We Are All Negotiators Now

download We Are All Negotiators Now

of 41

Transcript of We Are All Negotiators Now

  • 8/12/2019 We Are All Negotiators Now

    1/41

    More than ever, effectiveproblem-solving de-mands that we knowwhen and how to createvaluable agreementswith other parties. But

    negotiating isnt alwaysbest. Heres how to getto yes when its appro-priateand evencrucial.

    STRATEGY TOOL #5

    We Are All Negotiators Now:

    An Introduction to Negotiation in

    Community Problem-Solvingby Xavier de Souza Briggs

    The Art and Science of Community Problem-Solving Project atHarvard University

    July 2003

    Sections to guide you:

    Ideas in brief

    Ideas at work

    Taking stock: applying

    the ideas in your

    community

    w w w . c o m m u n i t y - p r o b l e m - s o l v i n g . n e t

    Download this and other strategy tools free at

  • 8/12/2019 We Are All Negotiators Now

    2/41

    Weareallnegotiatorsnow,becauseagrowing

    numberofpublicandprivateissuesarejointlyde

    cided.Asmoreandmorestakeholdersasktopar

    ticipateindecisionsthataffectthem,andasthe

    workofpublicproblemsolvingissharedacross

    thegovernment,business,andnongovernmental(nonprofit)sectors,thedemandfornegotiation

    growsdramatically.Noonecanaffordtoignore

    thiscorecivicskillbeingabletocreativelyad

    vancesharedinterestsandresolvedifferencestoo.

    Yettomanycivicmindedpeople,negotiationcon

    juresupnegativeimagesofhorsetradinghard

    ball,selfinterestedtransactinginwhichpower

    games,threats,anddeceptiondominate.Plus,it

    isntalwaysclearwhennegotiationismostappro

    priateinalargerefforttotacklesocialproblemsor,

    forexample,hownegotiationrelatestoothercivic

    practices,suchasstakeholderorganizing,participa

    toryplanning,orbuildingpartnerships.Finally,

    communityproblemsolvingofteninvolvesspecialchallengesassociatedwithinformalbargaining,

    powerfulsubtextsgroundedinacommunityshis

    tory,ambiguousrulesaboutwhoshouldbeatthe

    tableandwhocanrepresentwhom.

    Thistoolprovidesanoverviewofnegotiationfunda

    mentals,adiscussionofthespecialissuesoutlined

    above,handyworksheetsforpreparingyourown

    negotiations,andasetofpitfallstoavoid.

    Ideas in BriefStrategy tool #5

    Ideas at Work

    KEY ISSUE OPPORTUNITIES CHALLENGES AND PITFALLS

    Negotiation (or conflict management) is one

    tool, not always the right tool, for problem-

    solving with others. Itsimportantto

    knowthepotentialandlimitsof

    negotiationand torecognizethat

    sometimeswehavenochoice:we

    findourselvesnegotiatingwhere

    weneedthecooperationofothers.

    Strategiesandtacticsforcomingto

    agreementareobviouslyimportant

    forprogressonsocialproblems.

    Withoutthem,jointproblem

    solvingcanleadtoprocessparaly

    sis(talkthatthwartsratherthan

    supportsaction),impasse,orold

    styleimposeddecisionsthatlack

    constituencies.

    Ifoneormorepartiesarenotcom

    mittedtoit,negotiationcanbea

    devicefordistractionormanipula

    tion,particularlyifsomepartiesdo

    nothavetheinfluenceneededto

    protectandadvancetheirinterests.

    Also,poorlyhandlednegotiation

    candeepenconflictandmistrust.

    Classic advice to negotiate interests, notpositions becomes challenging to practice in

    the context of problems with many dimen-

    sions, ideological divides, and complex stake-

    holder interests.Subtexts,suchasa

    tensionbetweenthecivicoldguard

    andthenew,canunderminepro

    gress.Still,recognizingthatele

    mentsofcompetitioncancoexist

    withcooperationcanshiftmindsets

    fromstandoffandfingerpointing

    toproblemsolving.

    Togofrombargaininginthenar

    rowsenseofnegotiatingfixedin

    terestsandoptionstoproblem

    solvingtogether,groupsmustbe

    consciousaboutframingproblems

    wellupfront,workinghardatgen

    eratingoptions,andthenmoving

    theideastowardnegotiatedagree

    ment.Divergentthinkingcan

    sharpenthe stakesandbeasource

    ofbreakthroughinnovation.

    Jointproblemsolvingtakeswill,

    timeandotherresources,andprac

    tice,practice,practice.Facilitators

    andaccesstodiverseexpertisecan

    help,butmuchhingesontheabil

    ityofthepartiestoquestionas

    sumptionswithoutresentment,

    applyflexiblethinking,andcrea

    tivelyexploittheirdifferences.

    Muchjointgainisbuiltontrades

    betweenpartiesthatwantdifferent

    things.

    A large part of community problem-solving isgetting effective agents (representatives) to

    negotiate on behalf of coalitions of stake-

    holders.Sometimes,comingtoagree

    mentonoursideanddirectingour

    agenteffectivelyareatleastas

    trickyasnegotiatingwiththeother

    side(s).

    Agentsoftenplayacrucialrolein

    brokeringagreementsacrossmulti

    plelevelsofconflict,whereeach

    sidehasseveralsubgroups.Com

    ingtoagreementmeanslearning

    howtonavigatetherulesofagame

    withseverallevels.

    Agentscanabusetheirrolestostall

    agreementandadvancepersonal

    agendas.Plus,theconventional

    wisdomthatweshouldcometo

    firminternalconsensus(circlethe

    wagons)onoursideandthen

    negotiatewiththemcanbackfire

    badly,leadingtopositionalbar

    gainingandfailure.

    Copyright 2003 Xavier de Souza Briggs, The Community Problem-Solving Project @ MIT. No permission or fee is required for any and all educational use, pro-vided that this material is provided free or at cost of reproduction.

  • 8/12/2019 We Are All Negotiators Now

    3/41

    workstoreconciledonorsexpectations

    aboutaccountabilitywiththeflexibility

    required by fledgling grassroots or

    ganizations and experienced commu

    nitybasedserviceagencies.

    A community development organiza

    tion forgesadeal inwhicha forprofit

    corporationagreestoemployneighbor

    hoodresidentsandprocuregoodsand

    services from small businesses in ex

    change for communitybased support

    for the corporations presence in the

    area.

    A neighborhood planning effort in

    volves shared decisionmaking about

    many thingsthe scope of planning,

    the roles of key playersresidents,

    merchants, funders, facilitators, and

    othersintheprocess,andsubstantive

    priorities once the plan is ready for

    implementation.

    A collaborative of funders looks for

    ways to pool investments in a target

    issue (or place), advancing shared ob

    jectives while pursuing the funders

    specialized missions and program

    goalsaswell.

    AsRogerFisherandWilliamUryput

    it in GettingtoYes,the negotiationbest

    seller:

    Moreandmoreoccasionsrequire

    negotiation;conflictisagrowth

    industry.Everyonewantstopar

    ticipateindecisionsthataffect

    them;fewerandfewerpeoplewill

    acceptdecisionsdictatedbysome

    Negotiation happens in communities

    all the time, sincejoint action andjoint

    decisionmaking are crucial tomaking a

    differenceintheworld.Rarely isthefor

    malauthorityofanyonedecisionmaker

    or stakeholder enough to accomplish

    important ends, and all too often, im

    posed decisions are mandates without

    constituenciestoactonthem.

    As for the specifics,negotiationhap

    pens in many contexts, engages a huge

    variety of stakeholder groups and per

    sonal styles, and takes many forms. For

    example:

    A group of public, private, and non

    profitcommunityleadersgathersinfor

    mally to outline a local campaign to

    strengthen families and promote child

    wellbeing.Thegroupmustaccommo

    date the varied interests around the

    tableandchoosecommunicationstrate

    gies that, likewise, will mobilize a

    broadbaseinthecommunity.

    Residentsinaruralvillagemeettode

    velop a budget for allocating social

    investment funds to avariety of com

    munity infrastructure, income genera

    tion,andotherneeds.Participantsmust

    notonly chooseoptionsbutdecideon

    criteria to apply to the options and

    even decide how to decide:

    through majority vote, consensus

    process,someotherapproach?

    A company works out new guide

    linesonmitigatingpollution,dealing

    with localandstategovernmentand

    a coalition of environmental advo

    cacygroupstobalanceeconomicand

    socialobjectives.

    A nonprofit service provider negoti

    ates a performancebased contract

    with a government funder. The two

    parties look for ways to ensure re

    sultswhileprotecting thenonprofits

    autonomy todevelop its operational

    capacityandmanage services incul

    turally appropriate ways that serve

    thecommunity.

    Indevelopinganewcommunity ini

    tiative, a local civic intermediary

    We Are All Negotiators Now:An Introduction to Negotiating in Community Problem-Solvingby Xavier de Souza Briggs

    XavierdeSouzaBriggs isAssociateProfessor ofPublicPolicy at theJohnF.Kennedy

    School ofGovernment,HarvardUniversity,

    79 JFK Street, Cambridge, MA 02138,

    U.S.A.

    Part

    of

    The

    Art

    and

    Science

    of

    Com

    munity ProblemSolving Project, this tool

    waspreparedtoillustratestrategicchallenges

    and choices facing people and institutions

    around the globe rather than to highlight

    effective or ineffective handling ofparticular

    situations. Thisproject is madepossible by

    generous supportfrom theAnnie E. Casey

    Foundation, Harvards Hauser Center for

    NonprofitOrganizations,andtheRockefeller

    Foundation.

    Negotiationisbackandforthcommunicationde

    signedtoreachagreementwhenyouandtheother

    sidehavesomeintereststhataresharedandothers

    thatareopposed.FisherandUry,GettingtoYes

    3

  • 8/12/2019 We Are All Negotiators Now

    4/41

    governmental or

    ganizations, grant

    agreements be

    tween philanthro

    pies and nonprofit

    service providers

    and advocates, and

    more. And interna

    tional negotiations

    a r e i mpo r t a n t

    mechanisms for

    resolving differ

    ences within and

    acrossnations.And

    negotiation may

    include complex

    power games and,

    sometimes, decep

    tion. More gener

    ally, negotiating

    parties often use information strategi

    cally, to advance their interests. Parties

    emphasize certain ideas and not others,

    and theymay omit informationwithout

    actuallylyingtootherparties.

    But thepopular imagesofwherene

    gotiationhappens andhow itgetsdone

    blindus toagreatdealofvalue thatne

    gotiation adds to community problem

    solvingandtothemanysettingsinwhich

    it takesplace inourcivic livesveryof

    ten more informally than in those stock

    imagesofdiplomats andbusinesspeoplecuttingdeals,veryoftenbybuildingrela

    tionships(notsouringthem)andcreating

    newlearningsothatbetterideasarepos

    sible,notjustconvenientdeals.

    Thepopular imagesalsodistortwhat

    itmeans tobe an effectivenegotiator. If

    hardballandpowergamesweretherule,

    onewouldexpectcunning,assertiveness,

    impatience with those who do not con

    cede, emotional toughness and a lackof

    empathy, and similar traits to define an

    effectivenegotiators style.Masternego

    tiators would be those who have mas

    oneelse.Peoplediffer,andtheyuse

    negotiationtohandletheirdiffer

    encesNegotiationisabasic

    meansofgettingwhatyouwant

    fromothers.Itisbackandforth

    communicationdesignedtoreach

    agreementwhenyouandtheother

    sidehavesomeintereststhatare

    sharedandothersthatareopposed.

    A few big claims are embedded in

    that simple definition, The first is that

    negotiation is a means toward varied

    ends,notanendoragoodthinginand

    of itself. Negotiation can even be the

    wrongmeans toward certainends, aswe

    will see in amoment.More specifically,

    the aimofnegotiation is tomake agree

    ment possible (an interim goal, not an

    endgoal).The results of that agreement

    may or may not turn out as the partiesexpect. Negotiation does not provide a

    crystalball.

    The second implication is that nego

    tiationisprimarilyaprocessofcommuni

    cation,meaning that its subject tomany

    of the breakdowns and breakthroughs

    thataffecthuman communicationgener

    ally. Wires get crossed, signals sent are

    not necessarily those received. Clever

    persuasion can oversimplify important

    facts and mobilize people for all the

    wrong reasons.People canuseverydif

    ferentwordsandbody language, too

    to convey their expectations. And theneededinformationmaynotbeavailable

    ornottoeveryoneattherighttimes.

    Third and finally, negotiation is de

    fined by interests held by parties (or

    stakeholders). Negotiation is clearly

    not the only element in joint problem

    solving.Its theone focusedoncomingto

    decisionby (a)discovering commonalities

    orcommonground inwhattwoormore

    partieswant,alongwith

    (b)waystoresolvetheir

    differences.

    By definition, then,

    negotiationmakes sense

    whereandwhenparties,

    issues, and interests are

    already (more or less)

    defined and when the

    partiesbelieve they can

    dobetteratthenegotiat

    ing table than away

    from it. Negotiation

    involves seeking agree

    ment at key decision

    points,but a great deal

    of civic processin de

    mocratic societies, both

    young and old

    involves

    defining

    the

    parties,issues,andinterests,andsetting

    upadecisionprocess.

    Negotiation is therefore part of a

    largerprocessofjointproblemsolving.

    Itsnotasetoffacilitationtricksforuse

    atthetablethatmakeupforbadcivics

    awayfromthetable.

    Myths and RealitiesIn spiteof the fact thatnegotiation

    isuseful and increasingly common, to

    manycivicmindedpeople,negotiation

    hasabadname.Itconjuresupnegativeimages of horse tradinghardball,

    selfinterested transacting in which

    power games, threats, and deception

    dominate.Bargaining instead ofbuild

    ing consensus. Dealmaking instead of

    building relationships and creating

    newpossibilitiesforcivicaction.

    Negotiation includes all of those

    things, of course. It is important for

    completing many economic transac

    tionsnot just wage agreements but

    businessdealsofmanykinds,contracts

    be tween government and non

    Introduction to Negotiation

    Negotiation is therefore part of a larger process of

    joint problem-solving. Its not a set of facilitation

    tricks for use at the table that make up for bad civics

    away from the table.

    4

    To many civic-minded

    people, negotiation

    has a bad name. It

    conjures up images of

    horse trading andhard-ball, power

    games and deception

    dominate. Bargaining

    instead of building

    consensus. Dealmak-

    ing instead of build-

    ing relationships.

  • 8/12/2019 We Are All Negotiators Now

    5/41

    Introduction to Negotiation

    tered psychological tricks for throwing

    theothersideoffbalance.

    Notso.Indecadesofadvancedtrain

    ing in negotiation and conflict resolu

    tionatHarvardandmanyotheruniver

    sitiesweve learned that some of the

    leasteffective negotiators are definedby

    those

    traits.

    Negotiation

    does

    involve

    persuasion and can require tremendous

    assertiveness and toughness, but very

    often,italsorequiresactivelisteningskill,

    substantive creativity to invent options

    formutualgain,andtheabilitytowinthe

    trust of otherseven where that means

    overcoming apainfulpast orbuilding a

    relationshipfromscratch.

    Whats more, when we ask veteran

    negotiators from themilitaryorbusiness

    world to negotiate with each other in

    simulations or roleplays, these pros

    oftendomuchworsethanbeginnerswith

    a littlebitof trainingandstrategyunder

    theirbelts.Notonlyarethetangibleout

    comesworse,buttheveterannegotiators

    leave the negotiations less emotionally

    satisfied andwith fewer useful relation

    ships with their counterparts across the

    table.The reason is that theveteransof

    ten have to unlearnbad habits. Because

    ofthenormsintheirownworkplacesand

    perhaps some factors ofpersonality and

    upbringingaswell,theveteransalsotend

    to

    view

    all

    negotiations

    as

    essentially

    competitive gamescontests wherein

    one party has to dobadly for the other

    party(ies)todowell.

    Of course, this does not mean that

    effectivenegotiationispurelyamatterof

    cooperation. Often,wecannotassumethat

    others willbe cooperative. Indeed, they

    maybealltooeagertoexploitourgood

    will and cooperativeness. They may

    hoard information while we share it.

    They may seek to improve their own

    alternatives to negotiation andworsen

    oursback us into a corner, so to

    speak, where we have little room to

    maneuver and (seemingly) little lever

    ageovertheoutcomesthatmattertous.

    Finding ways to create valuable coop

    eration while guarding against these

    risks is what negotiation skill is all

    about.

    Potential and Limits:Negotiation FundamentalsHow then should we define the

    fundamentals of negotiation in ways

    thatmakeusmoreeffective?Andhow

    shouldweunderstandthe limitsofne

    gotiation, too? The Taking Stock box

    (next page) offers an outline. It ad

    dresses the wide range of negotiation

    situations inwhich problemsolvers in

    th e public, private, and non

    governmental sectors may find them

    selves.The past few decades have seen

    dramatic growth and progress in the

    fieldsofnegotiation, mediation,alterna

    tive dispute resolution, and consensus

    building. The development of theory

    and practice in these areas is tremen

    dously positive, given the observation

    thatshareddecisionmaking is increas

    ingly the rule of the day in democ

    ratic societies. But enthusiasm for thetechniquescanblindustoasimplefact:

    Thebest tools are no goodand may

    evenbebad (harmful)when applied

    tothewrongtask.

    When bringing people together to

    effect change, the first question is not

    how to go about negotiatingdecisions

    effectively but rather : Is negotiation

    appropriate in this situation at all?

    Shouldwenegotiatewiththem?Why

    now?Whatarethealternativestonego

    tiation?

    And

    is

    a

    negotiation

    in

    fact

    pos

    siblewilltheyagreetonegotiate?

    Fromthestandpointofathirdparty

    wishingtohelppartiesinconflictcome

    toagreement,similarquestionsare:Are

    the parties that could craft a valuable

    agreementreadytonegotiate?Willthey

    recognize thevalue ofnegotiation and

    trulycommittotheprocess?Whatwill

    ittaketosupportthatprocessandseeit

    through?

    Sometimes, we have no choicebut

    to negotiate. We depend on others to

    help us accomplish things and influ

    ence decisions. We find that we have

    interests that are shared with other

    stakeholders, as Fisher and Ury de

    scribe it,but others that are opposed.

    Without formallyannouncing itor set

    tinganofficialtableatwhichtohold

    talks, we are negotiating. We are en

    gaged ingiveandtake toadvanceour

    interests.

    Butsometimeswedohaveachoice,

    and negotiation may notbe appropri

    ateornotyet.Forexample: Whenthenatureofaproblemand the

    best solution are clear and widely

    Negotiationdoes involvepersuasionandcan require

    tremendousassertivenessandtoughness,butveryof

    ten,italsorequiresactivelisteningskills,substantive

    creativityto inventoptionsformutualgain,andthe

    abilityto

    win

    the

    trust

    of

    otherseven

    where

    that

    meansovercomingapainfulpast.

    When bringing people together to effect change, the

    first question is not how to go about negotiating deci-

    sions effectively but rather: Is negotiation appropriate

    in this situation at all?

    5

  • 8/12/2019 We Are All Negotiators Now

    6/41

    understood,negotiationmayberedun

    dant, distracting, and even counter

    productive. Negotiation and conflict

    resolution have sometimes been criti

    cizedaspoorpeoplesjustice in that

    theycompensate forwhat the lawwill

    not

    enforce.

    More

    generally,

    negotia

    tion can lead to distraction and ma

    nipulation. Insome instances, lawand

    community norms point to a clear set

    of actionse.g., complianceby a key,

    powerfulparty.Negotiation canbean

    awkwardwaytomakekeypartiesdo

    therightthing.

    Whenitisnotclearlyintheinterestsof

    allparties tonegotiateorkeyparties

    otherwise lack commitment to the

    process.Thethresholdtesthere isthis:

    Do the parties to a negotiation recog

    nize, at minimum, the potential to do

    better at the negotiating table than

    away from it?This iskey to the com

    mitment thatnegotiation requires.But

    key parties may prefer lawsuit, inde

    pendentaction(goingitalone),orsome

    other alternative to negotiation. Dia

    logue and key eventsa change of

    statusorperceivedinterestsmaylead

    key parties to reassess the attractive

    nessoftheiralternatives(seebelow).

    Whenpartiesneedassistancebutdont

    yet have it. Sometimes, gaps in data

    and information, the technical com

    plexity of the issues, different world

    views, a history of strained relation

    ships,orotherbarriersmakeitimpossi

    bleforpartiestocometoagreementon

    theirown.Intheseinstances,mediators

    orother thirdpartyfacilitatorsmaybe

    helpful to support theprocess or sim

    ply

    to

    help

    parties

    explore

    the

    possibil

    ityofnegotiatingwith eachother (see

    below).

    As the tools in this series explore in

    detail, community problemsolving is

    defined by collective effort to identify

    and frame problems for public discus

    sion, tobuildmovementand create con

    stituencies for change, to setmeaningful

    directionschart a course or plan

    Introduction to Negotiation

    6

    TAKING STOCK (Part One): Negotiation Fundamentals

    1. Should we negotiate? Negotiation is not always best. Sometimes, parties are notcommitted to it, negotiation may be a device for distraction or manipulation(where little of value will actually be decided), or one or more parties may nothave the influence and autonomy needed to protect and advance its interests atthe table. But sometimes, we have no choice: where there is interdependence and

    people have different views of a problem or somewhat different interests, wefind ourselves, in effect, negotiating a way forward.

    2. What value does negotiation add? Negotiation is a part of problem-solving to-gether. Negotiations are defined by parties, issues, interests, alternatives (choicesof terms that together would make up an agreement), and the size of the bar-gaining range (in which agreement is actually possible). But specific negotia-tionscrucial episodes in time when agreement may be forged, given parties,issues, interests, and alternativesare often embedded in larger processes oforganizing stakeholders and issues for attention, planning that is substantivelysmart as well as participatory, and building partnerships to implement jointlycreated plans. Moreover, community problem-solving frequently involves a host ofnegotiations, and varied sets of parties, over timenot one big deal in whichall things are decided once and for all.

    3. Isnt it about competitive tricks and clever maneuvering? Negotiation ofteninvolves some element of competition, as when we each party wants part of alimited resource, but can also involve important and creative cooperation, aswhenparties invent new options to create more value for all sides. Sometimes, partiesvalue different things, not the same thing, and this provides a way to make valu-able win-win trades. Negotiation is not synonymous with either competition orcooperation alone.

    4. OK, but in the end, is it only dealmaking? Negotiations can be focused oncrafting a deal (to seize an opportunity) or resolving a dispute (to overcome acostly stand-off or conflict) or both. The same fundamentals are useful either way,but deals and disputes may be quite different in tone, tempo, and specifics.

    5. Dont some negotiations end in impasse anyway? Many impasses and ineffi-cient agreements result when parties refuse to negotiate their interests and in-stead focus on particular positions. Negotiation becomes a contest defined bydemands, a test of who will give in first.

    6. Is negotiation always about formal agreements and marathon sessions atthe table? No, negotiation can be quite formal, as when a process of seekingagreement is announced and agreements made are recorded and given legalstatus, perhaps in a contract or pact. But negotiation can also be quite informal--part of the give-and-take of everyday civic life, in which participation is neededto make progress possible, in which constituencies for change, and not just techni-cally promising ideas, are required.

    7. Who should participate? This depends on the issues and stakes. Negotiation cantake place between just two parties or among multiple parties. In the latter case,agreement may require the assent of all parties (unanimity) or some critical num-ber of the partiessay 5 out of 6 or 7 out of 10acting in a coalition. Plus,agents (representatives) must often negotiate on behalf of stakeholder groups.

    8. Arent mediators or facilitators important? Negotiation may be assisted by thirdparties, whether neutral or interested facilitators. The most well-known type ofthird-party facilitator is the neutral mediator, whose job it is to help parties cometo useful, sustainable agreements. Neutrals have no substantive interest in theoutcome, only an interest in improving the process. But problem-solving over timemay call for intervention by mediators with clout who press stubborn partiesinto giving negotiation a chance. Indeed, intermediaries or go-betweens play avariety of challenging but important roles in community problem-solving. (See thelinked tool in this series, Working the Middle: Roles and Challenges of Intermedi-aries.)

  • 8/12/2019 We Are All Negotiators Now

    7/41

    decisions. Everyone agrees that de

    mocracy

    demands

    dialogue

    and

    de

    liberationtoallowacarefultreatment

    of issues. But sustaining democracy

    alsorequiresconcreteactiononprob

    lemsintheworld,andactionrequires

    making choices, setting priorities,

    agreeing on roles, agreeing to dis

    agreeonsomeissuesbutmoveahead

    on others. Talk alone wont do the

    trick,evenifthattalkisinspiredand

    inclusive. Engage, define, deliberate,

    decide, act, and then engage again.

    Anywayyoudefine the civic action

    loop,decisionandactionare critical,

    and shared decision often requires

    the giveandtake of negotiation,

    whetheritsformalorinformal.

    Whenthereisawillingnesstodecide

    but basic communication break

    downsorotherprocessbarriersget

    in the way. Much of negotiation is

    about thinking and communicating

    more effectively to seize the potential

    agreementsthatseemtoliejustoutside

    ourgrasp.

    Whenaunilateraldecisioncouldgetthe

    jobdonebutajointdecisionwouldbe

    morelegitimateandsupportableinthe

    community.

    ThesecondmajorlessonintheTaking

    Stock box is that promoting the public

    interestthroughjointactioncommunity

    problemsolving, broadly definedmay

    involvearangeofnegotiationsovertime,

    not one big, formal negotiating table

    where all thingsgetdecided,whereone

    grand deal is struck. So we want to

    think of the work of tackling a public

    problem(s) or seizing a major opportu

    nity to promote the common good as

    demanding

    a

    host

    of

    negotiation

    skillsandsettings,dependingonwhat ismost

    appropriate when and whose interests

    areatstake.

    Furthermore, as Inotedabove,nego

    tiationisameansofdeliveringthegoods,

    but negotiation does not enable itself.

    Negotiation matters most to a commu

    nitysciviclifewhereitbuildsonaproc

    essoforganizingissuesandstakeholders,

    carrying out substantively smart aswell

    as participatory planning, and building

    partnershipstoimplementjointlycreated

    plans.Somedefinenegotiationsobroadly

    that it encompasses all of thesethe

    agreementseekingprocessitselfandeve

    rythingaround it.ButIfinditmoreuse

    ful to define and explore those other

    practices and processes as challenging,

    importantintheirownright,andworthy

    of careful strategies and tactics (see the

    toolsinthisseriesonthosetopics).

    Third,manyeffortstomakedecisions

    together include, unavoidably, elements

    ofcompetitionaswellascooperation. So

    Introduction to Negotiation

    based on stakeholder values as well as

    the substantive challenges posedby the

    problems people care about, and other

    processes.

    The work isboth art and science in

    that some patterns are regular and reli

    able but improvisation and good judg

    ment, as well as risktaking and acts of

    intuition,areusuallyrequiredtoo.

    The opportunities to apply negotia

    tion skills within these processes, often

    quite informally, aremany.Butnot eve

    ryone wants to or can participate effec

    tively innegotiation. (See thecaseexam

    ples

    on

    organizing

    and

    negotiation

    in

    the

    linked tool in this series, Organizing

    Stakeholders, Building Movement, Set

    tingtheAgenda.)

    Beforewemove on, letsbe clearon

    thekindsofsituations inwhichnegotia

    tion may not only be appropriate but

    actuallyessential:

    When parties share an interest in an

    outcomebuthavenot come toneeded

    See linked tool in this series,Organizing Stakeholders, Building Movement, Setting

    the Agenda

    Beyond being appropriate, negotiation may actually be essential where: parties

    share an interest in an outcome but have not come to needed decisions, there is a

    willingness to decide but communication breakdowns and other barriers get in

    the way, or a unilateral decision couldperhaps get the job donebut a joint one

    would be much more legitimate and supportable in the community.

    7

  • 8/12/2019 We Are All Negotiators Now

    8/41

    wewanttogetbetterat

    identifying and work

    ing through both as

    effectivelyaspossible.

    As we will see be

    low, this is more than

    an abstractprinciple of

    recognition. Cooperat

    ing and competing at

    the same time is chal

    lenging formost of us,

    because

    we

    are

    not

    ro

    bots. Efforts to get more of what we

    wantclaim value, as negotiation ex

    pertsJamesSebeniusandDavidLaxput

    itmaycrowdouteffortstocreatevalue

    forallof theparties involved.This ises

    peciallytruewhereemotionsarerunning

    high, the issuesarecomplex, theoptions

    seem limited, and time and other re

    sourcesareinshortsupply.

    Point four in the textbox remindsus

    that negotiations can be mainly about

    creating an opportunity that hinges on

    shareddecisionmakingadealtocreate

    a new policy or program, pool funds,

    exchange resources, etc.or mainly

    aboutsettlingadisputethatiscostlyand

    unacceptable to theparties involved.Or

    both. Not only aredealmaking anddis

    pute resolution somewhat different in

    tempoandtone,buttheconsequencesof

    not reachingagreementcanbequitedif

    ferent as well. No agreement in the

    contextofadealgenerallymeansthatthe

    parties find alternative ways to pursue

    the

    opportunities

    they

    value.

    But a failure to resolve adisputebe

    tween two or more parties can impose

    huge costs on other parties or the com

    munityatlarge,sourrelationshipsamong

    thedisputants(makingithardertoprob

    lemsolve together later on), and even

    generatenew,widerconflictsthedown

    wardspiralwhereconflictescalates.

    Fifth, as we will see in a moment,

    many people instinctively negotiate

    overpositionsspecific terms theypre

    ferrather than explore multiple op

    tions for advancing their interests (the

    underlying, valued things that posi

    tionsreflect).

    Forexample, innegotiationswitha

    companyandlocalgovernmentoveran

    economicdevelopment project, a com

    munitybased nonprofit group insists

    on a specific number of newjobs for

    neighborhood residents instead of ex

    ploringmultiplewaysofsatisfying the

    groupsunderlyinginterests,whichare

    to (a)enhanceeconomicsecurity in the

    neighborhood, inpartby (b)maximiz

    ingthepositivespilloversoftheproject.

    Finding these terms unacceptable, the

    company backs off, governments gets

    impatient with both parties, finger

    pointingbegins,andtheresultiscostly

    impasse.

    Byengaging theparties in learning

    and a process of considering different

    ways

    to

    satisfy

    the

    underlying

    interests,

    interestedbasedbargainingenhances

    the likelihood of a valuable agree

    mentaswellasarelationshiptodraw

    onanotherday.

    Wewill explore the final points in

    the textbox in the sections to come

    lookingattwopartyversusmultiparty

    negotiations, forexample, and the role

    of mediators and other thirdparty fa

    cilitators.Mediation isquite important

    in community problemsolving, even

    where it isunofficial and informal.And

    welluse some caseexamples toexplore

    what it means to prepare effectively for

    negotiationandactuallyworkthingsout

    atthetable,throughbackandforthcom

    munication. (For more illustrations, see

    thereadingandresourcelistattheendofthistool.)

    Principled Negotiation:An OverviewFornow,letsassumethatnegotiation

    actually is appropriateand perhaps

    even essentialin some context that

    matterstoyou.Therearedefinedpar

    ties, key issues, interests that are at

    least somewhat clear to shape and

    motivate the negotiation. Here are

    FisherandUrysbasicrulesforprincipled negotiation, which stand up again

    and again in practicein an incredibly

    widevarietyofspecificsituationsaround

    theworld:

    (People)SeparatethePeoplefromtheProb

    lem.Fisher andUry advisenegotiators

    nottomakebigassumptionsaboutthe

    othersidesintentionsandnottoentan

    gletherelationshipsinthesubstanceof

    the problem. Instead, they urge us to

    discussion perceptions, let each side

    blow off steam, and listen actively towhatisbeingsaid.

    (Interests) Focus on interests, not posi

    tions. Acknowledge their interests as

    part of problemsolving.Explore your

    multiple interests: ask why ques

    tions,get atbasic concernsbehind the

    statedpreferences.

    (Options)Generateavarietyofpossibilities

    before deciding what to do. Invent op

    tionsavoid the instinct to narrow

    immediately to specific terms or positionsby making time to brainstorm

    without judging. Use facilitators to

    supporttheprocessofinventingbefore

    deciding.

    (Criteria)Insistthattheresultbebasedon

    someobjectivestandard, such as market

    value, precedents or moral standards,

    bestavailable scientific judgments,

    professionalstandards,theprincipleof

    Introduction to Negotiation

    Failuretoresolveadisputebetweentwoormorepar

    ties can impose huge costs on otherparties or the

    community at large, sour relationships among the

    disputants,andevengeneratenew,widerconflicts.

    8

  • 8/12/2019 We Are All Negotiators Now

    9/41

    reciprocityorequity,measurable costs

    andbenefits,etc.

    Thedistinctionbetweenpositionsand

    interests is extremely important and,we

    have found,mucheasier said thanprac

    ticed. Negotiation

    educators often tell

    the storyof two chil

    dren fightingoveran

    orange. A parent in

    tervenesand,perhaps

    not surprisingly,gets

    the children to agree

    to split theorange in

    half.Fair and equita

    ble, it might seem.

    But it turns out that

    one child wanted to

    eat the orange (the

    fruit),whiletheotherwanted only the orange rindto use in a

    baking recipe.Eachchildcouldhavene

    gotiated a much better dealall of the

    fruit to one and all of the rind to the

    other. But by responding to positions

    rather than interests, the parent has un

    wittingly created a very inefficient deal.

    Intheshorthandofnegotiation, consider

    ablevaluehasbeenleftonthetable.

    AsFisherandUryhavelongstressed,

    these and otherprinciples aredrivenby

    practical,notmoralconsiderations.Thisis

    not to say that feltobligations toothers,

    or even allegiance to higher creeds and

    notionsofjustice,havenoplaceinnego

    tiation.Rather,theprinciplednegotiation

    approach seeks to enable negotiators

    who may have quite different moral

    commitmentsandeven limited trust in

    each other to problemsolve together.

    The approach isdesigned to help two

    or more parties do

    better through ne

    gotiation than they

    could otherwise,

    period. It does not

    relyonhighermoral

    principles about

    what we owe to

    others.

    That said, it certainly helps when

    negotiatorscometothetablewithsome

    commitmenttofairplayandagenuine

    interest in fair outcomes for all sides.

    Such commitment and interest may

    well be rooted in moral, religious, or

    culturaltraditionsaboutwhichthepar

    tiesfeelverystrongly.

    Letsputthese ideas towork in the

    firstcaseexample,inwhichwewillalso

    use the firstworksheet in this strategy

    tool.

    Case #1: Negotiating a Public/Nonprofit Contract for Services

    Imagine a meetingit could be in

    almost any community in any corner of

    the worldin which a government

    agency and a nonprofit, non

    governmental

    organization

    are

    scheduledto develop a contract for services. The

    nonprofitorganizationwillbetheservice

    provider, government the funder and

    regulator that invests public

    resources and monitors per

    formance toensurecompliance

    withapplicable lawsaswellas

    results. Lets say that the ser

    vice is screening and vaccinat

    ing children to prevent the

    spread of a crippling disease.

    (Theservicecouldjustaseasily

    be job training or environ

    mental cleanup or develop

    mentofaffordablehousing.)

    Letskeepitsimpletostartand

    imaginethattheonlyissueupfordiscus

    sionispricethefeethatgovernmentwill

    pay thenonprofit for a specificquantity

    and quality of service. There are, there

    fore,just twopartiesandonenegotiable

    issue.

    The worksheet on the next page

    (Getting Ready toNegotiate: Prep Tool #1)

    allows

    us

    to

    define

    the

    situation,

    betterunderstandouralternatives,andprepare

    an approach. Both partiesthe govern

    ment and nonprofit representatives

    could benefit from this preparation. To

    keepthisdiscussionclearer,though, lets

    supposethatIrepresentthenonprofit.

    We know there are two issues, and

    assume fornow that there ishistorybe

    tweenme and the otherparty. Itwould

    helpme toknowmoreabout theperson

    negotiatingacrossthetablefromme,soI

    decide to do some homework on their

    work styleand reputation (ifany) in thecommunity as a negotiator.Also,where

    influentialsareconcerned,assumethat

    therearenootherkeypartiesexcept for

    those ingovernment towhommynego

    tiation counterpart reports. Presumably,

    theirinterestswillbedirectlyrepresented

    by my counterpart. (Note that it would

    help if I knew somethingabout the per

    Introduction to Negotiation

    The principled negotia-tion approach seeks to

    enable negotiators who

    may have quite different

    moral commitments and

    even limited trust in

    each other to problem-

    solve together.

    9

    TAKING STOCK (Part Two) PRINCIPLED NEGOTIATION

    In Getting to Yes, Roger Fisher and William Ury provide four (4) core principles:

    1. (People) Separate the people from the problem. Many impasses and poor agree-ments result from confounding the substance of the issues with the relationship orpersonal issues between the negotiators.

    2. (Interests) Focus on interests, not positions. Intereststhe underlying things of

    value that negotiators really wantcan often be advanced in many ways (seenext point). So specific terms (positions) should not crowd out the effort to under-stand and address interests.

    3. (Options) Generate a variety of possibilities before deciding what to do. AsFisher and Ury add, Invent before deciding. Often, its psychological, not substan-tive barriers, that prevent parties from creating better options and more value forall sides.

    4. (Criteria) Insist that the result be based on some objective standard, such as mar-ket value, community precedents or shared moral standards, best-available scien-tific judgments, professional standards, the principle of reciprocity or equity, meas-urable costs and benefits, etc.

    (Continuedonpage11

  • 8/12/2019 We Are All Negotiators Now

    10/41

  • 8/12/2019 We Are All Negotiators Now

    11/41

    sons bossi.e., about who this person

    will report toon theoutcomeofourne

    gotiation.Ifthatpersonsperceptionsare

    important to my counterpart, then they

    become,by extension, important to me,

    too.)

    Next,letstrytounderstandthenum

    berandnatureoftheissuesbeingnegoti

    ated and what thebargaining range on

    thoseissuesmaylooklike.Theonetangi

    bleissuehereisprice.Wecanexpectthat

    thenonprofitwill favor a higher fee for

    its services, while government will seek

    to minimize the fee. The price issue is

    therefore inherently

    competitive; the two

    parties interests

    on this narrow is

    sueare at odds,and the negotiation

    looks much like a

    private, negotiated

    transaction, inwhich

    youorImightbuya

    homeorusedcaror

    ornament in a ba

    zaar.

    Before we make this situation more

    complexand also more realisticby

    bringingother issues intoview,consider

    how much room the two parties have,

    evenonthenarrowissueofprice,tocraft

    a mutually beneficial agreement and

    leavethetablesatisfied.

    First,thebargainingrange,sometimes

    called the zone ofpossible agreement,

    isdefinedby the limitsofwhat the two

    partieswillaccept.Rationally, ifgovern

    mentcanpurchasethesameservicefrom

    another vendor for, say, $12 per unit of

    service(perclientserved),whyshould it

    pay this nonprofit vendor any more?

    Twelvedollarsperunitofservice,whats

    knownastheBestAlternativetoNegotiated Agreement or BATNA in the

    shorthand,becomes the rational reserva

    tionprice (reservationvalue)of thegov

    ernmentparty.

    Tokeep thecase simple fornow,we

    are going to assume that government

    doeshavearangeofserviceprovidersto

    choosefrom(thoughthismaynotbethe

    case) and that it can compare providers

    and choose on thebasis ofprice alone

    (though realistically, a host of other

    factorsmightalsobeweighed).

    The nonprofits alternatives and

    reservationpricemaybemorecomplex,

    however.Governmentmaybetheonly

    funder in themarket forvaccination

    services.Thenonprofitmaybe lowon

    funds and eager toget thevaccination

    service funded. Its only alternative to

    governmentfundingmaybetoprovide

    adifferentservice,generatesomereve

    nuesthatwayandselffund(onamore

    limited basis) the vaccination service.

    Realistically, this nonprofitour non

    profitsfinancial

    options seem lim

    ited.

    Akey conclusion of

    this

    preliminary

    analysis, then, turns

    out tobe abig les

    son about bargain

    ing power: Some

    times, the bestway to

    gain leverage at the

    table is to improve

    your options away from the tablei.e.,

    your alternatives to negotiated agree

    ment.

    Butstickingtothesimpleversionof

    events, we, the nonprofit directors,

    have decided that we will accept as

    little as $6 per unit of service, which is

    just a little more than our costs ($5) for

    providing the service. Inprinciple, then,

    thebargainingrangerunsfromthemini

    mum $5 per unit thatwe will accept to

    the maximum $12 that government will

    pay($512).

    Analyzing the Case: Persuasion,First Offers, and Walk-Aways

    Whats striking, in the roleplayswe

    haverunintheclassroomwithhundreds

    of negotiators of all ages and back

    grounds, ishowvariedtheoutcomesare

    acrosspairsofnegotiatorsgiventhesame

    instructions and same basic structure

    (twoparties,one issue, fixed reservation

    values). While quite a few negotiators

    endupwithagreementsclustered in the

    middle of the bargaining range, more

    thanafewareattheextremes,andsome

    donotreachagreementatall,evenwhere

    thereseemstobemuchsoroomtoagree!

    How is this possible? First, the two

    partiesinvolvedrarelyknowexactlyhow

    much the other party willbe willing to

    accept. The frequently heard question,

    Whats yourbottom line? aims to se

    curethispreciousinformation.

    So one reason that our hundreds of

    pairs of negotiators end up in different

    places is that people make different as

    sumptionsabouttheothersidesreserva

    tion value and how much or how little

    willsatisfy them. Inmany instances,ne

    gotiators underestimate the fullbargain

    ing range: their own view of the issues

    blinds them to the other sides perspec

    tive and, in this case, financial room to

    maneuver. Sometimes, though, each ne

    gotiator overestimates how much the

    other party can concede, and stubborn,

    positionalbargaining ensues, leading to

    impasse orbruising,dissatisfying agree

    ments.

    Note,before we move on, note that

    the Worksheet is a device for recording

    everythingthatyoualreadyknowandfor

    Introduction to Negotiation

    11

    (Continuedfrompage9)

    Sometimes, the best way to gain leverage at the table

    is to improve your options away from the tablei.e.,

    your alternativesto negotiated agreement.

  • 8/12/2019 We Are All Negotiators Now

    12/41

    identifyingsomegapsinyourknowledge

    that careful ba ckground work

    (homework) might fill in. Typically,

    youwontknow thebargainingrangeas

    specificallyas Igave it toyouabove ($5

    to$12),butthemoreyoucanfindout in

    advance, the better. The more you can

    learn at the table to add to your home

    work,thebetteraswell.

    Asecondreasonthatnegotiationout

    comesdiffersodramaticallyfrompairto

    pair is that negotiation is a backand

    forthpersuasiveprocess, and somepeo

    ple are more persuasiveor conversely

    more easily persuadedthan others.

    More

    generally,

    negotiators

    strengths,

    weaknesses, and stylesvarywidely (see

    SkillsandStyleonthispage).

    In multiple examples of the simple

    price negotiation outlined here, we

    have heard every conceivable argument

    and requestat the table,during thene

    gotiationbyeveryimaginablepersonal

    ity!

    Some in the seller role (the party

    that seeks a higher price)will empha

    sizehowhard it is tomakeendsmeet,

    portraying itself as the resourcepoor

    party, the disadvantaged in the situa

    tion.Settingtheprice isframedasfun

    damentallyafairness issue.Otherswill

    make the most dramatic claims about

    the service they are selling, comparing

    theirservices(unaidedbyanythingthe

    facultyhave suggested) tothebest in

    theworldandstateoftheart.Other

    negotiators will emphasize the impor

    tance of a future working relation

    ship,evenwheretheinstructionsindi

    cate that no such future is likely, that

    thisistobeaoneoffdeal.

    Thekey is thathumanbeingsoften

    respond at least as much to the

    why (rationales) we offer as the

    what. Mountains of psychological

    research confirm this. We are much

    more likely to respond to people and

    ideas that strike us as reasonable and

    evenimportant.

    OnereasonIaskmystudentstothink

    about their specific arguments, and not

    just their interests, in advanceand to

    outline their arguments on the Work

    sheetis that a little attention to theseprinciples of persuasion can go a long

    way(andseePrinciplesofPersuasionon

    thenextpage).

    Persuading, of course, is about influ

    encinghowyouraudiencethinksandacts.So

    know your audience is rule oneand

    anotherreasontodoyourhomework.

    More Lessons: The Psychology ofNegotiation

    A third reason that outcomes range

    widely is anchoring, a welldocumented

    psychologicalphenomenon inwhichour

    mindsgetstuckoranchoredbyassign

    ingweight toapieceof information that

    is irrelevantor,atbest,modestly impor

    tant. As Max Bazerman and Margaret

    Neale show in Negotiating Rationally,

    manynegotiatorsusefirstoffersorother

    early, stagesetting remarks to anchor

    their counterparts in a favorable part of

    thebargainingrange.

    How does this work? The govern

    mentnegotiatormightbeginourcontract

    meetingwithastatement thatpasses forsmalltalk,Youknow,wevebeenburied

    in these contract talks lately. The other

    day, I spent fourhourswithanonprofit

    groupeventhoughIwaswillingtocome

    upto$7perunit!

    Thegovernmentscontractnegotiator

    is hoping I will do several things with

    this casual remark. First, she hopes I

    willviewmynegotiationwithher in the

    Introduction to Negotiation

    Negotiation is a backandforthpersuasiveprocess, and somepeople are more

    persuasiveorconversely,moreeasilypersuadedthanothers.

    12

    TAKING STOCK (Part Three) NEGOTIATION SKILLS & STYLE

    Roger Fisher and Wayne Davis find that six interpersonal skills are consistently impor-tant for effective negotiation. They help define a negotiators personal repertoire:

    1. Being able to express strong feelings appropriately.

    2. Remaining rational in the face of strong feelings.

    3. Being assertive within a negotiation without damaging the relationship.

    4. Improving a relationship without damage to a particular negotiation.

    5. Speaking clearly in ways that promote listening.

    6. Inquiring and listening effectively (active listening).

    Keith Allred, inventor of the Personal Conflict Profile, an assessment tool, recom-mends developing and, over time, measuring your success as a negotiator in multi-ple dimensions. You and those with whom you negotiate should rate you a success in

    1. Being persuasive.

    2. Maintaining strong relations with the other party.

    3. Making your reasoning clear for the positions you advocate.

    4. Understanding the other partys interests and communicating that you appreciatetheir perspective.

    5. Recognizing the relative importance of various issues to the other party, as well aswhich interests you share with them and which conflict.

    6. Generating options that effectively address the partys interests.

    7. Apologizing for problems or harms for which you are responsible and avoidinginappropriate blaming of the other party for problems which arise.

  • 8/12/2019 We Are All Negotiators Now

    13/41

    context of comparable negotiations held

    recently and perhaps accept a compara

    bleoutcomeas fair.Butunless thereare

    mandatedfeeschedulesandotherguide

    lines for these contracts, my contract

    shouldpresumablybedecidedonitsown

    meritsandaccordingtothewillingnessof

    the two parties at the table to craft the

    mostvaluable agreement they can.Who

    caresaboutthatothernegotiation?

    Second,mynegotiationcounterpartis

    hoping I will remem

    ber the words even

    though I was willing

    to

    come

    up

    to

    $7a

    signthatsheisacoop

    erative ba rgai ne r

    (willing) and that she really conceded

    something to come, in effect, all the

    wayupto$7.

    Without using overt hardbargainer

    tactics,my counterpart is seeking to an

    chormeatthelowendofthebargaining

    range so that I will think any outcome

    greater than $7 incredibly generous (on

    herpart)butperhapsevenunattainable.

    Another, more direct approach to

    anchoring ones counterpart is to make

    thefirstoffer,andthiscanbedoneinfor

    mally.My counterpartmight say,How

    muchdoyou really needto provide this

    service? About $5.50 per unit? Again,

    the$5.50figureismeanttogetmethink

    ing on the low end of the bargaining

    range,andwhileitisnotanofficialoffer,

    the implication is that my counterpart

    mentions itbecause shewould certainly

    bewilling toagreeonaprice thatmeets

    myneeds.

    AsFisherandUry remindus inGettingtoYes,ifnegotiationisaboutadvanc

    ing interests, we can disarm the hard

    bargainer without appearing unreason

    able.Idontthinkitsstrictlyaquestion

    of need, I say, So why dont we talk

    aboutafairpricefordeliveringavaluable

    servicetothecommunity?

    The most important defense against

    anchoringisrecognizingitandpracticing

    a littlemindfulness at the table, lest our

    ownmindsplaytricksonus.

    But the second defense hinges on amorebasic question:Whenshould Imake

    thefirstoffer?The ruleof thumb is that if

    youhavedone your homework and are

    fairly confidentyouknowyour counter

    parts reservation value, then make the

    first offer and work to anchor themin a

    portionofthebargainingrangefavorable

    toyou.Ifyouareunsureabouttheirreserva

    Introduction to Negotiation

    Disarming the hard bargainer: I dont think its strictly a question of need, I say,

    So why dont we talk about a fair price for delivering a valuable service to the

    community?

    Framing is important to persuasion because people perceive

    their interests differently depending on how choices are posed.

    13

    TAKING STOCK (Part Four) PRINCIPLES OF PERSUASION

    As Michael Watkins notes, framing is important to persuasion because people per-ceive their interests differently depending on how choices are posed. Taken too far,this is a recipe for manipulation, of course, but used appropriately, framing principlescan give our good ideas a needed boost. Here are some tried-and-true approachesto framing and otherwise conveying our ideas more persuasively:

    1. Invoke the common good. Many persuasive arguments emphasize collective bene-fits and downplay individual costs.

    2. Make connections to core values. Draw on the genius of marketing, which linksthings for sale (cars, clothes, etc.) to cherished values, such as independence, re-

    spect, and innovation.3. Heighten concerns about loss or risk. Emphasize what makes desired courses of

    action less risky than alternative courses of action.

    4. Leverage the power of contrasts to make requests seem more reasonable. Prac-titionersoften manage expectations by living the adage, Under-promise, over-deliver. Likewise, negotiators may ask for a great deal initially and then retreatto a more reasonable request. Advocates compare what they want to what othershave asked for, showing how their requests arent so big in the scheme ofthings (i.e., in comparison).

    5. Strategically narrow or broaden the focus. A choice that could be construed assetting an undesirable precedent might best be framed as a highly circumscribed,isolated situation independent of other decisions, says Watkins.

    6. Neutralize toxic issues. Table them or make up-front commitments that allow you

    to move on to other issues where you can generate momentum.

    7. Refute counter-arguments in advance. This rule goes back at least as far as theancient Greeks, notes Watkins. Anticipate their major reservations and addressthem preventively.

    8. Give your counterpart(s) a script for persuading others. Give those with whomyoure negotiating some arguments that address the concerns of key otherse.g.,their bosses, peers, allies, etc. Equip those you are persuading to persuade others.

    Source: Michael Watkins, The Power to Persuade (Harvard Business School Publishing, 2000).See also Cialdini, Influence: The Psychology of Persuasion (1984) and Zimbardo and Leippe, ThePsychology of Attitude Change and Social Influence (1991).

  • 8/12/2019 We Are All Negotiators Now

    14/41

    tionvalue,either let them make the first

    offer (andworkhard toavoidbeing an

    choredbyit)ormakeaflexiblefirstoffer

    that probes for information: What

    would do it for you here, say about

    $11? (Note that thiswording is lessag

    gressive than Whats your bottom

    line?)

    Thereareother,moresubtle, reasons

    thatpairsofnegotiators,given the same

    basic exercise with the same instruc

    tions,generatesuchawiderangeofout

    comes.One reason isdifferences inper

    ceptions of the situation. Some negotia

    tors

    instinctively

    see

    the

    process

    of

    seek

    ingagreementasaprimarilycompetitive

    process.Theyhaveawilltowinanduse

    the phrase winning to describe their

    outcomes.Inthissimplepricecase,com

    petitiveas it is,bothpartiescandobetter

    thantheirreservationvalueswhich isa

    form of winning open toboth parties

    yetsomenegotiatorscannothelpbutsee

    themselvesinaracewiththeotherparty.

    Anotherpsychologicaldistinctionwe

    often find is this: Some negotiators are

    muchmorewillingthanotherstoriskno

    agreement for the sake of winning con

    cessions from the other party (i.e.,

    claiming value for themselves). In

    plainer terms, some parties are much

    morewilling thanothers towalkaway

    fromthetable.Andthecredibleindica

    tion that theywill walk awayitmay

    or may notbe seen as a threat per

    secanbe apowerful source of influ

    enceovertheoutcome(specifictermsof

    the agreement). Not surprisingly, afavorite tactic in price negotiations, or

    other competitive oneissue negotia

    tions, ismakingtheotherpartybelieve

    that you are indifferent to the agree

    ment,couldtakeitorleaveit.

    Taking the Case Further: Reputa-tions, Linked Bargains, and JointGain

    Asapracticalmatter,mostnegotia

    tionsimportantincommunityproblem

    solvingarenot so limitedor sopurely

    competitive.Letsaddafewfeaturesto

    this public/nonprofit contract example.

    That is, lets change thegame inways

    that reflect more realworld features

    andpossibilities.

    Imagine,firstofall,thattheencoun

    terbetweenagovernmentagencyanda

    key nonprofit service provider is any

    thingbutaonetimeoroneoffagree

    ment, thatsome future is likely in that

    the parties will be dealing with each

    otheragainandperhaps inavarietyof

    settings. Immediately, we should recog

    nizeafewthingsabouthowdramatically

    this may shift our preparation for the

    negotiationandourbehavioratthetable:

    Reputation matters. The stakes are no

    longer limited to the tangible issues

    formally up for negotiation (such as

    priceforservices)butnowincludeour

    reputationsin the community.We care

    notonly about theneartermoutcome

    but about perceptions of the outcome

    andeffectsofthoseperceptionsonsub

    sequent encountersprobably with a

    range of parties, notjust our counter

    partsacrossthetablenow.

    Bargainscanbelinked.The termsof this

    agreementmaybe linked to other ne

    gotiations inwhich the same twopar

    tiesexpect toengage.That is, thisbar

    gainmaybelinkedtoanotheronethat

    includes the two parties, so we will

    probably think about the gains and

    concessions we make with a series of

    negotiations inmind, notjust the one

    encounter.Wemayevenexplicitlylink

    todays

    agreement

    to

    another

    one:

    Dothisformenow,andIwillcompensate

    youlater.

    Thequalityandusefulnessof therelation

    ship is at stake. For all of the just

    mentioned reasons, strengthening or

    weakening the relationship between

    thepartiesisalwaysapossibility,even

    if the parties do not discuss their

    Introduction to Negotiation

    Somenegotiatorsaremuchmorewillingthanothers torisknoagreementwalk

    awayfromthetableforthesakeofwinningconcessionsfromtheotherparty

    The stakes are no longer limited to the tangible

    issues formally up for negotiation but now include

    our reputations in the community.

    14

  • 8/12/2019 We Are All Negotiators Now

    15/41

    (intangible) interest in improving the

    relationship explicitly (or pursue it

    withequalgustoandeffectiveness).

    These considerations are incredibly

    commoninjointproblemsolvingandnotonly at the local or community level.

    Many of our most valuable agreements

    are forged with people with whom we

    willdealagainandagain.Networksop

    erate to communicate our reputations

    forfairorunfairplay,forcertaintypesof

    demandsandconcessions,foremploying

    a particular style of negotiation. Parties

    confronted with imposing limitations in

    theneartermfindwaystousethefuture

    to promise compensationwhat goes

    aroundcomesaround,wesay,andwin

    some, lose some, meaning that what

    matters isdoing aswell asyou can over

    thelonghaul,notjustwinningtoday.

    Lets change the price game in an

    otherimportantwaynow,expandingthe

    number and types of issues. (Note that

    one key question on the Worksheet is,

    Whataretheissues?andanotheris,Is

    there room to introduce additional is

    sues?)

    Evenwhereanegotiation ismainly

    a transaction between two parties, in

    public problemsolving, transactions

    arerarelyaboutone issuealone.Along

    withtangibleinterests

    inprice(financial

    resources),time,andsubstantiverolein

    whateverfollowstheagreement,parties

    often care about a host of intangibles,

    such as image, higher principles

    havingasay, forexample,orsettingan

    importantprecedentorrespectingcom

    munity traditions and the values be

    hindthem.

    There are two ways to look at the

    effects of adding issues, which often

    change the game. One way is to con

    clude that thenewgame ismore com

    plex,hardertoresolvebecausetheyare

    nowmoreconcernsandmoretofigure

    out and work out. And adding issues

    may sometimes just make things

    harder,itstrue.Butanother,morecrea

    tive way to look at this is to see that

    when theres more to negotiate, theres

    oftenmore room tonegotiate too.AsSe

    benius and Lax note in TheManager as

    Negotiator, where parties value different

    things (or the same things differently),

    theycanmakevaluable,winwintrades.

    Lets return to the case of our two

    partycontractnegotiation, thistimewithafewmoreissuesandafuturethepros

    pectofa relationshipand additional en

    countersinthemix.

    Imagine that thegovernment agency

    valuesthreethingsbutnotallthreetothe

    samedegree.Thepublicbudgetistighter

    thisyear than last, and allmanagersare

    under pressure to show cost savings

    whereverpossible.Soprice (forservices)

    isveryimportant,andultimatelythegov

    ernment caresmost about totalprice,not

    the

    unit

    price,

    because

    its

    the

    total

    costthatwillbemostvisibletothepublicand

    toelectedofficials.Second, theMayor is

    eager to show progress on campaign

    commitments to improve community

    health,most of all childrenshealth and

    safety.So timinghow soon the services

    can begin and get to communitywide

    scaleisalsovery important to thegov

    ernment. A third issue, program design

    (thespecificsofhowthevaccinationpro

    gram will function) is only somewhat

    important,aslongastheserviceprovider

    guarantees quality outcomes, and gov

    Introduction to Negotiation

    Where theres more to negotiate, theres often

    more room to negotiate too.

    15

    TAKING STOCK (Part Five) EFFECTIVE WORKING RELATIONSHIPS

    Effective relationships that allow people to work together over time share certaintraits. In general, such relationships tend to be

    1. Forward-looking. Change is expected, even anticipated. The parties involvedmake room for their relationship to grow. They look ahead to anticipate shocks andopportunities in the environment that might affect the outcomes they care aboutand thus the relationship.

    2. Committed and resilient. They withstand pressure, in part through willingness andcapacity to see things through before resorting to hardball. The parties avoidmaking major assumptions about each others intentions. Effective communication iskey, and this means more than sending signals clearly. It also includes active listen-inglistening to understand, summarizing what they say and checking with them tobe sure you have understood.

    3. Fairi.e., perceived as fair by both sides. The relationship reflects a balancedallocation of benefits and rewards, meets the parties criteriawhatever definesvalueover time, even if short-term costs and benefits are uneven here and there.

    4. Trust-based and forgivingbut provocable. Charles Sabel and other students ofcooperation recommend studied trust in which the parties make it easy for eachother to monitor compliance with commitments made. Beyond having a practicalvalue, supporting such mechanisms signals a willingness to do what you say. AndRobert Axelrod says parties can apply a tit-for-tat rule to infractions, beingprovocable but forgiving. Abuses will not be tolerated, but parties will extendeach other the benefit of the doubt and will be willing to forgive, at least withincertain limits.

    5. Realistic. Agreed-upon expectations are reasonable and, where possible, adjust-able. In a rush to agree, parties will not insist on or agree to things that cannot bedelivered, based on best-available information and standards.

  • 8/12/2019 We Are All Negotiators Now

    16/41

    ernment has some preferences about

    staffingandmaterialstobeused.

    Thenonprofitseesthingsabitdiffer

    ently. Itneeds toobtaina feeperunitof

    service that will cover its costs,but the

    organizationwouldbewillingtoforegoa

    largercontractforthesakeofflexibilityto

    experiment with the program design.

    Onereasonisthattheorganizationwants

    toestablish itselfasan innovator,andso

    the specifics of program delivery are

    quite important.A second reason is that

    the nonprofitwants to retain the auton

    omy to develop its own capacity in ap

    propriatewaysnotgetstuckwithstaff

    ingdictatedbygovernment,forexample,

    onlytoseefundingevaporateandpriori

    ties change.As for timing, thenonprofit

    would like togetup and running soon,

    butitdoesnotwanttorushintothefield

    (and make costly errors) simply for the

    sakeofvisibility.

    Figure1outlinesthesedistinctprefer

    ences.Intheshorthandofnegotiation, the

    interestsindicatewhatpartieswouldpre

    fer visvis specific issues, and weights

    indicatehow important (overall)agiven

    issueisrelativetotheotherissues.

    Whereasbeforewehad abargaining

    rangeinonedimension(price),nowthere

    aremanypossibilities for oneparty to

    trade (concede) something less impor

    tant to it in exchange for something it

    valuesmore.Forexample,inonepossi

    bleoutcome:

    Government grants significant flexi

    bility on pro

    gram design in

    exchange for a

    commitment by

    thenonprofit for

    early delivery,

    beginning in

    threeweeks.But

    the nonprofit

    convinces gov

    ernment that

    rapid startup

    shouldbelimitedtoapilotphasethat

    generates some lessons useful for a

    scaledup version of the program to

    start

    3

    4

    months

    from

    now.

    The

    pilot

    will show visible followup by the

    Mayorbutlimitcostlymistakes.

    Thenonprofitacceptsa smaller total

    contract (addressing governments

    needtolimittotalcosts)butsecuresa

    fairly high unit price that will help

    theorganizationbuildupaskilledstaff

    and the equipment needed to deliver

    quality community health programs.

    Pointing to evidence that cheap pro

    grams yield correspondingly limited

    results, the service provider

    argues

    successfully

    for

    qual

    ity and impact rather than

    milewide, inchdeep cov

    erageofthetotalpopulation.

    Eachparty isable toclaim

    victory on key intangible in

    tereststhe nonprofit has

    protected its autonomy to

    design and deliver an inno

    vative community health

    program, the government

    has ensured responsiveness

    onanurgentpublicproblem,

    aswellastheappearancethatitisman

    aging resources carefully in a tight

    budgetyear.

    This agreement reflects what is

    known in negotiation as a package or

    bundle.Itaddressesspecificoptionson

    severalissuesatonce.

    Whyisthisbundlingsoimportant?

    Goback toeach issuenamedabove,and

    you will notice that the government

    agency

    and

    nonprofit

    service

    providerseem to have conflicting interests. On

    time, for example, government favors

    start immediately and the nonprofit

    wants time to do things right. On pro

    gramdesign,governmenthassomepref

    erences, but the nonprofit would like

    total flexibility todo thingsas itsees fit.

    Andfinally,onepartycontinuestowant

    ahigher,andtheotheralower,price.

    Introduction to Negotiation

    Whereas before we had a bargaining range in one di-

    mension (price), now there are many possibilities for

    one party to trade (concede) something less impor-

    tant to it in exchange for something it values more.

    16

    PARTIES KEY INTERESTS (By Issue)

    Government Agency Shave costs in a tight-budget year.

    Show response on Mayors campaign promises(secure rapid implementation schedule)

    Ensure quality

    Nonprofit Service Provider Cover costs, ensure quality, develop capacity.

    Ensure quality, learn through pilot phase

    Protect autonomy, develop reputation for inno-vation

    ISSUES (Relative Importance)

    Price (very important) - focus is total price

    Time (very important) - i.e., schedule for imple-menting the service

    Program design (somewhat important)

    Price (very important) - focus is unit price

    Time (somewhat important)

    Program design (very important)

    Figure 1. Expanded Public/Nonprofit Negotiation over a Service Contract

  • 8/12/2019 We Are All Negotiators Now

    17/41

    Each individual issue in thisnegotia

    tion, then, is purely competitive (or

    zerosum). More for one party means

    less for the other. Try to negotiate the

    issuesonebyone,andwefaceaseriesof

    competitive,winloseexchanges.Nowin

    win(jointgain)willbepossible.

    How can the parties dobetter than

    this?The key is that the two partiesdo

    nothaveidenticalinterestsorweighteach

    issue the same way, as we outlined

    above. Tradesarepossiblewhere theparties

    can exploit these differences in what they

    wantnot the most intuitive idea, since

    negotiation is sometimesdescribed

    asanefforttofindcommonground.

    Yes, agreement will come only

    where the twopartiesjointlyagree

    on some package, but building a

    valuable

    package,

    among

    a

    host

    of

    alternative proposals, will clearly

    demand that thepartiesunderstandand

    exploretheirdifferences.

    AsGeorge Wu of theHarvard Busi

    ness School notes in Sources of Joint

    Gains in Negotiations, mostjoint gains

    areaboutleveragingdifferences,inwhich

    eachpartyreceivessomethingvaluableto

    itinexchangeforgivingsomethingcheap

    (or cheaper)to it.There aremultiple di

    mensions along which differences can

    leadtovaluablewinwintrades:

    Differencesin

    interests,aswesawinthis

    simplecaseexample,often in theform

    ofplacingdifferentweightsonspecific

    interests.Swapscreatevaluebytrading

    whateachpartyvalues less forwhat

    eachvaluesmore;

    Differences in belief about the future.

    Parties that expect different things

    can, in effect, place different bets

    about the future.This iswhatmakes

    stock markets run. In the exampleabove,governmentandthenonprofit

    might have very different beliefs

    aboutthepotentialofanuntriedpro

    gram.Theparty confident of a high

    payoff with the program might be

    willing toback it for little up front

    compensation, contingent on abig re

    ward if the program indeed pays off.

    Trades create valueby responding to

    each partys (different) prediction

    about the future,usuallyvia a contin

    gentagreementorbet.

    Differencesin

    aversion

    to

    risk. Somepeo

    pleare,aseconomistssay,riskseeking

    whileothersareriskaverse.Riskseek

    ers are willing to run bigger risks in

    exchange for bigger rewards, while

    othersprefertoplayit(comparatively)

    safe. Trades offer a guarantee to the

    more risk averse party while shifting

    bigger rewards, in the caseof success,

    to the riskseeking party. So a risk

    averse community development or

    ganization maybe happy to accept a

    limitednumberofguaranteedjobslots

    forneighborhood residents from a su

    permarket moving into the neighbor

    hood. What matters most is getting

    some jobs for sure. The more risk

    seekingparty (thesupermarket) tradesthat guarantee for flexibility to hire

    anyone it likes should the marketbe

    comevery successful (even if thepro

    portionofthemarkets employeeswho

    are neighborhood residents goes

    down).Amoreconventionalapproach

    wouldsimplysettleonanumberofjob

    slots,regardlessofthesedifferentappe

    titesforrisk.And

    Differencesintimepreference.Aswe saw

    above,

    making

    sure

    that

    somethinghappensrightawaymaybemuchmore

    important tooneparty than toothers.

    Thepartyagreeing to speed thingsup

    canbe compensated via issues that it

    caresaboutmorethantiming.

    Wusuggeststhatnegotiatorsnotjust

    identify interests they share with the

    other side(s)butalsoconstructan inven

    tory of differences. This can begin in ad

    Introduction to Negotiation

    Wu suggests that negotiators not just identify interests they

    share with the other side but also construct an inventory

    of differences that can be a guide to possible trades.

    17

    TAKING STOCK (Part Six) BARRIERS TO JOINT GAIN

    Win-winor creating value for all sidesis often possible in negotiation. Yet manyfactors can make it hard to find or deliver, for example:

    1. Assuming a fixed pie (that parties interests are directly opposed on all issues,with no room for trades).

    2. Assuming a conflict (parties actually want the same thing, but baggage, bias,and the escalation of conflict obscure it).

    3. Thinking narrowly about differences (the parties consider differences in interestonly, ignoring time, risk aversion, and other preference differences).

    4. Taking up zero-sum (competitive) issues one by one. Trades depend on workingacross issues to create value for both parties. Without bundling, the parties canonly carry out a series of competitive, win-lose negotiations that are less efficientand, typically, much less emotionally satisfying.

    5. Devaluing the other sides offers (proposals by the other side tend to be deval-uedwhy arent they giving in more?!?).

    6. Exaggerating claims and posturing.

    7. Being overconfident (each side believes the other will be willing to concede more).

  • 8/12/2019 We Are All Negotiators Now

    18/41

    vanceof thenegotiationand continue at

    thetable,asthepartieslearnmoreabout

    eachother.

    So far,weve added issues to a very

    basiconeissue(price)negotiation.Below,

    well see how adding more parties like

    wise expands the possibilities for valu

    able tradesand introducestheneed for

    more tools to manage the process

    through which parties interact. Before

    readingon,takeamomenttoreviewthe

    core concepts we have covered so far

    (nextpage).

    If you remember nothing else from

    this first case anddiscussion, remember

    this: Do your homework. Prepare, pre

    pare,prepare.Most inexperiencednego

    tiators, and many experienced ones too,

    underprepare significantly. In effect,

    they

    foolishly

    rely

    on

    assertiveness,

    clev

    erness,orcharmatthetable(orallofthe

    above) to compensate for huge gaps in

    the information they havegaps that

    might havebeen remedied with a little

    investmentoftimeandenergyupfront.

    Beyond the Basics: More Parties,More Issues, More Creative Solu-tions

    Weveseensofarthateffectivenego

    tiationhingesonchoosingsituationsthat

    are appropriateinsofar as one can

    chooseadopting some basic principles

    to enable joint problemsolving (rather

    than standoff or avoidance), preparing

    awayfromthetableforwhathappensat

    thetable,managingourownperceptions

    and thoseofothers, and looking forop

    portunities to create joint gain

    (sometimes in counterintuitive ways).

    These factors, which apply even in the

    case of two parties working out agree

    ment, become all the more important

    whenthenumberofpartiesincreasesand

    the negotiation process becomes more

    complex.

    First, lets look at the general fea

    tures that make multiparty negotia

    tionsspecialandapplythese ideastoa

    new case example, in which parties

    cometogetherinacommunitytodefine

    and implement solutions to a critical

    socialproblem.Manyof the ideas that

    applytonegotiations acrossorganizations

    or groups, such as in the case example

    below, also applywhenmultipleparties

    within an organization are negotiating a

    majordecision.

    Followingtheexample,wellconsider

    more advanced issues related to media

    torsandothertypesof thirdparty facili

    Introduction to Negotiation

    Most inexperienced negotiators, and many experienced ones too, under-prepare

    significantly. In effect, they foolishly rely on assertiveness, cleverness, or charm at

    the table (or all of those) to compensate for huge gaps in the information they

    have.

    18

    TAKING STOCK (Part Seven) REVIEWING KEY CONCEPTS

    1. Know your alternativesand improve them. Be clear on the value of your alter-natives to negotiated agreement, learn as much as you can about their (your coun-terparts) alternatives, and improve yours if you can. Alternatives to negotiatedagreement define the bargaining range, and the quality of these alternatives helpsdetermine the leverage that parties have. Sometimes, the most important thing youcan do to gain leverage at the table is to improve your alternatives away from the

    tableor worsen the other sides perception of its alternatives. Options are asource of power.

    2. Shape their perceptions through principled arguments. Since information aboutthe other party(ies) is often incomplete, much of the persuasion in negotiation cen-ters on shaping the other sides perceptions about the bargaining range and desir-ability of particular outcomes within it. This is different from convincing them simplyto share your interests or give in for the sake of fairness. So know your audience,and prepare your arguments and counter-arguments carefully.

    3. Make the first offer if your information is good. First offer can help anchor theother party(ies) in a portion of the bargaining range favorable to you, but makethe first offer if your information on their reservation value is good, or make anopen-ended, probing offer to improve your information.

    4. Be mindful of your own perceptions. What makes negotiation a human process,

    and not a robotic exercise in information exchange, is the power of our perceptionsand biasesas well as, more positively, our capacity to self-correct and rescueourselves. Be careful about attributing (rather than confirming) the other partysintentions, listen well and communicate as clearly as possible (and confirm that theyunderstand), re-negotiate the process if their conduct does not seem respectful orconstructive.

    5. Change the game to create a more valuable agreement. Even negotiations thatseem narrow and limited to competition can often be expanded to consider futurerelationship, intangible interests, and linked issues (such as quality linked to price).

    6. Look for valuable trades. In multi-issue negotiations, win-win trades are possible,but its usually differences in what parties want that makes trades possible. Somekey types of trade-able differences relate to interests, beliefs about the future,aversion to risk, and time preferences.

    7. Do your homeworkon the issues; options; other partys interests, alternatives,and negotiating style, and more. Once youve identified the stakeholders, learnall that you can about them, what they value, and how they view the world. Mostinexperienced negotiators, and many experienced ones too, under-prepare signifi-cantly. Use your personal networks, public information sources, industry databases,key informants or knowledgeable observers (including well-informed journalists),and other sources. Dont rush to the table ill-prepared.

  • 8/12/2019 We Are All Negotiators Now

    19/41

    tators, the challenges of negotiating on

    behalf of constituents (being an

    agent)a very common pattern in

    communityproblemsolvingandmore.

    Negotiations that include three or

    more parties present dynamics that are

    quite different from the twoparty case

    we worked on above. First, unless full

    consensus (unanimous support) is re

    quired, agreementgenerallydependson

    getting a coalitionofparties to supporta

    package or proposal. That is, when the

    numberofpartiesgoesfromtwotothree,

    something new can happen: two parties

    canally tooppose the third.Thespecific

    number

    of

    parties

    that

    must

    support

    a

    proposal may depend on law or prece

    dent,or itmaybeuptothediscretionof

    civicleaderswhosimplywanttoensurea

    broadbaseofsupportforagivenpolicy,

    program,orinitiative.

    As Howard Raiffa shows in TheArt

    andScienceofNegotiation, thismakes fora

    more complex process of engagement

    amongthepartiesbutalsoarichersetof

    possibilitiesfor trades, for example

    than oneonone negotiation offers. For

    instance:

    The process can be complex. Many

    important negotiations can happen

    among subgroups of the parties, in

    sidemeetings.So theremay, for ex

    ample, be twoparty and threeparty

    negotiations embedded ina largersix

    party negotiation process. When key

    partiesorpublicobserversdislikesuch

    meetings, they complain about

    backroomdeals.Butmany informal,

    smallgroup consultations can, with

    proper safeguards, be invaluable asmechanisms for exploring options,

    clarifying statements made in public

    (e.g., in themedia), sharing controver

    sial concerns, and removing obstacles

    toagreement.Partiesoftenopenup in

    smaller, informal settings inways that

    larger gatherings, particularly if open

    tothepublic,donotencourage.

    Coalitionscanbebuiltinawidevariety

    ways, for example by leveraging

    shared interests (tangible or intangi

    ble), sharedpositionsonaparticular

    proposal(e.g.,asharedpreferencefor

    nodealor even nonegotiation),

    sharedhistory(commonexperiences,

    an important relationship, sharedtraditions),sharedvulnerability (e.g.,

    to being excluded from a valuable

    agreement ) , valuable trades

    (carrots)orpenalties(sticks)that

    influencesupport,andcommonallies

    orenemies.

    Recruiting allies is often hardand

    so iskeeping them.MichaelWatkins

    and SusanRosegrant, in Sourcesof

    Power in Coalition Building, notes

    that framingandothereffectiveper

    suasion techniques are crucial for

    delivering on all of these. Recogniz

    ingapotentialcoalitiononpaperis

    onething.Buildingareal,committed

    coalition by recruiting and retaining

    alliesisanother.

    Building a strong coalition sometimesdependsonwhenweapproachparticu

    larparties,notjustwhowe approach.

    Ratherthanapproachpotentialalliesin

    just any order, coalitionbuilders look

    tocreatebandwagoneffects(wherein

    onepartysdecisiontooffersupport is

    influenced by the appearance of a

    group already in favor) and exploit

    patterns of deference to particular in

    fluential or respected parties (Since

    partyXsupportsyou,Ishouldtoo).

    Coalitions that are built can also be

    brokenusingavarietyof those strate

    gies. Those who oppose a given pro

    posal may look for weak links in a

    coalition inhopesofdissolvingorun

    dermining it. Parties that can be re

    cruited easily may also be recruited

    awayeasilytoanadverseorblock

    ing coalition. (Note that one partys

    favorable coalition is typically an op

    posingpartysadverseone.)

    Beyond these key features, many

    multiparty negotiations in community

    problemsolving present with certain

    common contextual features. These in

    clude some of the issues we considered

    above in the enriched version of the

    twopartynegotiation.

    For example, the parties around the

    table can bring varied resourcesfrom

    money and facilities to reputation and

    political legitimacyto bear on commu

    nity problems and opportunities. So

    problemsolving together includes animportantelementof identifying,under

    standing,andbundlingthoseresourcesin

    creativeways.Thekeyquestionsarenot

    just whatdoyouwant? (interests)but

    Introduction to Negotiation

    The key questions inmultipartyproblemsolving are notjust what doyou

    want?(interests)butwhatcanyoudo?(capacityandresources).

    Recognizing a potential coalition on paper is one

    thing. Building a real, committed coalition by recruit-

    ing and retaining allies is another.

    19

  • 8/12/2019 We Are All Negotiators Now

    20/41

    what can you do? (capacity and re

    sources).

    Next, theplayersgenerally expect to

    bedealin