William Roseberry -- La Falta de Brazos

31
La Falta de Brazos Land and labor in the coffee economies of nineteenth-century Latin America WILLIAM ROSEBERRY New School for Social Research A persistent problem for anthropologists and historians attempting to understand social change in rural Latin America is the placement of local regions within wider - global and "national" - economic, social, and political frameworks) One temptation is to subsume the local within the global, to make the "system" - "capitalist" or "modern" - determinative, as in the more extreme versions of dependency and world-system theories that dominated the literature in the 1960s and 1970s. Another temptation is to avoid the problem altogether, to reject any discussion of global political and economic pressures as totalizing, reductive, or teleological. This view, increasingly popular over the past decade, would have us reject the ''fiction of the whole"2 Although both perspectives, as extremes, can point to respectable intellectual pedigrees and can attract the sympathetic attention of theo- retically inclined scholars, the student examining substantive problems and aspects of social change in, say, Silo Paulo or Antioquia of the 1920s must remain skeptical. Confronting the global extremists, she or he will agree that Antioquia was dominated by a coffee economy that had drawn the region toward the centers of world economy; yet the very shape of that economy, its most basic social relations and contra- dictions, were fundamentally different from other coffee economies that emerged at roughly the same time. Trying to understand why Antioquia looked different, she or he will begin to explore the settle- ment of the relatively open frontier, the prior emergence of a gold pan- ning movement, the accumulation of capital by urban merchants buying up gold, and their investment of accumulated resources in land and coffee. In short, the "global" begins to recede from view and the "local" seems predominant. Yet it hardly seems helpful to dismiss the whole as a "fiction?' Our student of 1920s Antioquia cannot ignore the Theory and Society 20: 351-382, 1991. 1991 KluwerAcademic Publishers. Printed in the Netherlands.

description

William Roseberry - La falta de brazos

Transcript of William Roseberry -- La Falta de Brazos

  • La Falta de Brazos

    Land and labor in the coffee economies of nineteenth-century Latin America

    WILLIAM ROSEBERRY New School for Social Research

    A persistent problem for anthropologists and historians attempting to understand social change in rural Latin America is the placement of local regions within wider - global and "national" - economic, social, and political frameworks) One temptation is to subsume the local within the global, to make the "system" - "capitalist" or "modern" - determinative, as in the more extreme versions of dependency and world-system theories that dominated the literature in the 1960s and 1970s. Another temptation is to avoid the problem altogether, to reject any discussion of global political and economic pressures as totalizing, reductive, or teleological. This view, increasingly popular over the past decade, would have us reject the ''fiction of the whole "2

    Although both perspectives, as extremes, can point to respectable intellectual pedigrees and can attract the sympathetic attention of theo- retically inclined scholars, the student examining substantive problems and aspects of social change in, say, Silo Paulo or Antioquia of the 1920s must remain skeptical. Confronting the global extremists, she or he will agree that Antioquia was dominated by a coffee economy that had drawn the region toward the centers of world economy; yet the very shape of that economy, its most basic social relations and contra- dictions, were fundamentally different from other coffee economies that emerged at roughly the same time. Trying to understand why Antioquia looked different, she or he will begin to explore the settle- ment of the relatively open frontier, the prior emergence of a gold pan- ning movement, the accumulation of capital by urban merchants buying up gold, and their investment of accumulated resources in land and coffee. In short, the "global" begins to recede from view and the "local" seems predominant. Yet it hardly seems helpful to dismiss the whole as a "fiction?' Our student of 1920s Antioquia cannot ignore the

    Theory and Society 20: 351-382, 1991. 9 1991 KluwerAcademic Publishers. Printed in the Netherlands.

  • 352

    massive investment of North American finance capital during the "dance of the millions" directed toward the construction of roads and railroads and the acquisition of controlling shares in local banks and exporting firms. And she or he cannot forget that the 1920s were fol- lowed by the 1930s, the general depression and the collapse of the world coffee market. The confident assertions of the postmodern theo- fist, telling us that we can relegate the world-system to the back- ground, 3 begin to lose some of their seductive appeal in the face of such events and movements. A more careful reading of global and local histories is necessary.

    One form of sociological understanding that needs to be recovered if we are to understand the contradictory formation of human subjects at the conjunction of global and local histories is that sketched by E H. Cardoso and Enzo Faletto in their call for studies of the "internaliza- tion of the external" in Latin America. Surveying the emergence of capitalism in various Latin American countries, they argue:

    The very existence of an economic "periphery" cannot be understood without reference to the economic drive of advanced capitalist economies, which were responsible for the formation of a capitalist periphery and for the integration of traditional noncapitalist economies into the world market. Yet, the expansion of capitalism in Bolivia and Venezuela, in Mexico or Peru, in Brazil and Argentina, in spite of having been submitted to the same global dynamic of international capitalism, did not have the same history or conse- quences. The differences are rooted not only in the diversity of natural resources, nor just in the different periods in which these economies have been incorporated into the international system (although these factors have played some role). Their explanation must also lie in the different moments at which sectors of local classes allied or clashed with foreign interests, organized different forms of state, sustained distinct ideologies, or tried to implement various policies or defined alternative strategies to cope with imperialist challenges in diverse moments of history. 4

    What we need, according to this view, is a "history of... diversity," a sense that "the history of capital accumulation is the history of class struggles, of political movements, of the affirmation of ideologies, and of the establishment of forms of domination and reactions against them. ''5 A history of diversity is necessarily comparative. One way of approaching such a comparison is to examine the various regions that produced a particular export commodity during a particular period - coffee, say, during the late nineteenth and early twentieth centuries. All such regions would be subject to certain common global pressures; they would be experiencing the same "world historical fact "'6 Yet an understanding of the particular forms and dynamics of social and eco-

  • 353

    nomic relations in the various regions would require careful attention to local contexts, local fields of power. This essay is directed toward such a comparative history.

    The comparative problem

    The nineteenth century (that is, roughly, from 1830-1930) was the cof- fee century in Latin America. It was a period that witnessed a dramatic increase in world trade (from 320 metric tons in 1770, mostly from Asia; to 90,000 metric tons in 1820, with half coming from Brazil; to 450,000 metric tons in 1870 and 1,600,000 metric tons in 19207 ) and per capita consumption (in the United States, from 3 pounds in 1830 to 10 pounds in 1900 and 16 pounds in 19608). And it was a period in which coffee production was associated with a profound transforma- tion of landscape and society in several Latin American regions. In most cases, the expansion of coffee cultivation coincided with terri- torial expansion, the movement of settlers into frontier zones where tropical forests were destroyed, "new forests ''9 of coffee and shade planted, towns established, roads and railroads built, regional identities forged.

    It is not surprising, then, that we find some of the same processes and themes repeated from coffee-producing region to coffee-producing region - the incorporation of regions within an expanding world mar- ket, the establishment of outwardly focussed development strategies with the export of a primary product the price of which fluctuates sig- nificantly but is beyond the control of local producers and exporters, the building of roads and railroads (generally with foreign capital) to carry the coffee from the newly settled interior to port cities, the ambiguous question of land ownership in frontier zones and the con- flicts between rural settlers and urban investors, the related legal revo- lutions in landed property and labor regulations, and the ubiquitous concern for the labor problem - the "falta de brazos"

    What is perhaps more surprising is the remarkable variation in social, economic, and political structures and processes among coffee- producing regions, the radically distinct structures of landed property and the different resolutions of the labor problem encountered in Brazil or Costa Rica or Colombia. We need to consider this variation as an interpretive problem: how is it to be understood? Each of these regions turned toward coffee at roughly the same time (that is, within a

  • 354

    few important decades of each other: Brazil, Costa Rica, and Vene- zuela had important coffee economies by mid-century; Guatemala, El Salvador, and Colombia turned to coffee several decades later - the 1870s, 1880s and beyond). Each was producing the same primary product for export to the same European and North American ports (though one might export primarily to London, another to New York, another to Hamburg). The structure of trade (that is, the relation between local exporters and international firms) was roughly the same (though important differences developed in Brazil as it came to domi- nate the market). Each of the regions became "dependent" on a single export commodity, suffering the same reverses and enjoying the same booms.

    Despite the commonalities in their incorporation within the world market, however, their most basic social relations, including those associated with labor mobilization and "the specific economic form, in which unpaid surplus-labour is pumped out of direct producers "'l~ were fundamentally different. Easy assertions about the dominance of the "latifundia-minifundia complex" are out of place, as are more com- plex arguments that recognize variation but subsume the variation within a common emergence of two "large nodes of decision-making bodies" with the incorporation of regions within the world economy - one based on the "plantation" solution and the other based on the "merchant" solution (in which merchants dominate and capture the production of small farmers). 11 Such assertions explain away difference rather than confronting it.

    Let us, then, confront these differences in the coffee-growing regions in Latin America. Let us place Silo Paulo next to the Central Valley of Costa Rica or Antioquia and ask why such fundamental differences in landed property and labor mobilization occurred and what effects these differences might have had for the respective societies in which they occurred. A variety of easy resolutions are closed to us. None of the distinctions in timing or markets noted above was decisive. Nor do we have access to a mechanical opposition between closed and open frontiers or to different land and labor ratios. If our only contrast was one between El Salvador and Costa Rica, such oppositions and ratios might be convincing, but most of the regions were open frontiers, with different results of settlement that are too important to gloss over with grids and causal diagrams. A more considered examination of the societies in which the frontiers were opened and settled, the social, eco- nomic, political, and cultural contexts in which coffee became an important export crop, is necessary.

  • 355

    This essay represents a preliminary examination of such contexts, the aim of which is not to explain difference but to begin a comparative dis- cussion. I develop the comparison with a discussion of the manner in which coffee elites in different regions resolved one of their most press- ing problems - the mobilization and reproduction of labor. Although other aspects of the respective coffee economies (e.g., commercializa- tion and politics) deserve detailed attention, and will be treated else- where, the labor problem - "la falta de brazos" - was central to each of them, inflecting all aspects of social, economic, and cultural life. It therefore constitutes our necessary starting point.

    However much this may seem to resurrect the labelling controversies associated with the mode of production debates, the crucial difference in the present exercise needs to be stressed. The purpose of the present comparison is not to outline distinct modes of production, and I do not consider here the capitalist or non-capitalist character of the labor regimes examined. Indeed, one of the problems with earlier labelling exercises was that they directed our attention toward labels and away from a consideration of wider economic, social, political, and cultural fields of power.

    It is toward such a consideration that the present study of labor regimes in Latin American coffee economies, and the larger comparative study of which it is a part, are directed. We might briefly outline three dimen- sions of the labor problem that illuminate wider social and political relations and processes. First, in places such as Brazil, Colombia, and Guatemala, large landholders attempting to attract laborers were not acting in isolation. They might be competing with growers from other regions, with urban entrepreneurs, or, in the case of immigration schemes, with planters or entrepreneurs in other countries. This is not to say that landholders were powerless and a free market prevailed: the monopolization of land in some regions was the most effective means for securing a labor force. It is to say that planters acted within particu- lar contexts, particular sets of constraints, and that the systems they devised to attract workers in the first place, or to assure more careful tending of coffee trees, or to feed the working population, often created further constraints. Structures of decision making and control could become quite diffuse as coffee groves and food plots were let out to tenants.

    Second, labor mobilization schemes were never static. It would be insufficient to set up a comparison in simple spatial terms with large

  • 356

    estates and the colonato in Brazil, peasants and processors in Costa Rica, haciendas in Cundinamarca, and peasants in Antioquia - the large-estate regions being characterized by "oligarchic" domination and the peasant regions seen as more "democratic" In each of these regions, labor regimes changed over time. Haciendas in Cundinamarca began to disintegrate in the 1920s and 1930s, for example, partly due to economic problems encountered much earlier and partly due to the increasing organization and militance of their tenants. Careful attention to the fault lines created by hacendados' resolution of labor-mobiliza- tion problems in previous decades is essential for an understanding of their problems in the 1920s. In the peasant regions, in turn, we need to be sensitive to changes over time. In Costa Rica, for example, small farmers faced increasingly difficult pressures from the middle of the nineteenth century to 1930, as open lands closed off or as relations with processors became more exploitative or as household heads found it increasingly difficult to provide an inheritance for all of their children. 12

    Finally, if we think about labor mobilization in terms of contexts, con- straints, and fault lines, and if we consider the way particular resolu- tions of the labor problem change over time, we open up a most inter- esting area for investigation. One of the interesting developments that emerges in the literature on coffee in Latin America is the frequency with which elites experiment with different strategies. The most famous is probably the Vergueiro experiment in Brazil with immigrant share- croppers in the mid-nineteenth century, four decades before the end of slavery (see below)) 3 But we also find other experiments in, for exam- ple, Cundinamarca in the 1920s TM or Guatemala in the 1920s and 1930s. Indeed, careful attention to such experiments and debates can illuminate the most profound economic, political, and cultural dilem- mas confronting coffee elites. As we examine the kinds of solutions that are attempted and the solutions that are not even considered, we are able to sketch the limits of the possible (which include the limits of the socially constructed mental and cultural horizons of the elites at a par- ticular time) in various coffee-producing regions. An apparently simple "economic" question (how was labor organized), then, need not lead to a labelling exercise. A discourse about labor is seldom "just" about labor. Examining one such discourse, we may begin to unpack the sociology of racism in Guatemala or Brazil or Costa Rica; in examining another, we may begin to understand the particular features of liberal- ism in, say, early twentieth-century Colombia.

  • 357

    In what follows, I concentrate on Brazil, Costa Rica, and Colombia, which represent a range of resolutions to the labor problem in nine- teenth-century coffee economies. In this discussion, my aim is to devel- op a more detailed understanding of the dimensions of difference. I then suggest an interpretive framework in terms of which we can devel- op further comparative discussions.

    Land and labor in Latin America's new forests

    Although the primary focus of this essay concerns land and labor regimes and does not consider commercialization schemes in any detail, certain basic features of the coffee trade in nineteenth-century Latin America deserve brief consideration. For those newly independ- ent countries with exploitable subtropical soils, coffee served as a prin- cipal point of linkage to an expanding world economy, the means by which they could turn toward an "outwardly focussed" model of devel- opment. It could be stored for long periods with relatively little spoil- age; it had a high value per kilogram, making transport costs relatively low and making inland territories valuable in a way they could not be for crops such as sugar; 15 and it enjoyed a growing and lucrative acceptance in European and U.S. markets. For merchants and trading firms from countries entering the new Latin American markets, coffee became a focus of trade.

    Throughout the nineteenth century, coffee production and marketing followed classic free-trade patterns. Control of production was highly dispersed, both among coffee-producing countries and among pro- ducers within countries. Although international trade was controlled by merchant houses in London, Hamburg, and New York, there was no significant concentration among the houses until the early twentieth century. As concentration began to occur, it responded at once to changing processing and marketing structures in consuming countries and to crisis periods in producing countries, during which foreign firms might take more direct and active roles.

    Foreign coffee firms would establish credit and commercial relations with exporters and merchants in particular Latin American countries, loaning funds to exporters with which the exporters would acquire cof- fee - often by means of further loans to local producers and merchants. The general features of such arrangements can be briefly sketched. First, despite the close connection between European or North Amer-

  • 358

    ican firms and Brazilian or Costa Rican exporters and producers, local merchants and exporters were not subsidiaries of European or North American firms for most of the period under discussion. Even where the exporters were German or English expatriates, they were expatri- ates acting as individual entrepreneurs and adventurers, often with a privileged and preferred relationship with a particular London or Hamburg house, but the tie that bound them was one of credit and shared nationality rather than ownership. Second, exporters, acting with their own funds or with borrowed funds from abroad, were the principal sources of credit for local producers and merchants. For most of the period that concerns us, national or international banks were not involved in the coffee trade. Third, with purchasing and credit arrange- ments linking particular international firms and exporters, producers and merchants alike were subject to price fluctuations. Exporters lacked the means to withhold coffee in periods of low prices. There were no local exchanges, and states were not involved in coffee trade. It was only with the onset of the first general overproduction crisis in the 1890s that discussions began finally resulted in Brazil's valorization scheme of 1906. With this scheme, the first chinks in the free-trade armor appeared? 6

    Furthermore, the market was not homogeneous. In general, European consumers have preferred the "quality" milds produced in Costa Rica, Colombia, and Guatemala, and European markets were the principal outlets for the milds. These export markets were cemented with long- term arrangements with particular foreign houses. Indeed, during the free-trade period much of the quality coffee was exported not as Colombian or Costa Rican coffee but, "like French wines, ''17 under the mark of a particular Costa Rican processor (beneficiador) or Colom- bian hacienda. The United States, on the other hand, has served as a market for the harsher, less expensive coffees, especially from Brazil, but also as a subsidiary market early on for the other countries. As with all generalizations, this one requires some temporal specification. In the first place, no producing country exported to a single consuming country. Second, during the twentieth century the U.S. market became increasingly important throughout Latin America, especially during the two World Wars. Nonetheless, the segmentation of the coffee mar- ket is an important feature, especially when we consider the quality end of the scale. Given a marketing environment permeated by a discourse of quality and a pricing system based on the grading hierarchies, this provides an important point of control for coffee processors and mer- chants, especially in relation to small producers. But detailed consider-

  • 359

    ation of such relations remains beyond the scope of the present essay. We need to turn now from the structure of commerce and investment to the transformation of landscapes and societies.

    The frontier character of many of the coffee regions has often been stressed in regional studies? 8 If the frontier has impressed historians and social scientists, it has also impressed historical actors, both at the moment of frontier settlement and in memory. The memory of cutting down the forest (tumbando montes), or the image of a people forged in settlement and transformation (for example, "the ethos of the hacha" 19 [an ax] in Antioquia) is strong.

    Indeed, as we see in detail below, most of the areas converted to coffee cultivation attracted population migration and settlement. Guatemala and E1 Salvador serve as counterpoints in this story, in that both were densely populated. Even in Guatemala, however, the microregions that were to become the most dynamic production zones - the piedmont of Amatitlan, Suchitepequez, Solola, Quezaltenango, San Marcos, and the Alta Verapaz - contained much unused land. Only in E1 Salvador did the coffee zone correspond with a region of relatively dense colonial settlement, and only in El Salvador did the expansion of coffee and the transformation of landed property that accompanied it involve a wide- spread displacement and expropriation.

    Despite the frontier character of much of the coffee expansion, how- ever, most of the "wildernesses" into which coffee farmers moved were already encumbered by people, overlapping and competing claims to land, conceptions of space, time, and justice - in short, "history" - before the coffee expansion began, and these encumberances shaped their respective coffee economies even as the regions were transformed by the move toward coffee. In each of the regions considered in this essay, then, we begin with a brief discussion of the occupation of space and the transformation of landed property. With this foundation, we can then turn to a consideration of the labor problem in various sorts of production regimes.

    Brazil. Let us first consider Brazil, which stands alone in the dimen- sions of its forest. The extent of territory available and suitable for cof- fee cultivation, first in the Paraiba Valley of Rio province in the early and mid-nineteenth century and then into Minas Gerais and the S~o Paulo west from the mid- to late nineteenth century, dwarfs whole countries in Central America, not to mention the much more restricted

  • 360

    zones suitable for coffee. The destructive nature of this expansion, in which tropical forest would be cut and coffee planted, setting in morion a 30-40 year boom during which the soil would be depleted, the boom region set into decline, and then the coffee grove revert to pasture or waste as new regions to the west were opened up, is well known. 2~ In one respect, these interior regions were "new," "untouched," "virgin" The declining sugar complex of the northeast was quite distant. South- ern developments during the colonial period had centered around the administrative center in Rio and gold mining in Minas GerMs in the eighteenth century, which in turn stimulated cattle and agricultural complexes in the coastal and more accessible areas. Colonial claims to interior lands nonetheless emerged. During the colonial period, land belonged to the Crown unless it had been ceded by a personal grant (sesmaria), generally one square league (44 sqaure kilometers), in return for services to the Crown and on condition of cultivation. With the building of roads between Rio and the mines of Minas, sesmarias were granted, as the discovery of gold in Mato Grosso led to trail and road blazing and the establishment of way-stations. The lands encom- passed by these grants were underurilized in the absence of commercial opportunities, however, and they were settled by squatters who would displace Indians (who were not protected and who were written out very quickly, both in practice and in histories of settlement) toward the west. Squatters might engage in subsistence agriculture or service the way-stations along the proliferating mule tracks, but their lands (posses), which could be quite extensive and might overlap with under- exploited sesmarias, were not recognized in colonial land law. With the westward expansion of coffee, these conflicting claims became impor- tant as grant holders or the entrepreneurs to whom grants had been sold turned their claims into extensive plantations with vague bound- aries. With independence, sesmarias were no longer granted, but both sesmarias and posses were bought and sold in a conflictful rush to con- trol the land. The land law of 1850 resolved the conflict in favor of grant holders and those posseiros wealthy enough to purchase their claim from the state. That is, colonial grants were recognized as titles but the right of possession was not. Land could only be rifled by means of registration, survey, and the payment of a tax. In practice, this dis- placed small squatters toward the west, and the expansion into the Paraiba Valley or the western plateau of S~o Paulo was characterized by a series of displacements: squatters displaced Indians toward the west, only to be displaced by estate owners as roads or railroads stretched further into the interior. 21 Nonetheless, while the land law had the effect of displacing squatters, its desired effect of establishing a

  • 361

    land registry with carefully surveyed properties was not realized. Indeed, one of the remarkable features of the coffee economy through- out the period we consider is the resistance of large landholders to land surveys and registries. Such resistance within the particular field of power in which they operated allowed them to avoid taxes but also al- lowed them to extend the effective domain of their estates. 22

    The spread of the large estate should not be treated as unproblematic, however. No Latin American frontier of settlement was larger than the Brazilian interior in this period. A mechanical application of a frontier thesis might lead us to expect a more "democratic" landholding pattern to emerge. Yet here, as elsewhere, the importance of the larger field of power, the political, economic, and cultural context of frontier settle- ment, needs to be stressed. Again and again, historians point to this context and the mental and cultural horizon it produced. Commenting on the failure of smallholding in the vast frontier, Warren Dean notes, "Unfortunately, the royal administrators could never entertain serious- ly a reform that would bring about not only the desired increase in revenues but also what would appear to them to be a social revolution. The only organization they could conceive for the immense colony had to be a society precisely as aristocratic as that of the metropolis "'23 Of the spread of slavery to the frontier, Stein observes, "Free labor as an alternative hardly existed in the minds of the settlers,' 24

    Such conceptions and minds have historical and social armatures. While as a first approximation it might be useful to distinguish between the sugar-growing northeast and the expanding coffee provinces of the south, to see the one as conservative and aristocratic and the other as more liberal, "less wedded to the past," and holding "more adaptable economic and social views "'25 their liberalism took on a special, Brazil- ian character. Viotti da Costa stresses that despite a late eighteenth- and early nineteenth-century fascination with Enlightenment thought, which led to the formation of secret societies and pro-independence conspiracies, the liberalism that dominated in Brazil by independence was one that had been purged of its more radical social content:

    In Europe, liberalism had originally been a bourgeois ideology, an instru- ment in the struggle against the absolute power of kings, the privileges of the nobility, and the feudal institutions that inhibited economic development. But in Brazil, liberalism became the ideology of rural oligarchies, which found in the new ideas arguments they could use against the mother country. These men were primarly concerned with eliminating colonial institutions that restricted the landowners and merchants - the two most powerful

  • 362

    groups in colonial society. When they struggled for freedom and equality, they were actually fighting to eliminate monopolies and privileges that bene- fited the mother country and to liberate themselves from commercial restric- tions that forced Brazilians to buy and sell products through Portugal. Thus, during this period, liberalism in Brazil expressed the oligarchies' desire for independece from the impositions of the Portuguese Crown. The oligarchies, however, were not willing to abandon their traditional control over land and labor, nor did they want to change the traditional system of production. This led them to purge liberalism of its most radical tendencies. 26

    For both liberal and conservative planters, the monarchy became a means for preserving an aristocratic society in the postcolonial era. Indeed, a pact between northeastern sugar planters and the expanding Rio elite was crucial in the ascension of Pedro II to the throne in 1840.

    With this nineteenth-century monarchy, unique in Latin America, we might understand something of the political and cultural context that would attempt to extend into the frontier the system of production and privilege that had served as the basis for colonial society. We can understand the political context in which royal land grants were recog- nized as legitimate but not the rights of possession. We can understand the attempt to recreate a whole society and way of life, in which both land titles and aristocratic rank could be granted, in which a personal empire could rest on the labor of slaves.

    But the attempt to expand and reproduce such a society took place in new contexts. In the first place, planters viewing abundant land and a dependent labor force adopted production techniques that made for quick profits and long-term destruction. Initial productivity depended upon the natural fertility of the forest. Whole sections of forest would be cut and burned, and coffee trees planted in vertical rows up hill- sides, to facilitate access to the trees by slave gangs. At harvest, trees would be stripped of cherries and leaves. In a classic and oft-repeated description, this harvesting method (unique in Latin America) is pic- tured: "Each branch was encircled by thumb and forefinger, the hand then being pulled down and outward, thus 'stripping the branch in one swift motion' and filling the screen with leaves, dead twigs, and coffee berr ies . ''27 Such methods assured the productivity of labor but not of land; indeed, with the erosion caused by the vertical rows, they assured that the land would be exausted at the end of the 20-30 year cycle of the coffee trees themselves.

    Second, Brazil's new trade relationship with Britain threatened the

  • 363

    slave trade, and by mid-century the trade had effectively stopped. Thus, while the initial expansion into the Paraiba Valley had been facil- itated by the easy extension of slavery, the boom of the 1850s and 1860s brought with it an increasingly costly labor force. Slave prices doubled in the early fifties as an international trade was replaced by an interregional trade, with Rio planters buying slaves from the declining northeast. By the 1870s, central legislation began to limit slavery. The Rio Branco Law of 1871 freed slave children born after passage of the law, while the Sexagenarian Law of 1885 freed sixty-year-old slaves, e8

    Behind the picture of great wealth and aristocratic privilege created by estate agriculture and slave labor, then, lay a social reality of waste, decay, and impending crisis. Yet one of the features that impresses the reader of Stein's study of Vassouras in the Paraiba or Dean's study of Rio Claro in Sio Paulo is the inability of most planters to respond to that crisis, to envision anything other than the slavocracy that had been the basis of their wealth and was decaying around them. Their opposi- tion to abolition, their attempt to put it off for another generation, is striking. Even so, other planters, especially in Silo Paulo, could foresee the end of slavery and experimented early on with alternative forms of labor - alternatives that could not be realized as long as slavery con- tinued. Nicolau Vergueiro's experiment beginning in 1845 on his Silo Paulo plantation has received considerable attention. 29 Under this sys- tem, Vergueiro financed the immigration of German and Swiss workers who were to settle on his plantation, sharecrop an unspecified number of coffee trees, and pay off the debt incurred by their passage. Their compensation was to be half of the coffee yield (from which half was to be deducted to retire the debt), a house, and a food plot. While the ini- tial success of the experiment led to expanded immigration and share- cropping in the early 1850s, enthusiasm for the project had waned by the late 1850s, partly due to strikes and desertions of 1856-57, and partly due to decreased labor productivity. The central problem, according to Stolcke, was the initial debt. The indenture required the sharecropper to work off his debt, but the deduction for debt encour- aged the sharecropper to concentrate on the food plot rather than the coffee plot. The planter therefore had to enforce an indenture contract in a situation in which desertion was possible, and to stimulate produc- tivity in a situation in which control over the labor force was much more diffuse than with slavery.

    Despite the demise of the Vergueiro experiment in the 1850s and the continued dominance of slave labor until 1888, some planters con-

  • 364

    tinued to experiment with free-labor regimes. 3~ They faced two prob- lems. On the one hand, the initial debt associated with planter financ- ing of immigration created an immediate obstacle. On the other, the planter needed more control over the coffee production process - and by extension over the productivity of workers - than sharecropping allowed. The first problem was to be addressed by the transfer to the S~o Paulo state of the entire cost of immigration; the second was addressed with the adoption of a "mixed task and piece-rate system "'31 Together, by the 1880s, these two innovations became the distinctive features of the colonato. Beginning in 1871, Silo Paulo began to take over limited subsidization of European immigration for the coffee farms. In 1886, the Sociedade Promotora da Imigracao, a private organization under contract to the state, was formed, producing a 60- page booklet promoting Silo Paulo, published in Portuguese, German, and Italian, and opened European offices, promoting and organizing the immigrant stream. With the fall of the Empire and the establish- ment of a republic in which the states had significant power and auton- omy, the immigration program was taken over by S~o Paulo's Depart- ment of Agriculture. 32 "From 1889 to the turn of the century," Hollo- way writes,

    nearly three-quarters of a million more foreigners arrived in Silo Paulo, of which 80 percent were subsidized by the government. From abolition to the Depression nearly two and one-quarter million immigrants came in, com- pared to a population base in S~o Paulo in 1886 of one and one-quarter mil- lion. Some 58 percent of all immigrants in that period were subsidized by the state. 33

    The vast majority of the immigrants were Italian, although Italy prohib- ited further subsidized emigration to Brazil in 1902. 34 Furthermore, the state engaged in a remarkable coordination of planter needs and labor supply. Immigrants would be transferred from Santos to a hostel in Silo Paulo, where the state would serve as labor contractor. While at the hostel, the immigrant family would sign a contract to work on a particular plantation and would then be given railroad passage from Sgo Paulo to the interior. 35

    The contracts they signed represented a unique form of labor mobiliza- tion. First, they received a fixed wage per thousand coffee trees weeded and maintained during the year, regardless of yield. Second, harvest labor was compensated on the basis of yield (so much per 50 liters of cherries). Third, they received a house, and fourth, they received a food plot. Variations might appear in regions where coffee was being plant-

  • 365

    ed, allowing colonos to plant food crops between rows of recently planted coffee. The system preserved some of the advantages of a sharecropping regime (some of the risk was reduced with the harvest compensation tied to yield; costs were reduced with the provision of a food plot) but eliminated some of sharecropping's disadvantages (the set wage for tending a number of trees allowed more space for planter control of the labor process).

    Because of state subsidization of immigration and the elimination of debt as a social and economic relation between planter and colono, there was extraordinary movement of persons in the S~o Paulo West at the close of each annual cycle. Colonos on the plantation might leave and move farther west, especially to zones of expansion, where con- tracts were perceived by colonos as being more lucrative. As long as the immigrant stream was maintained, however, the instability in terms of personnel was of little concern for the planter. A dependable, state subsidized and controlled mass of cheap and replaceable labor re- mained available, a6

    Once implanted, the colonato system dominated coffee production in Sao Paulo throughout the period that concerns us here, lasting until the 1960s. The combination of incentives to individual laborers, cost- reducing features, and a structure of labor discipline, proved a powerful source of planter power in the early decades of this century. Stolcke emphasizes, for example, that planters were able to weather increas- ingly frequent periods of low prices because the provision of food plots allowed planters to reduce wages and compensate for decreased prices, a7 Nonetheless, we need to look to the fault lines in any labor regime. A labor regime that provides flexibility in response to one set of pressures may create obstacles in others. The planters' dependence on an ever-flowing immigrant stream was one such obstacle. Another lay in the attraction of contracts in zones of expansion, providing a built-in incentive to increase production as planters entered decades of overproduction. Thus, while the combination of food and coffee production provided planters with flexibility during low-price periods, the incentives built into the colonato could exacerbate the overproduc- tion problem, making price troughs more frequent and severe.

    Costa Rica also moved toward coffee cultivation early in the nineteenth century, but the occupation of space and titling of land differed markedly from the Brazilian example, a8 In the first place, the land suit- able for coffee is restricted, concentrated in the Central Valley from

  • 366

    Alajuela in the west to Ujarrfis in the southeast. Throughout the colo- nial period, Costa Rica was a periphery of a periphery. Part of the Audienca of Guatemala, most of Costa Rican territory lay beyond the area of dense Mesoamerican indigenous settlement, and the Spaniards who settled in the frontier colonial outposts found little in the way of exploitable resources or population. At the end of the colonial period, 40,000 out of a total population of about 50,000 lived in the Central Valley. The most important colonial commercial crop, cacao, had not been grown there but on the Atlantic Coast, and the bulk of the Valley's population lived in towns such as San Jos6, Heredia, and Cartago and villages, practicing a "village economy. ''39

    With independence came a search for a viable commercial crop. In 1821 the municipality of San Jos6 distributed coffee plants among indigents and conceded land to anyone who would plant and fence cof- fee groves. In 1831 the national assembly declared that anyone who planted coffee in national lands (terrenos baldios) for five years would be granted title to the land. n~ This was the first of a series of relatively open and generous (though not always conflict-free) legal instruments granting national lands to settlers who would cultivate them. 41 It also led to the early establishment of a land registry and survey, through which small holders could protect and defend their holdings.

    The expansion of coffee cultivation in the Central Valley can be distin- guished among three regions: 42 (1) the nucleus around San Jos6 and Heredia and surrounding villages, which was the first to move toward coffee, which had the most fertile lands for coffee cultivation, and which was the most densely settled center of coffee production and commercialization; (2) the Alajuela/San Ram6n region to the west, along and near the road from San Jos6 to Puntarenas, toward which migrants from San Jos6/Heredia began to move from the 1840s but especially during the last half of the century, practicing a mixed coffee/ sugar cane/cattle and other crops regime; 43 and (3) the Reventaz6n and Tundalba Valleys to the east, which did not develop coffee farms until the completion of the Limon railway, which passed through the Valleys. Unlike the other regions, Turrialba did not attract peasant migration and settlement but was characterized by large coffee, sugar cane, and banana farms. Unlike the development of coffee in other countries, regional expansion in Costa Rica was not accompanied by the decline of earlier centers of production. The San Jos6/Heredia nucleus remained the center of coffee production and commercializa- tion even as new regions were opened up.

  • 367

    The expansion of coffee cultivation in Costa Rica's Central Valley occurred within a social, political, and cultural context that represents a stark contrast to the Brazilian example. Colonial society had produced a town and village aristocracy who were not far removed, in social and economic terms, from the rest of the population. Slavery was virtually nonexistent (no more than 200 slaves at any point during the colonial era) and was outlawed in 1824. 44 Nor were other forms of servile labor widespread. As Gudmundson notes:

    Political and religious office went hand in hand with the generation and pre- servation of wealth, just as in other, more dynamic Spanish colonial societies. Ownership of land was not the surest or quickest road to enrichment in this society, however much it may have been both a form of security and a neces- sary element in securing elite status and acceptance. Unlike other Central American societies, landownership in central Costa Rica (excluding Guana- caste) did not bring with it a servile labor force, a fact that meant that there was even less interest in landholding among the elite . . . . [lln Costa Rica land- ownership was not the distinguishing feature of the elite; instead it was a combination of commerce, office holding, and diverse investments in urban and rural real estate. 45

    Many authors have painted a picture of a widespread rural, peasant population fanning subsistence crops. 46 For these authors, the dis- persed peasantry serves as a starting point for their analysis of develop- ments during the coffee era, a minority view arguing that coffee led to an accumulation of landholdings and a proletarianization of the peas- antry and a majority view arguing that the widespread peasantry served as the social basis for smallholding commercial production with the expansion of coffee cultivation. 47 On both sides, we encounter silences. In Seligson's case, for example, the analysis seems to follow from a theoretical model of the effects of commercial agriculture, along with a presentist reading of nineteenth-century census categories like jornalero. In Hall's case, her most vigorous argument against land con- centration and proletarianization stresses the contrast with Brazil. Unlike the huge landholdings in Brazil, that is, large coffee farms in the Central Valley were relatively small - 60 manzanas on average, with 60,000 trees. By the 1930s, these farms held perhaps 25 percent of the coffee land in the San Jos&Heredia nucleus. 48 While this does repre- sent a stark contrast with Brazil, once the contrast has been made the Costa Rican estate needs to be placed in a Costa Rican context. A 60,000 tree farm is not a peasant farm and cannot be worked with family labor. We need to move beyond the contrast, then, and explore a specifically Costa Rican field of power.

  • 368

    This is an area where Gudmundson's model of a colonial village econ- omy and the ruralization of the peasantry with the expansion of coffee cultivation is especially suggestive. It is a model that helps us better to understand those nineteenth-century social processes that historians have delineated: the privatization of baldfos, the move from subsistence production to commercial crops, a specific migration pattern in which a particular region would be occupied and then the sons and daughters of a subsequent generation would be faced with the choice of divided and reduced holdings, occasional or permanent labor on nearby estates, or migration to the western frontier of the Central Valley. The property-holding commercial peasantry represented an obstacle to land concentration. The expanding estate owner had to purchase small properties and could not depend on generous land grants or the sale of extensive bald/os or a structural space created by vague titles and non- existent registries and surveys.

    While this landholding peasantry represents a significant contrast with other Latin American experiences, it should not be romanticized. With the passing of generations and the increasing shortage of land, small- holders were to be divided by growing inequalities. 49 Further, the requirements of processing and marketing their coffee placed them in direct contact with coffee processors (beneficiadores), who were to become the coffee elite of Costa Pica. Indeed, as Hall notes, the large- estate holders of the San Jos6/Heredia nucleus were beneficiadores.

    An examination of this commercial infrastructure lies beyond the scope of this essay. 5~ For now it needs to be noted that the Costa Rican field of power is inconceivable without it. As in the colonial period, landholding was not the primary route to power. Both the accumula- tion of land and access to labor depended on one's position within and access to accumulated commercial wealth. As Gudmundson con- cludes:

    Coffee fundamentally transformed a colonial re#me and village economy built on direct extraction by a city-based elite from a peasantry that was as yet privatized to only a small degree. The replacement of this direct extrac- tion by more subtle and productive market-mediated mechanisms created a qualitatively new, antagonistic relationship between the coffee elite of processors-exporters and the thoroughly mercantile, landholding peasantry. The road to agrarian capitalism in Costa Rica followed along these lines, rather than those of an estate model based on the rapid proletarianization of a formerly self-sufficient and self-determined peasantry. 5~

  • 369

    Yet the elite's immobility in confronting the labor problem needs to be emphasized. Given the situation of the large estate within a peasant milieu, estate owners attracted permanent and seasonal laborers with relatively high wages. The Costa Rican peon, as Cardoso stresses, "was basically an employee, a wage labourer and not a 'serf. '''52 Yet they were unable to mount any sustained effort to attract additional laborers to Costa Rica. On the one hand, this represents their more modest resources in a world in which other countries - Brazil and Argentina - had begun massive subsidized immigration schemes, not to mention the North American zones of attraction for Italian migrants during the same period. On another, it represents the limits of their own mental and cultural horizons. The 1862 colonization law specifically forbade settlement by blacks and Chinese, and Tomas Guardia rejected Chi- nese workers in 1875, claiming they were "gamblers, thieves, and opium smokers? '53 Moreover, even when contracts were signed for the construction of a railway to the Atlantic Coast, the Costa Rican government stipulated that the West Indian laborers brought in to work on the railway were not to enter the Central Valley. 54

    Colombia. The expansion of coffee production in Colombia began much later than in Brazil and Costa Rica. Three branches of the Andes divide the country into regions that, in the nineteenth century, were iso- lated from each other and far removed from ports that could be reached via the river systems of the Magdalena and the Cauca. At the close of the colonial period, the bulk of the population lived in the highlands, which had also been the site of indigenous settlement. Around highland towns and cities, haciendas developed alongside and often at the expense of indigenous reserves (resguardos). But the haciendas and resguardos provisioned regional, urban markets. Topo- graphy and demography combined to hinder the development of an export economy and promote the development of relatively isolated regional economies. Just as a "national" market or export economy was weakly developed, the central government was quite weak. Local hacendados held power in particular regions, and though struggles between liberals and conservatives concerned control of the central government, they also, and often more importantly, concerned control of local governments, their public offices and records, and their legisla- tive power.

    This is not to say that there were no exports at all, or that the new mer- chants and free tradists in cities such as Bogotfi did not organize proj- ects and attempt to establish closer ties with world markets. Gold

  • 370

    mining in Antioquia was an important export activity and source of capital, and the mid-nineteenth-century tobacco boom in the Magda- lena valley, while short-lived, showed some of the possibilities of the sub-tropical lowlands and slopes. But it was only with the move toward coffee production, which began in earnest after 1870, that firm links with world markets were established. With the move toward coffee, the regional structuration of Colombian topography, demography, and economy was important. The development of the coffee economy fol- lowed three cycles, each of which was concentrated in a particular region. Each region, in turn, began its coffee cycle with a different colo- nial legacy in terms of prevailing social relations and the occupation of space.

    Santander, in the northeast, near the Venezuelan border, was the first Colombian region to turn toward coffee, after 1850. A region of colo- nial settlement, hacendados were able to turn to coffee as their tobac- co, cotton, or cacao markets collapsed. As the first region to turn to coffee, Santander was to dominate Colombian production throughout its first coffee cycle, accounting for some 60 percent of Colombian pro- duction at the end of the nineteenth century. 55 An important percent- age of its coffee was exported via the developing Venezuelan port at Maracaibo, as coffee production was expanding in the Venezuelan Andes at roughly the same time. By the turn of the century, Santander- ean production was beginning to level off, and the region accounted for an decreasing percentage of production in this century (only 8.9 per- cent by 1943). 56 Although the move to coffee involved changes in structures of production and landed property, with an accumulation of large properties aided by regional liberal/conservative wars (during which victorious forces would destroy local land registries57), it did not depend on or attract strong population movement.

    In Cundinamarca and Tolima, however, the expansion of coffee after 1870 took place along mountain slopes and on lands that had not been important during the colonial and early post-colonial period. Although there were important towns that were to become centers of the coffee trade, the coffee expansion also opened up new lands. The new lands, however, were encumbered by claims. From the late eighteenth century, lands in the temperate slopes were claimed in large latifundia. 5s The expansion toward coffee involved the investment by Bogotfi and Medellin 59 merchants, a "new class ''6~ looking for investments in export agriculture and buying and dividing larger latifundia or buying public lands to establish coffee haciendas. 61 It also involved the move-

  • 371

    ment of indigenous and mestizo peasants from the Sabana de Bogotfi and the highlands of Boyac~i, who settled as renters on the emerging haciendas. Although the Cundinamarca/Tolima coffee zone of the western slopes of the eastern Cordillera was an important coffee zone in that it served as the base for an oligarchic elite that lived in Bogot~i and accumulated properties in the Cundinamarca/Tolima slopes, it was never the most important producing region in terms of volume of pro- duction. By the time Santander entered into a prolonged decline, the western, Antioquefio expansion was firmly established, and the Antio- quia/Caldas coffee zone dominated Colombian production.

    This western zone has been the subject of a powerful myth - the Antio- quefio colonization, the establishment of a settler society as colonists moved into the sub-tropical frontier, carved out farms, and established towns and small-scale enterprises, with a "democratizing" effect on Antioquefio and Colombian society. More recent studies have empha- sized the less idyllic aspects of this process, the appropriation of large tracts of land by a few, the exploitation of small producers by urban merchants, the violent conflicts over land and resources as public lands were privatized. 62

    Unlike the Santanders or Cundinamarca/Tolima the area of western colonization contained a good deal of unclaimed public lands (baldios) at the close of the colonial period. The predominant economic activity was gold mining, which was not characterized by the servile labor rela- tions predominant in other regions. Most of the gold had been mined by mazamorreros, descendents of slaves and mestizos who had left other regions and worked independently by mining gold along western rivers and streams, selling their gold to urban merchants in Medellin. At the beginning of the Antioquefio colonization, then, the gold econ- omy provided a social base for independent settlement and activity (the mazamorreros) and a source of capital accumulation allowing urban merchants to invest in new enterprises. 63

    The settlement of baldios in the nineteenth century fell into two broad periods. During the first, from independence to the 1870s, public lands were sold as a source of revenue for a weak central government and without regard to the occupation of land by settlers, setting up the basis for the same kind of conflict that occurred in Brazil. During this period, colonization took a "collective" character, in which a whole settlement would be granted title, including house and farm plots. In this form, baldfos might be ceded by the state of Antioquia, or colonists would

  • 372

    settle uncultivated forest land held in colonial land title (tierras realengas), or merchants would organize settlement projects and obtain title, ceding some land to settlers but maintaining the bulk of the land for cattle haciendas. Thus a mixture of large and small holding resulted, with large cattle haciendas occupying the lowlands and small farms on the forested mountainsides. In contrast with Brazil, the passage of laws 61 of 1874 and 48 of 1882 placed limits on the size of holdings that could be titled from public lands and, more importantly, recognized the rights of prior settlement and possession. In practice, this did not represent a transfer of power from large landholders to small, and sta- tistical analyses of public-land sales and grants show a continued pre- dominance of large holdings. But it created a legal terrain on which settlers could struggle, and through which they could oppose the appropriation of their farms. 64

    The laws of 1874 and 1882 were especially important as the lands held by settlers increased in value with the expansion of coffee production in the west from 1890s forward. Before this period, Medellin mer- chants interested in coffee invested in haciendas in the Cundinamarca/ Tolima region, especially around Sasaima. 65 The first Antioquefio cof- fee farms were established on large haciendas near MedeUin (Fredonia) in the 1880s. Further expansion in the 1890s and 1900s occurred in the areas of small-scale settlement, on the mountain slopes to the south. By 1913, Antioquia and Caldas had displaced the Santanders as the most important producing region, creating the basis for a prodi- gious twentieth-century expans ion . 66

    Within and among the three Colombian regions that dominated Colombian coffee production, we find land and labor regimes that approach the Brazilian and Costa Rican extremes and that cover a range of intermediate forms and relations. A rough survey of the three regions can be quickly sketched. 67 In Santander in its period of expan- sion and establishment (1840-1900), a form of sharecropping (aparceria) predominated in which a tenant would be given a house, food plot, and coffee plot in return for a third to a half of the coffee produced and a smaller portion of the food plot's yield. Arango sug- gests that this system emerged after an early use of wage labor and was a response to labor scarcity and the need to fix labor on the land. 68 This, in turn, supports Palacios' contention that Santanderean share- cropping was not associated with servile social relations. In this view, sharecropping represented a short-term economic contract that implied neither a long-term relationship with the land nor a servile

  • 373

    relationship with an absentee owner . 69 If outside labor was necessary for the harvest, it was employed by the sharecropper.

    In Cundinamarca, a form of labor rent (arrendamiento) emerged during its period of expansion and establishment (1875-1900). The large haciendas on the western slopes of the eastern cordillera were owned by Bogotfi merchants who hired resident administrators. Because the subtropical slopes had been relatively open at the begin- ning of the coffee cycle, the haciendas depended on the migration of highland Indians and mestizos from Boyacfi and Cundinamarca who would settle on hacienda lands and be given a house and access to land for food and livestock production. In return, they would be expected to provide a contracted number of days per month on the hacienda's coffee plot. While this was the most servile of the labor relations to emerge in Colombia, arrendatarios were in privileged positions in rela- tion to others such as the casual laborers (voluntarios) hired from the region or from highland Cundinamarca and Boyacfi for the harvest. Long-term rental arrangements on haciendas gave the arrendatarios access to a livelihood; their access to land for corn, beans, sugar, and livestock production created a space for an alternative commercial economy within the hacienda and with neighboring towns, of which some arrendatarios were able to take advantage, hiring voluntarios to do their obligatory work on the hacienda. TM

    In Antioquia during the initial expansion (1885-1905), large haciendas near Medellin and Fredonia used an intermediate system of agregados, in which the house alloted to the worker was separate from the land to be worked, minimizing the possibility that the agregado could develop an alternative agricultural economy within the hacienda. 7~ With the spread of coffee cultivation to the south, however, small-scale commer- cial peasant production was widespread, and a structure of production and commercialization similar to that of Costa Rica's Central Valley emerged.

    Although it is useful to make an initial distinction between a structure of production dominated by a commercial peasantry in the Antio- quefio west and one dominated by haciendas and dependent tenants in the east, such an opposition needs to be modified by more careful attention to spatial variation (the existence of small-scale production in regions dominated by haciendas, and of haciendas in regions domi- nated by peasants) and to temporal development. Palacios suggests that the development of coffee production in Colombia can be divided into

  • 374

    three broad periods: the hacienda phase (1870-1910), the peasant phase (1910-1950), and the empresarial phase (small-scale commer- cial farms, with much greater capital inputs for new strains, fertilizers, and labor, 1960 to present). 72 On the one hand, the "peasant phase" of the early twentieth century represents the growing importance of Antioquia and the southward expansion of settlement and coffee pro- duction. Yet it also reflects the fragmentation of hacienda holdings in the center.

    To understand the dynamics of this fragmentation, Palacios' emphasis on the peasant character of Colombian coffee production on haciendas is especially helpful. He begins by stressing the frontier character of the Cundinamarca coffee zone, the implantation of a hacienda regime that involved the investment of commercial capital from Bogotfi and the immigration of highland peasants from Boyacfi. But he suggests that it was "an entire peasant structure" that migrated, meaning that servile relations from the highlands were successfully implanted in the early decades but also that household-based production was installed at the very center of the hacienda regime. 73

    This was to be increasingly important as arrendatarios established commercial production in their food plots and pastures, and as hacen- dados needed to renovate their coffee plots. Hacienda administrators complained about the difficulty of enforcing labor obligations. That is, the manner in which hacendados resolved their labor problem created the structural space for an alternative economy within the hacienda, which was increasingly important at the close of the initial expansion phase. By the 1920s, the crisis on central haciendas was acute, as peas- ant movements began to organize, first against the arrendatarios and then in combination with the arrendatarios against the hacendados. One response of hacendados was to divide and sell off their estates to peasants and outsiders, a long process that continued through and beyond the depression. With this, the "cellular structure" that charac- terized the organization of production within haciendas became the basis for a new structure of landed property, and small-scale property and production became central in the two most important production zones of the country. TM As in Costa Rica, this peasantry should not be romanticized: the exploitative relationship between merchant proces- sors and small producers was crucial. But the importance of the peas- antry, both within the hacienda regime and in that regime's collapse, should not be forgotten. 75

  • 375

    Fields of power: Toward an interpretive framework

    This essay began with a paradox - the common transformation of Latin America's coffee republics in the late nineteenth century and the radi- cally distinct experience that transformation engendered. After a brief exploration of one dimension of those distinct experiences, we need now to ask why these different forms and relations emerged. My answer, which cannot satisfy those who prefer their explanations to be more precise and "economical" is that understanding can only be sought in the comparative discussion itself. "The determinate 'cause' of such changes" writes Sidney Mintz concerning another problem, "is a context, or a set of situations, created by broad economic forces. ''76 In this case, I have tried to sketch radically different social contexts into which these broad economic forces were inserted, and I wish now to suggest that these different contexts "determined" the different direc- tions the coffee economies took.

    However much this may look like an argument that the coffee econo- mies were different because they were different, the historical and anthropological understanding that informs it is more complex and requires elaboration. I have referred at various points in this essay to specific Paulista or Costa Rican fields of power. I need now to make my meaning more explicit. Despite the profilerating use of "power" as a concept in recent literature, my most direct source for the phrase is Eric Wolf's Peasant Wars of the Twentieth Century. 77 Characteristically, he defines what he means by practice rather than explicit precept. The phrase appears most prominently in his conclusion that, "Ultimately, the decisive factor in making a peasant rebellion possible lies in the relation of the peasantry to the field of power which surrounds it. ''78 While he goes on to use a definition of power offered by Richard Adams, his understanding of the field of power is less susceptible to codification. It clearly refers to the class structure of which the peasants are a part - the landlords, merchants, state officials, capitalist planters, and others who press claims upon or otherwise threaten peasant liveli- hoods. But his understanding of the class structure is one that is less dependent on a ready set of sociological categories than on detailed anthropological and historical investigation. Earlier, Wolf observed that

    the anthropologist is greatly aware of the importance of groups which medi- ate between the peasant and larger society of which he forms a part. The landlord, the merchant, the political boss, the priest stand at the junctures in social, economic, and political relations that connect the village to wider-

  • 376

    ranging elites in markets or political networks. In his study of peasant villages he has learned to recognize their crucial role in peasant life, and he is per- suaded that they must play a significant role in peasant involvement in polit- ical upheaval. To describe such groups, and to locate them in the social field in which they must maneuver, it is useful to speak of them as "classes" Classes are for me quite real clusters of people whose development or de- cline is predicated on particular historical circumstances, and who act to- gether or against each other in pursuit of particular interests prompted by these circumstances. In this perspective, we may ask - in quite concrete terms - how members of such classes make contact with the peasantry. In our accounts, therefore, we must transcend the usual anthropological account of peasants, and seek information also about the larger society and its constituent class groupings, for the peasant acts in an arena which also contains allies as well as enemies. This arena is characteristically a field of political battle. TM

    There is much in this statement that bears the marks of the period, over twenty years ago, in which it was written; there is also much in it that is extraordinarily refreshing in the context of theoretical preoccupations that have dominated the literature in the subsequent twenty years. What Wolf was marking out was less a confining set of concepts and hypotheses and more a historical and anthropological attitude, which he then took to his six case studies of peasant rebellion. It is in these case studies that we find, in practice, Wolf's concept of a field of power. In his study of the Mexican Revolution, for example, he begins with the formation of indigenous peasant communities during the colonial period, their relations to haciendas, cities, and the colonial state; the War of Independence and the social and political transformations of the nineteenth century (the liberal reforms and the expansion of haciendas, especially under the Diaz regime); the development of mining and industry in the north. It was only in this context that he ana- lyzed the various locally focussed Mexican Revolutions and some of the initial consequences for regional peasantries of the new Mexico that emerged. In each of the case studies, an attempt is made to under- stand the formation of a particular peasantry in terms of its internal relations, forms of landholding and community, its relations with hacendados, merchants, the Church, representatives of the state, etc., and to examine how this complex of relations changes with, say, the passage of new land laws in Mexico, the end of one colonialism or the introduction of another, the imposition of a head tax or the develop- ment of rice plantations in Vietnam. Although he does not use the lan- guage, each of the case studies can be seen as an attempt to capture the conjunction of local and global histories, or to explore the internaliza- tion of the external.

  • 377

    Although it might have seemed to some reviewers that Wolf's case studies are "too complex and vague" and that he writes the "least theo- retically" of the authors who examined peasant rebellions in the 1960s and 70s, 8~ it should be apparent that his approach to fields of power is actually well informed by theory. Likewise, the examination of coffee economies in this essay comes out of a certain theoretical understand- ing, one that organizes our account of the different social and cultural contexts in which coffee economies developed in a certain way. To each of the regions considered, I take a set of questions that fit comfortably within a historical materialist framework: the occupation of space and the transformation of landed property, the mobilization and reproduc- tion of labor, and (in a discussion to be presented elsewhere) the organ- ization and capitalization of markets, and the political and ideological processes associated with state formation and the emergence of hegemonic blocs.

    In addressing these questions, I have tried to avoid the temptation of filling structural boxes, by locating within each theme real problems that confronted historical actors - obtaining title to land, or resisting a land survey, recruiting a labor force by experimenting with various forms of compensation, pressing the state to pay for the transport of one's labor- ers, or agitating for market control in a depression and finding that the control scheme results in greater foreign domination. It is through attention to these problems, their varying local solutions, and the prob- lems created by those solutions that we can sketch the structure of class relations in Silo Paulo or Antioquia in a way that pays attention to the action of human subjects and to the contradictory forms and results of such actions.

    Notes

    1. This article presents a portion of the summary and argument contained in my intro- duction for a forthcoming volume on "Coffee, Society, and Power in Latin Amer- ica," edited by William Roseberry and Lowell Gudmundson. While the present essay concentrates on questions of land and labor, the longer introduction explores these questions in a wider range of countries and also treats questions of coffee processing, commercialization and trade, as well as class formation and politics, all of which are necessary for the comparative interpretation suggested here. The introduction, in turn, depends upon and was inspired by the essays by Michael Jimenez, Lowell Gudmundson, Mario Samper, Hector P6rez, Marco Palacios, Fer- nando Pic6, David McCreery, Verena Stolcke, and Mauricio Font gathered in the volume. The conference that led to the volume was generously funded by the Uni- versidad Nacional de Colombia and the Social Science Research Council, with funds from the National Endowment for the Humanities.

  • 378

    2. G. Marcus, "Imagining the Whole," Critique of Anthropology, 9 (3, 1989), 7. 3. G. Marcus, "Contemporary Problems of Ethnography in the Modern World Sys-

    tem," in J. Clifford and G. Marcus, editors, Writing Culture: The Poetics and Politics of Ethnography (Berkeley, University of California Press, 1986), 165-193.

    4. F.H. Cardoso and E. Faletto, Dependency and Development in Latin America (Berkeley, University of California Press, 1979), xvii.

    5. Ibid., xvii, xviii. 6. K. Marx and F. Engels, The German Ideology (New York, International, 1970

    l18461), 55-58. 7. J. de Graaf, The Economics of Coffee (Wageningen, Netherlands, Centre for Agri-

    cultural Publishing and Documentation, 1986), 26. 8. U.S. Department of Commerce, Business and Defense Services Administration,

    Coffee Consumption in the United States, 1920-1965 (Washington, D.C., 1961), 5. 9. M. Palacios, E1 Card en Colombia, 1850-1970, 2nd ed. (Mexico City, El Colegio de

    M6xico, 1983), 178. 10. K. Marx, Capital, vol. 3. (New York, International, 1967 [1984]), 791. 11. I. Wallerstein, The Modern World-System III: The Second Era of Great Expansion of

    the Capitalist World-Economy, 1730s-1840 (San Diego, Academic Press, 1989), 152-153.

    12. See L. Gudmundson, "Peasant, Farmer, Proletarian: Class Formation in a Small- holder Coffee Economy, 1850-1950," Hispanic American Historical Review, 69 (2, 1989), 221-258; M. Samper, "Enfrentamiento y Conciliaci6n: Comentarios a Prop6sito de las Relaciones entre Productores y Beneficiadores de Caf6," Revista de Historia, Ntimero Especial (1985), 207-212.

    13. S. Stein, Vassouras, A Brazilian Coffee County, 1850--1900: The Role of Planter and Slave in a Plantation Society, 2nd ed. (Princeton, Princeton University Press, 1985); W. Dean, Rio Claro: A Brazilian Plantation System, 1820-1920 (Stanford, Stanford University Press, 1976); T. HoUoway, Immigrants on the Land: Coffee and Society in S~o Paulo, 1886-1934 (Chapel Hill: University of North Carolina Press, 1980); V. Stolcke, Coffee Planters, Workers, and Wives: Class Conflict and Gender Rela- tions on $5o Paulo Plantations, 1850-1980 (New York: St. Martin's, 1988).

    14. A. Machado uses articles written by hacendados outlining the benefits of new forms of tenancy that they had recently adopted. Machado uses the articles as evi- dence of particular forms of sharecropping, but they are also interesting as elite dis- courses, as planters simultaneously trying to present themselves to each other in a particular way and trying (publicly) to resolve increasingly intractable problems as their tenants left the farms and worked on public works projects. (A. Machado, El Cafd: De la Aparceria al Capitalismo, [Bogotfi, Punta de Lanza, 1977] 179-199.)

    15. See L. Bergad, Coffee and the Growth of Agrarian Capitalism in Nineteenth Century Puerto Rico (Princeton, Princeton University Press, 1982), 38.

    16. With the depression of the 1930s and the closure of the European market in World War II, the United States and 14 producing countries signed the International Cof- fee Agreement of 1940, setting export quotas for the various countries. The agree- ment was the first of a series of international control schemes that stabilized the market and facilitated a dramatic post-war price increase. It also corresponded with (indeed required) the formation of national coffee-marketing boards, marking the effective end of the free-trade model of coffee marketing. Some of these boards had been formed earlier, during the depression, or, in Brazil, to administer the valorization schemes.

    17. M. Arango, Caf~ e lndustria, 1850-1930 (Bogot~i, Carlos Valencia Editores, 1977),

  • 379

    184. The analogy, while suggestive, is inexact. Coffee is subject to a grading system, at first developed by traders in consuming countries and in recent decades devel- oped by marketing boards in producing countries as well. It has never been asso- ciated with the sort of politically and commercially charged designation of lands that produce grapes that can be processed into wines with certain appellations, and within appellations, designation of grapes and the lands that produce them into grand, premier, and lesser crus, nor can it be. That a discourse of quality can give to a coffee processor a control analogous to that exercised by, say, a wine negociant is, nonetheless, an interesting possibility.

    18. Stein, Vassouras, 3; Dean, Rio Claro, 1-23; C. Hall, El Caf~ y el Desarrollo Hist6rico-Geogrdfico de Costa Rica (San Jos~, Editorial Costa Rica, 1976); Pala- cios, El Caf~ en Colombia, passim; D. A. Rangel, Capital y Desarrollo: La Vene- zuela Agraria (Caracas: Universidad Central, 1969); W. Roseberry, Coffee and Capitalism in the Venezuelan Andes (Austin, University of Texas Press, 1983), passim.

    19. Palacios, El Caf~ en Colombia, 294. 20. The classic account for Rio is Stein, Vassouras. 21. An excellent general treatment of land policy is in E. Viotti da Costa, The Brazilian

    Empire: Myths and Histories (Chicago, University of Chicago Press, 1985), 78-93. For treatments of the conflicts between squatters and grantholders in Rio and S~to Paulo, see Stein, Vassouras, 10-17; Dean, Rio Claro, 11-20; HoUoway, Immigrants on the Land, 112-114.

    22. See Holloway, Immigrants on the Land, 113, 120-121. 23. Dean, Rio Claro, 13. 24. Stein, Vassouras, 55. 25. B. Bums, A History of Brazil, 2nd ed, (New York, Columbia University Press,

    1980), 189. 26. Viotti da Costa, The Brazilian Empire, 7. 27. Stein, Vassouras, 35. 28. Stein, Vassouras, 65-67. 29. Dean, Rio Claro, 89-123; Holloway, Immigrants on the Land, 70-72; Stolcke,

    Coffee Planters, Workers, and Wives, 1-9; Viotti da Costa, Brazilian Empire, 94- 124.

    30. Stolcke, Coffee Planters, Workers, and Wives, 9-16. 31. Ibid., 17. 32. Holloway, Immigrants on the Land, 35-40. 33. Ibid., 41. 34. Other important nationalities of immigrants were Spanish, Portuguese, and Japan-

    ese. See ibid., 42-43. 35. Ibid., 50-61. 36. This summary has depended on descriptions in Stolcke, Coffee Planters, Workers,

    and Wives; Holloway, Immigrants on the Land, and Dean, Rio Claro. 37. Stolcke, Coffee Planters, Workers, and Wives, 28-34. 38. The best analysis of the occupation of space in Costa Rica is Hall, El Ca# y el

    Desarrollo Hist6rico-Geogr6fico. See as well idem, Costa Rica: A Geographical Interpretation in Historical Perspective (Boulder, Westview Press, 1985).

    39. L. Gudmundson, Costa Rica before Coffee: Society and Economy on the Eve of the Export Boom (Baton Rouge, Louisiana State University Press, 1986).

    40. Hall, El Caf~ y el Desarrollo Hist6rico-Geogrtifico, 35-37. 41. J.A. Salas Viquez, "La Bdsqueda de Soluciones al Problema de la Escasez de

  • 380

    Tierra en la Frontera Agr/cola: Aproximaci6n al Estudio del Reformismo Agrario en Costa Rica, 1880-1940." Revista de Historia, Nfimero Especial (1985), 97- 160.

    42. Hall, El Card y el Desarrollo Hist6rico-Geogrdfico, 72-101. 43. See as well M. Samper Kutschbach, "La Especializaci6n Mercantil Campesina en el

    Noroeste del Valle Central: 1850-1900. Elementos Microanaliticos para un Modelo." Revista de Historia Ntimero Especial (1985), 49-98.

    44. M. Seligson, Peasants in Costa Rica (Madison, University of Wisconsin Press, 1980), 8.

    45. Gudmundson, Costa Rica before Coffee, 57. 46. M. Seligson, Peasants in Costa Rica; E. Fonseca, Costa Rica Colonial (San JosE,

    EDUCA, 1983); C. Hall, El Cafd y el Desarrollo HistErico-Geogrdfico. 47. For the first view, see Seligson, Peasants in Costa Rica; for the second, see Hall, El

    Caf~ y el Desarrollo HistErico-Geogrdfico. 48. Hall, El Caf~ y el Desarrollo Hist6rico-GeogrEfico, 85-87. 49. L. Gudmundson, "Peasant, farmer, proletarian." 50. See the Introduction, cited in note 1, as well as Hall, El Caf~ y el Desarrollo His-

    t6rico-Geogr(~fico, 47-49; G. Peters Solorzano, "La formaci6n territorial de las grandes fincas de car6 en la Meseta Central: Estudio de la firma Tournon (1877- 1955)/' Revista de Historia (9-10, 1980), 81-167; V. H. Acufia Ortega, "Clases sociales y conflicto social en la econom/a cafetalera costarricense: productores con- tra beneficiadores: 1932-1936." Revista de Historia (Nfimero especial, 1985), 181-212.

    51. Gudmundson, Costa Rica Before Coffee, 152. 52. C. F. S. Cardoso, "The formation of the coffee estate in nineteenth-century Costa

    Rica," in Land and Labor in Latin America, ed. K. Duncan and I. Rutledge, (Cam- bridge, Cambridge University Press, 1977), 194.

    53. Hall, El CafO y el Desarrollo Hist6rico-Geogrtifico, 57. 54. Ibid. All the more interesting, then, the famous mural depicting Costa Rican econ-

    omy and society in San JosE's National Theater. The romanticized picture of coffee and banana workers shows them all to be white - an obvious misrepresentation of the banana zone, an accurate representation of an elite's self-image.

    55. Palacios, El Card en Colombia, 73. 56. Machado, El Caf~, 117; Palacios, El Caf~ en Colombia, 70-73. 57. Arango, Caf~ e Indastria, 47. 58. Palacios, El CafO en Colombia, 169. 59. On Medellin merchants in the early Cundinamarca coffee economy, see Arango,

    Card e Industria. 60. Palacios, El Caf~ en Colombia, 78-79. 61. Ibid., 131-169. 62. The classic study of Antioquefio colonization is J. J. Parsons, The Antique~o Colo-

    nization in Western Colombia, 2nd ed. (Berkeley, University of California Press, 1968). Recent reconsiderations include M. Palacios, El Caf~ en Colombia, 293- 340; M. Arango, Caf~ e Industria, 68-87. C. LeGrand's Frontier Expansion and Peasant Protest in Colombia, 1850-1936 (Albuquerque, University Of New Mexico Press, 1986) is not limited to Antioquia but offers an innovative study of the appro- priation of and conflict over public lands (baldios) in nineteenth- and early twen- tieth-century Colombia.

    63. Machado, El Caf~, 17-32; C. Bergquist, Labor in Latin America (Stanford, Stan- ford University Press, 1986), 287-290.

  • 381

    64. This entire discussion depends on LeGrand, Frontier Expansion, 10-18. See as well Arango, Caf~ e lndustria, 68-87.

    65. Arango, Caf~ e Industria. 66. Machado, El Ca#, 117. 67. Sources for this comparison include Palacios, El Caf~ en Colombia, 187-234;

    Arango, Caf~ e Industria, 130-151; Machado, El Cafd, 33-85; Bergquist, Labor in Latin America, 313-330.

    68. Arango, Caf~ e Industria, 149-151. 69. Palacios, El Caf~ en Colombia, 191. 70. Palacios, El Caf~ en Colombia, 206. 71. Palacios, El Caf~ en Colombia, 193. 72. Palacios, El Caf~ en Colombia, 342. 73. Ibid., 171-175. 74. Palacios, El Caf~ en Colombia, 372-401. See also M. Jimenez, "Traveling Far in

    Grandfather's Car: The Life Cycle of Central Colombian Coffee Estates. The case of Viotfi, Cundinamarca (1900-1930)," Hispanic American Historical Review 69 (no. 2, 1989), 216.

    75. Here again, the limited nature of the present comparison needs to be emphasized. A full understanding of the respective fields of power sketched in this essay re- quires consideration of the relations between small producers and merchants. But the bases for merchant control, and the special characterisitics of coffee that make such control possible, are sketched elsewhere. See the Introduction, cited in note 1, as well as the Costa Rican sources cited in note 50. For Colombia, see Palacios, El Caf~ en Colombia; Arango, and Card e lndustria. For other countries, see Rose- berry, Coffee and Capitalism; Bergad, Coffee and the Growth of Agrarian Capital- ism.

    76. S. Mintz, Sweetness and Power." The Place of Sugar in Modern History (New York, Viking, 1985), 181.

    77. E. Wolf, Peasant Wars of the Twentieth Century (New York: Harper and Row, 1969).

    78. Ibid., 290. 79. Ibid., xii. 80. T. Skocpol, "What Makes Peasants Revolutionary?" in R. Weller and S. Guggen-

    heim, Power and Protest in the Countryside (Durham, 1982), 166, 178.