this reason, I employ stepwise regression to horserace all variables and only keep

those features loading significantly at the 0.10 level. In Table 6, columns 1 and 2 indicate that

seven overvaluation features (PriceRunUp, P/B, P/V, AssetGrowth, NOA, MScore, and

LowEarnings) and six uncertainty features (BidAskSpread, NonBlock, LowDedicated,

LowAccQuality, ICW, and NonBig4) survive.21 In column 3, I put all overvaluation and uncertainty

features together and the same 13 variables survive, suggesting that these two sets of features

explain largely non-overlapping variation. Based on these 13 variables, I create two aggregate

variables: Overvaluation is the average of all seven overvaluation indicators and Uncertainty is

the average of the six uncertainty indicators, respectively.

Column 4 of Table 6 presents results using the aggregate variables and confirms the

previous inferences that H2 and H3 are supported. Specifically, the coefficients on both

Overvaluation and Uncertainty are positive and highly significant. Regarding marginal effects,

given all other variables at the mean values, the probability of being targeted by activist short-

sellers increases from 0.47% (0.59%) to 5.25% (2.17%) when Overvaluation (Uncertainty)

increases from zero to one, an 11-time (four-time) increase in the probability of being targeted.

21 Widely used in accounting and finance (e.g., Ou and Penman 1989; Klassen and Laplante 2012; Titman and Tiu

2011), stepwise regression adds and removes variables one by one based on a pre-determined p-value threshold (in

this test, 0.10). Those variables with coefficients significant at the 0.10 or better levels are kept and otherwise removed.

Page 32: Activist Short-Selling - University of Toronto T-Space · Activist short-selling – short-sellers publicly talking down securities to benefit their short positions – attracts attentions

23

6 Overvaluation and Uncertainty Features and Short-

and Long-Term Returns

6.1 Models and Variables

To test H4-A vs. H4-B regarding price consequences in the short and long term, I estimate

model (2): CAR (cumulative abnormal returns) refers to returns with different windows such as

short-term AR(0) (abnormal return on the disclosure date), CAR(0, 1), CAR(0, 2), medium-term

CAR(1 Week), CAR(1 Month), and long-term CAR(1 Year).22 All CARs are adjusted using the

Fama–French three-factor model.

, 0 1 , 2 , 3 , 4 ,

5 , 6 , 7 , 8 ,

9 , 10 ,

11

[ 5,0] [ 5,0]

[ 5,0

i t i t i t i t i t

i t i t i t i t

i t i t

CAR Overvaluation Uncertainty Size Leverage

Illiquidity Volatility LnAnalyst ShortInterest

EarnAnnounce AnForecast

ConfCall

, ,]i t i t i tIND QTR

(2)

In addition to all control variables in model (1), I also control for three important

information sources that shape the corporate information environment (Beyer, Cohen, Lys, and

Walther 2010): mandatory disclosure, voluntary disclosure, and analyst forecasting. Specifically,

I include three indicator variables in model (2): EarnAnnounce[-5, 0], ConfCall[-5, 0], and

AnForecast[-5, 0] that indicate the existence of earnings announcements, conference calls, and

analyst forecasts in the five days prior to the activist short-selling date, respectively.

6.2 Sample and Regression Results

Panel A of Table 7 provides summary statistics of variables used in the market-reaction

tests. Specifically, AR(0) and all CARs are negative, confirming the observation in Section 4 that

the market reacts negatively to activist short-selling. Panel B presents the regression results. In

22 It is notoriously difficult to estimate long-term abnormal returns because of the “Bad-model problems” (Fama 1998).

Following Fama’s recommendation, I use CARs rather than BHARs in the main test but all inferences remain

unchanged if I calculate one-year abnormal returns using a buy-and-hold approach.

Page 33: Activist Short-Selling - University of Toronto T-Space · Activist short-selling – short-sellers publicly talking down securities to benefit their short positions – attracts attentions

24

short-term windows, such as the abnormal return on the disclosure date (i.e., AR(0)), the coefficient

on Uncertainty is significantly negative at the 1% level. The significance decreases monotonically

as the CAR windows extend and the coefficient becomes insignificant for CAR(1 Year). By

contrast, the coefficient of Overvaluation is insignificant for AR(0), but it becomes increasingly

significant as the CAR windows extend. In particular, it is highly significant for CAR(1 Year).

Moreover, the relative magnitude of the coefficients on Uncertainty and Overvaluation

(i.e., the ratio of coefficients on these two variables) decreases dramatically as the CAR windows

extend. On the disclosure date, compared to firms with none of the uncertainty features (i.e.,

Uncertainty = 0), firms with all six uncertainty features (i.e., Uncertainty = 1) have 4.17% more

negative returns; note the mean of AR(0) is -1.5%. In contrast, the equivalent statistic for

Overvaluation is only 0.59%. The ratio of β1 (i.e., the coefficient on Overvaluation) to β2 (i.e., the

coefficient on Uncertainty) increases dramatically and monotonically from 0.141 for AR(0) (-

0.59%/-4.17%) to 0.636 (-3.54%/-5.57%) for CAR (1 Week), and finally to 8.605 (-88.6%/-10.3%)

for CAR (1 Year). These observations provide support for H4-B based on the HOB view that the

importance of overvaluation features relative to uncertainty features increases from the short to the

long term.

Note that the dependent variables across columns have very different distributions, so I

cannot directly compare coefficients of Overvaluation (Uncertainty) between different columns.

Instead, at the bottom of Panel B, I tabulate results with standardized CARs by decile ranks ranging

from 0 to 1. The coefficients of Overvaluation become monotonically more negative from -0.0344

for AR(0) to -0.2572 for CAR(1 Year), while those of Uncertainty become monotonically less

negative from -0.1685 for AR(0) to -0.0265 for CAR(1 Year). The differences in coefficients

between columns 1 and 6 on both variables are significant at the 5% level (p-value = 0.0001 for

Overvaluation and 0.023 for Uncertainty), providing further support to H4-B.

6.3 An Ex-Ante Approach to Separate Winners vs. Losers among

Activist Short-Selling

The above results have potentially important trading-strategy implications for both activist

short-sellers and other investors who pay attention to short-selling campaigns. To illustrate, I split

Page 34: Activist Short-Selling - University of Toronto T-Space · Activist short-selling – short-sellers publicly talking down securities to benefit their short positions – attracts attentions

25

the whole sample into four groups based on whether Overvaluation or Uncertainty is higher than

the determinant-test sample median (i.e., including both targeted and non-targeted firm-quarters).

Figure 1 plots the mean cumulative abnormal returns in a window of (-60, 250) for targets in these

four groups: High Overvaluation and High Uncertainty (solid line), High Overvaluation and Low

Uncertainty (dotted line), Low Overvaluation and High Uncertainty (short dash line), and Low

Overvaluation and Low Uncertainty (long dash line). Overvaluation features clearly dominate the

return pattern in the long term: the solid and dotted lines substantially trend down while the other

two lines trend up shortly after being targeted. However, in the short term, the uncertainty features

also have some impact. For example, both the solid line and the short dash line present a sudden

drop immediately after the activist short-selling.

As a result, the ideal targets for activist short-sellers would be firms with both

overvaluation and uncertainty features – the solid line drops about 60% over the following year.

If short-sellers can bear the risk of holding short positions for a long time, they can simply ignore

the uncertainty features. By contrast, they can also choose to target firms with high uncertainty

and prepare to exit quickly. Also, Figure 1 can be interpreted as an ex-ante way to separate

legitimate vs. manipulative activist short-selling, an issue exemplified in the opening quote of this

paper. If a firm has egregious overvaluation features, short-selling against this stock is more likely

to be legitimate. By contrast, a short-selling campaign against a stock with little indication of

overvaluation but high uncertainty is more likely to be manipulative.

7 Activist Short-Sellers’ Allegations and Firms’ Tendency

to Respond

Using the rich information provided by ASR, in this section, I explore the implications of

overvaluation and uncertainty features. Specifically, I examine the relations between these features

and short-selling allegations and firms’ tendency to respond after being attacked.

Page 35: Activist Short-Selling - University of Toronto T-Space · Activist short-selling – short-sellers publicly talking down securities to benefit their short positions – attracts attentions

26

7.1 Short-Sellers’ Allegations

ASR identifies the primary allegation for each activist short-selling campaign and classifies

them into 18 types. Table 8 tabulates the frequency, the mean CAR(0, 1), the proportion of firms

that respond to short-sellers, and the mean and median values of Overvaluation and Uncertainty

by each type. It is not surprising that those allegations explicitly focused on valuation/accounting

issues, such as Bubble, Stock Promotion, and Accounting Fraud, have relatively high

Overvaluation, suggesting that short theses provide information regarding the underlying

overvaluation of the targeted firms. Another interesting observation is that severe allegations, such

as Accounting Fraud and Major Business Fraud, have relatively higher Uncertainty and bigger

market reactions, suggesting that activist short-sellers are more likely to raise severe allegations to

create panic among investors who are relatively easier to influence. Also, it is natural to expect

that firms receiving these severe allegations are more likely to respond.

To formally test the relations among stock features, allegations, and firms’ tendency to

respond, I aggregate these five allegations (40.3% of all cases) as “Overvaluation Allegations”:

Accounting Fraud, Bubble, Misleading Accounting, Other-Overvaluation, and Stock Promotion,

and these four allegations (26.6% of all cases) as “Severe Allegations”: Accounting Fraud, Major

Business Fraud, Pyramid Scheme, and Other-Illegal. Columns 1 and 2 of Panel B confirm the

above descriptive observations: Overvaluation features are associated with the allegations

regarding valuation issues, and Uncertainty features are associated with allegations that are

perceived as severe. To the extent that the variable Overvaluation captures the actual

overvaluation, the results in column 1 are consistent with the information view that the short theses

are informative. However, column 2 suggests that short-sellers are likely overstating the problems

for firms with higher uncertainty to convince investors – consistent with the information view, and

to create panic – consistent with the HOB view.

7.2 Firms’ Tendency to React to Short-Sellers’ Allegations

Column 3 of Panel A (Table 8) indicates that 42.7% of targets respond to short-selling

allegations. Those firms usually accuse short-sellers of manipulation and provide additional

relevant information (or misinformation). For example, after being accused by several short-

Page 36: Activist Short-Selling - University of Toronto T-Space · Activist short-selling – short-sellers publicly talking down securities to benefit their short positions – attracts attentions

27

sellers, on October 6, 2015, Valeant released “Valeant Corrects Misleading Reports,” listing

“Facts” to address each “Assertion” from short-sellers.23 It is not clear whether firms with more

overvaluation features are more likely to respond, but firms with more uncertainty features should

be more motivated to respond for at least two reasons: (1) investors of these firms are in greater

need of credible information, and (2) they are more easily influenced – by both short-sellers and

managers. Indeed, column 3 of Panel B (Table 8) indicates that firms with more uncertainty

features are more likely to react to short-selling allegations. Column 4 indicates that firms are also

more likely to respond to severe allegations. These results are consistent with both the information

view and the HOB view, as I cannot separate the possibility that firms provide information in such

responses from the possibility that they only hope to reduce panic.

8 Supplemental Analyses and Robustness Tests

8.1 Separating ASR and SA Samples

All analyses so far are conducted combining both SA and ASR samples. Since ASR covers

celebrity shorts while SA is largely about man-on-the-street shorts, it is not surprising that the

market reactions to the ASR sample are much larger. For example, the disclosure date return is -

1.1% for the SA sample but -5% for the ASR sample (untabulated). More importantly, all

inferences about the determinants and consequences of activist short-selling hold in both samples.

Specifically, Panel A of Table 9 shows that, in both samples, activist short-sellers are more likely

to target firms with overvaluation features and firms with uncertainty features. Panels B and C of

Table 9 show that the importance of overvaluation features relative to uncertainty features in

affecting returns increases from the short to the long term.

23 See https://www.sec.gov/Archives/edgar/data/885590/000119312515337744/d83478dex991.htm.

Page 37: Activist Short-Selling - University of Toronto T-Space · Activist short-selling – short-sellers publicly talking down securities to benefit their short positions – attracts attentions

28

8.2 Overvaluation and Uncertainty Features and Short-Interest

This section examines whether activist short-sellers’ targets are just firms with high

(increase in) short-interest ratio.24 In column 1 of Panel A (Table 10), I regress the short-interest

ratio at the first settlement date 45 days after the fiscal end of the data quarter

(ShortInterest_45Days) on Overvaluation and Uncertainty, with all control variables and fixed

effects in Equation (1). I also consider the possibility that these determinants variables only predict

high short-interest ratio. Then in column 2, I construct a dependent variable named

TopShortInterest_45Days, coded as one if ShortInterest_45Days is among the top 1.79% of all

firms in the same quarter, and zero otherwise (note that 1.79% of firm-quarters are targeted by

activist short-sellers). Similarly, in columns 3 and 4, I use an indicator of the increase in short-

interest ratio in the first 45 days after the end of the data quarter (IncShortInterest) and an indicator

of whether such increase is among the top 1.79% (TopIncShortInterest) as dependent variables. In

all four columns, the coefficients on Overvaluation are significantly positive as expected (but with

much smaller magnitudes than those in Table 4), while those on Uncertainty are all negative,

suggesting that these two features do not predict short-interest ratio or its increase in the same way

as they predict activist short-selling.

8.3 Overvaluation and Uncertainty Features and Analysts’

Recommendations

Analysts’ issuances of Sell (or downgrading) recommendations resembles activist short-

selling in that both are “public talking-down” behaviors. But these two phenomena differ

profoundly because short-sellers are real investors in the analyzed stocks while analysts are not.

This section examines whether Overvaluation and Uncertainty predict Sell or Downgrading

recommendations in the same way as they predict activist short-selling. For a given fiscal quarter,

AnalystSell is one if a firm receives at least one Strong Sell or Sell rating from any of its analysts

24 Anecdotes suggest that this is not the case. For example, veteran activist short-seller Doug Kass claims he has a

strict rule that he would never short a stock with short-interest higher than 8% because “I simply don’t want to get

caught in a short squeeze.” See page 183, “The Most Dangerous Trade” by Richard Teitelbaum. A short squeeze is a

rapid increase in the price of a stock that occurs when there is a lack of supply and an excess of demand for that stock.

Short squeezes result when short-sellers cover their positions on a stock.

Page 38: Activist Short-Selling - University of Toronto T-Space · Activist short-selling – short-sellers publicly talking down securities to benefit their short positions – attracts attentions

29

from 45 days after the end of the fiscal quarter to 45 days after the end of the next fiscal quarter,

and zero otherwise. Downgrade is one if a firm receives at least one downgrade (i.e., from a more

favorable rating to a less favorable one) from any of its analysts from 45 days after the end of the

fiscal quarter to 45 days after the end of the next fiscal quarter, and zero otherwise. Columns 5 and

6 of Panel A (Table 10) show that analysts are less likely to issue Sell and to downgrade ratings

for firms with more overvaluation and uncertainty features – exactly opposite to what activist

short-sellers do. These results also echo Drake, Rees, and Swanson’s (2011) finding that analysts

sometimes recommend stocks with features negatively associated with future returns.

8.4 A Pseudo Test Using Peer Firms Matched on Firm Features

One may argue that firms with different levels of Overvaluation and Uncertainty could

vary in subsequent returns even without being targeted by activist short-sellers. To confirm that

the results in Panel B of Table 7 are attributable to the impact of activist short-selling, I conduct a

pseudo test as follows. For each targeted observation, I match a non-targeted firm with the same

values of Overvaluation and Uncertainty, the same Fama–French 48 industry membership, and

the closest market cap in the month end before the targeted firm’s activist short-selling date. Then

I label the targeted firm’s activist short-selling date as the pseudo date for the matched firm and

rerun Equation (2) using this pseudo sample. Panel B of Table 10 presents the results. The

coefficients on Overvaluation are much smaller in magnitude than those in Table 7, while

coefficients on Uncertainty are largely positive (not even negative as for real targets). Also, the

R2s are all much smaller than their counterparts in Table 7. These results corroborate the causal

inference that activist short-selling leads to the return patterns documented in Section 6.

8.5 The Interaction Effects of Overvaluation and Uncertainty

Features

The main analyses focus on the separate impact of overvaluation and uncertainty features.

I also check the interaction of these two features in both determinants and consequences

regressions. In Table A1, I find some weak evidence of substitution effects in the determinants

model but complementary effects in the price consequences model. Specifically, as Panel A shows,

for activist short-sellers’ decision to target firms (especially for ASR shorts’), Overvaluation

Page 39: Activist Short-Selling - University of Toronto T-Space · Activist short-selling – short-sellers publicly talking down securities to benefit their short positions – attracts attentions

30

(Uncertainty) is less important as Uncertainty (Overvaluation) increases. For price consequences

as shown in Panel B, the negative association between Overvaluation and long-term returns

becomes more negative as Uncertainty increases.

8.6 The Role of Media and Short-Sellers’ Reputation

This section explores two essential elements for activist short-sellers’ success: the publicity

of campaigns and the credibility of short-sellers. First, if a campaign attracts the attention of

mainstream media, it reaches a bigger audience. For each activist short-selling case, I manually

count Factiva Top US Newspapers articles with the names of both the short-seller and the target

company mentioned in the Headline and Lead Paragraph. Seventy-five campaigns from 23 short-

sellers are covered within 30 days after the activist short-selling. Unsurprisingly, media-covered

campaigns have much more negative returns (i.e., mean AR (0) is -8.8%). However, all inferences

remain the same if I only focus on activist short-selling cases that are not covered in mainstream

media, as Table A2 presents. Second, I use the average CAR(0, 1) of a short-seller’s previous

campaigns as a proxy for her reputation. Table A3 shows that there are strong positive associations

between past returns and returns in the current campaign. These results are consistent with both

the information view and the HOB view because reputable short sellers could have both better

information and better coordination of other investors’ beliefs (Gao 2008).

8.7 Multiple Activist Short-Selling Events in the Same Firm-

Quarter

All 6,081 activist short-selling cases target 3,344 firm-quarters, suggesting that many firm-

quarters are attacked more than once. For example, Herbalife (NYSE: HLF) was targeted 47 times

in the second quarter of 2014. In the main analyses, I treat firm-quarters targeted once the same

way to firm-quarters targeted multiple times. Table A4, Panel A shows that all inferences are the

same if I use a Negative Binomial or OLS with the number of times a firm-quarter is targeted as

the dependent variable. For price consequences, all inferences remain the same if I focus on the

first activist short-selling case for each firm-quarter (Panel B).

Page 40: Activist Short-Selling - University of Toronto T-Space · Activist short-selling – short-sellers publicly talking down securities to benefit their short positions – attracts attentions

31

8.8 Other Robustness Checks

First, the patterns documented in this paper are stable over time: all inferences on

determinants and consequences hold in both the first and second half of each sample (Table A5).

Second, I construct the feature variables by using the decile ranks of these variables. In this

specification, NOA, LowEarnings, and LowDedicated are no longer significant at the 0.10 level.

But eight out of 12 overvaluation features and seven out of nine uncertainty features are still

significant at the 0.10 level or better in individual regressions (Table A6). Third, all results remain

quantitatively similar if I construct Overvaluation (Uncertainty) by either averaging all 12

overvaluation (nine uncertainty) features in Panel A of Table A7 or by averaging 10 overvaluation

(eight uncertainty) features that load significantly in Table 4 (Table 5) in Panel B of Table A7.

Fourth, all inferences remain the same if I calculate abnormal returns based on either the market

model or the Fama–French three-factor plus momentum model (Table A8). Fifth, all findings are

robust if I cluster standard errors differently, such as by quarter, by industry, or by firm and quarter

(Table A9). Sixth, my return results hold using only those observations without any analyst

revisions, conference calls, and earnings announcements in the five days prior to the activist short-

selling date (Table A10). Seventh, the inferences on the return tests hold even if I control for short-

seller fixed effects, indicating that the firm characteristics have substantial explaining power in

predicting returns in addition to who the short-seller is (Table A11). Eighth, all return results are

similar if I only use observations with no missing value in any CARs (Table A12). Ninth, Table

A13 emphasizes the role of liquidity. I find that the investors facing higher uncertainty are more

likely to respond to short-seller’s bearish signal only if the liquidity is low – they are afraid that if

they do not sell now, they can only sell at a much lower price later. This test provides further

support for the HOB view. Tenth, Figure A1 plots that we can separate winners vs. losers in both

SA and ASR sample.

9 Conclusion

The existing short-selling literature primarily focuses on the “passive” dimension of short-

selling, although activist short-selling attracts the most intense attention from the public and the

Page 41: Activist Short-Selling - University of Toronto T-Space · Activist short-selling – short-sellers publicly talking down securities to benefit their short positions – attracts attentions

32

media. This dissertation fills the void in the literature by conducting a large-sample study on the

determinants and consequences of activist short-selling. Combining information from Seeking

Alpha (SA) and Activist Shorts Research (ASR), I show that activist short-selling is increasingly

frequent over the past decade, and causes much larger market reactions than passive short-selling

does. For determinants, I find that activist short-sellers are more likely to target firms with

egregious overvaluation features and uncertainty features. For the price consequences of firms

being targeted, the overvaluation (uncertainty) features become increasingly (decreasingly)

important in determining returns as the CAR windows extend from the short term to the long term.

These results are consistent with Higher-Order Beliefs (HOB) theory, which provides a rational

explanation for the commonly held allegations against activist short-sellers that they create panic

in the marketplace.

In addition, I find that stocks with more overvaluation features are more likely to receive

short-selling allegations on valuation issues (e.g., “bubble”), while stocks with more uncertainty

features are more likely to receive severe allegations (e.g., “fraud”). Finally, firms with more

uncertainty features are more likely to respond by accusing short-sellers of manipulation or

providing relevant information to address their allegations. These findings indicate that firm-level

characteristics also have implications on the interactions between short-sellers and their targets.

This study has certain caveats. First, I compile a large sample of activist short-selling by

combining information from SA and ASR. However, I cannot rule out the possibility that some

short-sellers disclose their short theses on platforms other than SA and are under the radar of ASR

(although likely not common). Second, I focus on the roles of overvaluation and uncertainty

features but hold an agnostic view on what causes these features in the first place. I leave a

thorough investigation on the causes of these features to future research. Third, except for the

broad classification of short-selling allegations, I do not dive into the detailed content of short

theses as Chen (2016) and Ljungqvist and Qian (2016) do in their much smaller samples, because

my primary focus is on ex-ante available firm characteristics. I argue that the nature of firms (i.e.,

whether they should be shorted or should not have been shorted) – not who the short-sellers are or

what they say – are the first-order factor determining whether firms are targeted and what are the

return consequences. To avoid distracting from the main messages of this paper, I leave a thorough

examination of the content of short theses to future research. Finally, I only compare two rational

Page 42: Activist Short-Selling - University of Toronto T-Space · Activist short-selling – short-sellers publicly talking down securities to benefit their short positions – attracts attentions

33

frameworks – the information view and the HOB view – when I interpret results. However, I

cannot and do not intend to rule out the possibility that these results can be explained by alternative

theories, especially behavioral ones. For example, noise traders’ overreaction to salient news

(Shiller 1984; Daniel, Hirshleifer, and Subrahmanyam 1998; Lee and So 2014) such as activist

short-selling could provide the same empirical predictions as HOB does.

Page 43: Activist Short-Selling - University of Toronto T-Space · Activist short-selling – short-sellers publicly talking down securities to benefit their short positions – attracts attentions

34

References of Chapter 1

Aitken, M. J., Frino, A., McCorry, M. S., & Swan, P. L. (1998). Short sales are almost

instantaneously bad news: Evidence from the Australian Stock Exchange. The Journal of

Finance, 53(6), 2205-2223.

Allen, F., Morris, S., & Shin, H. S. (2006). Beauty contests and iterated expectations in asset

markets. Review of Financial Studies, 19(3), 719-752.

Amihud, Y. (2002). Illiquidity and stock returns: Cross-section and time-series effects. Journal of

Financial Markets, 5(1), 31-56.

Beneish, M. D., Lee, C. M., & Nichols, D. C. (2013). Earnings manipulation and expected

returns. Financial Analysts Journal, 69(2), 57-82.

Beneish, M. D., Lee, C. M., & Nichols, D. C. (2015). In short supply: Short-sellers and stock

returns. Journal of Accounting and Economics, 60(2), 33-57.

Beyer, A., Cohen, D. A., Lys, T. Z., & Walther, B. R. (2010). The financial reporting environment:

Review of the recent literature. Journal of Accounting and Economics, 50(2), 296-343.

Brent, A., Morse, D., & Stice, E. K. (1990). Short interest: Explanations and tests. Journal of

Financial and Quantitative Analysis, 25(02), 273-289.

Bushee, B. J. (1998). The influence of institutional investors on myopic R&D investment

behavior. The Accounting Review, (73)3, 305-333.

Chen, H., De, P., Hu, Y. J., & Hwang, B. H. (2014). Wisdom of crowds: The value of stock

opinions transmitted through social media. Review of Financial Studies, 27(5), 1367-1403.

Chen, J., Novy-Marx, R., and Zhang, L., (2010). An alternative three-factor model. University of

Rochester working paper.

Chen, L. (2016). The informational role of internet-based short-sellers: The evidence from short

sellers’ reports on US-listed Chinese firms. Journal of Business Finance & Accounting,

43(9-10), 1444-1482.

Comerton-Forde, C., Jones, C. M., & Putniņš, T. J. (2016). Shorting at close range: A tale of two

types. Journal of Financial Economics, 121(3), 546-568.

Cooper, M. J., Gulen, H., & Schill, M. J. (2008). Asset growth and the cross‐section of stock

returns. The Journal of Finance, 63(4), 1609-1651.

Corwin, S. A., & Schultz, P. (2012). A simple way to estimate bid‐ask spreads from daily high and

low prices. The Journal of Finance, 67(2), 719-760.

Daniel, K., Hirshleifer, D., & Subrahmanyam, A. (1998). Investor psychology and security market

under‐and overreactions. Journal of Finance, 53(6), 1839-1885.

Daniel, K., & Titman, S. (2006). Market reactions to tangible and intangible information. The

Journal of Finance, 61(4), 1605-1643.

Dechow, P. M., Hutton, A. P., Meulbroek, L., & Sloan, R. G. (2001). Short-sellers, fundamental

analysis, and stock returns. Journal of Financial Economics, 61(1), 77-106.

Dechow, P. M., Sloan, R. G., & Sweeney, A. P. (1995). Detecting earnings management. The

Accounting Review, 70(2), 193-225.

De Long, J. B., Shleifer, A., Summers, L. H., & Waldmann, R. J. (1990). Noise trader risk in

financial markets. Journal of Political Economy, 703-738.

Desai, H., Krishnamurthy, S., & Venkataraman, K. (2006). Do short sellers target firms with poor

earnings quality? Evidence from earnings restatements. Review of Accounting

Studies, 11(1), 71-90.

Page 44: Activist Short-Selling - University of Toronto T-Space · Activist short-selling – short-sellers publicly talking down securities to benefit their short positions – attracts attentions

35

Diamond, D. W., & Verrecchia, R. E. (1987). Constraints on short-selling and asset price

adjustment to private information. Journal of Financial Economics, 18(2), 277-311.

Drake, M. S., Rees, L., & Swanson, E. P. (2011). Should investors follow the prophets or the

bears? Evidence on the use of public information by analysts and short sellers. The

Accounting Review, 86(1), 101-130.

Engelberg, J., Reed, A. V., & Ringgenberg, M. (2016). Short selling risk. UNC Kenan-Flagler

working paper.

Fama, E. F. (1998). Market efficiency, long-term returns, and behavioral finance. Journal of

Financial Economics, 49(3), 283-306.

Figlewski, S., & Webb, G. P. (1993). Options, short sales, and market completeness. The Journal

of Finance, 48(2), 761-777.

Frankel, R., & Lee, C. M. (1998). Accounting valuation, market expectation, and cross-sectional

stock returns. Journal of Accounting and Economics, 25(3), 283-319.

Gao, P. (2008). Keynesian beauty contest, accounting disclosure, and market efficiency. Journal

of Accounting Research, 46(4), 785-807.

Green, J., Hand, J. R., & Soliman, M. T. (2011). Going, going, gone? The apparent demise of the

accruals anomaly. Management Science, 57(5), 797-816.

Grossman, S. J., & Stiglitz, J. E. (1980). On the impossibility of informationally efficient

markets. The American Economic Review, 70(3), 393-408.

Hirshleifer, D., Hou, K., Teoh, S. H., & Zhang, Y. (2004). Do investors overvalue firms with

bloated balance sheets? Journal of Accounting and Economics, 38, 297-331.

Hu, D. (2016). Does the public availability of market participants’ trading data affect firm

disclosure? Evidence from short sellers. Doctoral dissertation. University of Toronto,

Rotman School of Management.

Huddart, S. J., & Ke, B. (2007). Information asymmetry and cross‐sectional variation in insider

trading. Contemporary Accounting Research, 24(1), 195-232.

Jones, C. M., Reed, A. V., & Waller, W. (2016). Revealing shorts: An examination of large short

position disclosures. Review of Financial Studies, forthcoming.

Kahraman, B., & Pachare, S. (2016). The impact of increased public disclosure policies in the

shorting market. University of Oxford working paper.

Karpoff, J. M., & Lou, X. (2010). Short sellers and financial misconduct. The Journal of

Finance, 65(5), 1879-1913.

Keynes, J. M. (1936). The general theory of interest, employment and money. London: Macmillan.

Khan, M., & Lu, H. (2013). Do short sellers front-run insider sales? The Accounting Review, 88(5),

1743-1768.

Klassen, K. J., & Laplante, S. K. (2012). Are US multinational corporations becoming more

aggressive income shifters? Journal of Accounting Research, 50(5), 1245-1285.

Lakonishok, J., Shleifer, A., & Vishny, R. W. (1994). Contrarian investment, extrapolation, and

risk. The Journal of Finance, 49(5), 1541-1578.

Lamont, O. A. (2012). Go down fighting: Short-sellers vs. firms. Review of Asset Pricing

Studies, 2(1), 1-30.

Lamont, O. A., & Stein, J. C. (2004). Aggregate short interest and market valuations. American

Economic Review, 94(2), 29-32.

Lee, C. M. C., & So, E. C. (2014). Alphanomics: The informational underpinnings of market

efficiency. Foundations and Trends in Accounting, 9(2-3), 59-258.

Page 45: Activist Short-Selling - University of Toronto T-Space · Activist short-selling – short-sellers publicly talking down securities to benefit their short positions – attracts attentions

36

Lee, J. (2013). Activist short sellers: Market manipulators or market protectors? Review of Banking

& Financial Law, 32, 274-565.

Lee, L. F., & Lo, A. K. (2016). Do opinions on financial misstatement firms affect analysts’

reputation with investors? Evidence from reputational spillovers. Journal of Accounting

Research, 54(4), 1111-1148.

Li, K. K., & Mohanram, P. (2014). Evaluating cross-sectional forecasting models for implied cost

of capital. Review of Accounting Studies, 19(3), 1152-1185.

Liu, J., Nissim, D., & Thomas, J. (2002). Equity valuation using multiples. Journal of Accounting

Research, 40(1), 135-172.

Ljungqvist, A., & Qian, W. (2016). How constraining are limits to arbitrage? Evidence from a

recent financial innovation. Review of Financial Studies, 29(8), 1975-2028.

Mohanram, P. S. (2014). Analysts’ cash flow forecasts and the decline of the accruals

anomaly. Contemporary Accounting Research, 31(4), 1143-1170.

Morris, S., & Shin, H. S. (2002). Social value of public information. The American Economic

Review, 92(5), 1521-1534.

Novy-Marx, R., (2010). The other side of value: Good growth and the gross profitability premium.

University of Chicago working paper.

Ohlson, J. A. (1980). Financial ratios and the probabilistic prediction of bankruptcy. Journal of

Accounting Research, 18(1), 109-131.

Pownall, G., & Simko, P. J. (2005). The information intermediary role of short sellers. The

Accounting Review, 80(3), 941-966.

Ou, J. A., & Penman, S. H. (1989). Financial statement analysis and the prediction of stock

returns. Journal of Accounting and Economics, 11(4), 295-329.

Park, C. W., & Stice, E. K. (2000). Analyst forecasting ability and the stock price reaction to

forecast revisions. Review of Accounting Studies, 5(3), 259-272.

Qu, H. (2013). How do market prices and cheap talk affect coordination? Journal of Accounting

Research, 51(5), 1221-1260.

Reed, A. V. (2013). Short selling. Annual Review of Financial Economics, 5, 245-258.

Reed, A. V. (2015). Connecting supply, short-sellers and stock returns: Research

challenges. Journal of Accounting and Economics, 60(2), 97-103.

Savor, P. G., & Gamboa-Cavazos, M. (2011). Holding on to your shorts: When do short sellers

retreat? Working paper. Harvard University.

Senchack, A. J., & Starks, L. T. (1993). Short-sale restrictions and market reaction to short-interest

announcements. Journal of Financial and Quantitative Analysis, 28(2), 177-194.

Shiller, R. J. (1984). Stock prices and social dynamics. Brookings Papers on Economic

Activity, 1984(2), 457-510.

Short-selling: Nasty, brutish, and short. (2008, June 19). The Economist. Retrieved from

http://www.economist.com/node/11591349.

Sloan, R. (1996). Do stock prices fully reflect information in accruals and cash flows about future

earnings? The Accounting Review, 71(3), 289-315.

Stambaugh, R. F., Yu, J., & Yuan, Y. (2012). The short of it: Investor sentiment and

anomalies. Journal of Financial Economics, 104(2), 288-302.

Titman, S., & Tiu, C. (2011). Do the best hedge funds hedge? Review of Financial Studies, 24(1),

123-168.

Titman, S., Wei, K. J., & Xie, F. (2004). Capital investments and stock returns. Journal of

Financial and Quantitative Analysis, 39(04), 677-700.

Page 46: Activist Short-Selling - University of Toronto T-Space · Activist short-selling – short-sellers publicly talking down securities to benefit their short positions – attracts attentions

37

Woolridge, J. R., & Dickinson, A. (1994). Short selling and common stock prices. Financial

Analysts Journal, 50(1), 20-28.

Page 47: Activist Short-Selling - University of Toronto T-Space · Activist short-selling – short-sellers publicly talking down securities to benefit their short positions – attracts attentions

38

Appendices of Chapter 1

Appendix A: Activist Short-Selling in Seeking Alpha and Activist Shorts Research This appendix illustrates the two sources of my sample in greater detail. Panel A presents the SA “Short Ideas”

category where I identify my SA sample and a typical SA short-selling article. Panels B to D show three scenarios

regarding whether the SA article author is short the analyzed stock(s) or not.25 Panel E presents a typical newsletter

ASR sends to its subscribers. ASR tracks and summarizes all prominent short-selling campaigns in its newsletters.

Panel A: A typical article on SA “Short Ideas” category

25 These SA articles are available at http://seekingalpha.com/article/3740536-herbalife-moving-underground-

business-opportunity-pitch (Panels A and B), http://seekingalpha.com/article/3784096-mannkinds-bear-thesis-

remains-intact-woes-continue (Panel C), and http://seekingalpha.com/article/3778456-apple-needs-bring-cash-home-

sooner-better (Panel D).

Page 48: Activist Short-Selling - University of Toronto T-Space · Activist short-selling – short-sellers publicly talking down securities to benefit their short positions – attracts attentions

39

Panel B: A typical SA article indicating that the author is short a stock

Panel C: A typical SA article indicating that the author may short a stock

Panel D: A typical SA article indicating that the author has no plan to short a stock

Panel E: An ASR newsletter sent to its subscribers

main body of

the article (this

is the end)

SA contributor’s disclosure that

s/he is short the analyzed stock

SA contributor’s

disclosure that s/he is

not short the analyzed

stock but may short in

the next 72 hours

Page 49: Activist Short-Selling - University of Toronto T-Space · Activist short-selling – short-sellers publicly talking down securities to benefit their short positions – attracts attentions

40

Appendix B: The Activist Short-Selling Date and Financial Reporting Data

This appendix illustrates how I match financial reporting data with the activist short-selling

date. To make sure that the financial statement data are available when an activist short-seller

decides to target a firm, I match each activist short-selling case to the last fiscal quarter ended at

least 45 days prior to the activist short-selling date. That fiscal quarter is labeled as “data quarter”

of a certain activist short-selling case. Suppose A, C, E, and G are the fiscal quarter ending dates

of Q1, Q2, Q3, and Q4. The activist short-selling cases from B to D are matched with Q1 data,

from D to F are matched with Q2 data, from F to H are matched with Q3 data, and from H to I are

matched with Q4 data. There are 45 days between A and B, C and D, E and F, and G and H. If

there is no activist short-selling against one firm from B to D, then the Q1 quarter of this firm is

classified as a non-targeted observation.

Page 50: Activist Short-Selling - University of Toronto T-Space · Activist short-selling – short-sellers publicly talking down securities to benefit their short positions – attracts attentions

41

Appendix C: Variable Definitions

Following Beneish et al. (2015), all income statement and cash flow statement variables are trailing four quarters.

Balance sheet variables are for the most recent quarter. Lagged income statement variables are for quarters t-7 to t-4.

Lagged balance sheet variables are for quarter t-4.

Variables Definitions

Variables in determinants tests: Dependent variables

Target Indicator. For a given fiscal quarter, one if a firm is targeted by activist short-

sellers at least once from 45 days after the fiscal end of the quarter to 45 days

after the fiscal end of the next quarter, and zero otherwise. As illustrated in

Appendix B, Target is one for Q1 if there is at least one activist short-selling

case from B to D.

Variables on Overvaluation Features (all 12 individual continuous variables are transformed

into 0-1 indictors such that all values in the top quintile are defined as one, and zero otherwise)

PriceRunUp The raw return in the one year ending at the fiscal end of the data quarter.

P/B The percentile rank of market cap to book value of equity in each Fama–

French 48 industry at the fiscal end of the data quarter.

P/V The ratio of price to intrinsic value at the fiscal end of the data quarter. The

estimation of intrinsic value follows the Earnings Persistent model in Li and

Mohanram (2014). Specifically, I estimate a cross-sectional forecasting model

, 0 1 , 2 , 3 , , ,*i t i t i t i t i t i tE NegE E NegE E to generate earnings

forecasts for year t+1 to year t+5, where Et+π = (ib-spi)t+π/cshot (where ib, spi,

and csho are Compustat items for income before extraordinary items, special

items, and common shares outstanding, respectively); NegE is an indicator for

negative earnings. Then I assume the abnormal earnings remain constant after

year t+5. The intrinsic value is the aggregate discounted abnormal earnings,

where the cost of capital is assumed to be 12%.

LowGrossProf

it

(-1)*(Salest – Cost of Goods Soldt) /Total assetst

AssetGrowth Total assetst /Total assetst-4

Investment (CAPEXt + Increase in inventoryt)/ Total assetst-4

NOA (Debt in current liabilitiest + Long-term debtt +Total equityt)/ Total assetst

Accruals (Net incomet – Cash from operationst)/ Total assetst

LowPayout% (-1)*Clean Surplus Relation Payoutt / MVEt-4

LowEarnings (-1)*Income before extraordinary itemst/Total assetst

OScore -0.407*size+6.03*tlta–1.43*wcta+0.0757*clca–2.37*nita–1.83*futl+

0.285*intwo–1.72*oeneg–0.521*chin–1.32.

size=ln(Total assetst);

tlta=Total liabilitiest/Total assetst;

wcta=(Current assetst – Current liabilitiest)/ Total assetst;

clca=Current liabilitiest/Current assetst;

nita=Net incomet/Total assetst;

futl=CFOt/Total liabilitiest;

chin=(NIt–NIt-4]/[Abs(NIt)+Abs(NIt-4)];

oeneg=1 if total equityt is negative and 0 otherwise;

intwo=1 if net income is negative in both of the last two years and 0 otherwise

Page 51: Activist Short-Selling - University of Toronto T-Space · Activist short-selling – short-sellers publicly talking down securities to benefit their short positions – attracts attentions

42

MScore -4.84+0.92*dsri+0.528*gmi+0.404*aqi+0.892*sgi+0.115*depi –

0.172*sgai+4.679*tata–0.327*levi

dsri=(Receivablest/Salest)/(Receivablest-4/Salest-4);

gmi=Gross margint-1/Gross margint (Gross margin=1–COGS/Sales);

aqi=(1– (PPEt+CAt)/Assetst]/[1– (PPEt-4+CAt-4)/Assetst-4;

sgi=Salest/Salest-4; depi=[DPt-1/(DPt-1+PPEt-1)]/[DPt/(DPt+PPEt)] (DP=Depreciation);

sgai=(SGAt/Salest)/(SGAt-4/Salest-4);

tata=(IBt – CFOt)/ Total assetst ;

lvgi=Leveraget/Leveraget-4 (Leverage=debt/assets)

Overvaluation The average of the following seven variables that survive from the stepwise

regression: PriceRunUp, P/B, P/V, AssetGrowth, NOA, LowEarnings, and

MScore.

Variables on Uncertainty Features (all continuous variables are transformed into 0-1 indictors

such that all values in the top quintile are defined as one, and zero otherwise)

LowInstOwn (-1)* The institutional ownership at the fiscal end of the data quarter.

LowAccQualit

y

The standard deviation of discretionary accruals from fiscal year t-4 to fiscal

year t. Fiscal year t is the fiscal year consisting of the data quarter.

Discretionary accruals are calculated based on modified Jones model

(Dechow, Sloan, and Sweeney 1995).

AnalystDisagr

ee

The standard deviation of analyst forecast error for each analyst’s last EPS

forecast prior to the data quarter earnings announcements. Forecast error is

scaled by the closing price of the month prior to the earnings announcement.

BidAskSpread The quarterly average of daily bid/ask spread as calculated by Corwin and

Schultz (2012).

NonBIG4 Indicator. One if the auditor in the data quarter is not among the Big Four

auditors.

ICW Indicator. One if internal control weakness is identified in the previous fiscal

year.

AuditSwitch Indicator. One if there is auditor switch in the previous fiscal year.

NonBlock Indictor. One if there is no blockholder (holding >=5% shares) in the company.

LowDedicated (-1)*the number of dedicated institutional investors classified by Bushee’s

website (Bushee 1998).

Uncertain The average of the following six variables that survive from the stepwise

regression: LowAccQuality, BidAskSpread, NonBig4, ICW, NonBlock, and

LowDedicated.

Variables in market-reaction tests

AR(0) Abnormal return on the disclosure date adjusted by Fama–French three-factor

model returns. Factor loadings are estimated in a 110-day pre-event window

ending 30 trading days before the CAR window starts (the same procedure for

all CARs).

CAR(0, 1) Cumulative abnormal return in a two-day window starting from the activist

short-selling date adjusted by Fama–French three-factor model returns.

CAR(0, 2) Cumulative abnormal return in a three-day window starting from the activist

short-selling date adjusted by Fama–French three-factor model returns.

Page 52: Activist Short-Selling - University of Toronto T-Space · Activist short-selling – short-sellers publicly talking down securities to benefit their short positions – attracts attentions

43

CAR(1 Week) Cumulative abnormal return in a five-day window starting from the activist

short-selling date adjusted by Fama–French three-factor model returns.

CAR(1 Month) Cumulative abnormal return in a 22-day window starting from the activist

short-selling date adjusted by Fama–French three-factor model returns.

CAR(1 Year) Cumulative abnormal return in a 250-day window starting from the activist

short-selling date adjusted by Fama–French three-factor model returns.

Control variables

Size The log of total assets at the fiscal end of the data quarter.

Leverage The ratio of total liabilities to total assets at the fiscal end of the data quarter.

Illiquidity The mean of Amihud’s (2002) daily illiquidity measure in the data quarter,

which is measured as the log of one plus the ratio of absolute return and the

dollar trading volume and scaled by 106.

Volatility The quarterly standard deviation of daily return in the data quarter.

LnAnalyst Log of one plus the number of analysts who provide EPS estimates for the data

quarter prior to the earnings announcements.

ShortInterest The ratio of total shares in short position to total shares outstanding based on

the last settlement date prior to the fiscal end of the data quarter.

EarnAnnounce

[-5,0]

Indicator. One if there is an earnings announcement in the period five days

prior to the activist short-selling date.

AnForecast

[-5,0]

Indicator. One if there is at least one analyst forecast in the period five days

prior to the activist short-selling date.

ConfCall

[-5, 0]

Indicator. One if there is at least one conference call in the period five days

prior to the activist short-selling date. 26

Variables used in tests regarding primary allegations and targets’ tendency to respond

Overvaluation

Allegations

Indicator (only for ASR sample). One if the primary allegation from the short-

sellers is one of the following: Bubble, Stock Promotion, Other-

Overvaluation, Misleading Accounting, and Accounting Fraud.

Severe

Allegations

Indicator (only for ASR sample). One if the primary allegation from the short-

sellers is one of the following: Accounting Fraud, Major Business Fraud,

Pyramid Scheme, and Other-Illegal.

Firms Respond Indicator (only for ASR sample). One if the firm responds specifically to the

short-selling allegations.

Variables used in supplement analyses

Target by SA Indicator. One if a firm is targeted by at least one SA activist short-seller from

45 days after the fiscal end of the data quarter to 45 days after the fiscal end

of the next data quarter. Those data quarters that are matched only with ASR

shorts are set as missing.

Target by ASR Indicator. One if a firm is targeted by at least one ASR activist short-seller

from 45 days after the fiscal end of the data quarter to 45 days after the fiscal

end of the next data quarter. Those data quarters that are matched only with

SA shorts are set as missing.

26 Conference call data are collected from http://seekingalpha.com/earnings/earnings-call-transcripts. I thank Jingjing

Wang for sharing the data.

Page 53: Activist Short-Selling - University of Toronto T-Space · Activist short-selling – short-sellers publicly talking down securities to benefit their short positions – attracts attentions

44

ShortInterest_

45Days

The ratio of total shares in short position to total share outstanding based on

the first settlement date at least 45 days after the fiscal end of the data quarter.

TopShortIntere

st_45Days

Indicator. One if ShortInterest_45Days is among the top 1.79% of the quarter,

and zero otherwise. Note 1.79% is the unconditional probability a firm-quarter

is targeted by activist shorts in this study.

IncShortIntere

st

Indicator. One if ShortInterest_45Days is larger than ShortInterest. This

variable captures whether short-interest increases in the 45 days after the fiscal

end of the data quarter.

TopIncShortInt

erest

Indicator. One if ShortInterest_45Days – ShortInterest is among the top 1.79%

of the quarter, and zero otherwise.

AnalystSell Indicator. For a given fiscal quarter, one if a firm receives at least one Sell or

Strong Sell rating from any of its analysts from 45 days after the fiscal end of

the quarter to 45 days after the fiscal end of the next quarter, and zero

otherwise.

Downgrade Indicator. For a given fiscal quarter, one if a firm receives downgrading at

least once from any of its analysts from 45 days after the fiscal end of the

quarter to 45 days after the fiscal end of the next quarter, and zero otherwise.

Downgrading includes all changes from a more favorable rating to a less

favorable rating.

Page 54: Activist Short-Selling - University of Toronto T-Space · Activist short-selling – short-sellers publicly talking down securities to benefit their short positions – attracts attentions

45

Main Tables of Chapter 1

Table 1: Sample of Activist Short-Selling

This table illustrates the construction steps and the distribution of the activist short-selling sample. Panel A explains

the detailed steps through which I construct the sample. In particular, I combine articles from the “Short Ideas” section

in SA, campaigns collected from ASR, and the self-collected campaigns from these ASR short-sellers. Panel B

presents the distribution of the final sample of activist short-selling by year and by stock exchange.

Panel A: Sample-selection steps

SA data (Seeking Alpha) ASR data (Activist Shorts Research)

Sample Selection Steps No. of Obs. Sample Selection Steps No. of Obs.

SA “Short Ideas” articles from

2006 to 2015

15,072 Campaigns from ASR 773

Articles identified as activist

short-selling

5,738 Campaigns hand-collected on

those ASR shorts

172

Activist short-selling cases

(short-seller – stock – date level)

6,197 ASR short-selling cases

(short-seller – stock – date

level)

945

Combining SA and ASR 6,801 (341 are in both SA and ASR)

With PERMNO and GVKEY 6,08127

Panel B: Year distribution of the activist short-selling sample

Year\Exchange NYSE AMEX NASDAQ Total % by year

2006 33 18 40 91 1.50%

2007 100 16 86 202 3.32%

2008 164 46 98 308 5.06%

2009 170 4 112 286 4.70%

2010 158 14 127 299 4.92%

2011 125 21 302 448 7.37%

2012 208 20 347 575 9.46%

2013 447 48 591 1,086 17.86%

2014 622 60 815 1,497 24.62%

2015 635 41 613 1,289 21.20%

Total 2,662 288 3,131 6,081 100%

% by Exchange 43.78% 4.74% 51.49% 100%

27 Most of the stocks missing PERMNO are on OTC or oversea markets. It is worth noting that my sample includes

almost all observations used in Chen (2016) and Ljungqvist and Qian (2016).

Page 55: Activist Short-Selling - University of Toronto T-Space · Activist short-selling – short-sellers publicly talking down securities to benefit their short positions – attracts attentions

46

Table 2: Market Reactions to Activist Short-Selling and Passive Short-Selling28

This table reports the daily abnormal returns (Fama–French three-factor model adjusted) to activist short-selling (Panel

A) and five passive short-selling benchmarks (Panels B to F) that rely on market reactions to short-interest

announcements. Specifically, Panel B (C) reports the abnormal returns to the short-interest announcement by a firm

with the closest (increase in) short-interest ratio, in the same month, Fama–French 48 industry, and same size quintile

with each targeted stock. Panel D (E) reports the abnormal returns to the short-interest announcement by a firm with

the highest (increase in) short-interest ratio, in the same month, Fama–French 48 industry, and same size quintile with

each targeted stock. Panel F reports the abnormal returns to the latest short-interest announcement by each targeted

stock five days before the activist short-selling.

Trading Day -3 -2 -1 0 - Event 1 2 3

Panel A: Market reaction to activist short-selling (N=5,808)

Mean AR -0.0005 0.0008 -0.0015 -0.0156 -0.0054 -0.0013 -0.0016

Median AR -0.0017 -0.0018 -0.0030 -0.0058 -0.0028 -0.0018 -0.0021

t-stat -0.46 0.65 -1.19 -16.64 -7.31 -2.06 -2.52

Panel B: Benchmark 1 – industry peer with the closest short-interest ratio (N=3,061)

Mean AR -0.0006 0.0003 0.0004 -0.0009 -0.0003 0.0003 -0.0010

Median AR -0.0007 -0.0009 -0.0005 -0.0010 -0.0009 -0.0006 -0.0016

t-stat -1.09 0.49 0.83 -1.79 -0.64 0.51 -1.99

Panel C: Benchmark 2 – industry peer with the closest increase in short-interest (N=3,041)

Mean AR -0.0009 -0.0001 0.0000 -0.0005 0.0000 -0.0017 -0.0009

Median AR -0.0008 -0.0009 -0.0005 -0.0009 -0.0003 -0.0012 -0.0011

t-stat -1.70 -0.14 0.03 -1.04 -0.07 -3.34 -1.88

Panel D: Benchmark 3 – industry peer with the highest short-interest ratio (N=2,268)

Mean AR -0.0032 0.0004 0.0002 -0.0016 -0.0015 -0.0017 -0.0018

Median AR -0.0017 -0.0006 -0.0010 -0.0012 -0.0013 -0.0022 -0.0015

t-stat -2.66 0.44 0.27 -1.90 -1.93 -1.70 -1.86

Panel E: Benchmark 4 – industry peer with the highest increase in short-interest (N=2,193)

Mean AR -0.0023 -0.0006 -0.0022 -0.0016 -0.0020 0.0000 -0.0017

Median AR -0.0011 -0.0013 -0.0016 -0.0017 -0.0019 -0.0019 -0.0015

t-stat -1.91 -0.63 -2.44 -1.94 -2.52 -0.02 -1.68

Panel F: Benchmark 5 – the target’s own latest short-interest announcement (N=4,508)

Mean AR 0.0006 -0.0007 0.0003 -0.0001 0.0008 -0.0001 -0.0008

Median AR -0.0009 -0.0010 -0.0007 -0.0010 -0.0015 -0.0018 -0.0017

t-stat 0.85 -0.99 0.45 -0.17 1.00 -0.15 -0.93

28 The median short-interest ratio of Benchmark 1 (Benchmark 3) is 7.2% (26.9%), while the median ratio for the

target firms is 8.5%. The median increase in short-interest of Benchmark 2 (Benchmark 4) is 0.000% (2.103%), while

the median increase for the target firms is 0.007%. Note that the number of observations is not the same in all panels

because (1) one stock can be targeted by activist short-sellers for multiple times, and these cases would match the

same industry peer and same short-interest announcement of its own, and (2) multiple stocks can be in the same size

quintile of the same industry and they would match the same stock with the highest (increase in) short-interest ratio.

Page 56: Activist Short-Selling - University of Toronto T-Space · Activist short-selling – short-sellers publicly talking down securities to benefit their short positions – attracts attentions

47

Table 3: Descriptive Statistics of the Sample for Determinants Tests

This table illustrates the distribution and summary statistics of the sample for determinants tests (firm – quarter level).

Note that the “quarter” is the fiscal quarter of which financial reporting data is used (labeled as “data quarter” in

Appendix B). Panel A shows the by-year distribution of the firm-quarters by whether that are targeted by activist

shorts or not; Panel B compares the determinant-test variables between the firm-quarters that are targeted by activist

shorts and the firm-quarters that are not; Panel C tabulates the Pearson correlations among variables used in the

determinants tests. The correlation coefficients in bold and italic are significant at the 0.05 level. All variables are

defined in the Appendix C.

Panel A: By-year distribution of determinants sample (firm-quarter level)

Year/Type Non-Target Target Total % by Year

2005 5,071 7 5,078 2.72%

2006 19,988 91 20,079 10.75%

2007 19,643 156 19,799 10.60%

2008 19,089 179 19,268 10.32%

2009 17,844 170 18,014 9.64%

2010 17,414 204 17,618 9.43%

2011 17,096 244 17,340 9.28%

2012 16,692 340 17,032 9.12%

2013 16,254 772 17,026 9.12%

2014 16,985 701 17,686 9.47%

2015 17,352 480 17,832 9.55%

Total 183,428 3,344 186,772 100.00%

% by type 98.21% 1.79% 100.00%

Page 57: Activist Short-Selling - University of Toronto T-Space · Activist short-selling – short-sellers publicly talking down securities to benefit their short positions – attracts attentions

48

Panel B: Summary statistics for firm-quarters by whether they are targeted by activist short-sellers

Variables Firm-QTR not targeted Firm-QTR targeted Mean Difference

No. Obs Mean No. Obs Mean

Size 183,428 6.502 3,344 6.967 0.465***

Leverage 183,428 0.502 3,344 0.515 0.013***

Illiquidity 183,428 0.176 3,344 0.033 -0.142***

Volatility 183,428 0.031 3,344 0.033 0.002***

LnAnalyst 183,428 1.402 3,344 1.959 0.557***

ShortInterest 183,428 0.045 3,344 0.103 0.057***

PriceRunUp 183,428 0.196 3,344 0.285 0.089***

P/B 183,428 0.197 3,344 0.374 0.177***

P/V 183,428 0.131 3,344 0.255 0.124***

AssetGrowth 183,428 0.184 3,344 0.304 0.119***

Investment 183,428 0.147 3,344 0.189 0.042***

NOA 183,428 0.200 3,344 0.192 -0.008

Accruals 183,428 0.182 3,344 0.160 -0.022***

LowPayout% 183,428 0.183 3,344 0.222 0.039***

OScore 183,428 0.199 3,344 0.218 0.019***

MScore 183,428 0.175 3,344 0.231 0.056***

LowGrossProfit 183,428 0.186 3,344 0.172 -0.014**

LowEarnings 183,428 0.198 3,344 0.253 0.055***

LowInstOwn 183,428 0.203 3,344 0.179 -0.024***

NonBlock 183,428 0.186 3,344 0.183 -0.003

LowDedicated 183,428 0.263 3,344 0.195 -0.068***

LowAccQuality 183,428 0.118 3,344 0.133 0.015***

AnalystDisagree 183,428 0.130 3,344 0.188 0.058***

NonBig4 183,428 0.233 3,344 0.196 -0.037***

AuditSwitch 183,428 0.048 3,344 0.047 -0.000

ICW 183,428 0.054 3,344 0.064 0.010**

BidAskSpread 183,428 0.199 3,344 0.224 0.025***

Page 58: Activist Short-Selling - University of Toronto T-Space · Activist short-selling – short-sellers publicly talking down securities to benefit their short positions – attracts attentions

49

Panel C: Pearson correlations among variables used in the determinants tests

1 Target 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10 11 12 13 14 15 16 17 18 19

2 Size 0.03

3 Leverage 0.01 0.35 4 Illiquidity -0.04 -0.44 -0.03 5 Volatility 0.01 -0.40 0.03 0.44 6 LnAnalyst 0.07 0.56 0.12 -0.44 -0.27 7 ShortInterest 0.10 0.11 0.02 -0.17 -0.01 0.25 8 PriceRunUp 0.03 -0.02 -0.01 -0.09 0.00 0.02 0.04 9 P/B 0.06 -0.06 0.07 -0.09 -0.03 0.13 0.07 0.16 10 P/V 0.05 -0.12 -0.04 0.00 0.10 0.02 0.07 0.03 0.05 11 AssetGrowth 0.04 -0.02 -0.05 -0.08 0.01 0.07 0.09 0.14 0.08 0.02 12 Investment 0.02 0.00 -0.02 -0.03 0.02 0.05 0.04 0.01 0.03 0.00 0.11 13 NOA 0.00 -0.15 -0.29 0.03 0.04 -0.11 -0.03 -0.03 -0.08 0.03 0.07 0.00 14 Accruals -0.01 -0.05 -0.05 0.02 -0.01 -0.06 -0.01 0.03 -0.03 -0.03 0.10 -0.09 0.04 15 LowPayout% 0.01 -0.15 0.00 0.05 0.19 -0.09 0.00 0.09 -0.02 0.10 0.34 0.05 0.09 0.02 16 OScore 0.01 -0.34 0.35 0.25 0.34 -0.23 -0.04 -0.04 0.10 0.16 -0.02 -0.03 0.01 -0.02 0.23 17 MScore 0.02 -0.14 -0.08 0.02 0.07 -0.07 0.01 0.05 0.03 0.05 0.18 -0.01 0.08 0.20 0.11 0.03 18 LowGrossProfit 0.00 -0.03 0.07 0.03 0.11 -0.12 -0.05 -0.04 -0.05 0.11 0.06 -0.05 0.21 0.09 0.24 0.27 0.08 19 LowEarnings 0.02 -0.41 -0.03 0.20 0.35 -0.21 -0.04 -0.06 0.04 0.29 -0.02 -0.01 0.06 -0.07 0.26 0.47 0.04 0.26 20 LowInstOwn -0.01 -0.13 0.02 0.17 0.17 -0.21 -0.11 -0.04 -0.04 0.02 -0.01 -0.02 0.06 -0.02 0.11 0.16 0.05 0.08 0.16

21 NonBlock 0.01 -0.24 -0.09 0.12 0.17 -0.13 -0.02 0.01 0.02 0.06 0.07 0.05 0.00 0.04 0.10 0.12 0.06 -0.03 0.17

22 LowDedicated 0.01 -0.11 0.00 0.09 0.10 -0.11 -0.01 -0.02 -0.02 0.04 0.01 0.01 0.00 0.02 0.04 0.07 0.04 0.00 0.07

23 LowAccQuality 0.02 0.00 0.12 -0.09 0.13 0.15 0.04 -0.07 -0.07 0.15 0.01 0.01 0.03 -0.01 0.13 0.17 0.04 0.14 0.20

24 AnalystDisagree 0.01 -0.44 -0.01 0.32 0.52 -0.33 -0.09 -0.03 -0.02 0.09 -0.02 0.00 0.06 0.00 0.22 0.39 0.07 0.16 0.43

25 NonBig4 -0.01 -0.47 -0.14 0.35 0.21 -0.39 -0.13 0.00 -0.02 0.02 0.03 0.03 0.09 0.08 0.08 0.17 0.07 0.02 0.15

26 AuditSwitch 0.00 -0.10 -0.02 0.08 0.06 -0.10 -0.02 -0.01 -0.01 0.03 0.02 0.00 0.01 0.01 0.03 0.05 0.04 0.00 0.05

27 ICW 0.00 -0.05 -0.02 0.17 0.07 -0.25 -0.10 0.00 -0.01 -0.07 0.00 0.01 0.02 0.02 0.04 0.05 0.05 0.00 0.03

28 BidAskSpread -0.02 -0.32 -0.02 0.34 0.25 -0.35 -0.17 -0.03 -0.04 0.04 -0.01 -0.01 0.07 0.02 0.11 0.21 0.09 0.08 0.20

20 21 22 23 24 25 26 27 21 NonBlock 0.08

22 LowDedicated 0.06 0.08 23 LowAccQuality 0.08 0.04 0.02 24 AnalystDisagree 0.21 0.19 0.10 0.13 25 NonBig4 0.09 0.17 0.12 -0.06 0.25 26 AuditSwitch 0.04 0.05 0.13 0.00 0.07 0.13 27 ICW 0.01 0.04 0.04 -0.06 0.10 0.14 0.03 28 BidAskSpread 0.64 0.13 0.10 0.04 0.29 0.24 0.08 0.10

Page 59: Activist Short-Selling - University of Toronto T-Space · Activist short-selling – short-sellers publicly talking down securities to benefit their short positions – attracts attentions

50

Table 4: The Determinants of Being Targeted by Activist Short-Sellers: Overvaluation Features

This table tests H2 that activist short-sellers are more likely to target firms with overvaluation features. Each column reports Logit regression results regarding one

overvaluation feature. All continuous variables are transformed into 0-1 indictors such that all values in the top quintile are defined as one, and zero otherwise. All

variables are defined in the Appendix C. t statistics in parentheses are based on standard errors clustered by firm. * p < 0.1, ** p < 0.05, *** p < 0.01 (two-sided

tests)

DV=Target (1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6) (7) (8) (9) (10) (11) (12)

Overvaluation

Feature =

Price

Runup

P/B P/V Low

Gross

Profit

Asset

Growth

Investment NOA Accruals Low

Payout%

OScore MScore Low

Earnings

Overvaluation 0.354*** 0.781*** 0.666*** 0.147 0.452*** 0.166** 0.125* -0.026 0.203*** 0.258*** 0.407*** 0.389***

Feature (7.46) (11.71) (9.52) (1.56) (6.77) (2.32) (1.78) (-0.39) (3.42) (3.16) (6.73) (5.70)

Size 0.023 0.087*** 0.037 0.018 0.029 0.023 0.019 0.019 0.023 0.037 0.029 0.043

(0.81) (3.08) (1.31) (0.63) (1.03) (0.81) (0.67) (0.65) (0.80) (1.26) (1.02) (1.49)

Leverage -0.184 -0.396*** -0.202 -0.183 -0.138 -0.169 -0.127 -0.178 -0.184 -0.372** -0.148 -0.242*

(-1.40) (-2.79) (-1.55) (-1.39) (-1.05) (-1.29) (-0.96) (-1.35) (-1.40) (-2.45) (-1.13) (-1.85)

Illiquidity -1.822*** -1.738*** -1.819*** -1.907*** -1.815*** -1.905*** -1.903*** -1.909*** -1.893*** -1.935*** -1.861*** -1.919***

(-7.57) (-7.64) (-7.50) (-7.61) (-7.49) (-7.62) (-7.62) (-7.63) (-7.57) (-7.63) (-7.57) (-7.51)

Volatility 25.125*** 26.822*** 23.887*** 24.694*** 25.088*** 25.163*** 25.025*** 25.149*** 24.413*** 24.268*** 24.738*** 23.030***

(20.08) (21.31) (19.14) (19.49) (20.04) (20.11) (20.04) (20.02) (19.59) (19.25) (19.78) (17.75)

LnAnalyst 0.393*** 0.277*** 0.344*** 0.393*** 0.368*** 0.380*** 0.392*** 0.388*** 0.391*** 0.389*** 0.391*** 0.382***

(8.59) (6.73) (8.14) (8.59) (8.40) (8.44) (8.56) (8.51) (8.55) (8.55) (8.56) (8.45)

ShortInterest 3.336*** 3.308*** 3.298*** 3.360*** 3.220*** 3.345*** 3.363*** 3.361*** 3.344*** 3.346*** 3.300*** 3.364***

(15.32) (15.53) (15.23) (15.34) (14.63) (15.21) (15.33) (15.29) (15.20) (15.11) (14.75) (15.30)

FF 48 FE YES YES YES YES YES YES YES YES YES YES YES YES

QTR FE YES YES YES YES YES YES YES YES YES YES YES YES

Constant -8.131*** -8.566*** -8.111*** -8.010*** -8.163*** -8.040*** -8.058*** -7.996*** -8.037*** -8.057*** -8.160*** -8.123***

(-13.45) (-14.57) (-13.46) (-13.38) (-13.51) (-13.47) (-13.49) (-13.39) (-13.46) (-13.50) (-13.60) (-13.61)

Observations 181,76729 181,767 181,767 181,767 181,767 181,767 181,767 181,767 181,767 181,767 181,767 181,767

Pseudo R2 0.145 0.154 0.149 0.143 0.146 0.143 0.143 0.143 0.144 0.144 0.145 0.145

29 The number of observations is smaller than that in Panel B of Table 3, because Logit model with industry FE only uses those industries with at least one

observation being targeted. This explanation also applies to subsequent tables with Logit models.

Page 60: Activist Short-Selling - University of Toronto T-Space · Activist short-selling – short-sellers publicly talking down securities to benefit their short positions – attracts attentions

51

Table 5: The Determinants of Being Targeted by Activist Short-Sellers: Uncertainty Features

This table tests H3 that activist short-sellers are more likely to target firms with uncertainty features. Each column reports Logit regression results regarding one

uncertainty feature. All continuous variables are transformed into 0-1 indictors such that all values in the top quintile are defined as one, and zero otherwise. All

variables are defined in Appendix C. t statistics in parentheses are based on standard errors clustered by firm. * p < 0.1, ** p < 0.05, *** p < 0.01 (two-sided tests)

DV=Target (1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6) (7) (8) (9)

Uncertainty

Feature =

Low

InstOwn

Non

Block

Low

Dedicated

Low

AccQuality

Analyst

Disagree

NonBig4 Audit

Switch

ICW BidAskSpread

Uncertainty 0.1683** 0.3502*** 0.2395*** 0.2567*** -0.0270 0.3913*** 0.2879*** 0.3790*** 0.2554***

Feature (2.30) (5.03) (3.27) (3.19) (-0.41) (4.91) (2.77) (3.91) (3.58)

Size 0.0155 0.0062 0.0215 0.0265 0.0182 0.0437 0.0198 0.0209 0.0267

(0.55) (0.23) (0.76) (0.93) (0.64) (1.49) (0.70) (0.74) (0.93)

Leverage -0.1792 -0.1450 -0.1896 -0.1823 -0.1702 -0.1594 -0.1780 -0.1860 -0.1984

(-1.36) (-1.12) (-1.44) (-1.37) (-1.28) (-1.21) (-1.35) (-1.41) (-1.50)

Illiquidity -1.9437*** -1.9655*** -1.9864*** -1.9206*** -1.9143*** -2.0243*** -1.9160*** -1.9228*** -1.9592***

(-7.64) (-7.68) (-7.70) (-7.61) (-7.65) (-7.77) (-7.65) (-7.66) (-7.57)

Volatility 24.6971*** 24.7225*** 24.6263*** 24.8857*** 25.3041*** 25.1617*** 25.1147*** 24.8520*** 22.6003***

(19.56) (19.62) (19.71) (19.76) (19.68) (20.08) (20.01) (19.73) (17.21)

LnAnalyst 0.4028*** 0.4263*** 0.4055*** 0.3889*** 0.3898*** 0.4100*** 0.3928*** 0.3958*** 0.3982***

(8.61) (9.22) (8.71) (8.55) (8.43) (8.85) (8.59) (8.68) (8.65)

ShortInterest 3.3694*** 3.3607*** 3.3981*** 3.3624*** 3.3607*** 3.3728*** 3.3456*** 3.3498*** 3.3651***

(15.21) (14.75) (15.41) (15.36) (15.30) (15.39) (15.13) (15.27) (15.25)

FF 48 FE YES YES YES YES YES YES YES YES YES

QTR FE YES YES YES YES YES YES YES YES YES

Constant -8.0300*** -8.0200*** -8.0907*** -8.0488*** -8.0039*** -8.2710*** -8.0429*** -8.0814*** -8.0323***

(-13.45) (-13.58) (-13.56) (-13.50) (-13.41) (-13.89) (-13.49) (-13.58) (-13.48)

Observations 181,767 181,767 181,767 181,767 181,767 181,767 181,767 181,767 181,767

Pseudo R2 0.143 0.144 0.144 0.144 0.143 0.145 0.143 0.144 0.143

Page 61: Activist Short-Selling - University of Toronto T-Space · Activist short-selling – short-sellers publicly talking down securities to benefit their short positions – attracts attentions

52

Table 6: The Determinants of Being Targeted by Activist Short-Sellers: Stepwise

Regressions and Including Both Features Together

This table uses stepwise regressions and considers two sets of determinants together: overvaluation features and

uncertainty features. In columns 1–3, I use stepwise Logit regressions, removing all variables that are insignificant at

the 0.10 level. Specifically, seven overvaluation features survive in column 1, six uncertainty features survive in

column 2, and the same 13 variables survive in column 3, where I put all overvaluation and uncertainty features

together. In column 4, I use two aggregate variables, which are the average of the seven overvaluation features and

six uncertainty features, respectively. All variables are defined in Appendix C. t statistics in parentheses are based on

standard errors clustered by firm. * p < 0.1, ** p < 0.05, *** p < 0.01 (two-sided tests)

DV=Target (1) (2) (3) (4)

Only

Overvaluation

Features

Only

Uncertainty

Features

Both Features:

Individual

Measures

Both Features:

Aggregate

Measures

PriceRunUp 0.1560*** 0.1619***

(3.34) (3.47)

P/B 0.6898*** 0.6967***

(11.02) (11.16)

P/V 0.5137*** 0.5465***

(7.51) (7.99)

AssetGrowth 0.3079*** 0.2748***

(4.87) (4.36)

LowEarnings 0.3098*** 0.2645***

(4.51) (3.85)

NOA 0.1328* 0.1139*

(1.92) (1.65)

MScore 0.3071*** 0.2798***

(4.94) (4.51)

BidAskSpread 0.1808** 0.1806**

(2.53) (2.57)

NonBlock 0.3036*** 0.2680***

(4.33) (3.87)

LowDedicated 0.1884** 0.2241***

(2.53) (3.08)

LowAccQuality 0.2016** 0.1414*

(2.50) (1.80)

ICW 0.3039*** 0.2751***

(3.13) (2.82)

NonBIG4 0.3288*** 0.3274***

(4.08) (4.08)

Overvaluation 2.4654***

(14.94)

Uncertainty 1.3267***

(7.79)

Control variables YES YES YES YES

FF 48 FE YES YES YES YES

QTR FE YES YES YES YES

Constant -8.9839*** -8.4275*** -9.3845*** -9.3046***

(-15.05) (-14.33) (-15.95) (-15.45)

Observations 181,767 181,767 181,767 181,767

Pseudo R2 0.164 0.148 0.168 0.164

Page 62: Activist Short-Selling - University of Toronto T-Space · Activist short-selling – short-sellers publicly talking down securities to benefit their short positions – attracts attentions

53

Table 7: Market Reactions to Activist Short-Selling

This table presents details for the market-reaction tests. Panel A presents summary statistics for variables used in the

market-reactions tests; Panel B shows the regression results, with CAR windows extending from AR(0) in column 1

to CAR(1 Year) in column 6. At the bottom of Panel B, I briefly report the results using standardized CARs as

dependent variables. All variables are defined in the Appendix C. t statistics in parentheses are based on standard

errors clustered by firm. * p < 0.1, ** p < 0.05, *** p < 0.01 (two-sided tests)

Panel A: Market reactions to activist short-selling: summary statistics30

Variables Obs. Mean STD 1st Quartile Median 3rd Quartile

AR(0) 5,702 -0.015 0.060 -0.029 -0.005 0.010

CAR(0,1) 5,701 -0.020 0.074 -0.041 -0.008 0.014

CAR(0,2) 5,699 -0.022 0.085 -0.049 -0.010 0.017

CAR(1 Week) 5,694 -0.026 0.104 -0.064 -0.013 0.024

CAR(1 Month) 5,629 -0.042 0.199 -0.127 -0.027 0.060

CAR(1 Year) 4,474 -0.257 1.187 -0.742 -0.117 0.402

Overvaluation 5,702 0.300 0.211 0.143 0.286 0.429

Uncertainty 5,702 0.155 0.198 0.000 0.167 0.167

Size 5,702 7.251 2.249 5.665 7.247 8.775

Leverage 5,702 0.555 0.300 0.310 0.558 0.770

Illiquidity 5,702 0.025 0.127 0.000 0.001 0.006

Volatility 5,702 0.034 0.018 0.021 0.029 0.041

LnAnalyst 5,702 2.101 1.075 1.386 2.197 2.996

ShortInterest 5,702 0.133 0.177 0.021 0.075 0.187

EarnAnnounce[-5,0] 5,702 0.119 0.324 0.000 0.000 0.000

AnForecast[-5,0] 5,702 0.410 0.492 0.000 0.000 1.000

ConfCall[-5, 0] 5,702 0.014 0.116 0.000 0.000 0.000

30 I require non-missing values for AR(0) and all control variables. That explains why I have 5,702 observations in

Table 7 but 5,808 in Panel A of Table 2. Also, all inferences remain if I require non-missing values for all return

measures, i.e., from AR(0) to CAR(1Year).

Page 63: Activist Short-Selling - University of Toronto T-Space · Activist short-selling – short-sellers publicly talking down securities to benefit their short positions – attracts attentions

54

Panel B: Market reactions to activist short-selling: regression results (1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6)

AR(0) CAR(0,1) CAR(0,2) CAR

(1 Week)

CAR

(1 Month)

CAR

(1 Year)

Overvaluation (β1) -0.0059 -0.0113* -0.0237*** -0.0354*** -0.1000*** -0.8863***

(-1.16) (-1.88) (-3.65) (-4.30) (-5.44) (-5.92)

Uncertainty (β2) -0.0417*** -0.0481*** -0.0469*** -0.0557*** -0.0774*** -0.1030

(-5.74) (-5.61) (-3.80) (-3.53) (-3.17) (-0.48)

Size 0.0016** 0.0027*** 0.0026*** 0.0028** 0.0064** 0.0727***

(2.46) (3.30) (2.79) (2.26) (2.53) (3.10)

Leverage 0.0045 0.0014 -0.0009 -0.0000 0.0112 -0.0528

(1.09) (0.27) (-0.16) (-0.00) (0.66) (-0.31)

Illiquidity -0.0094 -0.0184 -0.0169 -0.0129 -0.0094 0.0090

(-0.70) (-1.53) (-1.07) (-0.69) (-0.24) (0.03)

Volatility 0.0081 -0.1568* -0.1559 -0.2835* -0.6668* -10.3406***

(0.12) (-1.66) (-1.39) (-1.90) (-1.70) (-3.27)

LnAnalyst 0.0060*** 0.0067*** 0.0086*** 0.0096*** 0.0199*** 0.0280

(4.76) (3.99) (4.46) (3.98) (3.84) (0.71)

ShortInterest 0.0053 0.0083 0.0118* 0.0202** 0.0401* 0.3076

(1.08) (1.23) (1.67) (2.06) (1.69) (1.41)

EarnAnnounce[-5,0] 0.0047 0.0000 0.0008 0.0018 -0.0055 0.0393

(1.30) (0.00) (0.13) (0.27) (-0.62) (0.64)

AnForecast[-5,0] -0.0026 -0.0028 -0.0020 -0.0053 -0.0048 -0.0666

(-1.36) (-1.13) (-0.69) (-1.37) (-0.72) (-1.57)

ConfCall[-5, 0] 0.0040 0.0138 0.0149 0.0124 0.0108 0.0385

(0.54) (1.27) (1.31) (0.99) (0.45) (0.35)

FF 48 FE Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes

QTR FE Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes

Constant -0.0246* -0.0301*** -0.0295*** -0.0503** -0.1027 -0.0633

(-1.85) (-3.76) (-2.87) (-2.17) (-1.57) (-0.28)

Observations 5,702 5,701 5,699 5,694 5,629 4,474

Adjusted R2 0.075 0.091 0.083 0.080 0.089 0.182

β1/ β2 0.141 0.235 0.505 0.636 1.292 8.605

Standardized CARs as dependent variables (i.e., decile ranks ranging from zero to one)

Overvaluation (β1) -0.0344 -0.0442* -0.0867*** -0.1166*** -0.1530*** -0.2572***

(-1.51) (-1.90) (-3.72) (-4.95) (-5.35) (-6.80)

Diff with Column 1 p = 0.763 p = 0.108 p = 0.012 p = 0.001 p < 0.001

Uncertainty (β2) -0.1685*** -0.1619*** -0.1165*** -0.1077*** -0.0997*** -0.0265

(-5.03) (-5.03) (-3.28) (-3.04) (-2.79) (-0.50)

Diff with Column 1 p = 0.886 p = 0.287 p = 0.212 p = 0.160 p = 0.023

β1/ β2 0.204 0.273 0.744 1.083 1.535 9.706

Page 64: Activist Short-Selling - University of Toronto T-Space · Activist short-selling – short-sellers publicly talking down securities to benefit their short positions – attracts attentions

55

Table 8: Do Overvaluation and Uncertainty Features Predict Short-Sellers’ Primary

Allegations and Firms’ Tendency to Respond?

This table considers the relations among firm features, short-selling allegations, and firms’ responses. Panel A

tabulates the basic statistics by each type of primary allegation. Panel B reports regression results regarding how

overvaluation and uncertainty features affect short-selling allegations and firms’ tendency to respond.

Panel A: Descriptive statistics by each allegation group

Primary Allegation

N. of

Obs.

CAR

(0, 1)

Proportion of Firms

that Respond

Overvaluation Uncertainty

Mean Median Mean Median

Accounting fraud 58 -0.098 0.828 0.333 0.286 0.325 0.333

Bubble 35 -0.051 0.171 0.469 0.429 0.205 0.167

Competitive pressures 31 -0.028 0.097 0.323 0.286 0.199 0.167

Dividend cut coming 6 -0.054 0.500 0.167 0.143 0.083 0.083

Industry issues 47 -0.026 0.191 0.219 0.143 0.113 0.000

Ineffective roll-up 18 -0.089 0.556 0.262 0.286 0.120 0.167

Major business fraud 68 -0.115 0.882 0.252 0.286 0.400 0.333

Medical effectiveness 65 -0.055 0.215 0.519 0.571 0.254 0.167

Misleading accounting 53 -0.041 0.340 0.270 0.286 0.179 0.167

Other – Illegal 39 -0.063 0.692 0.352 0.286 0.239 0.167

Other – Overvaluation 74 -0.044 0.257 0.324 0.286 0.245 0.167

Over-levered 29 -0.050 0.414 0.217 0.143 0.253 0.167

Patent expiration 5 -0.136 0.400 0.514 0.714 0.200 0.167

Patent invalid 14 -0.001 0.357 0.316 0.286 0.143 0.000

Product ineffective 35 -0.062 0.314 0.367 0.286 0.352 0.333

Pyramid scheme 5 -0.112 1.000 0.200 0.143 0.000 0.000

Stock promotion 38 -0.092 0.553 0.414 0.429 0.395 0.500

Upcoming earnings miss 20 -0.011 0.000 0.257 0.286 0.217 0.167

Total 640 -0.061 0.427 0.332 0.286 0.254 0.167

Panel B: Logit regression results (1) (2) (3) (4)

Overvaluation

Allegations

Severe

Allegations

Firms Respond Firms Respond

Overvaluation 1.1222* -0.5868 0.3207 0.5991

(1.94) (-0.75) (0.44) (0.76)

Uncertainty -0.6451 1.8736** 3.4145*** 3.3159***

(-1.04) (2.52) (4.70) (4.27)

Overvaluation Allegations 0.2942

(1.03)

Severe Allegations 2.5671***

(7.14)

Control Variables Yes Yes Yes Yes

FF 48 FE Yes Yes Yes Yes

QTR FE Yes Yes Yes Yes

Constant -0.0323 -1.7260 -2.1368 -2.8438

(-0.03) (-1.34) (-1.31) (-1.55)

Observations 601 579 561 561

Pseudo R2 0.191 0.295 0.199 0.304

Page 65: Activist Short-Selling - University of Toronto T-Space · Activist short-selling – short-sellers publicly talking down securities to benefit their short positions – attracts attentions

56

Table 9: Comparing SA Sample and ASR Sample: Determinants and Consequences

This table presents regression results focusing on only either SA sample or ASR sample. Panel A examines the

determinants of being targeted by SA (column 1) or ASR (column 2) activist shorts. Panel B presents regression results

regarding the market reactions to SA activist short-selling. Panel C presents regression results regarding the market

reactions to ASR activist short-selling. In both panels, CAR windows extend from AR(0) in column 1 to CAR(1 Year)

in column 6. All variables are defined in Appendix C. t statistics in parentheses are based on standard errors clustered

by firm. * p < 0.1, ** p < 0.05, *** p < 0.01 (two-sided tests)

Panel A: Determinants of being targeted by SA or ASR short-sellers

(1) (2)

Target by SA Target by ASR

Overvaluation 2.4372*** 2.6786***

(13.98) (11.59)

Uncertainty 1.2659*** 1.5717***

(7.15) (6.27)

Size 0.1310*** -0.0765*

(4.51) (-1.69)

Leverage -0.0630 -0.4789**

(-0.49) (-2.24)

Illiquidity -1.6754*** -3.3598***

(-6.96) (-4.65)

Volatility 19.7637*** 9.2944***

(14.86) (3.74)

LnAnalyst 0.3904*** 0.0350

(8.65) (0.59)

ShortInterest 3.0794*** 3.6662***

(14.30) (13.24)

FF 48 FE Yes Yes

QTR FE Yes Yes

Constant -10.2821*** -7.7433***

(-13.33) (-8.37)

Observations 181,767 175,991

Pseudo R2 0.167 0.157

Page 66: Activist Short-Selling - University of Toronto T-Space · Activist short-selling – short-sellers publicly talking down securities to benefit their short positions – attracts attentions

57

Panel B: Consequences of activist short-selling in the SA sample (1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6)

AR(0) CAR(0,1) CAR(0,2) CAR

(1 Week)

CAR

(1 Month)

CAR

(1 Year)

Overvaluation (β1) -0.0038 -0.0067 -0.0187*** -0.0295*** -0.0918*** -0.8751***

(-0.84) (-1.21) (-3.13) (-3.83) (-5.09) (-5.69)

Uncertainty (β2) -0.0390*** -0.0480*** -0.0470*** -0.0543*** -0.0742*** -0.0927

(-5.14) (-5.41) (-3.48) (-3.16) (-2.89) (-0.40)

Control variables Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes

FF 48 FE Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes

QTR FE Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes

Constant -0.0250*** -0.0181* -0.0103 0.0041 -0.0545 -0.2656

(-3.58) (-1.94) (-0.97) (0.31) (-1.24) (-1.23)

Observations 5,243 5,242 5,240 5,235 5,177 4,117

Adjusted R2 0.067 0.081 0.076 0.075 0.080 0.178

β1/ β2 0.097 0.140 0.398 0.543 1.237 9.440

Panel C: Consequences of activist short-selling in the ASR sample (1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6)

AR(0) CAR(0,1) CAR(0,2) CAR

(1 Week)

CAR

(1 Month)

CAR

(1 Year)

Overvaluation (β1) -0.0072 -0.0257 -0.0256 -0.0383 -0.1433*** -1.1476***

(-0.41) (-1.23) (-1.15) (-1.49) (-3.04) (-3.53)

Uncertainty (β2) -0.0630*** -0.0450* -0.0343 -0.0400 -0.1493** 0.0133

(-3.39) (-1.81) (-1.22) (-1.29) (-2.51) (0.04)

Control variables Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes

FF 48 FE Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes

QTR FE Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes

Constant -0.0113 -0.0061 -0.0154 -0.0461 0.0364 0.4931

(-0.34) (-0.20) (-0.50) (-1.10) (0.33) (1.05)

Observations 753 753 753 753 745 576

Adjusted R2 0.089 0.105 0.099 0.122 0.133 0.222

β1/ β2 0.114 0.571 0.746 0.958 0.960 -86.29

Page 67: Activist Short-Selling - University of Toronto T-Space · Activist short-selling – short-sellers publicly talking down securities to benefit their short positions – attracts attentions

58

Table 10: Several Sets of Pseudo Analyses

This table reports several sets of pseudo analyses. Panel A presents regression results on how overvaluation and

uncertainty features predict short-interest ratio, increase in short-interest, and unfavorable analyst recommendations.

Column 1 is OLS regression with short-interest ratio as the dependent variable; columns 2 to 6 are Logit regressions

with the indicators of top short-interest ratio (top 1.79% in the quarter), of short-interest increase, of top increase in

short-interest (top 1.79% in the quarter), of Sell recommendations, and of analyst downgrading as dependent variables,

respectively. Panel B reports market reaction tests using pseudo targets matched on Overvaluation, Uncertainty, size,

and industry, with CAR windows extending from AR(0) in column 1 to CAR(1 Year) in column 6. All variables are

defined in Appendix C. t statistics in parentheses are based on standard errors clustered by firm. * p < 0.1, ** p < 0.05,

*** p < 0.01 (two-sided tests)

Panel A: Do overvaluation and uncertainty predict short-interest and analyst recommendations? (1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6)

ShortInterest

_45Days

(OLS)

TopShort

Interest_45Days

(Logit)

IncShort

Interest

(Logit)

TopIncShort

Interest

(Logit)

Analyst

Sell

(Logit)

Down

grade

(Logit)

Overvaluation 0.0053*** 0.3003* 0.5750*** 0.8554*** -0.2820*** -0.4711***

(3.82) (1.71) (16.64) (6.12) (-3.66) (-5.31)

Uncertainty -0.0105*** -0.0116 -0.2890*** -0.5943*** -0.1450 -0.2481**

(-6.51) (-0.06) (-8.08) (-3.79) (-1.40) (-2.07)

Size 0.0006** 0.0239 0.0074* 0.1354*** 0.1892*** 0.1600***

(2.56) (0.76) (1.79) (6.37) (14.69) (11.32)

Leverage 0.0105*** 0.7121*** 0.0459** 0.4293*** -0.1268* -0.1780**

(8.71) (6.43) (2.08) (4.28) (-1.72) (-2.23)

Illiquidity 0.0014 0.4043** 0.0434*** 0.1746** -1.2684*** -1.2590***

(0.68) (2.54) (2.72) (2.06) (-6.96) (-6.17)

Volatility 0.3777*** 19.5760*** 0.8443** 22.3793*** 9.7842*** 9.2408***

(14.90) (12.48) (2.30) (18.64) (11.49) (9.82)

LnAnalyst -0.0017*** -0.3230*** 0.0484*** -0.0623* 0.8469*** 0.8556***

(-4.08) (-6.29) (6.64) (-1.79) (33.40) (28.17)

ShortInterest 0.8925*** 16.3190*** -2.4705*** 3.5261*** 2.2216*** 1.9154***

(57.52) (20.32) (-23.05) (11.81) (12.18) (11.84)

FF 48 FE YES YES YES YES YES YES

QTR FE YES YES YES YES YES YES

Constant -0.0044 -7.4074*** -0.0162 -5.2364*** -5.2678*** -6.7353***

(-0.91) (-11.75) (-0.18) (-15.43) (-21.02) (-20.66)

Observations 186,772 186,772 186,772 186,772 186,772 186,772

Adjusted/Pseudo R2 0.468 0.441 0.031 0.069 0.179 0.151

Panel B: Return consequences of pseudo targets (1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6)

AR(0) CAR(0,1) CAR(0,2) CAR(1 Week) CAR(1 Month) CAR (1 Year)

Overvaluation (β1) -0.0032 -0.0095*** -0.0156*** -0.0166*** -0.0666*** -0.5530***

(-1.48) (-3.34) (-4.39) (-3.12) (-4.74) (-5.10)

Uncertainty (β2) 0.0052* 0.0035 0.0076 0.0042 0.0302 -0.0346

(1.85) (0.80) (1.33) (0.53) (1.59) (-0.24)

Control variables Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes

FF 48 FE Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes

QTR FE Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes

Constant 0.0021 0.0026 -0.0011 0.0632 -0.0223 -0.2236

(0.44) (0.31) (-0.13) (1.08) (-0.35) (-0.79)

Observations 4,722 4,721 4,719 4,714 4,661 3,681

Adjusted R2 0.004 0.005 0.015 0.013 0.045 0.110

Page 68: Activist Short-Selling - University of Toronto T-Space · Activist short-selling – short-sellers publicly talking down securities to benefit their short positions – attracts attentions

59

Main Figures of Chapter 1

Figure 1: Mean Cumulative Abnormal Returns for Targets with High and Low

Overvaluation and Uncertainty

This figure plots the mean cumulative abnormal returns in a window of (-60, 250) for four groups of targets with

Overvaluation or Uncertainty higher or lower than the medians of the determinant-test sample (i.e., including both

targeted and non-targeted firm-quarters). The long dash line represents targets with Low Overvaluation and Low

Uncertainty, the short dash line represents targets with Low Overvaluation and High Uncertainty, the dotted line

represents targets with High Overvaluation and Low Uncertainty, and the solid line represents targets with High

Overvaluation and High Uncertainty. The abnormal return is calculated benchmarking on the Fama–French three-

factor model.

Page 69: Activist Short-Selling - University of Toronto T-Space · Activist short-selling – short-sellers publicly talking down securities to benefit their short positions – attracts attentions

60

Additional Robustness Tests

Table A1: The Interaction between Overvaluation and Uncertainty Features

This table presents the interaction effects of overvaluation and uncertainty features in the determinants and

consequences of activist short-selling. Panel A reports results on determinant-test models and Panel B reports results

on the return consequences.

Panel A: Determinants test

(1) (2) (3)

Target Target by SA Target by ASR

Overvaluation × Uncertainty 0.1762 0.2370 -1.6254*

(0.30) (0.38) (-1.92)

Overvaluation 2.4363*** 2.3985*** 3.0481***

(11.51) (10.78) (9.87)

Uncertainty 1.2706*** 1.1906*** 2.1584***

(4.94) (4.47) (5.35)

Size 0.1263*** 0.1310*** -0.0743

(4.46) (4.51) (-1.64)

Leverage -0.1430 -0.0612 -0.4857**

(-1.12) (-0.47) (-2.27)

Illiquidity -1.7937*** -1.6680*** -3.4761***

(-7.28) (-6.97) (-4.67)

Volatility 18.8672*** 19.7758*** 9.2793***

(14.37) (14.85) (3.75)

LnAnalyst 0.3746*** 0.3904*** 0.0296

(8.76) (8.65) (0.50)

ShortInterest 3.1826*** 3.0813*** 3.6491***

(14.89) (14.31) (13.07)

FF 48 FE Yes Yes Yes

QTR FE Yes Yes Yes

Constant -9.2984*** -10.2740*** -7.8543***

(-15.40) (-13.30) (-8.49)

Observations 181,767 181,767 175,991

Pseudo R2 0.164 0.167 0.157

Page 70: Activist Short-Selling - University of Toronto T-Space · Activist short-selling – short-sellers publicly talking down securities to benefit their short positions – attracts attentions

61

Panel B: Return consequence test

(1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6)

AR(0) CAR(0,1) CAR(0,2) CAR

(1Week)

CAR

(1Month)

CAR

(1Year)

Overvaluation 0.0276 -0.0050 -0.0325 -0.0525 -0.1314 -1.7977**

× Uncertainty (0.97) (-0.14) (-0.86) (-1.10) (-1.28) (-2.42)

Overvaluation -0.0102** -0.0105* -0.0185*** -0.0271*** -0.0792*** -0.5879***

(-2.05) (-1.68) (-2.59) (-2.91) (-3.49) (-3.35)

Uncertainty -0.0508*** -0.0465*** -0.0362** -0.0383* -0.0340 0.5047

(-4.13) (-3.24) (-2.07) (-1.68) (-0.80) (1.56)

Size 0.0016** 0.0027*** 0.0026*** 0.0028** 0.0064** 0.0728***

(2.47) (3.30) (2.78) (2.25) (2.52) (3.10)

Leverage 0.0047 0.0013 -0.0012 -0.0004 0.0103 -0.0585

(1.16) (0.26) (-0.19) (-0.05) (0.61) (-0.34)

Illiquidity -0.0080 -0.0186 -0.0186 -0.0157 -0.0162 -0.0882

(-0.59) (-1.54) (-1.17) (-0.82) (-0.42) (-0.31)

Volatility 0.0060 -0.1564* -0.1535 -0.2796* -0.6569* -10.306***

(0.09) (-1.65) (-1.37) (-1.88) (-1.68) (-3.30)

LnAnalyst 0.0061*** 0.0067*** 0.0085*** 0.0094*** 0.0195*** 0.0191

(4.85) (3.99) (4.40) (3.89) (3.75) (0.49)

ShortInterest 0.0055 0.0083 0.0115 0.0198** 0.0390 0.2889

(1.13) (1.23) (1.63) (2.02) (1.64) (1.33)

EarnAnnounce[-5,0] 0.0047 0.0000 0.0008 0.0018 -0.0054 0.0392

(1.30) (0.00) (0.14) (0.27) (-0.61) (0.64)

AnForecast[-5,0] -0.0026 -0.0027 -0.0020 -0.0053 -0.0047 -0.0645

(-1.36) (-1.13) (-0.68) (-1.36) (-0.71) (-1.52)

ConfCall[-5,0] 0.0041 0.0138 0.0148 0.0122 0.0104 0.0339

(0.55) (1.27) (1.30) (0.98) (0.44) (0.31)

FF 48 FE Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes

QTR FE Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes

Constant -0.0239* -0.0302*** -0.0304*** -0.0517** -0.1061 -0.1112

(-1.85) (-3.75) (-3.04) (-2.30) (-1.62) (-0.47)

Observations 5,702 5,701 5,699 5,694 5,629 4,474

Adjusted R2 0.075 0.090 0.083 0.081 0.089 0.185

Page 71: Activist Short-Selling - University of Toronto T-Space · Activist short-selling – short-sellers publicly talking down securities to benefit their short positions – attracts attentions

62

Table A2: Excluding Activist Short-Selling Cases Covered by Mainstream Media

This table reports return consequence results using activist short-selling cases that are not covered by Top U.S.

Mainstream media. I manually check Factiva Top US Newspapers articles with the names of both the short-seller and

the target company mentioned in the Headline and Lead Paragraph.

(1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6)

AR(0) CAR(0,1) CAR(0,2) CAR

(1Week)

CAR

(1Month)

CAR

(1Year)

Overvaluation -0.0033 -0.0095* -0.0206*** -0.0306*** -0.0950*** -0.8822***

(-0.77) (-1.69) (-3.33) (-3.85) (-5.18) (-5.92)

Uncertainty -0.0440*** -0.0531*** -0.0512*** -0.0581*** -0.0695*** -0.0361

(-5.86) (-5.81) (-4.60) (-4.09) (-2.74) (-0.16)

Size 0.0017*** 0.0024*** 0.0023** 0.0028** 0.0065** 0.0639***

(2.61) (3.04) (2.57) (2.26) (2.49) (2.74)

Leverage 0.0037 0.0004 -0.0019 -0.0018 0.0092 -0.0197

(0.95) (0.09) (-0.32) (-0.22) (0.59) (-0.12)

Illiquidity -0.0148 -0.0211* -0.0194 -0.0180 -0.0151 -0.0005

(-1.12) (-1.69) (-1.19) (-0.92) (-0.39) (-0.00)

Volatility -0.0067 -0.1586* -0.1334 -0.2754* -0.5013 -10.0363***

(-0.10) (-1.69) (-1.19) (-1.86) (-1.29) (-3.34)

LnAnalyst 0.0046*** 0.0057*** 0.0079*** 0.0088*** 0.0200*** 0.0282

(3.76) (3.39) (3.93) (3.52) (3.80) (0.70)

ShortInterest 0.0020 0.0066 0.0077 0.0134 0.0284 0.2455

(0.32) (0.98) (1.05) (1.49) (1.14) (1.17)

EarnAnnounce[-5,0] 0.0037 0.0000 0.0013 0.0015 -0.0046 0.0538

(1.10) (0.01) (0.22) (0.22) (-0.53) (0.91)

AnForecast[-5,0] -0.0028 -0.0033 -0.0031 -0.0060 -0.0031 -0.0583

(-1.53) (-1.41) (-1.06) (-1.56) (-0.46) (-1.40)

ConfCall[-5,0] 0.0069 0.0115 0.0084 0.0111 0.0080 0.0454

(1.12) (1.04) (0.72) (0.87) (0.32) (0.40)

FF 48 FE Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes

QTR FE Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes

Constant -0.0113 -0.0242** -0.0278* -0.0437 -0.0583* 0.0364

(-0.95) (-2.41) (-1.73) (-1.15) (-1.73) (0.13)

Observations 5,226 5,225 5,223 5,218 5,156 4,106

Adjusted R2 0.073 0.088 0.081 0.080 0.086 0.173

Page 72: Activist Short-Selling - University of Toronto T-Space · Activist short-selling – short-sellers publicly talking down securities to benefit their short positions – attracts attentions

63

Table A3: The Role of Short-Seller’s Reputation

This table highlights the role of the short-seller’s reputation in affecting returns after firms are targeted. CumReturn is

the accumulated CAR(0, 1) for the same short-seller’s all previous activist short-selling cases.

(1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6)

AR(0) CAR(0,1) CAR(0,2) CAR

(1Week)

CAR

(1Month)

CAR

(1Year)

CumReturn 0.0046*** 0.0051*** 0.0040*** 0.0040** 0.0057 0.0346

(4.41) (3.92) (2.92) (2.30) (1.22) (1.31)

Overvaluation -0.0060 -0.0119** -0.0243*** -0.0354*** -0.0968*** -0.8860***

(-1.31) (-2.10) (-3.96) (-4.46) (-5.41) (-5.87)

Uncertainty -0.0396*** -0.0468*** -0.0469*** -0.0548*** -0.0792*** -0.1017

(-5.51) (-5.52) (-3.82) (-3.49) (-3.29) (-0.47)

Size 0.0013** 0.0024*** 0.0024*** 0.0027** 0.0066*** 0.0723***

(2.05) (2.94) (2.59) (2.16) (2.62) (3.13)

Leverage 0.0032 -0.0002 -0.0017 -0.0006 0.0098 -0.0483

(0.80) (-0.04) (-0.29) (-0.07) (0.60) (-0.29)

Illiquidity -0.0093 -0.0192 -0.0181 -0.0139 -0.0086 0.0056

(-0.69) (-1.59) (-1.14) (-0.74) (-0.22) (0.02)

Volatility 0.0056 -0.1374 -0.1358 -0.2627* -0.5548 -9.8060***

(0.09) (-1.49) (-1.23) (-1.79) (-1.43) (-3.11)

LnAnalyst 0.0055*** 0.0064*** 0.0080*** 0.0090*** 0.0191*** 0.0265

(4.59) (3.99) (4.28) (3.86) (3.75) (0.68)

ShortInterest 0.0053 0.0075 0.0112 0.0204** 0.0414* 0.2965

(1.07) (1.13) (1.61) (2.15) (1.73) (1.35)

EarnAnnounce[-5,0] 0.0047 0.0004 0.0014 0.0022 -0.0048 0.0460

(1.37) (0.08) (0.25) (0.34) (-0.55) (0.78)

AnForecast[-5,0] -0.0027 -0.0029 -0.0024 -0.0057 -0.0064 -0.0692

(-1.48) (-1.21) (-0.83) (-1.48) (-0.96) (-1.63)

ConfCall[-5,0] 0.0043 0.0135 0.0150 0.0133 0.0122 0.0342

(0.58) (1.24) (1.33) (1.07) (0.51) (0.31)

FF 48 FE Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes

QTR FE Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes

Constant -0.0209 -0.0266*** -0.0264** -0.0484** -0.1053 -0.0777

(-1.60) (-3.27) (-2.51) (-2.06) (-1.63) (-0.35)

Observations 5,606 5,605 5,603 5,598 5,533 4,393

Adjusted R2 0.075 0.092 0.081 0.080 0.089 0.179

Page 73: Activist Short-Selling - University of Toronto T-Space · Activist short-selling – short-sellers publicly talking down securities to benefit their short positions – attracts attentions

64

Table A4: Results are Not Driven by Firm-Quarters That Are Targeted Multiple Times

This table addresses the possibility that the results are driven by some firm-quarters targeted by multiple times. Panel

A explicitly models the number of times each firm-quarter is targeted in the determinant test. The same overvaluation

and uncertainty features survive the step-wise regressions. Panel B focuses on the first activist short-selling case for

each firm-quarter.

Panel A: Modeling the number of times a firm-quarter is targeted

(1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6)

N_Target

(Negative

Binomial)

N_Target

(Negative

Binomial)

lnN_Target

(OLS)

lnN_Target

(OLS)

N_Target

(Negative

Binomial)

lnN_Target

(OLS)

Size 0.1908*** 0.1187*** 0.0025*** 0.0012** 0.2003*** 0.0027***

(6.76) (3.84) (4.53) (2.27) (6.87) (4.76)

Leverage -0.1172 0.0045 -0.0052** -0.0024 0.0290 -0.0019

(-0.74) (0.03) (-1.98) (-0.94) (0.19) (-0.74)

Illiquidity -1.6610*** -2.2906*** -0.0025 -0.0081*** -1.9173*** -0.0043***

(-7.17) (-8.11) (-1.61) (-6.55) (-7.39) (-2.90)

Volatility 29.5617*** 28.6861*** 0.3616*** 0.3468*** 22.9882*** 0.2793***

(16.91) (15.11) (12.11) (11.43) (13.00) (9.81)

LnAnalyst 0.2027*** 0.5023*** 0.0027*** 0.0063*** 0.3570*** 0.0047***

(4.63) (7.61) (3.77) (6.50) (6.80) (5.64)

ShortInterest 4.5082*** 5.2621*** 0.1432*** 0.1579*** 4.8448*** 0.1492***

(9.65) (9.87) (5.19) (5.55) (9.54) (5.33)

Run-up 0.1018* 0.0038***

(1.76) (3.82)

HighP/B 0.8691*** 0.0159***

(10.69) (6.75)

HighP/V 0.4794*** 0.0158***

(5.45) (5.17)

HighAssetGrowth 0.3953*** 0.0092***

(4.83) (4.02)

LowQTREarning 0.3146*** 0.0039***

(3.83) (2.67)

HighNOA 0.2001** 0.0023**

(2.44) (2.00)

HighManipulation 0.3568*** 0.0042***

(4.56) (2.91)

HighB/SSpread 0.2340** 0.0032***

(2.55) (2.64)

NonBlockholder 0.4242*** 0.0062***

(5.10) (5.45)

LowDedicated 0.2832*** 0.0035***

(3.16) (3.01)

LowEarnQuality 0.2653*** 0.0028*

(2.76) (1.72)

HighSTDFE -0.1966**

(-2.40)

NonBIG4 0.4248*** 0.0055***

(4.30) (3.97)

AuditSwitch 0.3234** 0.0038*

Page 74: Activist Short-Selling - University of Toronto T-Space · Activist short-selling – short-sellers publicly talking down securities to benefit their short positions – attracts attentions

65

(2.51) (1.83)

IntCntrlWeak 0.2855**

(2.31)

Overvaluation 2.8292*** 0.0549***

(12.68) (7.89)

Uncertainty 1.7256*** 0.0206***

(8.16) (6.41)

FF 48 FE Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes

QTR FE Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes

Constant -9.7738*** -9.4165*** -0.0450*** -0.0345*** -10.1642*** -0.0513***

(-15.07) (-14.42) (-5.89) (-4.84) (-15.49) (-6.40)

Observations 186,772 186,772 186,772 186,772 186,772 186,772

Adjusted/Pseudo R2 0.155 0.153 0.035 0.030 0.154 0.034

Panel B: Focusing on the first activist short-selling case of each firm-quarter

(1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6)

AR(0) CAR(0,1) CAR(0,2) CAR

(1Week)

CAR

(1Month)

CAR

(1Year)

Overvaluation -0.0087 -0.0119 -0.0222*** -0.0329*** -0.0781*** -0.7040***

(-1.51) (-1.61) (-2.80) (-3.43) (-4.33) (-6.03)

Uncertainty -0.0474*** -0.0507*** -0.0537*** -0.0609*** -0.0764*** -0.1403

(-5.95) (-5.28) (-4.80) (-4.39) (-3.20) (-0.94)

Size 0.0015** 0.0021** 0.0019* 0.0015 0.0032 0.0299*

(2.06) (2.24) (1.85) (1.16) (1.36) (1.87)

Leverage 0.0035 0.0002 -0.0031 -0.0010 0.0178 -0.0564

(0.74) (0.04) (-0.48) (-0.13) (1.28) (-0.60)

Illiquidity -0.0037 -0.0121 -0.0105 -0.0147 -0.0201 0.0356

(-0.30) (-1.01) (-0.62) (-0.74) (-0.51) (0.13)

Volatility 0.0374 -0.1755 -0.1570 -0.2674 -0.7195** -10.225***

(0.41) (-1.49) (-1.07) (-1.55) (-2.11) (-4.35)

LnAnalyst 0.0067*** 0.0086*** 0.0101*** 0.0112*** 0.0245*** 0.0597*

(4.54) (4.31) (4.40) (4.06) (4.68) (1.78)

ShortInterest 0.0007 0.0004 0.0016 0.0094 0.0444 0.3478**

(0.10) (0.04) (0.14) (0.52) (1.59) (2.39)

EarnAnnounce[-5,0] 0.0066 0.0051 0.0071 0.0037 0.0079 0.0078

(1.48) (1.02) (1.20) (0.54) (0.66) (0.10)

AnForecast[-5,0] -0.0027 -0.0017 0.0004 -0.0012 -0.0034 -0.0567

(-1.14) (-0.58) (0.12) (-0.31) (-0.46) (-1.19)

ConfCall[-5,0] -0.0059 -0.0022 -0.0024 0.0067 -0.0168 -0.0837

(-0.66) (-0.24) (-0.24) (0.56) (-0.75) (-0.65)

FF 48 FE Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes

QTR FE Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes

Constant -0.0219 -0.0242*** -0.0234** -0.0419* -0.0962 0.1325

(-1.59) (-2.77) (-2.00) (-1.75) (-1.45) (0.77)

Observations 3,373 3,373 3,373 3,368 3,331 2,635

Adjusted R2 0.077 0.097 0.091 0.087 0.075 0.111

Page 75: Activist Short-Selling - University of Toronto T-Space · Activist short-selling – short-sellers publicly talking down securities to benefit their short positions – attracts attentions

66

Table A5: Results are Consistent in Different Time Periods

This table shows that the key inferences hold in different sample periods. Panel A tabulates determinant results each year from 2006 to 2015; Panel B reports return

consequence results using years prior to 2012; Panel C reports return consequence results using years after 2013 (note earlier years have fewer firms targeted by

activist short-sellers.)

Panel A: Determinant test

DV = Target (1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6) (7) (8) (9) (10)

2006 2007 2008 2009 2010 2011 2012 2013 2014 2015

Overvaluation 2.7037*** 3.1853*** 2.9567*** 2.8194*** 2.8474*** 2.9033*** 3.0972*** 1.8111*** 2.5188*** 1.7388***

(5.23) (6.37) (5.77) (5.51) (5.66) (6.34) (8.48) (7.26) (9.35) (4.33)

Uncertainty 1.3294* 1.2298* 0.5503 0.2021 1.9401*** 2.2108*** 1.1808*** 0.8107*** 0.9925*** 0.6124

(1.70) (1.65) (0.71) (0.19) (3.33) (4.62) (2.61) (2.82) (3.64) (1.33)

Size 0.4046*** 0.3139*** 0.4018*** 0.3454*** 0.2223*** 0.2504*** 0.2248*** -0.0892** 0.0237 0.0733

(5.46) (3.96) (6.42) (4.59) (2.88) (3.69) (3.64) (-2.08) (0.50) (1.54)

Leverage -0.9332 -0.5517 0.4559 0.1955 -1.4401*** -1.3177*** -0.6708** 0.1673 0.1570 0.1773

(-1.47) (-1.15) (1.08) (0.39) (-3.00) (-3.28) (-1.96) (0.92) (0.77) (0.75)

Illiquidity -1.6046 -14.3867 -2.2347 -2.6260 -3.8858 -1.9363** -1.7580*** -1.6579*** -1.4186*** -1.3925***

(-1.47) (-1.58) (-0.97) (-0.88) (-1.26) (-2.53) (-2.95) (-4.46) (-2.87) (-3.81)

Volatility 43.7564*** 29.2849*** 4.0020 10.1460*** 20.2885*** 16.3969*** 25.8508*** 19.3989*** 18.6050*** 18.9834***

(5.13) (4.66) (1.15) (2.62) (2.82) (2.79) (6.06) (7.01) (6.38) (5.89)

LnAnalyst 0.4846*** 0.6941*** 0.5623*** 0.6209*** 0.3717*** 0.3775*** 0.2273** 0.3626*** 0.2716*** 0.4001***

(2.71) (4.99) (4.18) (3.82) (3.37) (3.13) (2.23) (5.03) (3.81) (5.15)

ShortInterest 2.8802*** 2.4476*** 2.2287*** 3.3029*** 3.5579*** 3.8716*** 3.4514*** 3.7828*** 3.6372*** 3.1547***

(4.74) (5.29) (4.75) (4.31) (6.41) (6.36) (6.68) (7.01) (8.25) (6.13)

FF 48 FE YES YES YES YES YES YES YES YES YES YES

QTR FE YES YES YES YES YES YES YES YES YES YES

Constant -21.4790*** -23.9080 -22.3262*** -8.3393*** -19.8827*** -6.0738*** -19.4499*** -4.5231*** -4.8707*** -18.5515***

(-27.63) (-27.36) (-27.46) (-6.47) (-25.53) (-5.64) (-36.81) (-5.32) (-4.70) (-35.01)

Observations 16,039 16,301 17,024 16,594 16,493 16,441 16,408 16,706 17,300 13,376

Pseudo R2 0.146 0.205 0.208 0.197 0.149 0.158 0.158 0.114 0.123 0.107

Page 76: Activist Short-Selling - University of Toronto T-Space · Activist short-selling – short-sellers publicly talking down securities to benefit their short positions – attracts attentions

67

Panel B: Return consequences prior to year 2012

Pre 2012: (1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6)

AR(0) CAR(0,1) CAR(0,2) CAR

(1Week)

CAR

(1Month)

CAR

(1Year)

Overvaluation 0.0065 -0.0083 -0.0258** -0.0470*** -0.1137*** -0.8269***

(0.79) (-0.84) (-2.33) (-3.37) (-3.46) (-3.91)

Uncertainty -0.0321*** -0.0434*** -0.0320* -0.0538** -0.0883* -0.2893

(-2.69) (-2.84) (-1.84) (-2.30) (-1.84) (-1.19)

Size 0.0015 0.0033** 0.0032** 0.0033* 0.0063 0.0501**

(1.51) (2.50) (2.14) (1.76) (1.47) (2.14)

Leverage 0.0120* 0.0036 0.0038 -0.0017 0.0096 -0.1067

(1.73) (0.40) (0.38) (-0.13) (0.36) (-0.70)

Illiquidity -0.0195 -0.0174 0.0030 0.0297 -0.0197 0.1909

(-0.64) (-0.76) (0.10) (1.13) (-0.29) (0.58)

Volatility -0.0330 -0.2193 -0.2465 -0.3496 0.1337 -2.3137

(-0.33) (-1.52) (-1.38) (-1.61) (0.19) (-0.65)

LnAnalyst 0.0063*** 0.0081*** 0.0109*** 0.0123*** 0.0298*** 0.1094**

(2.93) (2.90) (3.40) (3.26) (3.32) (2.27)

ShortInterest 0.0036 0.0078 0.0121 0.0020 0.0282 0.4056**

(0.46) (0.66) (0.96) (0.12) (0.85) (2.17)

EarnAnnounce[-5,0] 0.0079 0.0104 0.0113 0.0136 -0.0042 -0.0669

(1.30) (1.44) (1.43) (1.47) (-0.24) (-0.72)

AnForecast[-5,0] -0.0004 -0.0029 -0.0021 -0.0031 -0.0095 -0.0462

(-0.13) (-0.73) (-0.47) (-0.55) (-0.86) (-0.84)

ConfCall[-5,0] 0.0013 0.0039 0.0025 -0.0010 0.0088 0.0867

(0.15) (0.32) (0.21) (-0.08) (0.33) (0.72)

FF 48 FE Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes

QTR FE Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes

Constant -0.0317** -0.0364*** -0.0376*** -0.0470* -0.1256* -0.2892

(-2.11) (-3.08) (-2.68) (-1.93) (-1.67) (-1.07)

Observations 2,009 2,009 2,009 2,009 2,009 2,009

Adjusted R2 0.094 0.105 0.094 0.089 0.100 0.191

Page 77: Activist Short-Selling - University of Toronto T-Space · Activist short-selling – short-sellers publicly talking down securities to benefit their short positions – attracts attentions

68

Panel C: Return consequences after year 2013

Post 2013 (1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6)

AR(0) CAR(0,1) CAR(0,2) CAR

(1Week)

CAR

(1Month)

CAR

(1Year)

Overvaluation -0.0123* -0.0130* -0.0232*** -0.0312*** -0.0855*** -0.7042***

(-1.87) (-1.70) (-2.85) (-3.02) (-4.07) (-3.54)

Uncertainty -0.0445*** -0.0507*** -0.0559*** -0.0605*** -0.0773** 0.0446

(-4.68) (-4.44) (-3.21) (-2.79) (-2.51) (0.14)

Size 0.0014* 0.0024** 0.0017 0.0019 0.0050 0.1002***

(1.73) (2.30) (1.42) (1.18) (1.58) (3.11)

Leverage 0.0025 0.0001 -0.0025 0.0004 0.0159 0.0611

(0.49) (0.02) (-0.32) (0.04) (0.84) (0.32)

Illiquidity -0.0063 -0.0211 -0.0279 -0.0328 -0.0010 -0.2353

(-0.55) (-1.46) (-1.61) (-1.54) (-0.02) (-0.65)

Volatility 0.0395 -0.1471 -0.1699 -0.3611* -1.3410*** -15.7544***

(0.42) (-1.10) (-1.10) (-1.66) (-2.85) (-3.41)

LnAnalyst 0.0060*** 0.0056*** 0.0074*** 0.0082*** 0.0132** -0.0759

(3.86) (2.63) (3.07) (2.67) (2.09) (-1.48)

ShortInterest 0.0086 0.0101 0.0160 0.0330** 0.0518 0.0278

(1.13) (1.07) (1.53) (2.40) (1.42) (0.09)

EarnAnnounce[-5,0] 0.0041 -0.0042 -0.0036 -0.0034 -0.0053 0.1347*

(0.95) (-0.72) (-0.50) (-0.44) (-0.54) (1.67)

AnForecast[-5,0] -0.0045* -0.0029 -0.0018 -0.0056 -0.0023 -0.0807

(-1.94) (-0.97) (-0.47) (-1.12) (-0.27) (-1.31)

ConfCall[-5,0] -0.0079 0.0215 0.0665 0.0703 0.1076 0.3517

(-0.67) (0.77) (0.98) (0.95) (0.61) (0.32)

FF 48 FE Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes

QTR FE Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes

Constant -0.0902*** -0.0763*** -0.0682*** -0.0641*** -0.0316 0.4885

(-8.19) (-5.16) (-3.88) (-2.64) (-0.63) (1.19)

Observations 3,693 3,692 3,690 3,685 3,620 2,465

Adjusted R2 0.062 0.079 0.078 0.081 0.094 0.246

Page 78: Activist Short-Selling - University of Toronto T-Space · Activist short-selling – short-sellers publicly talking down securities to benefit their short positions – attracts attentions

69

Table A6: Using decile ranks rather than top-quintile

This table uses overvaluation and uncertainty features that are constructed as decile ranks (rather than indicators based on top quintiles). Panel A reports results on

individual overvaluation features. Panel B reports results on individual uncertainty features.

Panel A: Individual overvaluation features

DV=Target (1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6) (7) (8) (9) (10) (11) (12)

Overvaluation

Features =

Price

Runup

P/B P/V Low

Gross Profit

Asset

Growth

Investment NOA Accruals Low

Payout%

OScore MScore Low

Earnings

Overvaluation 0.2898*** 1.1159*** 1.0154*** 0.0147 0.5868*** 0.2299* -0.0750 -0.2964*** 0.5622*** 0.0691 0.2661*** 0.1267

Features (3.95) (9.93) (8.04) (0.10) (5.74) (1.88) (-0.66) (-2.69) (5.06) (0.47) (2.97) (1.18)

Size 0.0202 0.0958*** 0.0739** 0.0355 0.0406 0.0601* 0.0199 0.0581* 0.0679** 0.0234 0.0125 0.0226

(0.71) (3.21) (1.99) (1.14) (1.34) (1.67) (0.70) (1.88) (2.11) (0.76) (0.41) (0.79) Leverage -0.1627 -0.2327 -0.2982* -0.0731 0.0486 -0.1430 -0.2139 -0.1234 -0.0759 -0.2341 -0.1923 -0.1997

(-1.22) (-1.54) (-1.84) (-0.52) (0.34) (-0.89) (-1.53) (-0.86) (-0.53) (-1.30) (-1.35) (-1.53)

Illiquidity -1.8373*** -1.6422*** -1.7190*** -1.7298*** -1.6429*** -1.5843*** -1.9141*** -1.7488*** -1.6371*** -1.9139*** -2.0326*** -1.9168*** (-7.55) (-7.43) (-5.88) (-6.80) (-6.59) (-5.92) (-7.66) (-6.47) (-6.39) (-7.65) (-6.70) (-7.62)

Volatility 25.9950*** 28.0915*** 24.9219*** 23.8982*** 24.5813*** 23.9133*** 25.1419*** 23.6466*** 21.8840*** 24.9587*** 26.4485*** 24.5520***

(19.96) (21.42) (15.63) (17.13) (17.74) (15.12) (20.02) (16.80) (15.83) (19.72) (19.43) (18.79) LnAnalyst 0.3921*** 0.2379*** 0.2577*** 0.4011*** 0.3901*** 0.4056*** 0.3842*** 0.3959*** 0.4009*** 0.3864*** 0.3811*** 0.3873***

(8.45) (5.49) (4.36) (7.92) (8.01) (6.78) (8.45) (7.74) (7.88) (8.41) (7.53) (8.43)

ShortInterest 3.3986*** 3.5437*** 3.7296*** 3.5068*** 3.4294*** 3.8147*** 3.3734*** 3.6329*** 3.5393*** 3.3754*** 3.3819*** 3.3849*** (15.52) (16.89) (13.40) (15.43) (14.88) (12.53) (15.26) (13.86) (15.65) (15.27) (14.62) (15.37)

FF 48 FE YES YES YES YES YES YES YES YES YES YES YES YES

QTR FE YES YES YES YES YES YES YES YES YES YES YES YES Constant -8.1955*** -9.1609*** -10.841*** -8.0927*** -8.5133*** -7.6678*** -7.9444*** -8.2962*** -8.5070*** -8.0270*** -8.2905*** -8.0480***

(-13.56) (-14.85) (-9.97) (-13.69) (-14.12) (-12.90) (-13.32) (-12.54) (-14.06) (-13.28) (-12.56) (-13.36)

Observations 181,055 181,767 124,131 168,916 169,766 134,498 181,426 165,225 167,160 181,426 164,618 181,399 Pseudo R2 0.144 0.152 0.162 0.142 0.146 0.151 0.143 0.144 0.144 0.143 0.147 0.143

Page 79: Activist Short-Selling - University of Toronto T-Space · Activist short-selling – short-sellers publicly talking down securities to benefit their short positions – attracts attentions

70

Panel B: Individual uncertainty features

DV=Target (1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6) (7) (8) (9)

Uncertainty

Features =

Low

InstOwn

Non

Block

Low

Dedicated

Low

AccQuality

Analyst

Disagree

NonBig4 Audit

Switch

ICW BidAskSpread

Uncertainty 0.3502*** 0.5426*** 0.1465 0.7145*** -0.1247 0.3952*** 0.3656*** 0.3647*** 1.1915***

Features (5.03) (5.63) (1.27) (5.00) (-1.14) (4.82) (3.48) (3.57) (9.04)

Size 0.0062 0.0124 0.0250 0.1262*** 0.0576* 0.0329 0.0211 0.0224 0.0982***

(0.23) (0.45) (0.87) (3.00) (1.72) (1.09) (0.69) (0.74) (3.06)

Leverage -0.1450 -0.1724 -0.1838 -0.4925** -0.1090 -0.1063 -0.0432 -0.0515 -0.2668**

(-1.12) (-1.32) (-1.39) (-2.17) (-0.72) (-0.80) (-0.31) (-0.36) (-2.00)

Illiquidity -1.9655*** -2.0045*** -1.9198*** -1.7181*** -3.7774*** -2.1292*** -1.7832*** -1.7875*** -1.8166***

(-7.68) (-7.59) (-7.63) (-5.20) (-3.63) (-7.27) (-6.55) (-6.56) (-7.11)

Volatility 24.7225*** 23.5767*** 25.0088*** 26.4366*** 28.2667*** 24.7304*** 23.3148*** 23.0639*** 16.2624***

(19.62) (18.74) (19.99) (13.27) (17.82) (18.92) (16.53) (16.21) (11.80)

LnAnalyst 0.4263*** 0.4578*** 0.4004*** 0.3924*** 0.5170*** 0.4141*** 0.4176*** 0.4189*** 0.4013***

(9.22) (9.52) (8.56) (6.36) (6.68) (8.46) (8.07) (8.11) (8.67)

ShortInterest 3.3607*** 3.4610*** 3.3671*** 3.5628*** 3.3092*** 3.4142*** 3.5149*** 3.5225*** 3.2714***

(14.75) (14.88) (15.32) (11.00) (13.63) (15.21) (14.98) (15.18) (14.71)

FF 48 FE YES YES YES YES YES YES YES YES YES

QTR FE YES YES YES YES YES YES YES YES YES

Constant -8.0200*** -8.2836*** -8.1153*** -9.0499*** -8.6273*** -8.1464*** -8.1348*** -8.1396*** -8.8326***

(-13.58) (-13.87) (-13.57) (-12.28) (-12.70) (-13.38) (-13.42) (-13.51) (-14.51)

Observations 181,767 181,767 181,767 108,724 119,398 171,416 161,381 161,381 181,748

Pseudo R2 0.144 0.145 0.143 0.155 0.132 0.144 0.142 0.142 0.147

Page 80: Activist Short-Selling - University of Toronto T-Space · Activist short-selling – short-sellers publicly talking down securities to benefit their short positions – attracts attentions

71

Table A7: An Alternative Way of Aggregating Individual Features: Using All Individual

Features

This table reports results based on aggregate overvaluation and uncertainty measures (i.e., Overvaluation_All and

Uncertainty_All) that average all individual features (rather than only those surviving the step-wise regressions in the

main analyses). Specifically, Panel A reports the results of determinant test and Panel B reports the results of the return

consequence test.

Panel A: Determinant test

(1) (2) (3)

Target Target by SA Target by ASR

Overvaluation_All 2.5340*** 2.5121*** 2.5707***

(12.25) (11.59) (8.58)

Uncertainty_All 1.1499*** 1.1481*** 1.1780***

(5.94) (5.73) (3.99)

Size 0.1074*** 0.1139*** -0.1140**

(3.69) (3.84) (-2.48)

Leverage -0.3394*** -0.2579** -0.6932***

(-2.64) (-1.98) (-3.21)

Illiquidity -1.8439*** -1.7212*** -3.5408***

(-7.20) (-6.89) (-4.60)

Volatility 18.3106*** 19.0635*** 9.9757***

(13.80) (14.14) (3.94)

LnAnalyst 0.3887*** 0.4080*** 0.0246

(8.93) (8.87) (0.42)

ShortInterest 3.1884*** 3.0864*** 3.7486***

(14.44) (13.86) (13.54)

FF 48 FE Yes Yes Yes

QTR FE Yes Yes Yes

Constant -9.0083*** -10.0140*** -7.2495***

(-14.84) (-12.94) (-7.82)

Observations 181,767 181,767 175,991

Pseudo R2 0.158 0.161 0.148

Page 81: Activist Short-Selling - University of Toronto T-Space · Activist short-selling – short-sellers publicly talking down securities to benefit their short positions – attracts attentions

72

Panel B: Return consequence test

(1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6)

AR(0) CAR(0,1) CAR(0,2) CAR

(1Week)

CAR

(1Month)

CAR

(1Year)

Overvaluation_All -0.0074 -0.0136* -0.0280*** -0.0430*** -0.0880*** -0.8673***

(-1.25) (-1.74) (-3.27) (-3.75) (-3.72) (-4.33)

Uncertainty_All -0.0423*** -0.0471*** -0.0471*** -0.0549*** -0.0554** 0.0014

(-5.02) (-4.75) (-3.60) (-3.33) (-2.01) (0.01)

Size 0.0017*** 0.0029*** 0.0027*** 0.0029** 0.0076*** 0.0780***

(2.63) (3.40) (2.83) (2.28) (2.92) (3.27)

Leverage 0.0062 0.0038 0.0029 0.0053 0.0226 0.0464

(1.48) (0.74) (0.47) (0.62) (1.33) (0.27)

Illiquidity -0.0103 -0.0194 -0.0175 -0.0136 -0.0087 0.0342

(-0.77) (-1.61) (-1.11) (-0.73) (-0.23) (0.13)

Volatility 0.0106 -0.1567 -0.1470 -0.2706* -0.7249* -10.4125***

(0.16) (-1.63) (-1.29) (-1.80) (-1.79) (-3.21)

LnAnalyst 0.0065*** 0.0073*** 0.0090*** 0.0099*** 0.0191*** 0.0094

(5.20) (4.34) (4.63) (4.09) (3.64) (0.23)

ShortInterest 0.0053 0.0085 0.0120* 0.0206** 0.0417* 0.3108

(1.03) (1.21) (1.67) (2.13) (1.71) (1.43)

EarnAnnounce[-5,0] 0.0047 0.0000 0.0009 0.0019 -0.0053 0.0411

(1.31) (0.01) (0.15) (0.28) (-0.60) (0.66)

AnForecast[-5,0] -0.0026 -0.0028 -0.0021 -0.0054 -0.0050 -0.0708*

(-1.36) (-1.14) (-0.71) (-1.39) (-0.76) (-1.66)

ConfCall[-5,0] 0.0036 0.0133 0.0142 0.0116 0.0086 0.0285

(0.48) (1.22) (1.25) (0.93) (0.36) (0.26)

FF 48 FE Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes

QTR FE Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes

Constant -0.0255* -0.0316*** -0.0304*** -0.0510** -0.1186* -0.1425

(-1.84) (-3.75) (-2.99) (-2.34) (-1.85) (-0.61)

Observations 5,702 5,701 5,699 5,694 5,629 4,474

Adjusted R2 0.072 0.088 0.081 0.079 0.082 0.174

Page 82: Activist Short-Selling - University of Toronto T-Space · Activist short-selling – short-sellers publicly talking down securities to benefit their short positions – attracts attentions

73

Table A8: Alternative Risk Adjustment

This table presents results using abnormal returns based on the Fama–French three-factor plus momentum model

rather than Fama-French three-factor model used in the main analyses.

(1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6)

AR(0) CAR(0,1) CAR(0,2) CAR

(1Week)

CAR

(1Month)

CAR

(1Year)

Overvaluation -0.0056 -0.0103* -0.0233*** -0.0359*** -0.1032*** -0.9198***

(-1.11) (-1.71) (-3.64) (-4.45) (-5.61) (-6.06)

Uncertainty -0.0414*** -0.0471*** -0.0461*** -0.0544*** -0.0746*** -0.1054

(-5.64) (-5.43) (-3.71) (-3.46) (-3.04) (-0.48)

Size 0.0017*** 0.0030*** 0.0028*** 0.0029** 0.0063** 0.0690***

(2.63) (3.67) (3.04) (2.41) (2.57) (2.93)

Leverage 0.0046 0.0015 -0.0008 0.0016 0.0169 -0.0376

(1.12) (0.30) (-0.13) (0.20) (1.09) (-0.21)

Illiquidity -0.0090 -0.0197 -0.0189 -0.0138 -0.0120 -0.0618

(-0.66) (-1.61) (-1.18) (-0.73) (-0.30) (-0.23)

Volatility 0.0097 -0.1430 -0.1451 -0.2870** -0.7290* -10.8153***

(0.15) (-1.50) (-1.34) (-1.96) (-1.94) (-3.39)

LnAnalyst 0.0059*** 0.0064*** 0.0085*** 0.0095*** 0.0200*** 0.0278

(4.61) (3.82) (4.46) (4.05) (3.91) (0.70)

ShortInterest 0.0054 0.0084 0.0110 0.0203** 0.0410* 0.3525

(1.07) (1.25) (1.61) (2.11) (1.70) (1.55)

EarnAnnounce[-5,0] 0.0051 0.0004 0.0012 0.0016 -0.0076 0.0411

(1.43) (0.09) (0.20) (0.23) (-0.87) (0.68)

AnForecast[-5,0] -0.0029 -0.0030 -0.0021 -0.0050 -0.0046 -0.0596

(-1.50) (-1.22) (-0.71) (-1.31) (-0.69) (-1.42)

ConfCall[-5,0] 0.0033 0.0146 0.0170 0.0159 0.0213 0.0092

(0.44) (1.34) (1.52) (1.29) (0.87) (0.07)

FF 48 FE Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes

QTR FE Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes

Constant -0.0239* -0.0282*** -0.0271*** -0.0457** -0.0850 0.0622

(-1.71) (-3.48) (-2.99) (-2.24) (-1.20) (0.23)

Observations 5,702 5,701 5,699 5,694 5,629 4,474

Adjusted R2 0.075 0.090 0.085 0.083 0.089 0.180

Page 83: Activist Short-Selling - University of Toronto T-Space · Activist short-selling – short-sellers publicly talking down securities to benefit their short positions – attracts attentions

74

Table A9: Two-way Clustering

This table reports t-stats based on standard errors that are clustered by both firm and quarter (rather than by only firm - it is technically challenging to conduct two-

way clustering in step-wise regressions). Panel A reports determinant-test results on individual overvaluation features. Panel B reports determinant-test results on

individual uncertainty features. Panel C reports results of the return consequence test.

Panel A: Determinants test based on individual overvaluation features

DV=Target (1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6) (7) (8) (9) (10) (11) (12)

Overvaluation

Features =

Price

Runup

P/B P/V Low

Gross

Profit

Asset

Growth

Investment NOA Accruals Low

Payout%

OScore MScore Low

Earnings

Overvaluation 0.354*** 0.781*** 0.666*** 0.147 0.452*** 0.166** 0.125* -0.026 0.203*** 0.258*** 0.407*** 0.389*** Features (7.46) (9.67) (9.35) (1.64) (6.31) (2.34) (1.70) (-0.35) (3.43) (3.71) (6.88) (5.23) Size 0.023 0.087** 0.037 0.018 0.029 0.023 0.019 0.019 0.023 0.037 0.029 0.043 (0.60) (2.18) (0.99) (0.47) (0.75) (0.60) (0.50) (0.48) (0.59) (0.94) (0.75) (1.10) Leverage -0.184 -0.396** -0.202 -0.183 -0.138 -0.169 -0.127 -0.178 -0.184 -0.372** -0.148 -0.242* (-1.28) (-2.46) (-1.39) (-1.27) (-0.97) (-1.18) (-0.90) (-1.25) (-1.28) (-2.27) (-1.05) (-1.68) Illiquidity -1.822*** -1.738*** -1.819*** -1.907*** -1.815*** -1.905*** -1.903*** -1.909*** -1.893*** -1.935*** -1.861*** -1.919*** (-7.77) (-7.74) (-7.51) (-7.68) (-7.72) (-7.68) (-7.71) (-7.68) (-7.68) (-7.66) (-7.68) (-7.55) Volatility 25.125*** 26.822*** 23.887*** 24.694*** 25.088*** 25.163*** 25.025*** 25.149*** 24.413*** 24.268*** 24.738*** 23.030*** (14.01) (14.75) (12.70) (13.03) (13.40) (13.15) (13.22) (13.16) (13.30) (12.82) (13.00) (12.30) LnAnalyst 0.393*** 0.277*** 0.344*** 0.393*** 0.368*** 0.380*** 0.392*** 0.388*** 0.391*** 0.389*** 0.391*** 0.382*** (8.03) (5.85) (7.23) (8.06) (7.75) (7.82) (8.01) (7.89) (7.97) (7.97) (7.96) (7.84) ShortInterest 3.336*** 3.308*** 3.298*** 3.360*** 3.220*** 3.345*** 3.363*** 3.361*** 3.344*** 3.346*** 3.300*** 3.364***

(14.31) (14.28) (14.48) (14.44) (13.76) (14.36) (14.45) (14.37) (14.38) (14.32) (14.03) (14.46) FF 48 FE YES YES YES YES YES YES YES YES YES YES YES YES

QTR FE YES YES YES YES YES YES YES YES YES YES YES YES

Constant -8.131*** -8.566*** -8.111*** -8.010*** -8.163*** -8.040*** -8.058*** -7.996*** -8.037*** -8.057*** -8.160*** -8.123***

(-17.27) (-19.15) (-17.50) (-17.55) (-17.37) (-17.64) (-17.76) (-17.48) (-17.61) (-17.73) (-17.80) (-17.80)

Observations 181,767 181,767 181,767 181,767 181,767 181,767 181,767 181,767 181,767 181,767 181,767 181,767

Pseudo R2 0.145 0.154 0.149 0.143 0.146 0.143 0.143 0.143 0.144 0.144 0.145 0.145

Page 84: Activist Short-Selling - University of Toronto T-Space · Activist short-selling – short-sellers publicly talking down securities to benefit their short positions – attracts attentions

75

Panel B: Determinants test based on individual uncertainty features

DV=Target (1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6) (7) (8) (9)

Uncertainty

Features =

Low

InstOwn

Non

Block

Low

Dedicated

Low

AccQuality

Analyst

Disagree

NonBig4 Audit

Switch

ICW BidAskSpread

Uncertainty 0.1683** 0.3502*** 0.2395*** 0.2567*** -0.0270 0.3913*** 0.2879** 0.3790*** 0.2554***

Features (2.26) (4.53) (3.29) (3.52) (-0.39) (4.87) (2.32) (4.18) (3.99)

Size 0.0155 0.0062 0.0215 0.0265 0.0182 0.0437 0.0198 0.0209 0.0267

(0.41) (0.17) (0.56) (0.69) (0.47) (1.10) (0.52) (0.54) (0.70)

Leverage -0.1792 -0.1450 -0.1896 -0.1823 -0.1702 -0.1594 -0.1780 -0.1860 -0.1984

(-1.24) (-1.04) (-1.31) (-1.26) (-1.19) (-1.12) (-1.24) (-1.29) (-1.38)

Illiquidity -1.9437*** -1.9655*** -1.9864*** -1.9206*** -1.9143*** -2.0243*** -1.9160*** -1.9228*** -1.9592***

(-7.72) (-7.76) (-7.63) (-7.69) (-7.81) (-7.73) (-7.67) (-7.69) (-7.60)

Volatility 24.6971*** 24.7225*** 24.6263*** 24.8857*** 25.3041*** 25.1617*** 25.1147*** 24.8520*** 22.6003***

(12.88) (13.22) (13.25) (12.97) (13.15) (13.23) (13.19) (13.19) (12.12)

LnAnalyst 0.4028*** 0.4263*** 0.4055*** 0.3889*** 0.3898*** 0.4100*** 0.3928*** 0.3958*** 0.3982***

(8.03) (8.91) (8.22) (7.97) (7.83) (8.25) (8.01) (8.09) (8.04)

ShortInterest 3.3694*** 3.3607*** 3.3981*** 3.3624*** 3.3607*** 3.3728*** 3.3456*** 3.3498*** 3.3651***

(14.38) (13.99) (14.59) (14.48) (14.39) (14.64) (14.30) (14.45) (14.40)

FF 48 FE YES YES YES YES YES YES YES YES YES

QTR FE YES YES YES YES YES YES YES YES YES

Constant -8.0300*** -8.0200*** -8.0907*** -8.0488*** -8.0039*** -8.2710*** -8.0429*** -8.0814*** -8.0323***

(-17.68) (-18.05) (-17.84) (-17.70) (-17.59) (-18.27) (-17.49) (-17.76) (-17.76)

Observations 181,767 181,767 181,767 181,767 181,767 181,767 181,767 181,767 181,767

Pseudo R2 0.143 0.144 0.144 0.144 0.143 0.145 0.143 0.144 0.143

Page 85: Activist Short-Selling - University of Toronto T-Space · Activist short-selling – short-sellers publicly talking down securities to benefit their short positions – attracts attentions

76

Panel C: Return consequence test

(1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6)

AR(0) CAR(0,1) CAR(0,2) CAR

(1Week)

CAR

(1Month)

CAR

(1Year)

Overvaluation -0.0059 -0.0113* -0.0237*** -0.0354*** -0.1000*** -0.8863***

(-0.96) (-1.65) (-3.87) (-4.22) (-5.53) (-5.68)

Uncertainty -0.0417*** -0.0481*** -0.0469*** -0.0557*** -0.0774*** -0.1030

(-7.04) (-5.53) (-4.03) (-4.30) (-3.69) (-0.68)

Size 0.0016*** 0.0027*** 0.0026*** 0.0028** 0.0064*** 0.0727***

(2.94) (2.79) (2.73) (2.18) (3.22) (3.79)

Leverage 0.0045 0.0014 -0.0009 -0.0000 0.0112 -0.0528

(1.20) (0.30) (-0.18) (-0.00) (0.62) (-0.33)

Illiquidity -0.0094 -0.0184* -0.0169 -0.0129 -0.0094 0.0090

(-0.74) (-1.76) (-1.09) (-0.70) (-0.23) (0.04)

Volatility 0.0081 -0.1568* -0.1559 -0.2835* -0.6668 -10.3406***

(0.12) (-1.71) (-1.27) (-1.73) (-1.38) (-2.85)

LnAnalyst 0.0060*** 0.0067*** 0.0086*** 0.0096*** 0.0199*** 0.0280

(5.37) (3.45) (3.69) (2.93) (3.82) (0.68)

ShortInterest 0.0053 0.0083** 0.0118*** 0.0202*** 0.0401** 0.3076

(1.56) (1.97) (2.96) (2.98) (2.25) (1.37)

EarnAnnounce[-5,0] 0.0047 0.0000 0.0008 0.0018 -0.0055 0.0393

(1.44) (0.00) (0.16) (0.31) (-0.70) (0.81)

AnForecast[-5,0] -0.0026* -0.0028 -0.0020 -0.0053 -0.0048 -0.0666**

(-1.65) (-1.42) (-0.83) (-1.47) (-0.75) (-2.01)

ConfCall[-5,0] 0.0040 0.0138 0.0149 0.0124 0.0108 0.0385

(0.50) (1.16) (1.12) (0.91) (0.44) (0.37)

FF 48 FE Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes

QTR FE Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes

Constant -0.0441 -0.0204 -0.0200 -0.0686 -0.1958 -0.0978

(-1.16) (-0.98) (-0.59) (-0.99) (-1.35) (-0.31)

Observations 5,702 5,701 5,699 5,694 5,629 4,474

Adjusted R2 0.075 0.091 0.083 0.080 0.089 0.182

Page 86: Activist Short-Selling - University of Toronto T-Space · Activist short-selling – short-sellers publicly talking down securities to benefit their short positions – attracts attentions

77

Table A10: Excluding Observations with Analyst Revisions, Earnings Announcements, or

Conference Calls in the Previous Five Days

This table only uses these activist short-selling cases of which there are no analyst revisions, earnings announcements,

or conference calls in the five days prior to the activist short-selling date. The purpose is to (partially) address one

alternative explanation that the results can be driven by other informational events that coincide with activist short-

selling.

(1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6)

AR(0) CAR(0,1) CAR(0,2) CAR

(1Week) CAR

(1Month) CAR

(1Year)

Overvaluation -0.0064 -0.0174** -0.0315*** -0.0461*** -0.0891*** -0.8655***

(-0.92) (-2.13) (-3.55) (-4.33) (-3.79) (-5.10)

Uncertainty -0.0550*** -0.0608*** -0.0601*** -0.0654*** -0.1081*** -0.2394

(-6.18) (-5.63) (-3.97) (-3.60) (-3.69) (-1.01)

Size 0.0019** 0.0024** 0.0018 0.0013 0.0068* 0.0637**

(2.38) (2.25) (1.53) (0.88) (1.93) (2.26)

Leverage 0.0071 0.0029 0.0006 -0.0001 0.0103 -0.0493

(1.34) (0.44) (0.08) (-0.01) (0.47) (-0.25)

Illiquidity 0.0057 -0.0076 -0.0120 -0.0169 -0.0013 -0.0788

(0.58) (-0.62) (-0.67) (-0.78) (-0.03) (-0.24)

Volatility 0.0293 -0.2070 -0.2089 -0.4220** -0.7857 -10.8708***

(0.32) (-1.59) (-1.37) (-2.14) (-1.54) (-3.16)

LnAnalyst 0.0049*** 0.0065*** 0.0094*** 0.0100*** 0.0157** 0.0204

(3.21) (3.31) (4.29) (3.66) (2.53) (0.47)

ShortInterest 0.0058 0.0070 0.0093 0.0204* 0.0266 0.0833

(0.85) (0.59) (0.92) (1.71) (0.98) (0.41)

FF 48 FE YES YES YES YES YES YES

QTR FE YES YES YES YES YES YES

Constant -0.0239 -0.0237** -0.0214* -0.0428* -0.0911 0.2022

(-1.34) (-2.19) (-1.78) (-1.72) (-1.15) (0.88)

Observations 3,271 3,270 3,268 3,263 3,229 2,576

Adjusted R2 0.095 0.115 0.102 0.095 0.088 0.182

Page 87: Activist Short-Selling - University of Toronto T-Space · Activist short-selling – short-sellers publicly talking down securities to benefit their short positions – attracts attentions

78

Table A11: Control for Short-Seller Fixed Effects

This table presents results controlling for short-seller fixed effects. The purpose of doing so is to show that target-firm

characteristics are important conditional on the short-seller characteristics.

(1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6)

AR(0) CAR(0,1) CAR(0,2) CAR

(1Week)

CAR

(1Month)

CAR

(1Year)

Overvaluation -0.0065 -0.0145* -0.0250*** -0.0362*** -0.0685*** -0.4855***

(-0.87) (-1.70) (-2.77) (-3.27) (-2.87) (-2.65)

Uncertainty -0.0343*** -0.0437*** -0.0338** -0.0440*** -0.0974*** -0.1097

(-4.01) (-4.10) (-2.48) (-2.65) (-3.17) (-0.46)

Size 0.0017* 0.0037*** 0.0040*** 0.0046*** 0.0119*** 0.1387***

(1.94) (3.31) (3.24) (2.70) (3.37) (4.29)

Leverage -0.0027 -0.0048 -0.0094 -0.0037 -0.0155 -0.0959

(-0.51) (-0.80) (-1.36) (-0.39) (-0.76) (-0.46)

Illiquidity -0.0129 -0.0220 -0.0159 -0.0066 0.0029 0.2248

(-0.78) (-1.36) (-0.81) (-0.31) (0.07) (0.83)

Volatility 0.0282 -0.1087 -0.1301 -0.3481** -0.9118* -11.3919***

(0.33) (-0.97) (-0.95) (-1.98) (-1.93) (-3.27)

LnAnalyst 0.0051*** 0.0055** 0.0085*** 0.0093*** 0.0117* -0.0173

(2.97) (2.42) (3.51) (3.09) (1.81) (-0.36)

ShortInterest 0.0148* 0.0192** 0.0251** 0.0371*** 0.0619** 0.4839**

(1.84) (2.02) (2.42) (2.74) (2.10) (2.27)

EarnAnnounce[-5,0] 0.0031 -0.0032 -0.0025 -0.0002 -0.0023 0.0272

(0.72) (-0.53) (-0.34) (-0.03) (-0.23) (0.42)

AnForecast[-5,0] -0.0020 -0.0018 -0.0007 -0.0032 -0.0030 -0.0337

(-0.87) (-0.60) (-0.20) (-0.68) (-0.38) (-0.77)

ConfCall[-5,0] 0.0026 0.0120 0.0113 0.0067 0.0240 -0.0598

(0.29) (0.89) (0.82) (0.44) (0.89) (-0.41)

FF 48 FE Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes

QTR FE Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes

Short-Seller FE Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes

Constant -0.0235 0.0006 -0.0168 -0.0803 -0.1567 -0.0317

(-0.44) (0.02) (-0.32) (-0.80) (-0.73) (-0.07)

Observations 5,697 5,696 5,694 5,689 5,624 4,469

Adjusted R2 0.068 0.099 0.113 0.114 0.154 0.301

Page 88: Activist Short-Selling - University of Toronto T-Space · Activist short-selling – short-sellers publicly talking down securities to benefit their short positions – attracts attentions

79

Table A12: Non-Missing Values for All CARs

This table presents results only using observations with non-missing values of all CARs. As a result the same

observations are used in all columns.

(1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6)

AR(0) CAR(0,1) CAR(0,2) CAR

(1Week)

CAR

(1Month)

CAR

(1Year)

Overvaluation -0.0003 -0.0048 -0.0186*** -0.0315*** -0.0917*** -0.8863***

(-0.05) (-0.76) (-2.72) (-3.60) (-4.39) (-5.92)

Uncertainty -0.0425*** -0.0526*** -0.0504*** -0.0598*** -0.0743*** -0.1030

(-5.09) (-5.52) (-3.57) (-3.32) (-2.87) (-0.48)

Size 0.0016** 0.0025*** 0.0025** 0.0032** 0.0071** 0.0727***

(2.31) (2.88) (2.51) (2.34) (2.41) (3.10)

Leverage 0.0038 -0.0009 -0.0046 -0.0074 -0.0001 -0.0528

(0.89) (-0.18) (-0.76) (-0.80) (-0.01) (-0.31)

Illiquidity -0.0098 -0.0229* -0.0181 -0.0217 -0.0005 0.0090

(-0.65) (-1.71) (-1.03) (-1.03) (-0.01) (0.03)

Volatility 0.0088 -0.1826* -0.1899 -0.3945** -0.6948 -10.3406***

(0.12) (-1.74) (-1.54) (-2.49) (-1.55) (-3.27)

LnAnalyst 0.0055*** 0.0057*** 0.0070*** 0.0066** 0.0174*** 0.0280

(3.97) (3.09) (3.40) (2.56) (3.11) (0.71)

ShortInterest 0.0041 0.0056 0.0099 0.0202* 0.0319 0.3076

(0.77) (0.75) (1.26) (1.92) (1.25) (1.41)

EarnAnnounce[-5,0] 0.0063 0.0018 0.0036 0.0049 -0.0005 0.0393

(1.59) (0.32) (0.54) (0.66) (-0.05) (0.64)

AnForecast[-5,0] -0.0014 -0.0014 -0.0007 -0.0025 -0.0080 -0.0666

(-0.67) (-0.53) (-0.24) (-0.63) (-1.02) (-1.57)

ConfCall[-5,0] 0.0016 0.0103 0.0102 0.0069 0.0088 0.0385

(0.21) (0.92) (0.86) (0.53) (0.36) (0.35)

FF 48 FE Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes

QTR FE Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes

Constant -0.0250* -0.0255*** -0.0254** -0.0424* -0.0988 -0.0633

(-1.89) (-3.05) (-2.26) (-1.78) (-1.50) (-0.28)

Observations 4,474 4,474 4,474 4,474 4,474 4,474

Adjusted R2 0.081 0.096 0.085 0.088 0.085 0.182

Page 89: Activist Short-Selling - University of Toronto T-Space · Activist short-selling – short-sellers publicly talking down securities to benefit their short positions – attracts attentions

80

Table A13: The Role of Illiquidity

This table provides additional suggestive evidence on Higher-Order Beliefs (HOB) view. I find that the sensitivity of

return to Uncertainty is stronger in the more illiquid sample than in the less illiquid sample. The Amihud illiquidity

measure captures the price impact of a certain trading volume. For illiquid stocks, an investor could only sell at a

much lower price when other investors sell the stocks. For liquid stocks, the same amount of shares sold by other

people do not matter that much. In other words, investors of illiquid stocks would more likely panic. In the presence

of activist short-selling, for high uncertainty firms, investors would put more weight on the short-seller’s signal, but

the weight would be even higher when they care more about other people’s exit.

Panel A: High illiquidity sample

(1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6)

AR(0) CAR(0,1) CAR(0,2) CAR

(1Week)

CAR

(1Month)

CAR

(1Year)

Overvaluation -0.0064 -0.0165 -0.0309*** -0.0465*** -0.0851*** -0.6943***

(-0.71) (-1.62) (-2.80) (-3.34) (-3.21) (-3.26)

Uncertainty -0.0446*** -0.0493*** -0.0462*** -0.0576*** -0.0741*** -0.1406

(-5.23) (-4.81) (-3.42) (-3.49) (-2.62) (-0.56)

Size 0.0018 0.0031** 0.0029* 0.0013 0.0088* 0.1062***

(1.60) (1.99) (1.65) (0.56) (1.93) (2.61)

Leverage 0.0030 -0.0018 -0.0076 -0.0065 0.0113 -0.0719

(0.58) (-0.27) (-0.98) (-0.63) (0.55) (-0.35)

Illiquidity -0.0092 -0.0157 -0.0124 -0.0100 0.0115 0.1206

(-0.68) (-1.24) (-0.76) (-0.52) (0.29) (0.41)

Volatility -0.0100 -0.2301* -0.2554* -0.4810*** -1.1346** -15.3534***

(-0.11) (-1.90) (-1.74) (-2.60) (-2.32) (-4.02)

LnAnalyst 0.0069*** 0.0096*** 0.0124*** 0.0141*** 0.0244*** 0.0335

(3.62) (3.76) (4.32) (3.91) (3.33) (0.65)

ShortInterest -0.0074 -0.0028 0.0028 0.0186 0.0393 0.2369

(-0.73) (-0.19) (0.18) (0.95) (1.04) (0.63)

EarnAnnounce[-5,0] 0.0099* 0.0046 0.0065 0.0048 -0.0150 -0.0480

(1.75) (0.71) (0.91) (0.58) (-0.93) (-0.48)

AnForecast[-5,0] -0.0047 -0.0040 -0.0017 -0.0052 0.0009 -0.0626

(-1.27) (-0.93) (-0.34) (-0.84) (0.08) (-0.90)

ConfCall[-5,0] -0.0127 0.0167 0.0223 0.0359 0.0558 0.1396

(-0.67) (1.05) (1.28) (1.56) (1.22) (0.52)

FF 48 FE Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes

QTR FE Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes

Constant -0.0194 -0.0284** -0.0269* -0.0528* -0.1245 0.1144

(-0.99) (-2.44) (-1.75) (-1.84) (-1.26) (0.37)

Observations 2,865 2,865 2,865 2,862 2,837 2,274

Adjusted R2 0.055 0.079 0.074 0.075 0.079 0.195

Page 90: Activist Short-Selling - University of Toronto T-Space · Activist short-selling – short-sellers publicly talking down securities to benefit their short positions – attracts attentions

81

Panel B: Low illiquidity sample

(1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6)

AR(0) CAR(0,1) CAR(0,2) CAR

(1Week)

CAR

(1Month)

CAR

(1Year)

Overvaluation -0.0026 -0.0051 -0.0153** -0.0212** -0.0850*** -0.9142***

(-0.53) (-0.74) (-1.97) (-2.11) (-3.74) (-5.28)

Uncertainty -0.0049 -0.0061 -0.0161 -0.0103 -0.0258 -0.0198

(-0.42) (-0.45) (-1.01) (-0.46) (-0.50) (-0.03)

Size 0.0027*** 0.0033** 0.0036** 0.0054*** 0.0138*** 0.1027**

(2.84) (2.57) (2.28) (2.70) (3.54) (2.03)

Leverage -0.0015 0.0017 0.0057 0.0069 0.0076 0.2001

(-0.28) (0.25) (0.73) (0.69) (0.32) (0.78)

Illiquidity 11.4002 -1.8695 -2.5690 4.1218 106.1941** 729.6384*

(1.25) (-0.17) (-0.20) (0.23) (2.33) (1.78)

Volatility 0.0218 0.0566 0.0837 0.2087 0.2787 2.7574

(0.23) (0.39) (0.48) (0.92) (0.51) (0.59)

LnAnalyst 0.0042*** 0.0016 0.0021 0.0021 0.0230** 0.1446**

(2.74) (0.72) (0.81) (0.60) (2.47) (1.99)

ShortInterest 0.0086 0.0017 0.0062 0.0120 0.0355 0.4572**

(1.49) (0.19) (0.60) (0.91) (1.14) (2.21)

EarnAnnounce[-5,0] 0.0008 -0.0034 -0.0034 0.0002 0.0088 0.1379**

(0.18) (-0.46) (-0.38) (0.02) (1.03) (2.03)

AnForecast[-5,0] -0.0017 -0.0029 -0.0033 -0.0060 -0.0077 -0.0330

(-1.07) (-1.29) (-1.08) (-1.44) (-1.27) (-0.70)

ConfCall[-5,0] 0.0113 0.0140 0.0122 0.0015 -0.0072 -0.0251

(1.54) (0.98) (0.81) (0.09) (-0.26) (-0.20)

FF 48 FE Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes

QTR FE Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes

Constant -0.0367*** -0.0217 -0.0153 -0.0276 -0.1785*** -1.3369**

(-3.06) (-1.27) (-0.77) (-1.00) (-2.91) (-2.07)

Observations 2,837 2,836 2,834 2,832 2,792 2,200

Adjusted R2 0.011 0.017 0.029 0.039 0.088 0.260

Page 91: Activist Short-Selling - University of Toronto T-Space · Activist short-selling – short-sellers publicly talking down securities to benefit their short positions – attracts attentions

82

Figure A1: Separate Winners vs. Losers in both SA and ASR

This figure plots the return patterns of targets in the window of [-60, 250] around the activist short-selling dates for

both SA (Panel A) and ASR (Panel B) sample.

Panel A: Separating winners vs. losers for in the SA sample

Panel B: Separating winners vs. losers for in the ASR sample

Page 92: Activist Short-Selling - University of Toronto T-Space · Activist short-selling – short-sellers publicly talking down securities to benefit their short positions – attracts attentions

83

Chapter 2 Selling Financial Analysts Short: The Impact of Activist Short-

Selling on Sell-Side Analysts

1 Introduction

Financial analysts have indispensable roles in capital markets as information intermediaries.

However, the sell-side business model does not guarantee (and arguably frequently fail to provide)

objective, independent, and effective research largely because of the inherent incentive problems.

Prior research has shown that analysts are motivated to bias optimistically to generate trading

commissions (e.g., Jackson 2005; Beyer and Guttman 2011), attract underwriting business (e.g.,

Lin and McNichols 1997; Michaely and Womack 1999) or cater to management for future

favorable access of their private information (e.g., Chen and Matsumoto 2006). As the survey of

Brown, Call, Clement, and Sharp (2015) shows, private communication with management is “even

more useful to analysts than their own primary research, the firms’ recent earnings performance,

and the recent 10-K or 10-Q reports” (page 10). Meanwhile, prior research has well documented

the fact that management has strong incentives to withhold negative news (e.g., Kothari, Shu, and

Wysocki 2009). In a world where analysts rely on management for information and strategically

disseminate management-favorable message, negative information would be in short supply and

analysts’ roles as information intermediaries would be severely compromised.

Among all market participants who could meet the demand of negative information, short-

sellers are arguably best equipped with incentives and capabilities to do so (e.g., Karpoff and Lou

2010). While most short-selling is done quietly in which negative information is revealed through

the trade (i.e., short-positions), some short-sellers take an aggressive approach by publicly talking

down securities, a recent financial innovation called activist short-selling by the investing

community (Ljungqvist and Qian 2016; Zhao 2017). In this way, they can more quickly

disseminate negative information into the market and accelerate the price correction. More

importantly, activist short-sellers also frequently accuse sell-side’s systematic optimism (or

“talking-up”) as a major driver of security overvaluation. For example, almost every Citron

Page 93: Activist Short-Selling - University of Toronto T-Space · Activist short-selling – short-sellers publicly talking down securities to benefit their short positions – attracts attentions

84

Research report makes fun of Wall Street analysts, claiming that they should have done a better

job with higher diligence and intelligence.1 Such an aggressive approach makes activist short-

sellers a unique source of negative information and usually puts analysts into the corner such that

they feel obliged to respond. Anecdotal evidence shows that analysts pay great attention to

prominent short-selling campaigns such as Citron Research’s attack on Valeant in October 2015.2

Recently, a news report mentions that “now his [Carson Block of Muddy Waters Research –

another prominent activist short-seller] reports are a regular part of Wall Street’s conversation.”3

However, prior literature largely ignores the consequences of short-selling activities (let

alone activist short-selling) on the sell-side analyst community. Several papers on the information

flow between analysts and short-sellers either examine the possibilities of analysts’ tipping short-

sellers before downgrades (Christophe, Ferri, and Hsieh 2010) and short-sellers’ predicting

analysts’ downgrades (Boehmer, Jones, and Zhang 2015), or report no evidence on analysts’

reaction to short-selling reports (Ljungqvist and Qian 2016). To fill the gap in literature, I ask four

related questions in this paper. First, do analysts react to activist short-selling allegations on their

covered firms? Second, what factors explain variation in analysts’ reactions? Third, does activist

short-selling damage analysts’ reputations? Finally, does activist short-selling affect analysts’

career paths?

I start from the large sample of 6,081 activist short-selling cases from 2006 to 2015

complied by Zhao (2017) who combines information from Seeking Alpha (SeekingAlpha.com,

SA hereafter) and Activist Shorts Research (ActivistShorts.com, ASR hereafter). SA is the largest

crowdsourced investing platform appealing to non-celebrity short-sellers, while ASR tracks all

1 For the most vivid illustration, see page 12 of this report on JCOM: http://www.citronresearch.com/wp-

content/uploads/2016/03/JCOM-final-c21.pdf. 2 For example, in a note to clients, Nomura analyst Shibani Malhotra said that the weakness in Valeant's stock offers

a buying opportunity, as the brokerage firm believes the concern raised by Citron is likely “misinformation” (see

http://www.reuters.com/article/us-valeant-citron-idUSKCN0SF22520151021). By contrast, BMO analyst Alex

Arfaei said that “we cannot defend the specialty pharmacy structure,” and downgraded Valeant’s shares to “market

perform” (see http://business.financialpost.com/investing/global-investor/valeant-pharmaceuticals-international-inc-

is-tanking-again-today-after-longtime-bull-downgrades-stock). Further, User Raffat of Evercore ISI and Gregg

Gilbert from Deutsche Bank even terminated the coverage because the price was no longer determined by value (see

http://www.streetinsider.com/Analyst+Comments/Deutsche+Bank+Suspends+Coverage+on+Valeant+Pharma+(VR

X)/11374531.html). 3 See http://uk.businessinsider.com/carson-block-told-us-he-regrets-not-having-shorted-one-stock-in-2016-2016-10.

Page 94: Activist Short-Selling - University of Toronto T-Space · Activist short-selling – short-sellers publicly talking down securities to benefit their short positions – attracts attentions

85

influential activist short-selling events, providing a good complement to the SA sample. As many

firms are targeted by multiple times in a short period of time, I focus on the activist short-selling

case with the most negative returns in the first two days following short-sellers’ public talking-

down if a firm is targeted by multiple times in a year, leaving me 2,583 activist short-selling cases.

To start with, I confirm that analysts do react to activist short-selling: they are more likely

to lower and less likely to raise price targets if short-sellers seem to be right (i.e., initial market

reaction is negative), but they are more likely to raise and less likely to lower price targets if short-

sellers seem to be wrong (i.e., initial market reaction is positive). These findings contrast to

Ljungqvist and Qian’s (2016) conclusion that “there is little evidence that analysts consider

arb[arbitrageur]’s information in their recommendations” (page 1986) based on the finding that

the distribution of recommendation types largely remains stable after firms are targeted by short-

selling reports. Note changing recommendations is not a necessary condition to infer that analysts

are considering new information. It could be that analysts keep the Buy recommendations only

because the price has declined so much that creates a new Buy opportunity after the activist short-

selling. As a result, my approach using price targets is more powerful in examining whether

analysts react to activist short-selling.

Although analysts on average revise down their target prices when short-sellers seem to be

right (i.e., prices drop after activist short-selling) and revise up otherwise, there is still large

variation in the direction and timeliness of their revisions. I find that analysts are more likely to

delay their revisions when the short-sellers seem to be wrong or when analysts are employed by

smaller brokerage houses, have a shorter experience in the profession, have a longer history of

covering the target firm, provide bullish forecasts before targeted, or only cover fewer firms.

Similarly, analysts are more likely to raise their target prices when the short-sellers seem to be

wrong or when they have a longer history of covering the target firm, present less optimism in

previous forecasts, have fewer other analysts covering the firm, or have a style of frequent

revisions. These results suggest that analysts’ incentives (i.e., history with the target firm and the

size of coverage portfolio) and abilities (i.e., size of the brokerage house and the experience as an

analyst) as well as the initial impact of the activist short-selling determine whether and how

analysts react to activist short-selling.

Page 95: Activist Short-Selling - University of Toronto T-Space · Activist short-selling – short-sellers publicly talking down securities to benefit their short positions – attracts attentions

86

Next I examine whether and how analysts’ reputations are damaged by short-sellers’ public

talking-down behavior. Following prior literature, I investigate how the market reacts to analysts’

EPS revisions differently after activist short-selling. Depending on the CAR windows I use, the

market-reaction spreads (i.e., the difference in market reactions to the top and bottom decile of

analyst revisions) are reduced by 26% to 30% after activist short-selling. In other words, investors

are less sensitive/responsive to those analysts’ revisions afterwards. Note this is not because

investors become less responsive to all information signals after activist short-selling. For example,

they are comparably responsive to quarterly earnings announcements before and after activist

short-selling. As a result, I label this reduction in market reaction spreads to analyst revisions as

analysts’ reputation loss.

Further, I investigate under what circumstances analysts can avoid or suffer more

reputation losses. Intuitively, if analysts are relatively conservative, they would be less humiliated

by activist short-sellers. Also, if the short-selling campaign does not lead to substantial negative

return, they could also avoid reputation loss because the market is not convinced by short-sellers.

Indeed, the reputation loss is not significant when analysts’ last target price for a given stock before

activist short-selling is below the median (i.e., relatively less bullish) or when the first two-day

return after activist short-selling is positive (i.e., short-sellers seem to be wrong). In particular, the

market is 50% less responsive to analysts’ revisions (i.e., 50% loss in reputation) if they are

relatively bullish and short-sellers seem to be right.

I also investigate whether analysts can save their reputation by reacting in a certain way

after activist short-selling. Ex ante, it is unclear whether reacting in a more timely or “humble”

manner (i.e., revising down rather than defending previous optimistic positions) could help,

because the market could interpret such actions as a lack of ability and confidence in their own

stances. I find that timely reactions help: in a quarter of cases in which analysts react most timely,

the reputation loss is not statistically significant, but for the quarter of cases in which analysts who

provide the least timely reactions, the reputation loss is highly significant. But surprisingly, the

direction of revision does not seem to matter much – analysts suffer from reputation loss no matter

whether she revises up or down.

Page 96: Activist Short-Selling - University of Toronto T-Space · Activist short-selling – short-sellers publicly talking down securities to benefit their short positions – attracts attentions

87

Finally, I examine the career consequences of activist short-selling on analysts. Specifically,

I investigate whether an analyst moves to a smaller brokerage house one, two, and three years after

activist short-selling. I find that an analyst is more likely to move to a smaller brokerage house if

her covered firms are targeted by activist short-sellers. Further, the probability of moving down is

increasing in the number of covered firms being targeted. The pattern lasts for at least three years,

indicating that activist short-selling has a persistent impact on the analysts’ career path. Additional

analyses show that analysts whose covered firms are targeted are less likely to exit the analyst

business, suggesting that their outside option is also limited by the short-selling attacks. This is

consistent with Clement and Law (2016) who show that high-ability analysts hired under a tight

labor market are more likely to leave the profession after the condition improves.

This chapter of my dissertation makes the following contributions. First, this paper adds to

the emerging literature on the consequences of competition among information intermediaries.

Prior literature documents that biases are reduced by competition among analysts (Hong and

Kacperczyk 2010; Merkley, Michaely, and Pacelli 2017) and among credit rating agencies (Becker

and Milbourn 2011; Doherty, Kartasheva, and Phillips 2012; Xia 2014). While these papers focus

on the competition among the same type of intermediaries, I examine the consequences of

competition between different types. In this spirit, a recent study by Jame, Markov, and Wolfe

(2017) is closest to mine: they document a disciplinary role of Estimize, a crowdsourced platform

for short-term earnings forecasts, on sell-side analysts. They find that analysts reduce short-term

forecast bias after their covered firms are added to Estimize. However, they have not considered

how quick analysts react to Estimize forecasts and the reputation and career consequences of this

crowdsourced platform on the sell-side community.

Second, this paper reconciles the contradictions between real-world cases and Ljungqvist

and Qian’s (2016) conclusion that analysts largely ignore short-selling reports based on the

observation that the distribution of recommendations remains stable for a long time. More broadly,

this study adds a new perspective to the literature regarding the information flow between analysts

and short-sellers. While prior literature provides evidence in support of either the tipping

hypothesis (i.e., analysts give tips to short-sellers, who therefore can trade prior to analyst

downgrades) or the prediction hypothesis (i.e., short-selling activities predict analyst downgrades).

Page 97: Activist Short-Selling - University of Toronto T-Space · Activist short-selling – short-sellers publicly talking down securities to benefit their short positions – attracts attentions

88

This paper raises and provides evidence for a new reaction hypothesis (i.e., analysts react to short-

sellers’ activities).

Third, this article contributes to the literature on analyst reputation. Prior research has

documented analysts’ incentives to build reputation among investors (e.g., Stickel 1992; Jackson

2005). I focus on a scenario in which analysts’ reputations are severely damaged. As a result, my

study complements a recent paper by Lee and Lo (2016) who show that analysts who provide

bullish forecasts prior to restatements suffer from loss in reputation. However, restatement is a

very different setting from activist short-selling, because analysts know that they are definitely

wrong after firms restate the prior mistakes, but it is usually unclear whether they are wrong in the

presence of activist short-selling – that’s why I also find huge variation in their reactions and

provide recommendations on how they should react to avoid reputation loss – react quickly.

Finally, this paper adds to the literature on analysts’ career concerns. Prior literature finds

that some certain actions can lead to better or worse career consequences (e.g., Hong, Kubik, and

Solomon 2000; Hong and Kubik 2003; Ke and Yu 2006). In particular, Hong and Kubik (2003)

find that controlling for accuracy, analysts who are optimistic relative to the consensus are more

likely to move to more prestigious brokerage houses. This paper shows that such an “optimism”

strategy is risky – it could eventually hurt analysts’ job prospects if the optimism attracts activist

short-sellers.

The remainder of this paper is organized as follows. Section 2 reviews related literature.

Sections 3 examines whether analysts revise their price targets after activist short-selling. Section

4 explores variation in analysts’ reactions in target-price revisions. Section 5 focuses on whether

and how analysts’ reputations are damaged by activist short-sellers. Section 6 investigates the

impact of activist short-selling on analysts’ career prospects. Section 7 presents several robustness

checks and supplemental analyses. Section 8 concludes.

Page 98: Activist Short-Selling - University of Toronto T-Space · Activist short-selling – short-sellers publicly talking down securities to benefit their short positions – attracts attentions

89

2 Related Literature

2.1 Sell-Side Optimism

Prior research has documented the systematic optimism of sell-side outputs at least since

Brown, Foster, and Noreen (1985). Although recent research documents that analysts “walk-down”

their EPS forecasts over the year to make it easier for managers to meet or beat (e.g., Richardson,

Teoh, Wysocki 2004), overwhelming evidence shows that they bias their investing

recommendations optimistically. Several incentive-based explanations are raised to answer why

analysts have such optimism. 4 First, in the presence of short-selling constraints, optimistic

recommendations are more likely to generate trading commissions than pessimistic forecasts

(Jackson 2005). Second, analysts may be motivated to provide optimistic recommendations to

cater management for the purpose of either gaining underwriting business deals (Lin and

McNichols 1998) or maintaining the assess to management’s private information (Francis and

Philbrick 1993; Soltes 2014). Third, analysts also have incentives to promote stocks that are held

by fund families affiliated with their brokerage houses (Mola and Guidolin 2009). Note that being

optimistic seems a rational strategy for analysts from a career perspective, as Hong and Kubik

(2003) show that optimism is an important predictor of analysts’ career success (as measured by

moving to more prestigious brokerage houses) in addition to accuracy.

Such prevailing optimism probably explains why following analysts’ recommendations

could be sometimes costly. For example, Jegadeesh, Kim, Krische, and Lee (2004) show that

analysts tend to recommend stocks with quantitative characteristics that are associated with

negative future returns, such as low book-to-market, high sales growth, and high accruals. Indeed,

as long as analysts rely on management for information and have incentive to mute potentially

negative information, they will tend to over-recommend. In other words, information provided by

4 While these incentive-based explanations claim that analysts add bias to their true beliefs, prior research also suggests

alternative explanations in which analysts are reporting their true beliefs. For example, McNichols and O’Brien (1997)

discuss the possibility that analysts are more likely to report on stocks about which they have favorable views.

Similarly, Hayes (1998) builds a model to illustrate that analysts have stronger incentives to cover firms that they

expect to perform well.

Page 99: Activist Short-Selling - University of Toronto T-Space · Activist short-selling – short-sellers publicly talking down securities to benefit their short positions – attracts attentions

90

the analysts is skewed to the positive side, creating a need for alternative source of negative

information.

2.2 Activist Short-Sellers as a Source of Negative Research

Among all market participants, short-sellers are arguably the best source of negative

information as they are best-equipped with the right incentives and capabilities. Note that short-

sellers have a unique business model of benefiting from the decline of stock prices. As a result,

they have strong incentives to collect, process, and disseminate negative information into the

marketplace. Prior research has documented that they are among the most sophisticated players in

the financial market. For example, Aitken, Frino, McCorry, and Swan (1998) use intraday data

and show that short sales are instantaneously bad news. Such sales can help impound adverse

information into stock prices within fifteen minutes. Dechow, Hutton, Meulbroek, and Sloan (2001)

confirm that short sellers are sophisticated traders in that they use fundamental analysis to exploit

the lower expected future return of firms with lower ratio of fundamentals to market values. Further,

Drake, Rees, and Swanson (2011) recommend that we follow short-sellers rather than analysts

when they disagree with each other.

Prior literature focuses on the aspect that short-sellers incorporate their negative

information into prices through trading (i.e., taking short-positions). However, as short-selling is

a risky business, short-sellers may avoid taking short-positions in the presence of analysts’ public

talking-up, which could amplify the noise-trader risk (De Long, Shleifer, Summers, and

Waldmann 1990). This dilemma can be partially solved by a financial innovation commonly

referred to as “activist short-selling” in the investing community, where short-sellers publicly talk

down stocks to benefit their short positions (Ljungqvist and Qian 2016; Zhao 2017). They usually

provide arguments and evidence on why the targeted stocks are severely overvalued and should

be shorted. As a public signal informing the market, they can not only potentially reduce the noise-

trader risk, but also create panic among existing shareholders who might try to sell as soon as

possible (Zhao 2017).

Such public talking-down exerts substantial threats to analysts. Different from the situation

where short-sellers take positions quietly, analysts are almost “forced” to join in a public debate

Page 100: Activist Short-Selling - University of Toronto T-Space · Activist short-selling – short-sellers publicly talking down securities to benefit their short positions – attracts attentions

91

regarding the valuation of stocks. What makes the situation even more intense is that many activist

short-sellers specifically highlight analysts’ mistakes and attack their misaligned incentives and

dependence on management for information. Under much greater public scrutiny, it’s likely that

some analysts feel obliged to respond – either acknowledging the merit in the short-thesis or

defending their previous positions. However, it’s also possible that some other analysts are

concerned about taking a wrong stance in a public debate and remain silent for a long time.

2.3 Prior Research on the Information Flows between Short-Sellers

and Analysts

Prior research has documented abnormally high short-selling activities prior to analyst

downgrades. There are at least three explanations: (1) analysts provide tips to short-sellers before

they downgrade (or tipping), (2) short-sellers predict the downgrades with their sophistication (or

prediction), and (3) analysts learn from and react to the short-selling activities (or reaction).

Christophe, Ferri, and Hsieh (2010) use 670 downgrades for NASDAQ stocks in 2000 and 2001

and find abnormal levels of short-selling in the three days before downgrades are publicly

announced. They claim that their evidence is more consistent with the tipping explanation than the

prediction explanation based on two sets of analyses. First, they find that firms with higher

abnormal short-interest are not likely to report negative earnings surprise. Second, abnormal short-

interest in day (-3, -1) is significantly higher than that in day (-10, -6), where day (0) is the day

when analysts downgrade stocks.

Boehmer, Jones, and Zhang (2015) use a five-year panel of proprietary NYSE short sale

order data and find heavier shorting in the week before analyst downgrades. They argue that their

evidence cannot be fully explained by tipping, but consistent with the prediction explanation,

because short-sales have incremental predictability in stock underperformance beyond analyst

downgrades, suggesting that short-sellers have information that analysts do not know and therefore

cannot tip.

To the best of my knowledge, Ljungqvist and Qian (2016) is the only paper that discusses

the reaction hypothesis. However, they conclude that analysts are very slow in incorporating

information from the short-selling reports based on the observation that analysts’

Page 101: Activist Short-Selling - University of Toronto T-Space · Activist short-selling – short-sellers publicly talking down securities to benefit their short positions – attracts attentions

92

recommendations stay very stable for one year. This is surprising and inconsistent with the

anecdote evidence we observe in the real world, for example, from the Valeant vs. Citron Research

case I mention earlier. They correctly conclude that their evidence is “consistent with the well-

known tendency among analysts to avoid annoying top management at companies they cover,”

but no change in recommendation does not mean that analysts are not reacting to these short-

selling reports, as I explain in the next section.

3 Do Financial Analysts React to Activist Short-Selling?

To examine whether analysts react to activist short-selling, I make use of 6,081 activist

short-selling constructed by Zhao (2017) from Seeking Alpha (SA) and Activists Shorts Research

(ASR). Whereas SA is the largest crowdsourced investing platform therefore an ideal for non-

celebrity shorts, ASR tracks short-selling campaigns waged by prominent traders. For those short

theses published on SA, Zhao (2017) defines activist short-selling as those articles in which the

authors disclose explicitly that they hold short-positions in the discussed stocks. Appendix A

explains how these cases are identified.

Note that some firms are targeted by activist short-sellers by multiple times within a short

period of time. To increase the power of the analyses, for each firm in a given year, I focus on one

activist short-selling case that leads to the biggest price decline in the first two days starting from

the activist short-selling date.5 To illustrate, suppose Firm A is targeted by short-seller I, II, and

III on February 1, April 1, and June 1, 2010, respectively and the two-day raw returns of these

three campaigns are -1%, -5%, and 1%. I only focus on the case that Firm A is targeted by the

short-seller II on April 1, 2010. All analyst forecasts prior to April 1, 2010 are defined as pre-

activist short-selling, and those after that date are defined as post-activist short-selling. This

approach leaves me 2,583 activist short-selling cases, each of which corresponds to a unique firm-

year. Figure 1 presents the distribution by year. There is a clear trend that more and more firms are

targeted by activist short-sellers in recent years.

5 All inferences remain if I either use all activist short-selling cases or only use the first case for each firm-year.

Page 102: Activist Short-Selling - University of Toronto T-Space · Activist short-selling – short-sellers publicly talking down securities to benefit their short positions – attracts attentions

93

I start my analysis by replicating what Ljungqvist and Qian (2016) find in their much

smaller sample regarding analyst recommendations around short-selling reports. In Figure 2 I plot

the number of recommendations by type (i.e., Strong Sell, Sell, Hold, Buy, and Strong Buy) in 18

five-day windows (i.e., period) prior to and after the activist short-selling. We can find that except

there is a spike of Hold recommendations around the activist short-selling date, the numbers of

other types of recommendations remain stable, largely consistent with Ljungqvist and Qian (2016).

As a result, it is tempting to conclude that analysts do not react to activist short-selling as

Ljungqvist and Qian (2016) do.

I argue that no change in recommendation does not mean that analysts are not reacting to

these short-selling reports. First, they could incorporate the new information into targeted prices

and forecast revisions, which are largely continuous, rather than into recommendations, which are

discrete with only five ratings. Second, it’s possible that analysts keep favorable (e.g., Strong Buy)

ratings because the price has dropped so much after the short-selling. In other words, it is possible

that they incorporate new information but still remain the same rating.

I focus on target price rather than recommendations in examining whether analysts react to

activist short-selling. The following Figure 3 illustrates how many analysts are changing their price

targets in each five-day interval before and after the activist short-selling.

We can find that for those targeted firms with negative returns in (0, 1) interval, 973

analysts lowered their target prices, a 50% increase from the previous 5-day intervals of 626. By

contrast, 460 analysts raised their target prices, slightly decrease from the previous 5-day intervals

of 498. Figure 1 Panel B illustrates the case for those targeted firms that do not witness negative

raw returns. The number of analysts who raised target prices increase by 50% from 218 to 330,

but the number of analysts who lowered target prices decreases by a quarter from 241 to 187 in

the first 5-day interval benchmarking on the previous 5-day interval. Importantly, the numbers of

raising and lowering price targets prior to activist short-selling in both panels are quite parallel.

It is very difficult to interpret Figure 3 using Tipping or Prediction explanations. First, it is

unclear why short-sellers need to put up a short-thesis when they know that analysts would revise

their forecasts down – they could have simply taken short positions quietly. In so doing, they could

profit from the short-selling but avoid the risk of activist short-selling. In particular, they can avoid

Page 103: Activist Short-Selling - University of Toronto T-Space · Activist short-selling – short-sellers publicly talking down securities to benefit their short positions – attracts attentions

94

humiliating the analysts who provide tips. Second, it is unclear how these two hypotheses explain

why the direction of analysts’ reaction depends on the initial market reaction of activist short-

selling. For example, it is puzzling why analysts even raise target prices after activist short-selling

that fails to bring down prices. Third, note that the market reactions to activist short-selling (mean

CAR(0, 1) = -2.6%) is way larger than those to forecast revisions (mean CAR(0, 1) = -0.4%) –

activist short-sellers are unlikely to rely on such revisions for profits. So the most likely

explanation would be that analysts react to activist short-selling.

4 What Determines Financial Analysts’ Reactions to

Activist Short-Selling?

In Section 3 we find that analysts react to activist short-selling but exhibits huge variation

in the timeliness and directions of such reactions. This section explores reasons that explain such

variation in the responses. As there is no explicit theoretical guidance from the prior literature

regarding what are the determinants of analysts reactions, I include several typical short-selling

campaign-level, analyst-level, firm-level, and firm-analyst level variables that capture analysts’

incentives, abilities, and their awareness of the short-selling. I focus on those analysts who provide

at least one target-price forecast in the 180 days prior to the activist short-selling and check when

and how they revise their price targets after activist short-selling. I estimate the following linear

models using OLS:

, 0 1 , 2 , 3 ,

4 , 5 , 6 ,

7 , 7 , 9 ,

10 , 11 , ,

/ i t i t i t i t

i t i t i t

i t i t i t

i t i t t t i t

Delay Raise ShortsImpact BrokSize LnCovDays

PreTalkUp AnaExperience LnCovFirm

LnCoverage TPFrequency Size

Leverage BTM Year Firm

(1)

Where Delay is defined as the log of one plus the number of days between activist short-

selling and the analyst’s first target-price revision. Raise is an indicator defined as one if the first

revision after activist short-selling is to raise the price target, and zero otherwise. In this

exploratory test, I test whether analysts reactions are affected by (1) the initial impact of the activist

Page 104: Activist Short-Selling - University of Toronto T-Space · Activist short-selling – short-sellers publicly talking down securities to benefit their short positions – attracts attentions

95

short-selling (ShortsImpact), defined as the first two-day raw return following the activist short-

selling date multiplied by minus one; (2) the brokerage house size (BrokSize), defined as the log

of one plus the number of unique analysts providing EPS forecasts in that year; (3) analyst’s

coverage history of the firm (LnCovDays), measured as the log of one plus the number of days

since the analyst provided the first EPS forecast on the firm; (4) analysts talk-up behavior prior to

the activist short-selling (PreTalkUp), measured as the decile rank of all analysts’ last target price

forecasts on a given firm prior to activist short-selling; (5) analyst experience (AnaExperience),

measured as the log of one plus the number of years the analyst has been in IBES universe; (6)

number of covered firms (LnCovFirm), measured by the log of one plus the number of unique

firms the analyst is providing EPS forecasts in the year; (7) number of analyst covering the firm

(LnCoverage), measured by the log of one plus the number of unique analysts who are providing

EPS to the firm in the year; and (8) target price forecasting frequency (TPFrequency), measured

as the log of one plus the number of times the analyst has provided target price forecast on the firm

in the 90 days prior to the activist short-selling. In addition, I also control for three firm-level

characteristics, including the size of the firm (Size), measured by the log of one plus the total assets

at the beginning of the fiscal year, the leverage of the firm (Leverage), measured by the ratio of

total liabilities to total assets at the beginning of the fiscal year, and the book-to-market ratio (BTM),

measured by the ratio of book value of equity to the total market capitalization at the beginning of

the fiscal year. Finally, I include firm and year fixed effects to control for factors that are specific

to each firm or each quarter. As each analyst has her own style in reacting to activist short-selling,

I cluster the standard errors at the analyst level.

Table 1, Panel A presents the summary statistics of variables used in the regressions. Some

statistics are worth mentioning. For example, the mean of Delay is 3.666. In other words, on

average analysts make the first target-price revision 48 days after activist short-selling, suggesting

that many analysts are hesitated to respond. But in more than 10% of the cases analysts respond

within the first week. Surprisingly, in half of the cases, analysts revise up the target price (Raise)

to defend the company and probably their previous positions, even though the mean of

ShortsImpact is 0.026 (i.e., on average there is substantial price drop after activist short-selling).

Table 1 Panel B presents the regression results. In general, I find that analysts are likely to

delay target-price revision if the initial market reaction is not in favor of short-sellers, if the

Page 105: Activist Short-Selling - University of Toronto T-Space · Activist short-selling – short-sellers publicly talking down securities to benefit their short positions – attracts attentions

96

analysts are from smaller brokerage house, if analysts have longer covering history with the firm,

if the analyst is previously more bullish, and if the analyst is covering fewer firms. With respect to

the direction of reaction, analysts are more likely to revise up if the market reaction is not in favor

of the short-seller, if analysts have longer history of covering the firm, if the analyst is previously

less bullish, if there are fewer analysts covering the firm,6 and if the analyst has a style of revising

frequently. These results show that the variation in analysts’ reaction to activist short-selling is

partially explained by the impact of activist short-selling (proxied by the initial market reaction),

the ability (captured by the size of brokerage house), and incentive of the analysts (captured by the

covering history with the firm).

5 Analysts’ Reputation Loss after Activist Short-Selling

5.1 Main Results

Activist short-sellers’ opportunities emerge when the sell-side analysts are over-optimistic

and ignore some material negative information. After the short-theses are published – no matter

whether short-sellers explicitly attack analysts for their lack of diligence and intelligence – it is

natural to expect that market would lose some confidence on analysts’ ability and/or incentives in

providing informative forecasts. This section examines whether and how activist short-selling

affects analysts’ reputation. Specifically, I compare how differently the market reacts to analysts’

EPS revisions before and after activist short-selling. I estimate the following model:

, 0 1 , 2 , 3 , ,

4 , 5 , 6 , ,

i t i t i t i t i t

i t i t i t t t i t

CAR RevRank Post RevRank Post

Size Leverage BTM Year Firm

(2)

Where, CAR is the cumulative abnormal return adjusted by Fama-French three factor

model. In the main analyses I use four short windows: CAR(0, 1), CAR(-1, 1), CAR(0, 2), and

6 This is consistent with Hong and Kacperczyk (2010) that more competition from other analysts leads to less biased

forecasts.

Page 106: Activist Short-Selling - University of Toronto T-Space · Activist short-selling – short-sellers publicly talking down securities to benefit their short positions – attracts attentions

97

CAR(-2, 2) are CAR in a two-day window starting from the EPS revision date, CAR in a three-day

window centered on the EPS revision date, CAR in a three-day window starting from the EPS

revision date, and CAR in a five-day window centered on the EPS revision date, respectively.

RevRank is the decile rank of the peer firm’s analyst forecast revision magnitude. The magnitude

is the revised EPS forecast minus the previous EPS forecast by the same analyst for the same fiscal

quarter scaled by the beginning-of-quarter share price ((FEPSrevised – FEPSprevious) / PRICEbeginning-

of-quarter). Then I transform this variable into decile rank and scale the rank to make it range from 0

to 1. Post is an indicator, defined as one if the EPS revision happens after the activist short-selling,

and zero otherwise. I include several basic firm-level characteristics as control variables, including

Size, Leverage, and BTM. Consistent with model 1, I also include firm and year fixed effects and

cluster standard errors at the analyst level.

Table 2, Panel A presents the summary statistics of the main variables. Panel B shows the

regression results. Note that RevRank ranges from 0 to 1, thus it is easy to interpret that the

coefficient of RevRank represents the difference in market reactions to the analyst revisions in the

top and bottom deciles. For example, in Column 1, it means that, in the Pre-activist short-selling

period, the CAR(0,1) is 4.38% higher for the top-decile revisions than for the bottom-decile

revisions. I label this 4.38% as the spread of market reactions between the top and bottom deciles.

The key coefficient of interest is the interaction term of RevRank×Post, which captures how much

the market reaction is less sensitive to the analyst revisions after activist short-selling. Again, in

Column 1, it means that in the post period, the spread of market reactions narrows by 1.14%, or

26.0% of 4.38%. In other words, after activist short-selling, the market is much less sensitive to

analyst revisions – a symptom that the investors do not believe analysts’ credibility as much as

they do in the pre-period. I label this reduction of sensitivity as reputation loss and quantify it as

the percentage of spread decrease – 26.0% in Column 1. Interestingly, the reputation loss is highly

consistent cross four columns based on different windows. The value ranges from 26% to 30%,

indicating that activist short-selling leads to substantial reputation loss of analysts. In the next two

sub-sections, I examine circumstances in which analysts suffer from less reputation loss.

Page 107: Activist Short-Selling - University of Toronto T-Space · Activist short-selling – short-sellers publicly talking down securities to benefit their short positions – attracts attentions

98

5.2 Cross-Sectional Variation: Analysts’ View Prior to Activist Short-

Selling

First, if the analysts are not as bullish as other analysts prior to the activist short-selling,

the short-theses and the associated price decline would echo their bearish view. In that case, those

analysts’ reputation would be less affected. For brevity I focus on CAR(-1, 1) in all cross-sectional

analyses. In Columns 1 - 2 of Table 3, Panel A, I spilt the sample into More vs. Less Bullish based

on whether an analyst’s last target-price forecast prior to the activist short-selling is higher than

the median of all analysts’ last forecasts of that firm. As expected, the coefficient of RevRank×Post

in the More Bullish sample is significantly negative at the 5% level, while the counterpart in the

Less Bullish sample is insignificant at the conventional level.

5.3 Cross-Sectional Variation: The Market’s Initial Reactions

Second, if the market does not believe the short-theses, then analysts’ reputation would not

be affected. In Columns 3 - 4 of Table 3, Panel A, I spilt the sample into Shorts Seem Wrong vs.

Right based on whether the target firms’ raw return in the first two-day window starting from the

activist short-selling date is negative or not. As expected, the coefficient of RevRank×Post in the

Shorts Seem Right sample is significantly negative at the 1% level, while the counterpart in the

Shorts Seem Wrong sample is insignificant at the conventional level. It is worth mentioning that

these two coefficients are significantly different at the 5% level.

I also combine the above two dimensions (More vs. Less Bullish and Shorts Seem Wrong

vs. Right) in Columns 5 – 8 in Table 3, Panel A. It seems that the key determinant of analysts’

reputation loss is whether short-sellers cause negative returns. Column 8 shows that analysts will

still suffer from reputation loss even if they are less bullish than the median as long as the initial

market reaction suggests that short-sellers might be right (0.0201/0.0535 = 37.6%). But

unsurprisingly, Column 6 indicates that the reputation loss would be more severe for those bullish

analysts (0.0276/0.0527 = 52.4% > 37.6%). By contrast, Columns 5 and 7 show that there is no

reputation loss as long as the market thinks the shorts are wrong, regardless how bullish the

analysts are. These results provide one explanation why analysts have incentives to defend their

previous positions and try to prevent price from collapsing after activist short-selling.

Page 108: Activist Short-Selling - University of Toronto T-Space · Activist short-selling – short-sellers publicly talking down securities to benefit their short positions – attracts attentions

99

5.4 Cross-Sectional Variation: What Analysts Can Do to Avoid

Reputation Loss

Next, I consider what analysts can do after activist short-selling to save their reputation.

Echoing the two dimensions in Section 4, I examine whether the timeliness and direction of

analysts’ reaction affects the reputation loss after activist short-selling. In Panel B of Table 3, I

split the sample into the Bottom Quartile Delay, Middle Delay, and Top Quartile Delay, based on

the first and third quartile of Delay (i.e., the time between activist short-selling and an analyst’s

first target-price revision). I find that the reputation loss is monotonically increasing with the Delay:

for those cases in which analysts react very quickly, the reputation loss is not significant (i.e.,

Column 1), but if analysts don’t provide timely responses, the reputation loss is much worse (i.e.,

Column 3). These results suggest that it is wise for analysts to provide timely responses after

activist short-selling.

But does the direction of reactions matter? This is not as clear as the other cross-sectional

predictions. On one hand, revising down could be interpreted as open-mind; on the other hand, it

could be interpreted as a lack of ability and confidence in their own analyses. In Panel C of Table

3, I split the sample based on whether the analyst’s first target-price revision in the post-period is

to Lower vs. Raise target prices. It seems that the direction does not make huge difference: the

coefficient of RevRank×Post is significantly negative in both two subsamples. Note that those

analysts who raise target prices are more reputable in the Pre-period. So the percentage reputation

loss is even larger for those analysts who lower target prices after activist short-selling (i.e.,

0.202/0.421 = 46.9% > 0.215/0.637 = 33.8%).

6 The Impact of Activist Short-Selling on Analysts’

Careers

To the extent that activist short-selling affects analysts’ reputation, we should expect it also

has impacts on analysts’ career prospects. Following prior literature on analysts career concerns

(e.g., Hong and Kubik 2003), I focus on unfavorable future job separations – whether they have to

Page 109: Activist Short-Selling - University of Toronto T-Space · Activist short-selling – short-sellers publicly talking down securities to benefit their short positions – attracts attentions

100

move to smaller brokerage houses. In particular, I examine this career consequence one, two, and

three years after the activist short-selling year using the following model based on a panel at the

analyst-year level.

, 0 1 , 2 ,

2 , 3 , ,

a t a t a t

a t a t t a t

MoveDown AffectedAnalyst BrokSize

LnCovFirm AnaExperience Year

(3)

Move Down is an indicator equal to one if an analyst is employed by a brokerage house

that has lower percentile ranking than the one she was at the activist short-selling date, and zero

otherwise. I use percentile ranking to (1) remove the growth of the analyst profession and (2)

increase the power of test by generating more variation in the outcome variable than focusing on

the move between top and non-top employers (Hong and Kubik 2003). The variable of interest is

AffectedAnalyst, an indictor equal one if the analyst has at least one covered firm being targeted

by activist short-sellers in that year, and zero otherwise. I also control for several analyst-level

characteristics, including BrokSize, LnCovFirm, and AnaExperience. Finally, I also include year

fixed effect and cluster standard errors at the analyst level.7 I also only focus on those affected

analysts and examine whether the number of covered firms being targeted (NumCovTargets)

matters.

Table 4, Panel A reports the summary statistics of variables used in this section. We can

find that 4.6%, 9.6%, and 13.4% analysts move to smaller brokerage houses in one, two, and three

years, respectively. In the universe of analysts, on average about one third (i.e., 34.6%) have at

least one covered firms being targeted by activist short-sellers. Among those affected analysts, on

average each has two covered firms being targeted.

Table 4, Panel B provides regression results. The first three columns find that analysts

whose covered firms are targeted by activist short-sellers are more likely to move to smaller

brokerage houses after one, two, and three years. The impact is also economically meaningful. For

example, the unconditional mean of Move Down in two years is 9.6%, but having covered firms

7 Note that the dataset is a panel at the analyst-year level. One firm could be covered by many analysts and one analyst

could cover multiple firms. As a result, it is not feasible to control for firm fixed effects in this regression.

Page 110: Activist Short-Selling - University of Toronto T-Space · Activist short-selling – short-sellers publicly talking down securities to benefit their short positions – attracts attentions

101

being targeted by activist short-sellers would increase the probability by 1.34% (Column 2), which

is 14% of the unconditional probability of 9.6%. Further, there is cross-sectional variation within

affected analysts – some analysts are so unlucky that they have more than one firms are targeted.

Columns 4-6 show that the likelihood of moving down is increasing with the number of covered

firms being targeted. For example, having one more covered firm being targeted by activist short-

sellers would increase the probability of moving down in two years by 0.84% (i.e., 8.8% of the

unconditional probability of 9.6%). These results suggest that activist short-selling causes real

damages to affected analysts’ job prospects.

I also investigate whether analysts affected by activist short-selling are more or less likely

to exit. As the prior literature is unclear whether leaving the profession is a favorable outcome for

sell-side analysts, I caution the reader on over-interpreting results of this test. Importantly, the

traditional wisdom assumes that losers leave the profession. For example, Hong, Kubik, and

Solomon (2000) write that “The probability that an analyst may have left for a better job such as

mutual fund manager after leaving the I/B/E/S sample is remote.” However, a recent paper by

Clement and Law (2016) show that high-ability analysts hired during a tight labor market are more

likely to leave the profession than other analysts do after the market condition improves. In other

words, their findings suggest that high-ability analysts have more/better outside job opportunities.

As a result, winners – rather than losers – may be more likely to leave the profession. My results

are consistent with Clement and Law’s view. I find that analysts who have covered firms attacked

by activist short-sellers are less likely to leave the profession in one, two, and three years. Among

those affected analysts, analysts with more covered firms targeted are less likely to leave in one

and two years (but not in three years) than analysts with fewer covered firms targeted. With

aforementioned caveats, I interpret these results as evidence that activist short-selling limits

affected analysts’ outside job opportunities.

Page 111: Activist Short-Selling - University of Toronto T-Space · Activist short-selling – short-sellers publicly talking down securities to benefit their short positions – attracts attentions

102

7 Robustness Checks and Supplemental Analyses

7.1 An Omitted-Variable Problem

One concern is that analysts could be reacting to the price movement rather than to the

activist short-selling. Note that to the extent the price movement is caused by the short-seller’s

public talking-down behavior, the analysts still react to activist short-selling – indirectly. If so the

relevant alternative explanation is whether analysts are reacting to price movement that is

unrelated to the activist short-selling. However, this is unlikely because Zhao (2017) shows that

the daily abnormal returns in several days prior to activist short-selling is not significantly negative

while the abnormal return on the event day is highly significant, indicating the arrival of negative

news prior to the activist short-selling is minimum. Further, I control for several alternative news

sources such as the occurrences of earnings announcements or conference calls in the five days

prior to the activist short-selling and all inferences remain. Finally, I find that analysts are less

likely to raise price targets after attacked by more influential short-sellers (i.e., ASR) than by less

influential short-sellers (i.e., SA), after controlling for the initial return of the activist short-selling.

To the extent that the arrival of firm-level shocks is unrelated to the identity of short-sellers, this

test provides further support that analysts are reacting to activist short-selling.

7.2 Analysts React by Revising EPS Forecasts

In Section 3 and 4 I check analysts’ target-price revisions and conclude that they react to

activist short-selling. This section provides further evidence by examining analysts’ EPS forecast

revisions around activist short-selling. Figure 4 plots the number of analysts who lower and raise

quarterly EPS forecasts for activist short-selling cases that have negative CAR(0, 1) in Panel A

and positive CAR (0, 1) in Panel B. The trend is largely consistent with that in Figure 3. In Table

5 I also re-examine the determinants of cross-sectional variation in analysts’ reactions using

quarterly EPS forecasts. The results are largely consistent with those in Panel B of Table 1. The

only exception is that the number of analyst coverage (LnCoverage) makes analysts more likely

to revise up EPS forecasts, but less likely to revise up price targets.

Page 112: Activist Short-Selling - University of Toronto T-Space · Activist short-selling – short-sellers publicly talking down securities to benefit their short positions – attracts attentions

103

7.3 Do Investors Become Less Responsive in General?

In this paper, I interpret the finding that investors become less responsive to analyst

revisions as evidence of analysts’ reputation loss after activist short-selling. However, one

alternative explanation is that activist short-selling adds noises to all information signals, including

analyst revisions. As a result, investors would be less responsive to all information signals – not

because they believe analysts less. One cross-sectional test shows that this is unlikely the case.

Specifically, if investors become less responsive to all information signals, why the reduction in

responsiveness is stronger for analysts who were more bullish on the targeted stock prior to the

activist short-selling?

Further, if this alternative explanation is justified, we should expect that investors are also

less responsive to other major information events, such as earnings announcements. To address

this possibility, I examine whether investors become less responsive to quarterly earnings

announcements (QEAs) after activist short-selling. Using all QEAs announced between 180 days

prior to activist short-selling date and 180 days after the date, I estimate the following model:

, 0 1 , 2 , 3 , , 4 ,

5 , , 6 , ,

_ i t i t i t i t i t i t

i t i t i t t t i t

CAR QEA UnexRank Post UnexRank Post Loss

Loss Post PreQEAReturn Year Firm

(4)

Where, CAR_QEA is the three-day cumulative abnormal return centered on the quarterly

earnings announcement date (Fama-French three-factor model adjusted); UnexRank is the decile

rank (transformed to range from zero to one) of unexpected earnings, which is the difference

between EPS and the latest analyst consensus; Post is an indicator whether the QEA is prior to the

activist short-selling date; Loss is an indictor whether the current quarterly EPS is negative or not;

PreQERReturn is the raw return of the stock from the consensus date to the earnings announcement

date. Table 6 presents the results. I include neither year nor firm FE in Column 1, only year FE in

Column 2, and both FEs in Column 3. Across three columns, the coefficient of interest – the

interaction of UnexRank and Post – is insignificantly positive, indicating that investors are not less

responsive to earnings announcements after activist short-selling. This serves as a pseudo test to

rule out the alternative explanation that investors react less to all information signals.

Page 113: Activist Short-Selling - University of Toronto T-Space · Activist short-selling – short-sellers publicly talking down securities to benefit their short positions – attracts attentions

104

8 Conclusion

The prior literature has well documented the optimism from sell-side analysts. As the

business model of this key information intermediary does not incentivize publishing negative

opinion, other market participants, particularly short-sellers, seize the opportunity and meet the

demand of negative information. Different from passive short-selling that is done quietly and

reveals information through the trade (i.e., taking short-positions), activist short-sellers publicly

talk-down stocks and sometimes explicitly accuse of the sell-side’s “talk-up” research as the major

driver of equity overvaluation. Using a large sample of activist short-selling cases from 2006 to

2015, I investigate the consequences of activist short-selling on the sell-side community.

I find that analysts react to activist short-selling by revising their target-price and EPS

forecasts on the target firms. Further, the variation in the timeliness and directions of their

responses can be explained by the initial market reaction to the activist short-selling, and the ability

and incentive of analysts. Consistent with the notion that analysts have a strong motivation to react

to short-selling allegations, I find that they on average suffer from serious reputation loss such that

the market are about 30% less sensitive to their earnings revisions. Further, I find that the

reputation loss is weaker or avoided if the analyst is not-so-bullish prior to the activist short-selling,

or the market reaction suggests that the short-seller is wrong. Also, if the reputation loss could be

largely avoided if analysts react very quickly, but either revising down or revising up does not

make a big difference in saving reputation loss. Finally, I find that analysts whose covered firms

are targeted by activist short-sellers are more likely to move to smaller brokerage houses in the

next three years.

In addition to the contribution to the literature on analysts and short-sellers, this paper can

inform the policy debate on the benefits of activist short-selling. The results from this paper show

that encouraging activist short-selling may help to discipline the sell-side community, and as a

result contributing to a more efficient capital market.

Page 114: Activist Short-Selling - University of Toronto T-Space · Activist short-selling – short-sellers publicly talking down securities to benefit their short positions – attracts attentions

105

References of Chapter 2 Aitken, M. J., Frino, A., McCorry, M. S., & Swan, P. L. (1998). Short sales are almost

instantaneously bad news: Evidence from the Australian Stock Exchange. The Journal of

Finance, 53(6), 2205-2223.

Becker, B., & Milbourn, T. (2011). How did increased competition affect credit ratings? Journal

of Financial Economics, 101(3), 493-514.

Beyer, A., & Guttman, I. (2011). The effect of trading volume on analysts’ forecast bias. The

Accounting Review, 86(2), 451-481.

Boehmer, E., Jones, C. M., & Zhang, X. (2015). What do short sellers know? Available at SSRN

2192958.

Brown, L. D., Call, A. C., Clement, M. B., & Sharp, N. Y. (2015). Inside the “Black Box” of sell‐side financial analysts. Journal of Accounting Research, 53(1), 1-47.

Brown, P., Foster, G., & Noreen, E. (1985). Security analyst multi-year earnings forecasts and the

capital market (No. 21). American Accounting Association.

Chen, S., & Matsumoto, D. A. (2006). Favorable versus unfavorable recommendations: The

impact on analyst access to management‐provided information. Journal of Accounting

Research, 44(4), 657-689.

Christophe, S. E., Ferri, M. G., & Hsieh, J. (2010). Informed trading before analyst downgrades:

Evidence from short sellers. Journal of Financial Economics, 95(1), 85-106.

Clement, M. B., & Law, K. (2016). Labor market dynamics and analyst ability. Working paper.

University of Texas at Austin.

De Long, J. B., Shleifer, A., Summers, L. H., & Waldmann, R. J. (1990). Noise trader risk in

financial markets. Journal of Political Economy, 98(4), 703-738.

Dechow, P. M., Hutton, A. P., Meulbroek, L., & Sloan, R. G. (2001). Short-sellers, fundamental

analysis, and stock returns. Journal of Financial Economics, 61(1), 77-106.

Doherty, N. A., Kartasheva, A. V., & Phillips, R. D. (2012). Information effect of entry into credit

ratings market: The case of insurers' ratings. Journal of Financial Economics, 106(2), 308-

330.

Drake, M. S., Rees, L., & Swanson, E. P. (2011). Should investors follow the prophets or the bears?

Evidence on the use of public information by analysts and short sellers. The Accounting

Review, 86(1), 101-130.

Francis, J., & Philbrick, D. (1993). Analysts' decisions as products of a multi-task

environment. Journal of Accounting Research, 216-230.

Hayes, R. M. (1998). The impact of trading commission incentives on analysts' stock coverage

decisions and earnings forecasts. Journal of Accounting Research, 36(2), 299-320.

Hong, H., & Kacperczyk, M. (2010). Competition and bias. The Quarterly Journal of

Economics, 125(4), 1683-1725.

Hong, H., & Kubik, J. D. (2003). Analyzing the analysts: Career concerns and biased earnings

forecasts. The Journal of Finance, 58(1), 313-351.

Hong, H., Kubik, J. D., & Solomon, A. (2000). Security analysts' career concerns and herding of

earnings forecasts. The Rand journal of economics, 121-144.

Jackson, A. R. (2005). Trade generation, reputation, and sell‐side analysts. The Journal of

Finance, 60(2), 673-717.

Jame, R., Markov, S., & Wolfe, M. C. (2017). Does crowdsourced research discipline sell-side

analysts? Working paper. University of Kentucky.

Page 115: Activist Short-Selling - University of Toronto T-Space · Activist short-selling – short-sellers publicly talking down securities to benefit their short positions – attracts attentions

106

Jegadeesh, N., Kim, J., Krische, S. D., & Lee, C. (2004). Analyzing the analysts: When do

recommendations add value? The Journal of Finance, 59(3), 1083-1124.

Karpoff, J. M., & Lou, X. (2010). Short sellers and financial misconduct. The Journal of

Finance, 65(5), 1879-1913.

Ke, B., & Yu, Y. (2006). The effect of issuing biased earnings forecasts on analysts' access to

management and survival. Journal of Accounting Research, 44(5), 965-999.

Kothari, S. P., Shu, S., & Wysocki, P. D. (2009). Do managers withhold bad news? Journal of

Accounting Research, 47(1), 241-276.

Lee, L. F., & Lo, A. K. (2016). Do opinions on financial misstatement firms affect analysts’

reputation with investors? Evidence from reputational spillovers. Journal of Accounting

Research, 54(4), 1111-1148.

Lin, H. W., & McNichols, M. F. (1998). Underwriting relationships, analysts' earnings forecasts

and investment recommendations. Journal of Accounting and Economics, 25(1), 101-127.

Ljungqvist, A., & Qian, W. (2016). How constraining are limits to arbitrage? Review of Financial

Studies, 29(8), 1975- 2028.

McNichols, M., & O'Brien, P. C. (1997). Self-selection and analyst coverage. Journal of

Accounting Research, 35, 167-199.

Michaely, R., & Womack, K. L. (1999). Conflict of interest and the credibility of underwriter

analyst recommendations. Review of Financial Studies, 12(4), 653-686.

Merkley, K. J., Michaely, R., & Pacelli, J. M. (2016). Does the scope of sell-side analyst industry

matter? An examination of bias, accuracy and information content of analyst reports. The

Journal of Finance, Forthcoming.

Mola, S., & Guidolin, M. (2009). Affiliated mutual funds and analyst optimism. Journal of

Financial Economics, 93(1), 108-137.

Park, C. W., & Stice, E. K. (2000). Analyst forecasting ability and the stock price reaction to

forecast revisions. Review of Accounting Studies, 5(3), 259-272.

Richardson, S., Teoh, S. H., & Wysocki, P. D. (2004). The walk‐down to beatable analyst forecasts:

The role of equity issuance and insider trading incentives. Contemporary Accounting

Research, 21(4), 885-924.

Soltes, E. (2014). Private interaction between firm management and sell‐side analysts. Journal of

Accounting Research, 52(1), 245-272.

Stickel, S. E. (1992). Reputation and performance among security analysts. The Journal of

Finance, 47(5), 1811-1836.

Xia, H. (2014). Can investor-paid credit rating agencies improve the information quality of issuer-

paid rating agencies? Journal of Financial Economics, 111(2), 450-468.

Zhao, W. (2017). Activist Short-Selling. Working paper. Rotman School of Management.

Page 116: Activist Short-Selling - University of Toronto T-Space · Activist short-selling – short-sellers publicly talking down securities to benefit their short positions – attracts attentions

107

Appendices of Chapter 2

Appendix A: Variable Definitions

Variables Definitions

Delay The log of one plus the number of days from activist short-selling to the

first target price revision

Raise Indicator. One if the first target price revision after activist short-selling is

to raise the target price.

ShortsImpact

The impact of activist short-selling, measured as (-1) * CR(0, 1), where

CR(0, 1) is the raw return of the target firm in the first two-day window

after activist short-selling

BrokSize

The brokerage house size of the analyst, measured as the log of one plus the

number of unique analysts providing EPS forecasts in that year

LnCovDays

The coverage history, measured as the log of one plus the number of days

since the analyst provided the first EPS forecast on the firm

PreTalkUp

Analysts talk-up behavior prior to the activist short-selling, measured as the

decile rank of all analysts’ last target price forecasts on a given firm prior to

activist short-selling. I then transform it into ranging from 0 to 1 such that

the 10% most bullish forecasts are given the value of 1 and the 10% least

bullish forecasts are given the value of 0.

AnaExperience Analyst experience, measured as the log of one plus the number of years the

analyst has been in IBES universe.

LnCovFirm

Number of covered firms, measured by the log of one plus the number of

unique firms the analyst is providing EPS forecasts in the year

LnCoverage Number of analyst covering the firm, measured by the log of one plus the

number of unique analysts who are providing EPS to the firm in the year.

TPFrequency

Target price forecasting frequency, measured as the log of one plus the

number of times the analyst has provided target price forecast on the firm in

the 90 days prior to the activist short-selling

Size

The size of the firm, measured by the log of one plus the total assets at the

beginning of the fiscal year

Leverage

The leverage of the firm, measured by the ratio of total liabilities to total

assets at the beginning of the fiscal year

BTM

The book-to-market ratio, measured by the ratio of book value of equity to

the total market capitalization at the beginning of the fiscal year.

CAR(0, 1) Cumulative abnormal return in a two-day window starting from the EPS

revision date adjusted by Fama-French three-factor model. Factor loadings

are estimated in a 110-day pre-event window ending 30 trading days before

the CAR windows starts (the same procedure for all CARs)

CAR(-1, 1) Cumulative abnormal return in a three-day window centered on the EPS

revision date

CAR(0, 2)

Cumulative abnormal return in a three-day window starting from the EPS

revision date

CAR(-2, 2)

Cumulative abnormal return in a five-day window centered on the EPS

revision date

Page 117: Activist Short-Selling - University of Toronto T-Space · Activist short-selling – short-sellers publicly talking down securities to benefit their short positions – attracts attentions

108

Post

Indicator. One if the EPS revision (or QEA in Supplemental Analyses)

happens after the activist short-selling, and zero otherwise

RevRank

The decile rank of the peer firm’s analyst forecast revision magnitude. The

magnitude is the revised EPS forecast minus the previous EPS forecast by

one analyst for the same fiscal quarter scaled by the beginning-of-quarter

share price ((FEPSrevised – FEPSprevious) / PRICEbeginning-of-quarter). Then I

transform this variable into decile rank and scale the rank to make it range

from 0 to 1.

More Talk-up Analysts whose last target price forecast on a certain target before activist

short-selling is higher than median. Otherwise they are defined as Less

Talk-up

Shorts Seem

Wrong

The first two-day return (i.e., CR(0, 1)) starting on the activist short-selling

date is negative. Otherwise it’s Shorts Seem Right

Bottom Quartile

Delay

I rank the time an analyst takes to respond to an activist short-selling case

attacking her covered stock (i.e., the delay). Those observations with the

bottom quartile of delay are defined as Bottom Quartile Delay. The next

two quartiles are defined as Middle Delay. The top quartile is defined as

Top Quartile Delay.

Raise Target

Price

Analysts who raise target price after activist short-selling. Otherwise it’s

defined as Lower Target Price

Move Down in

1/2/3 years

Indicator. One if an analyst moves down to a lower-ranked brokerage house

one/two/three years after the activist short-selling. I rank the brokerage

houses every year and rank them into percentiles based on their number of

analysts.

Exit in 1/2/3

years

Indicator. One if an analyst produces at least one EPS forecast in year t but

stops to produce EPS forecasts in year t+1/2/3.

AffectedAnalyst

Indicator. One if an analysts has at least one covered firm being targeted by

activist short-sellers in that year, and zero otherwise.

NumCovTarget

Number of covered firms that are targeted by activist short-sellers in that

year.

CAR_QEA

Three-day cumulative abnormal return centered on the quarterly earnings

announcement date (Fama-French three-factor model adjusted).

UnexRank

The decile rank (transformed to range from zero to one) of unexpected

earnings, which is the difference between EPS and the latest analyst

consensus.

Loss Indictor. One if the current quarterly EPS is negative, and zero otherwise.

PreQERReturn

The raw return of the stock from the consensus date to the earnings

announcement date.

Page 118: Activist Short-Selling - University of Toronto T-Space · Activist short-selling – short-sellers publicly talking down securities to benefit their short positions – attracts attentions

109

Main Tables of Chapter 2 Table 1: The Variation in Analysts’ Reactions to Activist Short-Selling

This table examines the determinants of variation in analysts’ reactions after activist short-selling. I focus on the target

price revisions by analysts who provide at least one target price forecasts on the target firm in the 90 days before

activist short-selling. All observations are at the firm-year-analyst level.

Panel A provides summary statistics. Panel B presents regression results based on OLS models. Variables are defined

in Appendix A. t statistics in parentheses are based on standard errors clustered by analyst. * p < 0.1, ** p < 0.05, ***

p < 0.01 (two-sided tests)

Panel A: Summary statistics

Variables Obs. Mean STD 1st Quartile Median 3rd Quartile

Delay 11,227 3.666 1.079 3.091 3.892 4.443

Raise 11,227 0.495 0.500 0.000 0.000 1.000

ShortsImpact 11,227 0.026 0.067 -0.008 0.017 0.048

BrokSize 11,227 3.083 1.668 0.693 3.555 4.554

LnCovDays 11,227 6.636 1.404 5.855 6.821 7.630

PreTalkUp 11,227 0.476 0.359 0.111 0.444 0.778

AnaExperience 11,227 1.743 0.875 0.527 1.946 2.485

LnCovFirm 11,227 2.182 1.080 0.527 2.639 2.996

LnCoverage 11,227 2.023 1.084 0.693 2.303 2.996

TPFrequency 11,227 0.867 0.250 0.693 0.693 1.099

Size 11,227 8.172 1.936 6.693 8.122 9.540

Leverage 11,227 0.534 0.262 0.318 0.535 0.716

BTM 11,227 0.475 1.216 0.139 0.287 0.527

Page 119: Activist Short-Selling - University of Toronto T-Space · Activist short-selling – short-sellers publicly talking down securities to benefit their short positions – attracts attentions

110

Panel B: Determinants of analyst reactions after activist short-selling (based on target prices)

(1) (2)

Delay Raise

ShortsImpact -2.1731*** -1.4285***

(-6.65) (-12.11)

BrokSize -0.0624*** -0.0081

(-5.33) (-1.59)

LnCovDays 0.0893*** 0.0058

(9.04) (1.60)

PreTalkUp 0.0855*** -0.1625***

(3.39) (-15.15)

AnaExperience -0.0829*** -0.0049

(-3.38) (-0.51)

LnCovFirm -0.1212*** -0.0053

(-4.58) (-0.52)

LnCoverage 0.0330*** -0.0180***

(3.07) (-3.99)

TPFrequency -0.0604 0.0497***

(-1.36) (2.83)

Size -0.0155 -0.0962***

(-0.41) (-5.62)

Leverage 0.2313 0.0798

(1.53) (1.16)

BTM 0.0951*** 0.0276***

(4.47) (2.68)

Year FE YES YES

Firm FE YES YES

Constant 4.0003*** 1.2324***

(11.24) (7.83)

Observations 11,227 11,227

Adjusted R2 0.213 0.394

Page 120: Activist Short-Selling - University of Toronto T-Space · Activist short-selling – short-sellers publicly talking down securities to benefit their short positions – attracts attentions

111

Table 2: Selling Analysts’ Reputation Short: Main Results

This table reports whether activist short-selling damages analysts’ reputation. I focus on the market reactions to EPS

revisions made in 180 days before and after activist short-selling.

Panel provides summary statistics. Panel B presents regression results. Variables are defined in Appendix A. t statistics

in parentheses are based on standard errors clustered by analyst. * p < 0.1, ** p < 0.05, *** p < 0.01 (two-sided tests)

Panel A: Summary statistics

Variables Obs. Mean STD 1st Quartile Median 3rd Quartile

CAR(0, 1) 17,741 -0.004 0.123 -0.030 -0.001 0.026

CAR(-1, 1) 17,740 -0.003 0.105 -0.040 -0.002 0.034

CAR(0, 2) 17,740 -0.004 0.132 -0.036 -0.001 0.030

CAR(-2, 2) 17,731 -0.004 0.112 -0.051 -0.002 0.041

Post 17,741 0.387 0.487 0.000 0.000 1.000

RevRank 17,741 0.500 0.319 0.222 0.556 0.778

Size 17,741 8.561 1.897 7.184 8.661 9.966

Lev 17,741 0.555 0.258 0.350 0.557 0.724

BTM 17,741 0.480 1.117 0.166 0.322 0.613

Panel B: Selling analysts’ reputation short: regression results

(1) (2) (3) (4)

CAR(0,1) CAR(-1, 1) CAR(0, 2) CAR(-2, 2)

Post 0.0059* 0.0037 0.0055 0.0029

(1.94) (1.13) (1.63) (0.76)

RevRank 0.0438*** 0.0505*** 0.0433*** 0.0519***

(11.10) (13.44) (10.01) (12.52)

RevRank*Post -0.0114** -0.0150*** -0.0128** -0.0157**

(-2.22) (-2.83) (-2.19) (-2.50)

Size -0.0150*** -0.0186*** -0.0157*** -0.0154***

(-4.28) (-3.92) (-3.90) (-2.84)

Leverage -0.0755*** -0.0063 -0.0776*** 0.0090

(-4.02) (-0.44) (-3.88) (0.63)

BTM 0.0007 0.0011 -0.0003 0.0008

(0.51) (1.02) (-0.28) (0.60)

Year FE YES YES YES YES

Firm FE YES YES YES YES

Constant 0.1101*** 0.1071*** 0.1215*** 0.0823*

(3.89) (2.68) (3.68) (1.77)

Observations 17,741 17,740 17,740 17,731

Adjusted R2 0.193 0.208 0.188 0.225

Page 121: Activist Short-Selling - University of Toronto T-Space · Activist short-selling – short-sellers publicly talking down securities to benefit their short positions – attracts attentions

112

Table 3: Selling Analysts’ Reputation Short: Cross-Sectional Variation

This table explores the cross-sectional variation in analysts’ reputation loss after activist short-selling. Panel A focuses on how much analysts talk-up the stock prior to the activist short-selling, and whether market’s initial reaction suggests activist short-sellers are right. Main partition variables are defined in

Appendix A. t statistics in parentheses are based on standard errors clustered by analyst. * p < 0.1, ** p < 0.05, *** p < 0.01 (two-sided tests)

Panel A: Previous talk-up and whether shorts are right

(1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6) (7) (8)

DV=CAR(-1, 1) More

Bullish

Less

Bullish

Shorts

Seem

Wrong

Shorts

Seem

Right

More

Bullish &

Shorts

Seem

Wrong

More

Bullish &

Shorts

Seem

Right

Less

Bullish &

Shorts

Seem

Wrong

Less

Bullish &

Shorts

Seem

Right

Post 0.0060 0.0029 0.0012 0.0058 0.0050 0.0078 -0.0013 0.0063

(1.22) (0.59) (0.24) (1.31) (0.75) (1.17) (-0.17) (0.98)

RevRank 0.0531*** 0.0511*** 0.0435*** 0.0512*** 0.0455*** 0.0527*** 0.0453*** 0.0535***

(9.89) (8.90) (8.62) (9.62) (5.83) (7.66) (6.45) (6.19)

RevRank*Post -0.0192** -0.0124 -0.0020 -0.0229*** -0.0086 -0.0276** 0.0001 -0.0201**

(-2.31) (-1.63) (-0.26) (-3.16) (-0.80) (-2.35) (0.01) (-2.03)

Size -0.0241*** -0.0123*** 0.0019 -0.0274*** 0.0026 -0.0338*** 0.0033 -0.0207***

(-3.14) (-2.62) (0.23) (-5.96) (0.22) (-5.13) (0.25) (-3.10)

Leverage -0.0166 0.0034 -0.0498** 0.0058 -0.0566* -0.0084 -0.0452 0.0241

(-0.77) (0.18) (-2.19) (0.24) (-1.89) (-0.31) (-1.36) (0.64)

BTM 0.0020 0.0002 -0.0027 0.0023* -0.0036 0.0035** -0.0014 0.0007

(1.27) (0.12) (-1.36) (1.69) (-1.07) (2.09) (-0.60) (0.43)

Year FE YES YES YES YES YES YES YES YES

Firm FE YES YES YES YES YES YES YES YES

Constant 0.1574** 0.0501 0.0273 0.0735* 0.0393 0.1139* -0.0042 0.0210

(2.42) (1.18) (0.36) (1.74) (0.35) (1.94) (-0.04) (0.33)

Observations 8,542 9,198 6,241 11,499 2,994 5,548 3,247 5,951

Adjusted R2 0.250 0.175 0.278 0.210 0.285 0.268 0.293 0.166

Page 122: Activist Short-Selling - University of Toronto T-Space · Activist short-selling – short-sellers publicly talking down securities to benefit their short positions – attracts attentions

113

Panel B: The timeliness of analysts’ reactions

(1) (2) (3)

DV = CAR(-1, 1) Bottom Quartile

Delay

Middle

Delay

Top Quartile Delay

Post 0.0039 0.0076 0.0089

(0.64) (1.28) (1.30)

RevRank 0.0553*** 0.0545*** 0.0526***

(6.33) (9.33) (6.82)

RevRank*Post -0.0164 -0.0195** -0.0290***

(-1.50) (-2.12) (-2.66)

Size -0.0399*** -0.0194*** -0.0215***

(-3.15) (-3.37) (-2.78)

Leverage -0.0297 -0.0011 0.0485*

(-0.69) (-0.06) (1.79)

BTM -0.0035 -0.0016 0.0089**

(-1.19) (-0.75) (2.13)

Year FE YES YES YES

Firm FE YES YES YES

Constant 0.2586** 0.1179** 0.1054

(2.43) (2.23) (1.61)

Observations 4,157 8,175 4,074

Adjusted R2 0.181 0.195 0.239

Page 123: Activist Short-Selling - University of Toronto T-Space · Activist short-selling – short-sellers publicly talking down securities to benefit their short positions – attracts attentions

114

Panel C: The directions of analysts’ reactions

(1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6)

DV = CAR(-1, 1) Lower TP Raise TP Shorts

Seem Right

& Lower TP

Shorts

Seem Right

&Raise TP

Shorts

Seem Wrong

& Lower TP

Shorts

Seem Wrong

& Raise TP

Post 0.0046 0.0089 0.0081 0.0093 -0.0017 0.0097

(1.05) (1.60) (1.40) (1.15) (-0.24) (1.37)

RevRank 0.0431*** 0.0637*** 0.0465*** 0.0652*** 0.0338*** 0.0587***

(8.96) (9.75) (6.95) (6.61) (4.78) (7.33)

RevRank*Post -0.0202** -0.0215*** -0.0294*** -0.0267** -0.0002 -0.0180*

(-2.51) (-2.71) (-2.70) (-2.33) (-0.02) (-1.68)

Size -0.0075 -0.0197*** -0.0183** -0.0310*** 0.0086 -0.0033

(-1.30) (-3.22) (-2.47) (-3.63) (0.68) (-0.27)

Leverage -0.0051 0.0196 -0.0181 0.1323*** -0.0185 -0.0697

(-0.27) (0.82) (-0.55) (2.63) (-0.44) (-1.38)

BTM -0.0042** 0.0098** -0.0036 0.0127* -0.0066*** 0.0082

(-2.13) (2.23) (-0.58) (1.79) (-2.96) (0.54)

Year FE YES YES YES YES YES YES

Firm FE YES YES YES YES YES YES

Constant 0.0079 0.1144** 0.0435 0.0033 -0.0538 0.0707

(0.15) (2.12) (0.52) (0.04) (-0.45) (0.61)

Observations 8,957 7,449 6,129 4,475 2,828 2,974

Adjusted R2 0.222 0.173 0.241 0.144 0.181 0.337

Page 124: Activist Short-Selling - University of Toronto T-Space · Activist short-selling – short-sellers publicly talking down securities to benefit their short positions – attracts attentions

115

Table 4: Analysts’ Careers after Activist Short-Selling

This table examines whether and how activist short-selling affects analysts’ future career path. I focus on whether an

analyst moves down to a smaller brokerage house one, two, and three years after activist short-selling. Panel A

provides summary statistics. Panel B presents regression results. All variables are defined in Appendix A. t statistics

in parentheses are based on standard errors clustered by analyst. * p < 0.1, ** p < 0.05, *** p < 0.01 (two-sided tests)

Panel A: Summary statistics

Variables Obs. Mean STD 1st Quartile Median 3rd Quartile

Move Down in 1 year 26,552 0.046 0.210 0.000 0.000 0.000

Move Down in 2 years 19,927 0.096 0.295 0.000 0.000 0.000

Move Down in 3 years 15,400 0.134 0.341 0.000 0.000 0.000

AffectedAnalyst 26,552 0.346 0.476 0.000 0.000 1.000

NumCoverTargets 9,186 2.065 1.632 1.000 1.000 3.000

BrokSize 26,552 3.722 1.078 2.996 3.761 4.673

LnCovFirm 26,552 2.421 0.714 2.079 2.639 2.944

AnaExperience 26,552 1.884 0.691 1.386 1.946 2.398

Exit in 1 year 32,910 0.193 0.395 0.000 0.000 0.000

Exit in 2 years 29,867 0.318 0.466 0.000 0.000 1.000

Exit in 3 years 26,625 0.402 0.490 0.000 0.000 1.000

Page 125: Activist Short-Selling - University of Toronto T-Space · Activist short-selling – short-sellers publicly talking down securities to benefit their short positions – attracts attentions

116

Panel B: Analysts’ careers after activist short-selling: moving down

(1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6)

All Analysts Only Affected Analysts

DV = Move Down In 1 year In 2 year In 3 year In 1 year In 2 year In 3 year

AffectedAnalyst 0.0067** 0.0134** 0.0165**

(2.09) (2.36) (2.18)

BrokSize -0.0263*** -0.0474*** -0.0732*** -0.0294*** -0.0522*** -0.0779***

(-19.07) (-17.63) (-18.61) (-11.70) (-10.92) (-11.36)

LnCovFirm 0.0107*** 0.0152*** 0.0228*** 0.0008 -0.0068 -0.0075

(5.37) (3.76) (3.95) (0.18) (-0.72) (-0.56)

AnaExperience -0.0039* -0.0064 -0.0205*** -0.0007 -0.0067 -0.0241**

(-1.78) (-1.49) (-3.25) (-0.17) (-0.89) (-2.12)

NumCovTargets 0.0046*** 0.0084*** 0.0154***

(2.92) (2.99) (3.06)

Year FE YES YES YES YES YES YES

Constant 0.1278*** 0.2403*** 0.3849*** 0.1487*** 0.3139*** 0.4962***

(15.61) (16.03) (17.85) (8.27) (9.68) (10.60)

Observations 26,552 20,367 15,934 9,186 6,691 4,696

Adjusted R2 0.020 0.031 0.052 0.019 0.030 0.052

Page 126: Activist Short-Selling - University of Toronto T-Space · Activist short-selling – short-sellers publicly talking down securities to benefit their short positions – attracts attentions

117

Panel C: Analysts’ career after activist short-selling: exit

(1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6)

All Analysts Only Affected Analysts

DV = Exit In 1 year In 2 years In 3 years In 1 year In 2 years In 3 years

AffectedAnalyst -0.0311*** -0.0213*** -0.0138*

(-6.55) (-3.18) (-1.70)

BrokSize -0.0118*** -0.0173*** -0.0197*** -0.0055* -0.0109** -0.0240***

(-5.85) (-5.68) (-5.21) (-1.73) (-2.16) (-3.53)

LnCovFirm -0.1371*** -0.1576*** -0.1602*** -0.1190*** -0.1504*** -0.1741***

(-35.52) (-29.24) (-24.88) (-15.43) (-13.84) (-12.84)

AnaExperience -0.0055 -0.0440*** -0.0597*** -0.0273*** -0.0675*** -0.0853***

(-1.43) (-7.63) (-8.27) (-4.75) (-7.42) (-6.86)

NumCovTargets -0.0048*** -0.0056* -0.0014

(-2.79) (-1.88) (-0.29)

Year FE YES YES YES YES YES YES

Constant 0.5701*** 0.8403*** 0.9858*** 0.5438*** 0.8765*** 1.1073***

(44.91) (49.30) (49.88) (19.97) (24.13) (25.53)

Observations 32,910 29,867 26,625 10,488 8,720 6,813

Adjusted R2 0.085 0.098 0.097 0.062 0.078 0.084

Page 127: Activist Short-Selling - University of Toronto T-Space · Activist short-selling – short-sellers publicly talking down securities to benefit their short positions – attracts attentions

Table 5: Cross-Sectional Variation in Analyst Reactions after Activist Short-Selling (Based

on Quarterly EPS Forecasts)

This table examines the determinants of variation in analysts’ reactions after activist short-selling using quarterly EPS

forecasts. I focus on the EPS revisions by analysts who provide at least one EPS forecast on the target firm in the 90

days before activist short-selling. All observations are at the firm-year-analyst level. Variables are defined in Appendix

A. t statistics in parentheses are based on standard errors clustered by analyst. * p < 0.1, ** p < 0.05, *** p < 0.01

(two-sided tests)

(1) (2)

Delay Raise

ShortsImpact -0.0047 -0.6137***

(-0.01) (-4.04)

BrokSize -0.0085 -0.0087*

(-0.73) (-1.85)

LnCovDays 0.0887*** -0.0042

(7.16) (-0.77)

PreTalkUp -0.0226 -0.1366***

(-0.84) (-10.90)

AnaExperience -0.0189 -0.0055

(-0.74) (-0.49)

LnCovFirm -0.1372*** -0.0108

(-5.22) (-0.91)

LnCoverage 0.3296*** 0.0588**

(5.23) (2.04)

TPFrequency -0.0663 0.0212

(-1.48) (1.05)

Size -0.1345*** -0.1446***

(-3.02) (-6.89)

Leverage 0.4881*** 0.1207

(2.87) (1.59)

BTM 0.0514*** 0.0224***

(3.83) (3.19)

Year FE YES YES

Firm FE YES YES

Constant 3.6033*** 1.5149***

(8.86) (7.95)

Observations 10,195 10,195

Adjusted R2 0.279 0.225

Page 128: Activist Short-Selling - University of Toronto T-Space · Activist short-selling – short-sellers publicly talking down securities to benefit their short positions – attracts attentions

119

Table 6: Market Reactions to Quarterly Earnings Announcements

This table examines the whether investors become less responsive to quarterly earnings announcements after activist

short-selling. All observations are at the firm-QEA (quarterly earnings announcement) level. Variables are defined in

Appendix A. t statistics in parentheses are based on standard errors clustered by firm. * p < 0.1, ** p < 0.05, *** p <

0.01 (two-sided tests)

(1) (2) (3)

CAR_QEA CAR_QEA CAR_QEA

UnexRank 0.0775*** 0.0774*** 0.1180***

(9.79) (9.80) (10.65)

Post -0.0028 -0.0028 -0.0064

(-0.70) (-0.72) (-1.43)

UnexRank × Post 0.0005 0.0006 0.0064

(0.07) (0.09) (0.83)

Loss -0.0082 -0.0083 0.0312***

(-1.44) (-1.45) (3.49)

UnexRank × Loss -0.0200 -0.0197 -0.1352***

(-1.14) (-1.12) (-5.19)

PreQEAReturn -0.0349** -0.0366*** -0.0458***

(-2.55) (-2.66) (-2.85)

Year NO YES YES

Firm NO NO YES

Constant -0.0412*** -0.0412*** -0.0672***

(-7.90) (-7.90) (-4.33)

Observations 9,079 9,079 9,079

Adjusted R2 0.082 0.083 0.118

Page 129: Activist Short-Selling - University of Toronto T-Space · Activist short-selling – short-sellers publicly talking down securities to benefit their short positions – attracts attentions

120

Main Figures of Chapter 2 Figure 1: The Year Distribution of the Firm-year Level Activist Short-Selling

This figure presents the year distribution of firm-year observations. Note the sample starts from Zhao’s

(2016) 6,081 activist short-selling cases from 2006 to 2015. Then for each firm-year, I focus on the activist

short-selling case that presents the lowest two-day return starting from the announcement date.

Page 130: Activist Short-Selling - University of Toronto T-Space · Activist short-selling – short-sellers publicly talking down securities to benefit their short positions – attracts attentions

121

Figure 2: Replicating Ljungvist and Qian (2016) Results Regarding Analyst

Recommendations

This figure is to replicate the observation in Ljungqvist and Qian (2016) that the proportion of buy and sell

recommendations are largely stable before and after activist short-selling. This figure presents the number

of five types of recommendations for sample firms in each period (i.e., one period = five days). For example,

there are about 250 Hold recommendations in the first five days after activist short-selling.

Page 131: Activist Short-Selling - University of Toronto T-Space · Activist short-selling – short-sellers publicly talking down securities to benefit their short positions – attracts attentions

122

Figure 3: Number of Analysts Raised or Lowered Target Prices in 18 Five-day Intervals

Before and After the Activist Short-Selling

This figure is to show that analysts react to activist short-selling by revising target prices. In both panels,

the blue solid line represents the number of revisions that lower target prices and the red dash line represents

the number of revisions that raise target prices in each five-day period. Panel A (B) reports the number of

revisions around activist short-selling with negative (positive) first two-day returns.

Panel A: Targeted firms of which shorts seem to be right

Panel B: Targeted firms of which the shorts seem to be wrong

Page 132: Activist Short-Selling - University of Toronto T-Space · Activist short-selling – short-sellers publicly talking down securities to benefit their short positions – attracts attentions

123

Figure 4: Number of Analysts Raised or Lowered Quarterly EPS Forecasts in 18 five-day

Intervals Before and After the Activist Short-Selling

This figure is to show that analysts react to activist short-selling by revising EPS forecasts. In both panels,

the blue solid line represents the number of revisions that lower EPS forecasts and the red dash line

represents the number of revisions that raise EPS forecasts in each five-day period. Panel A (B) reports the

number of revisions around activist short-selling with negative (positive) first two-day returns.

Panel A: Targeted firms of which the shorts seem to be right

Panel B: Targeted firms of which the shorts seem to be wrong