The Real Sterling Crisis - Civitascivitas.org.uk/content/files/The-Real-Sterling-Crisis.pdf · The...

154
The Real Sterling Crisis Why the UK needs a policy to keep the exchange rate down Roger Bootle and John Mills

Transcript of The Real Sterling Crisis - Civitascivitas.org.uk/content/files/The-Real-Sterling-Crisis.pdf · The...

Page 1: The Real Sterling Crisis - Civitascivitas.org.uk/content/files/The-Real-Sterling-Crisis.pdf · The fall in the value of sterling since the vote for Brexit has had commentators wringing

£9.00

Institute for the Study of Civil Society

55 Tufton Street, London, SW1P 3QL Tel: 020 7799 6677

Email: [email protected] Web: www.civitas.org.uk

ISBN 978-1-906837-83-9 Cover design: lukejefford.com

T he fall in the value of sterling since the vote for Brexit has had commentatorswringing their hands with concern. But why are so many so quick to assumethat a cheaper pound is a bad thing?

The truth, as leading economists Roger Bootle and John Mills explain here, isthat the British economy has suffered from an overvalued pound for many years.It has restricted exports by making them more expensive and stimulated importsby making them cheaper; it has therefore been a leading cause of the UK’s largecurrent account deficit.

But it has also reduced profits in relation to real wages, which has led to lowerinvestment, lower productivity growth and lower living standards. And becausethe effects of a high exchange rate fall disproportionately on manufacturing thishas helped create an unbalanced economy in which the winners are mostly located in financial services and the South-East.

The real sterling crisis, then, is not that the pound has fallen in recent months –but that it had previously been priced too high for many years.

This was allowed to happen by policymakers overly fixated with keeping downinflation and overly confident that ‘the markets know best’. In fact, markets maysystematically misprice financial variables, as is widely acknowledged now inrelation to equity and property.

In this pamphlet, Bootle and Mills – whose political sympathies, with the Rightand the Left respectively, cross the political divide – argue that the governmentshould now devise a new economic framework that has at its centre an exchange rate policy designed to ensure the pound continues to trade at a competitive level in the years ahead.

They outline the steps that might be undertaken towards such an approach andaddress head on the anxieties many have about a cheaper pound.

‘With the British people having voted to leave the EU, this is an ideal time for thegovernment to pursue an alternative policy framework. Indeed, setting a policythat would establish and maintain a competitive exchange rate for sterling is thesingle most important thing that a government can do for the promotion of aprosperous Britain.’

Roger B

ootle and John M

ills

The Real Sterling CrisisWhy the UK needs a policy to keep the exchange rate down

Roger Bootle and John Mills

Th

e Real S

terling

Crisis

W X

Page 2: The Real Sterling Crisis - Civitascivitas.org.uk/content/files/The-Real-Sterling-Crisis.pdf · The fall in the value of sterling since the vote for Brexit has had commentators wringing

The Real Sterling Crisis

The Real Sterling Crisis Layout.qxp_Layout 1 19/08/2016 10:46 Page i

Page 3: The Real Sterling Crisis - Civitascivitas.org.uk/content/files/The-Real-Sterling-Crisis.pdf · The fall in the value of sterling since the vote for Brexit has had commentators wringing

The Real Sterling Crisis Layout.qxp_Layout 1 19/08/2016 10:46 Page ii

Page 4: The Real Sterling Crisis - Civitascivitas.org.uk/content/files/The-Real-Sterling-Crisis.pdf · The fall in the value of sterling since the vote for Brexit has had commentators wringing

The Real Sterling Crisis

Why the UK needs a policy to keep the exchange rate down

Roger Bootle and John Mills

CIVITAS

The Real Sterling Crisis Layout.qxp_Layout 1 19/08/2016 10:46 Page iii

Page 5: The Real Sterling Crisis - Civitascivitas.org.uk/content/files/The-Real-Sterling-Crisis.pdf · The fall in the value of sterling since the vote for Brexit has had commentators wringing

First Published September 2016

© Civitas 201655 Tufton Street

London SW1P 3QL

email: [email protected]

All rights reserved

ISBN 978-1-906837-83-9

Independence: Civitas: Institute for the Study of CivilSociety is a registered educational charity (No. 1085494)and a company limited by guarantee (No. 04023541).Civitas is financed from a variety of private sources to avoid over-reliance on any single or small group of donors.

All publications are independently refereed. All theInstitute’s publications seek to further its objective ofpromoting the advancement of learning. The viewsexpressed are those of the authors, not of the Institute,as is responsibility for data and content.

Designed and typeset bylukejefford.com

Printed in Great Britain by4edge Limited, Essex

The Real Sterling Crisis Layout.qxp_Layout 1 19/08/2016 10:46 Page iv

Page 6: The Real Sterling Crisis - Civitascivitas.org.uk/content/files/The-Real-Sterling-Crisis.pdf · The fall in the value of sterling since the vote for Brexit has had commentators wringing

v

ContentsAuthors vi

Authors’ Acknowledgements ix

Executive Summary xi

Part One: The Problem

1 The impending economic disaster and the pound’s role in causing it 2

2 The current position of overseas trade and net wealth and where we are heading 11

3 The historical background to the UK’s current account 35

4 How could the current account gap be closed? 41

Part Two: Exchange Rates and Exchange Rate Policy

5 How British exchange rate policy has evolved over the last 100 years 52

6 Other countries’ attitudes to exchange ratemanagement, past and present 64

7 Is it possible to vary the real exchange rate by changing the nominal rate? 75

Part Three: Policy Proposals

8 Exchange rates and policy objectives 92

9 How to get the exchange rate lower 101

10 Objections to a lower exchange rate policy – and the answers 116

Conclusion: The case for action 129

The Real Sterling Crisis Layout.qxp_Layout 1 19/08/2016 10:46 Page v

Page 7: The Real Sterling Crisis - Civitascivitas.org.uk/content/files/The-Real-Sterling-Crisis.pdf · The fall in the value of sterling since the vote for Brexit has had commentators wringing

vi

Authors

One of the City of London’s best-known economists,Roger Bootle is Chairman of Capital Economics, one of the world’s largest independent economicsconsultancies, which he founded in 1999. Roger is alsoa Specialist Adviser to the House of Commons TreasuryCommittee, an Honorary Fellow of the Institute ofActuaries and a Fellow of the Society of BusinessEconomists. He was formerly Group Chief Economistof HSBC and, under the previous Conservativegovernment, he was appointed one of the Chancellor’spanel of Independent Economic Advisers, the so-called‘Wise Men’. He was a visiting Professor at ManchesterBusiness School from 1995 to 2003, and between 1999and 2011 served as Economic Adviser to Deloitte. In July2012, it was announced that Roger and a team fromCapital Economics had won the Wolfson Prize, thesecond biggest prize in Economics after the Nobel.

Roger Bootle studied at Oxford University, at Mertonand Nuffield Colleges, and then became a Lecturer inEconomics at St Anne’s College, Oxford. Most of hissubsequent career has been spent in the City of London.

Roger has written many articles and several books onmonetary economics. His latest book, The Trouble withEurope, examines how the EU needs to be reformed andwhat could take its place if it fails to change. This bookfollows The Trouble with Markets and Money for Nothing,

The Real Sterling Crisis Layout.qxp_Layout 1 19/08/2016 10:46 Page vi

Page 8: The Real Sterling Crisis - Civitascivitas.org.uk/content/files/The-Real-Sterling-Crisis.pdf · The fall in the value of sterling since the vote for Brexit has had commentators wringing

which were widely acclaimed. His earlier book, TheDeath of Inflation, published in 1996, became a best-sellerand was subsequently translated into nine languages.Initially dismissed as extreme, The Death of Inflation isnow widely recognised as prophetic. Roger is also jointauthor of the book Theory of Money, and author of Index-Linked Gilts.

Roger appears frequently on television and radio and is also a regular columnist for The Daily Telegraph.In The Comment Awards 2012 he was namedEconomics Commentator of the year.

John Mills is an entrepreneur and economist with a life-long political background in the Labour Party, leadinghim to being its largest individual donor. He graduatedin Philosophy, Politics and Economics from MertonCollege, Oxford, in 1961. He is currently Chairman ofJohn Mills Limited (JML), a consumer goods companyspecialising in selling products requiring audio-visualpromotion at the point of sale, based in the UK but withsales throughout the world. He was a member ofCamden Council, specialising in housing and finance,almost continuously from 1971 to 2006, with a breakduring the late 1980s when he was Deputy Chairman ofthe London Docklands Development Corporation. Hewas a parliamentary candidate twice in 1974 and for theEuropean Parliament in 1979.

John has been Secretary of the Labour Euro-Safeguards Campaign since 1975 and the LabourEconomic Policy Group since 1985. He has also been acommittee member of the Economic Research Councilsince 1997 and is now its Vice-Chairman. During theperiod running up to the June 2016 referendum he wasChair of The People’s Pledge, Co-Chairman of Business

vii

AUTHORS

The Real Sterling Crisis Layout.qxp_Layout 1 19/08/2016 10:46 Page vii

Page 9: The Real Sterling Crisis - Civitascivitas.org.uk/content/files/The-Real-Sterling-Crisis.pdf · The fall in the value of sterling since the vote for Brexit has had commentators wringing

THE REAL STERLING CRISIS

viii

for Britain, Chair of Labour for a Referendum, Chairand then Vice-Chair of Vote Leave and Chair of LabourLeave, which became independent of Vote Leave twomonths before the referendum.

John is the author of numerous pamphlets and articlesand he is a frequent commentator on radio andtelevision. He is Chair of the Pound Campaign whichproduces regular bulletins advocating that economicpolicy should be far more focused on the exchange ratethan it has been for many decades, arguing that an over-valued pound has been largely responsible for UK deindustrialisation and our grossly unbalancedeconomy. He is the author or joint-author of nine books,these being: Growth and Welfare: A New Policy for Britain(Martin Robertson and Barnes and Noble, 1972);Monetarism or Prosperity (with Bryan Gould and ShaunStewart; Macmillan 1982); Tackling Britain’s FalseEconomy (Macmillan 1997); Europe’s Economic Dilemma(Macmillan 1998); America’s Soluble Promises (Macmillan1999); Managing the World Economy (Palgrave Macmillan2000); A Critical History of Economics (PalgraveMacmillan 2002 and Beijing Commercial Press 2006);Exchange Rate Alignments (Palgrave Macmillan, 2012) and Call to Action (with Bryan Gould; EburyPublishing 2015).

The Real Sterling Crisis Layout.qxp_Layout 1 19/08/2016 10:46 Page viii

Page 10: The Real Sterling Crisis - Civitascivitas.org.uk/content/files/The-Real-Sterling-Crisis.pdf · The fall in the value of sterling since the vote for Brexit has had commentators wringing

Authors’Acknowledgements

This pamphlet is the result of a collaboration betweentwo people of both similar persuasions and oppositeones. John Mills has been a life-long committedsupporter of the Labour Party. Indeed, in recent years,he has been Labour’s largest individual donor. Bycontrast, although Roger Bootle has no formal politicalallegiance, his sympathies are generally with the Right.

Yet both individuals are an unusual combination ofeconomist and entrepreneur. John Mills founded andruns JML, the consumer products group. Roger Bootlefounded and runs Capital Economics, the economicsresearch house. Interestingly, both of us readPhilosophy, Politics and Economics at the sameinstitution – Merton College, Oxford.

And both of us are very worried about the shape ofthe British economy and the role of an excessivelystrong exchange rate in distorting it and holding back its growth rate. Both of us want to see the exchange rate occupying a key role in the setting of UKeconomic policy.

We gratefully acknowledge the help of staff at CapitalEconomics, especially Paul Hollingsworth, in obtainingdata and preparing charts. Also, we are extremelygrateful to Professor John Black, and to participants at

ix

The Real Sterling Crisis Layout.qxp_Layout 1 19/08/2016 10:46 Page ix

Page 11: The Real Sterling Crisis - Civitascivitas.org.uk/content/files/The-Real-Sterling-Crisis.pdf · The fall in the value of sterling since the vote for Brexit has had commentators wringing

a seminar we held in London in March 2016 to discussan early draft of the work. As usual, none of the aboveis at all responsible for any errors of commission oromission. These remain our responsibility. Furthermore,the views expounded here are those of the authorswriting in their personal capacities. The individuals and companies referred to above, both named andunnamed, are not necessarily in agreement with them.

Civitas’sAcknowledgements

Civitas is very grateful to the Nigel Vinson CharitableTrust for its generous support of this project.

THE REAL STERLING CRISIS

x

The Real Sterling Crisis Layout.qxp_Layout 1 19/08/2016 10:46 Page x

Page 12: The Real Sterling Crisis - Civitascivitas.org.uk/content/files/The-Real-Sterling-Crisis.pdf · The fall in the value of sterling since the vote for Brexit has had commentators wringing

Executive Summary

• Many people in the market and much of thecommentariat are currently concerned with therecent weakness of the pound on the exchanges.They are barking up the wrong tree. The real sterlingcrisis is that the pound has been too high.

• Accordingly, the Brexit-inspired bout of sterlingweakness was extremely good news for the Britisheconomy.

• Far from panicking about the lower pound, the UK authorities should be concerning themselveswith the question of how they can ensure that thepound continues to trade at a competitive level inthe future.

• The exchange rate of the pound is vital to the successand health of the UK economy and the fact that it haslong been stuck at much too high a level bears muchof the responsibility for the economy’s current ills.

• These results have not exactly been intended.Despite the exchange rate’s importance for the UK,for almost 25 years there has been no policy for it.As a policy variable the pound has been left in astate of neglect, in the belief that other things(principally inflation) should determine policy,and/or because ‘the markets know best’. This latterbelief mirrors the establishment’s faith in thefinancial markets prior to the crisis of 2008/9.

xi

The Real Sterling Crisis Layout.qxp_Layout 1 19/08/2016 10:46 Page xi

Page 13: The Real Sterling Crisis - Civitascivitas.org.uk/content/files/The-Real-Sterling-Crisis.pdf · The fall in the value of sterling since the vote for Brexit has had commentators wringing

• But we have subsequently learned, if we did notknow it beforehand, that, left to their own devices,the financial markets may systematically mispricefinancial variables, and that they may behave in areckless way in the pursuit of individual short-termgain that puts the long-term stability of the financialsystem at risk.

• Interestingly, although such reasoning is now widelyaccepted in relation to the equity and propertymarkets, recently no one seems to have made thesepoints about foreign exchange markets – until now.

• This would be surprising to an earlier generation ofeconomists schooled in the crises and policydisputes of the 1930s. They were brought up tobelieve that, not only could markets malfunctiondramatically, but they could produce and sustain adestabilising set of exchange rates, which could havedevastating consequences for the real economy.

• No one was more aware of the importance ofexchange rates than John Maynard Keynes. In the1930s, a series of devaluations and the imposition ofprotectionist trade policies were major contributorsto the Great Depression. Following that experience,Keynes was determined to establish for the post-warworld a global exchange rate regime that placedequal obligations on deficit and surplus countries toadjust, thereby ensuring that the new system did nothave a deflationary bias.

• This is most definitely not the system that we havetoday. Rather, financial pressures to adjust are felt bydeficit countries, while surplus countries, such asChina, Germany, the Netherlands and Switzerland,feel very little pressure at all. The result is adeflationary tendency for the world as a whole – feltparticularly strongly within the eurozone.

THE REAL STERLING CRISIS

xii

The Real Sterling Crisis Layout.qxp_Layout 1 19/08/2016 10:46 Page xii

Page 14: The Real Sterling Crisis - Civitascivitas.org.uk/content/files/The-Real-Sterling-Crisis.pdf · The fall in the value of sterling since the vote for Brexit has had commentators wringing

• The UK is not part of this deflationary tendency –although we suffer from its consequences. And wedo suffer acutely from exchange rate misalignment.There has been a deep-seated tendency for sterlingto settle at too high a level for the health of the UK economy.

• This is for two main reasons. First, because of theUK’s political stability and the extraordinaryliquidity and attractions of its asset markets, it has adecided tendency to attract private capital flows thatpush up the real exchange rate.

• Second, because of a history of inherently strongdomestic inflationary pressure, the UK policyauthorities have tended to welcome, and evenencourage, a strong exchange rate as a way ofbearing down on UK inflation.

• The results are devastating. On the financial side,persistent current account deficits undermine the country’s financial future. The UK is now asubstantial net debtor. Excessive borrowing wouldbe bad enough but the UK has increasingly sold real assets. The result is that not only is the presentborrowing from the future, but there is also a loss of national control over important parts of the economy.

• This weak external position particularly affects ourmanufacturing sector, bolstering the forces makingfor its decline as a share of GDP.

• This then diminishes our prospective rate ofproductivity growth (since productivity growth isstronger in manufacturing than services), intensifiesthe problems associated with employing lower-skilled workers, increases inequality, andaccentuates the regional divide.

xiii

EXECUTIVE SUMMARY

The Real Sterling Crisis Layout.qxp_Layout 1 19/08/2016 10:46 Page xiii

Page 15: The Real Sterling Crisis - Civitascivitas.org.uk/content/files/The-Real-Sterling-Crisis.pdf · The fall in the value of sterling since the vote for Brexit has had commentators wringing

• Accordingly, an economic policy that accorded amuch greater role for the exchange rate wouldpotentially bring significant benefits.

• As things stand, however, we do not have a freehand in adopting an exchange rate policy. The G7specifically forbids the deliberate manipulation ofexchange rates to gain competitive advantage.

• Mind you, this has not stopped Japan and theeurozone following closet policies of exchange rate depreciation. Outside the G7, China andSwitzerland, among umpteen others, have put themanagement of the exchange rate centre-stage. By contrast, as so often, the UK authorities are leftplaying ‘goody two shoes’.

• There are ways in which the UK could adhere to itsformal G7 commitments while effectively pursuinga policy that puts the maintenance of a competitiveexchange rate centre-stage. These include puttingless reliance on a policy of high interest rates.Continued fiscal stringency plus use of the Bank ofEngland’s Prudential Policy toolkit offers a way ofdoing this. In addition, measures could be taken tomake UK real assets less attractive to foreigners.

• Of course, we recognise that competitive devaluationis a zero sum game. Any attempt by the UK to gaincompetitiveness through a lower exchange ratecould be nullified if other countries followed suit. Inpractice, in current conditions, when the UK is nowonly a medium-sized player in the world economy,direct retaliation on any scale is not likely.

• Moreover, the UK has been a loser from othercountries’ depreciations – including by the eurozone.It would not be a case of the UK trying to boost itseconomy by following a mercantilist prescription in

THE REAL STERLING CRISIS

xiv

The Real Sterling Crisis Layout.qxp_Layout 1 19/08/2016 10:46 Page xiv

Page 16: The Real Sterling Crisis - Civitascivitas.org.uk/content/files/The-Real-Sterling-Crisis.pdf · The fall in the value of sterling since the vote for Brexit has had commentators wringing

order to increase its exports. The key point is that theUK is running a very large current account deficit.

• A change of policy regime to give greater weight tothe exchange rate would necessarily involve somechanges to the current inflation targeting regime. Butthat need not constitute a barrier. Inflation targetsare not the last word in macroeconomic policy andplenty of other countries do not allow their policy tobe completely dominated by inflation concerns. Butit should be possible to fashion a policy regimewhich retains inflation targets while givingsignificant weight to the exchange rate.

• Ideally, the world should move towards a newinternational policy regime that puts exchange rates centre stage and seeks to maintain exchangerates at a reasonable level in relation to the economicfundamentals. But the UK cannot wait for this to happen.

• With the British people having voted to leave theEU, this is an ideal time for the British governmentto pursue an alternative policy framework. Indeed,setting a policy that would establish and maintain acompetitive exchange rate for sterling is the singlemost important thing that a government can do forthe promotion of a prosperous Britain.

xv

EXECUTIVE SUMMARY

The Real Sterling Crisis Layout.qxp_Layout 1 19/08/2016 10:46 Page xv

Page 17: The Real Sterling Crisis - Civitascivitas.org.uk/content/files/The-Real-Sterling-Crisis.pdf · The fall in the value of sterling since the vote for Brexit has had commentators wringing

The Real Sterling Crisis Layout.qxp_Layout 1 19/08/2016 10:46 Page xvi

Page 18: The Real Sterling Crisis - Civitascivitas.org.uk/content/files/The-Real-Sterling-Crisis.pdf · The fall in the value of sterling since the vote for Brexit has had commentators wringing

Part One

The Problem

The Real Sterling Crisis Layout.qxp_Layout 1 19/08/2016 10:46 Page 1

Page 19: The Real Sterling Crisis - Civitascivitas.org.uk/content/files/The-Real-Sterling-Crisis.pdf · The fall in the value of sterling since the vote for Brexit has had commentators wringing

1 The impending economicdisaster and the pound’s

role in causing it

Unless something changes, the UK economy is headingfor the rocks. This is not because of the consequences ofBrexit. On the contrary, the factors that we identify inthis pamphlet that cause us such unease predate Brexit,or even the chance of it, and have practically nothing todo with it.

On the face of it, the British economy does not looktoo bad. But we are not paying our way in the world.Every year, we are borrowing and selling assets to thetune of about 5% of GDP. This is rapidly increasing theamount of our economy that is owned by foreigners.

This would not matter so much if we were using themoney provided by foreigners to invest in productivecapacity. But we are not. UK investment is extremelylow. We are borrowing and selling assets in order tomaintain our standard of consumption.

If things continue as at present then in 10 years’ timewe will have transferred to foreigners assets andownership of assets amounting to 50% of one year’sGDP. With this transfer goes a stream of income, paidto foreigners, out of what we produce in the UK. Thiswill mean that for any given level of what we produce

2

The Real Sterling Crisis Layout.qxp_Layout 1 19/08/2016 10:46 Page 2

Page 20: The Real Sterling Crisis - Civitascivitas.org.uk/content/files/The-Real-Sterling-Crisis.pdf · The fall in the value of sterling since the vote for Brexit has had commentators wringing

here in the UK (GDP), less will be available to beenjoyed by UK citizens. And if, as at present, foreignwealth holders buy UK real assets, along with thefinancial transfer goes a substantial amount of controlover our economy.

At a time of low interest rates, as at present, the cost ofbeing a net debtor is relatively low. But eventually, ofcourse, interest rates will rise. At that point the cost of theUK being a net debtor would be much higher than atpresent. Accordingly, the UK could be storing up a problemfor the future much larger than it currently imagines.

This outturn would be bad enough if the alternativewere to squeeze our living standards now in order toprotect and preserve our financial position and the levelof our living standards in future. But this is not thesituation. Our failure to pay our way derives from theweakness of net exports. Our economy is still operatinga substantial way below full capacity. In that case, itshould be possible to increase net exports and boostGDP. In other words, the thing that is hurting our livingstandards in future, is also reducing our incomes today.

If we were able to increase our net exports this wouldnot only boost incomes and employment but it woulddo so in parts of the economy that have recently donerelatively badly – the parts that have been heavilydependent upon manufacturing, thereby helping toaddress some of our country’s problems with inequality.

Moreover, there are links between the current accountdeficit and the UK’s other serious deficit, namely thefiscal one. The financial balance of the UK private sector,UK public sector and the overseas sector must sum tozero. Accordingly, if the government tries to improve itsfinancial position (i.e. the gap between expenditure andtax revenue) without there being an improvement in

THE IMPENDING ECONOMIC DISASTER

3

The Real Sterling Crisis Layout.qxp_Layout 1 19/08/2016 10:46 Page 3

Page 21: The Real Sterling Crisis - Civitascivitas.org.uk/content/files/The-Real-Sterling-Crisis.pdf · The fall in the value of sterling since the vote for Brexit has had commentators wringing

Britain’s overseas balance, then this can only happenthrough a worsening of the private sector financialbalance, which is often difficult to achieve. Another wayof putting this is that policies of austerity often fail.

By contrast, a spontaneous improvement in thecurrent account of the balance of payments wouldusually improve the financial balance of both the publicand private sectors. Higher incomes (from net exports)would automatically improve the financial balance ofthe private sector and, as they pay taxes on this income(and receive fewer state benefits because of increasedincome) the public deficit will fall.

The role of the exchange rate

There is more than one reason for our country’s weakposition on the balance of its overseas income andexpenditure (the current account of the balance ofpayments). Moreover, there is a plethora of problems inthe British economy that are not directly connected withthe weakness of our balance of payments and cannot beaddressed by changes in the value of the currency. Reallasting economic success, and successful dealings withother countries, depend upon building real competitiveadvantages that are difficult to replicate.

Nevertheless, these real factors are difficult to changein the short term. Moreover, sometimes the exchangerate can be stuck at the wrong level and this can be asource of severe difficulty, even if the ‘real’ sources ofcompetitive advantage are set favourably.

It is our contention in this paper that too high a levelof the pound on the foreign exchanges – the exchangerate against other currencies – is a leading cause of theUK’s large current account deficit and that this has

THE REAL STERLING CRISIS

4

The Real Sterling Crisis Layout.qxp_Layout 1 19/08/2016 10:46 Page 4

Page 22: The Real Sterling Crisis - Civitascivitas.org.uk/content/files/The-Real-Sterling-Crisis.pdf · The fall in the value of sterling since the vote for Brexit has had commentators wringing

major adverse consequences for our economy. Quitesimply, for countries heavily engaged in internationaltrade, as the UK is, the exchange rate is the mostimportant price in the economy. Too high a level of thepound will tend to restrict our exports (by making themmore expensive) and stimulate imports (by makingthem cheaper).

Moreover, the exchange rate has a critical bearing onanother crucial variable – the profit rate. Other thingsequal, a higher exchange rate reduces profits and boostsreal wages and the real value of other sources ofconsumer income. Reduced profits tend to lead to lowerinvestment – and lower investment leads to weakergrowth and hence lower living standards in future.

But the squeeze on profits is not uniform across theeconomy. On the contrary, it will be felt by industriesengaged in exporting and/or competing with imports.We refer to exports of goods and services, goods andservices that would be exported, imports of goods andservices, and goods and services that could beimported, as tradables.

A high exchange rate diminishes the price of tradablesrelative to non-tradables, and thereby diminishes theprofit rate of industries producing tradables relative tothose producing non-tradables. Furthermore, an exchangerate that undergoes substantial fluctuations will causesubstantial fluctuations in the profit rate in industries thatproduce tradables. This variability will diminish theattractions of investment in tradable industries.

Accordingly, an exchange rate that is too high forextended periods will tend to lead to an unbalancedeconomy – with too small a manufacturing sector. It isour contention that this is exactly what has happenedin the UK.

THE IMPENDING ECONOMIC DISASTER

5

The Real Sterling Crisis Layout.qxp_Layout 1 19/08/2016 10:46 Page 5

Page 23: The Real Sterling Crisis - Civitascivitas.org.uk/content/files/The-Real-Sterling-Crisis.pdf · The fall in the value of sterling since the vote for Brexit has had commentators wringing

It is often argued that the UK’s problems with itsexternal trade – and hence with its manufacturingindustry – originate with real factors, such as the rise ofChina, that have little, if anything, to do with theexchange rate. Such views are partly justified, andpartly dangerous nonsense. The UK steel industry hasrecently faced an existential crisis which is widelyblamed on the cheapness of steel production in theemerging markets, especially China. In fact, in 2014 theUK imported more than four times as much steel fromthe EU as from the whole of Asia. The exchange rate isseriously relevant to this.

What is the right value for the pound?

By how much is the pound over-valued? Or is it, post-Brexit, now at the right level? There is no hard and fastanswer, but we can begin to make some suggestionsabout orders of magnitude. First, we can trackmovements in the real effective exchange rate, that is tosay, the pound’s average value, once account is taken ofmovements in costs and prices in different countries.

When trying to gauge how over– or under-valued acurrency is, it is important not to be fixated upon theexchange rate against one particular currency. The mostlikely candidate for such currency fixation is the dollar.Yet the UK does much more of its trade with countriesthat don’t use the dollar, with the eurozone being themost important. Accordingly, the best way to measurethe value of the pound is to take the average of its valueagainst the currencies used in British trade, with theweight of each currency in the basket governed by the weight of that currency in Britain’s overall trade.The measure that does this is the trade-weighted index

THE REAL STERLING CRISIS

6

The Real Sterling Crisis Layout.qxp_Layout 1 19/08/2016 10:46 Page 6

Page 24: The Real Sterling Crisis - Civitascivitas.org.uk/content/files/The-Real-Sterling-Crisis.pdf · The fall in the value of sterling since the vote for Brexit has had commentators wringing

of the pound, sometimes known as the effective indexof the pound.

Yet it is important not to be fixated by the nominalvalue of this index. A country’s price competitiveness isgoverned by the relationship between the value of itscurrency and the level of domestic costs and pricescompared to costs and prices abroad. For instance, if acountry undergoes a 10% fall in its currency but alsoexperiences a 10% rise in its costs and prices relative tothose abroad, then its price competitiveness will nothave changed. Accordingly, to measure changes in pricecompetitiveness economists usually focus on the realexchange rate, that is to say the nominal rate adjustedfor changes in relative costs and prices across countries.

Even when these two adjustments are made, judgingby how much a currency may be over-valued is more ofan art than a science. But we can have a stab at comingto an answer. As Figure 1 shows, the last time that theUK ran a tolerably low current account deficit was inthe period immediately after the pound’s ejection fromthe ERM in September 1992. This provides a guide towhat should be a competitive exchange rate for the UK.

THE IMPENDING ECONOMIC DISASTER

7

Figure 1: Current account deficit (quarterly, % of GDP)

80 85 90 95 00 05 10 15

6

4

2

0

-2

-4

-6

-8

ERM exitSeptember 1992

The Real Sterling Crisis Layout.qxp_Layout 1 19/08/2016 10:46 Page 7

Page 25: The Real Sterling Crisis - Civitascivitas.org.uk/content/files/The-Real-Sterling-Crisis.pdf · The fall in the value of sterling since the vote for Brexit has had commentators wringing

It suggests that on the Bank of England’s measure of thepound’s average value, the so-called effective exchangerate, the pound should probably be somewhere close to75-80, compared to 100 in 2005.

But as Figure 2 shows, starting just before the electionof the Labour government in 1997, and continuingafterwards, the pound rose sharply. There followed a10-year period of rough stability - but stability at toohigh a level. Indeed, during this period the pound wasat roughly the same level that it had been at prior to itbeing forced out of the ERM in September 1992. (Thehistory of the real exchange rate over this period is veryclose to the nominal rate.)

THE REAL STERLING CRISIS

8

Its value took a dramatic dive immediately after thefinancial crisis in 2008/9, which returned its valueroughly to where it had been in the immediate wake ofthe ERM crisis – and at one brief point even lower.

After that, however, the effective exchange rate of thepound rose. At its recent peak in November 2015, it

Figure 2: The trade-weighted (effective) sterlingindex (1st Jan 2015 = 100)

90 95 00 05 10 15

125

120

115

110

105

100

95

90

85

80

ERM exit Labour elected

Poundlower

Northern Rock

The Real Sterling Crisis Layout.qxp_Layout 1 19/08/2016 10:46 Page 8

Page 26: The Real Sterling Crisis - Civitascivitas.org.uk/content/files/The-Real-Sterling-Crisis.pdf · The fall in the value of sterling since the vote for Brexit has had commentators wringing

stood 30% above the trough reached in March 2009.After the Brexit-inspired drop, in early July, theexchange rate stood roughly where it was after the ERMexit, and slightly above the trough that it reached afterthe financial crisis in 2009. Something like this may bethe right level for the UK to rebalance its economy.

We can also draw on the evidence of direct pricecomparisons. To make a more general assessment ofwhether prices are high or low in the UK it is useful tocompare prices to those in several other countries.Figure 3 shows comparative price levels for variousOECD countries. These data are for May 2016.

THE IMPENDING ECONOMIC DISASTER

9

This chart fits with conventional wisdom. For example,it shows that prices in the UK are generally much higherthan in much poorer economies such as Poland, Mexicoand Turkey. It also shows that prices in the UK are muchlower than in Switzerland, Denmark and Norway.

Less obviously, Figure 3 suggests that in May thegeneral price level was higher in the UK than in most

Figure 3: Price level compared with the UnitedStates (May 2016, OECD data)

160

140

120

100

80

60

40

20

0

US Price Level = 100

Poland

Mexico

Turkey

Spain

GermanyItaly

France

Japan

Sweden

Australia

UK

Norway

Denmark

Switz

erlan

d

The Real Sterling Crisis Layout.qxp_Layout 1 19/08/2016 10:46 Page 9

Page 27: The Real Sterling Crisis - Civitascivitas.org.uk/content/files/The-Real-Sterling-Crisis.pdf · The fall in the value of sterling since the vote for Brexit has had commentators wringing

other advanced economies. For example, it was 15%higher in the UK than in the US; 16% higher than inFrance; 13% higher than in Japan; and 24% higher thanin Germany. At face value, this suggests that the poundwas over-valued. The fall of the pound after the Brexitvote will have altered these figures considerably.

After the Brexit-inspired fall of the pound, it wastrading at a competitive level that hadn’t beenexperienced for many years. We believe that this willprove to be an extremely good thing for the UK economy.

But can the pound be kept somewhere near thiscompetitive level? That is a question that we address inthe later part of this pamphlet. First, though, we needto discuss in more detail quite where we are – and howwe got there.

THE REAL STERLING CRISIS

10

The Real Sterling Crisis Layout.qxp_Layout 1 19/08/2016 10:46 Page 10

Page 28: The Real Sterling Crisis - Civitascivitas.org.uk/content/files/The-Real-Sterling-Crisis.pdf · The fall in the value of sterling since the vote for Brexit has had commentators wringing

2 The current position of

overseas trade and net wealthand where we are heading

Recently the UK has been running a very large currentaccount deficit – around £90bn per annum, or 5% of ourGDP – matched by borrowing and sales of capital assetsto finance the shortfall of overseas revenue overexpenditure. How has such a large deficit come about?Is this sustainable? How can such a large deficit be goodfor the economy? What consequences does it have? If wewant to reduce the deficit, or even turn it into a surplus,what policies are there available to the UK authorities toenable them to achieve this? These are the questions thatthis pamphlet tries to answer. But before we do so wemust first tackle a niggling issue of measurement.

Are the balance of payments figures reliable?

The short answer is ‘no’. All macro-economic data areunreliable but the data on overseas payments may beparticularly so. And this is especially true wheneconomies pass through rapid structural change, as theUK has done over the last 30 years.

Indeed, we know that if you aggregate all the currentaccount positions in the world you find that the world

11

The Real Sterling Crisis Layout.qxp_Layout 1 19/08/2016 10:46 Page 11

Page 29: The Real Sterling Crisis - Civitascivitas.org.uk/content/files/The-Real-Sterling-Crisis.pdf · The fall in the value of sterling since the vote for Brexit has had commentators wringing

as a whole is in deficit. Yet until we start to trade withMars (or some other planet) this cannot be. Clearly thereis a significant measurement problem.

The balance of payments figures must balance – thatis to say, if there is an excess of imports over exports the money to pay for this needs to be found fromsomewhere. We can sell assets or borrow money. In anideal world there would be reliable statistics availableon all parts of the balance of payments. Unfortunately,we do not live in such a world. The truth has to bepieced together from incomplete data.

Suppose that there are exports or sources of overseasincome that the statisticians don’t record. For any givenreported imbalance of trade in goods, if recorded incomefrom services (or property income) does not match thisdeficit then it must be presumed that some sort of capitalinflow has provided the finance (or the government’sforeign exchange reserves have been run down).

The UK is particularly prone to such under-recordingsince its service sector is so big and it is heavily involvedin international capital markets. This means that the UK’scurrent account deficit is probably overstated by theofficial data, and the balance of payments data are proneto frequent, and sometimes substantial, revision. Figure4 shows the current estimate for the current accountdeficit relative to estimates made over the previous twoyears. In some periods, the revisions have been quitesubstantial, although this doesn’t alter the overall picture.

Indeed, it is unlikely that mismeasurement can occuron a scale sufficient to eradicate the deficit, or evensubstantially to reduce it. The recent trend in the deficithas been profoundly adverse, as shown in Figure 5. To explain this deterioration, the various distortionsthat we know about would have to have been getting

THE REAL STERLING CRISIS

12

The Real Sterling Crisis Layout.qxp_Layout 1 19/08/2016 10:46 Page 12

Page 30: The Real Sterling Crisis - Civitascivitas.org.uk/content/files/The-Real-Sterling-Crisis.pdf · The fall in the value of sterling since the vote for Brexit has had commentators wringing

worse. And, as this pamphlet establishes, it is not asthough the deterioration in the UK’s current accountposition is without explanation. We know full well why it has deteriorated. We do not need an alternativeexplanation founded on mismeasurement. The poorperformance of Britain’s overseas trade is part of awider pattern of disappointing performance.

13

THE CURRENT POSITION OF OVERSEAS TRADE

Figure 4: Revisions to current account deficit,2006–2015 (£bn)

Figure 5: The history of the current account balance, 1870–2015 (annual, % of GDP)

1870 1890 1910 1930 1950 1970 1990 2010

06 07 08 09 10 11 12 13 14 15 16

10

5

0

-5

-10

-15

5

0

-5

-10

-15

-20

-25

-30

-35

-40

June 2014 Estimate

June 2015 Estimate

June 2016 Estimate

Trade (goods and services)

Current account

WW1 WW2

The Real Sterling Crisis Layout.qxp_Layout 1 19/08/2016 10:46 Page 13

Page 31: The Real Sterling Crisis - Civitascivitas.org.uk/content/files/The-Real-Sterling-Crisis.pdf · The fall in the value of sterling since the vote for Brexit has had commentators wringing

An overall economic perspective

That said, the performance of the UK economy since the2008 financial crash has not been bad compared withmany other western countries, although it has beenmuch worse than some parts of the world, particularlyaround the Pacific Rim. We have much to be thankfulfor and, when criticising our record, some reasonableperspective is therefore required.

There may be deficiencies in the way our economy is structured and it may in a number of importantrespects be out of balance, but its absolute performancestill compares reasonably well with much of the rest of the world. Ranked in order of size, measured atmarket exchange rates, the UK economy comes in at number five or six, behind only the USA, China,Japan, Germany and sometimes France.

In terms of gross domestic product (GDP) per head on a purchasing power parity basis, however, ourperformance has clearly slipped. As measured by theInternational Monetary Fund (IMF) we come in at 29out of 188 countries, 29 out of 188 according to theWorld Bank and 40 out of 230 measured by the USCentral Intelligence Agency (CIA). The UK therefore hasa very substantial economy with average livingstandards which are higher than in many other parts ofthe world, but we have lost our historic pre-eminenceand many other countries have already overtaken us,while others are threatening to do so as our growth ratelags behind theirs.

The UK’s relative prosperity is partly the result of thefact that the Industrial Revolution started here and wehave therefore been increasing our output per head over

THE REAL STERLING CRISIS

14

The Real Sterling Crisis Layout.qxp_Layout 1 19/08/2016 10:46 Page 14

Page 32: The Real Sterling Crisis - Civitascivitas.org.uk/content/files/The-Real-Sterling-Crisis.pdf · The fall in the value of sterling since the vote for Brexit has had commentators wringing

a long period of time – much longer than in many otherparts of the world. During the 19th century, the UK hada higher level of GDP per head than almost anywhereelse, although the USA was catching up fast. Clearly wehave slipped back some considerable distance from thisenviable position since then.

The crucial issue for the future is whether this tendencyfor us to lose ground in relation to other countries isgoing to continue and whether our relatively low rate ofgrowth, which is responsible, is likely to be maintained.

Predicting future economic outcomes is always fraughtwith problems, because there are so many variables. Butthere are several key reasons for worrying that, evenafter post-Brexit anxiety has run its course, and evenwithout anything unexpected going wrong, the UKeconomy may grow slowly over the coming few years.

Weak investment

The first major UK economic weakness is that theproportion of our GDP which we invest rather thanconsume every year is desperately low. In 2015,excluding Research and Development, it was 13%. Somecontext for realising just how low this percentage isgiven by the fact that the world average, measured on acomparable basis, was 25.3% and for China it was 47.8%.

Admittedly, China’s investment share in GDP isabnormally high. Not only is much of this investmentwasted but the excessive rate of investment threatens tocause a sharp drop in GDP growth – or even a recession– if it adjusts sharply. The Chinese authorities face thedifficult task of reducing the share of investment in GDPand increasing the share of consumption.

15

THE CURRENT POSITION OF OVERSEAS TRADE

The Real Sterling Crisis Layout.qxp_Layout 1 19/08/2016 10:46 Page 15

Page 33: The Real Sterling Crisis - Civitascivitas.org.uk/content/files/The-Real-Sterling-Crisis.pdf · The fall in the value of sterling since the vote for Brexit has had commentators wringing

But, putting China aside, the UK’s investment share is low compared to most industrialised countries. As with many other issues in economics, there areconsiderable measurement difficulties associated withinvestment spending. Considerable amounts of spendingon intangibles, including software development and branding, may achieve significant commercialadvantage for individual firms – and real income gainsfor the economy as a whole – yet may be misclassifiedin the national accounts.

Because of the structure of the UK economy it ispossible that the UK has a disproportionately largeshare of such spending. Accordingly, appropriatelymeasured, the UK’s investment rate is probably not aslow as the official figures imply. Nevertheless, it ishighly unlikely that measurement issues can explainmore than a small fraction of the UK’s recordedinvestment deficiency.

There is worse news, however, in the detail. Of the UK investment total in 2014, only 21% was spent on thetype of investment – manufacturing broadly defined –which is most likely to increase productivity. Of theremainder, 17% was spent by the public sector on roads,schools, housing, etc., all of which may be highlydesirable on social grounds but which do little directlyto increase output per head and hence the growth ratein the short-term. Of the other remaining 62%, just overhalf was spent on private sector housing constructionand the remainder on building commercial premisesand service sector activities such as opening newrestaurants, none of which, again, contribute significantlyto productivity increases.

Thirteen per cent is a very low investment percentage,but when depreciation – running in 2013 at 11.4%

THE REAL STERLING CRISIS

16

The Real Sterling Crisis Layout.qxp_Layout 1 19/08/2016 10:46 Page 16

Page 34: The Real Sterling Crisis - Civitascivitas.org.uk/content/files/The-Real-Sterling-Crisis.pdf · The fall in the value of sterling since the vote for Brexit has had commentators wringing

of GDP – is deducted from it, only about 1.5% is left. Faced with these figures, it is not difficult to see whyproductivity in the UK is virtually static. Furthermore,1.5% of GDP is not even sufficient to keep up the valueof our accumulated capital assets in relation to our risingpopulation, which is currently increasing by at least500,000 people a year – about 200,000 from indigenousgrowth and 300,000 from immigration.

If you divide the total accumulated capital assets ofthe UK – worth £8.5trn at the end of 2014 according tothe Office for National Statistics (ONS) – by the totalpopulation of the UK, which was then 64.6m – youreach a figure of about £130,000. To avoid diluting downour accumulated capital, we therefore need to spend atleast 500,000 x £130,000 – i.e. £65bn – every year just toavoid slipping backwards. Clearly, we are a very longway from doing this. With no net investment per headof the population taking place at all, unless we benefitsubstantially from some other favourable extraneousfactor, it is not realistic to think that we are going to seeoutput per head going up to any significant extent.

Manufacturing squeezed

The second major problem with the UK economy is thatwe have allowed our manufacturing sector to decline toan extremely low level. As late as 1970, almost a thirdof our GDP came from manufacturing. The share is nowbarely 10%.

The absence of good quality manufacturing jobs hascontributed strongly to the increases in both regionaland socio-economic inequality which have been such apronounced development in recent decades. Moreover,if manufacturing is the strongest source of productivity

17

THE CURRENT POSITION OF OVERSEAS TRADE

The Real Sterling Crisis Layout.qxp_Layout 1 19/08/2016 10:46 Page 17

Page 35: The Real Sterling Crisis - Civitascivitas.org.uk/content/files/The-Real-Sterling-Crisis.pdf · The fall in the value of sterling since the vote for Brexit has had commentators wringing

increases, the smaller the proportion of GDP that itcomprises then, other things equal, the lower the rate ofproductivity increase in the economy as a whole.

Manufacturing plays a key role in our foreign trade.Despite our small manufacturing sector, about 55% ofall our export earnings are from goods rather thanservices, and although we have a substantial foreigntrade surplus on services, this is more than offset by amuch bigger deficit on goods – £88bn compared to£126bn in 2015. As a result, we have not had a tradesurplus since 1982 or an overall current account surplussince 1985.

The UK’s problem – reflected across much of thewestern world – is that internationally tradable low-and medium-tech manufacturing has been largelywiped out by competition from Asia, leaving usdependent on high-tech exports – aerospace, aircraftengines, pharmaceuticals, motor vehicles and armssales. Over and above this, in many key markets, the UKhas lost out to other developed countries.

There is a view that we need not worry aboutmanufacturing’s decline. We should simply accept it andrely on services, where we have a strong comparativeadvantage. We disagree with this view.

The problem is that the sectors in which we excel,important though they are, do not produce enough tofill the gap between our overseas income and ouroverseas expenditure. Moreover, they, in turn, are alsoeventually going to be vulnerable to competition fromlower cost countries.

And we are at risk of other pitfalls. Can we beconfident, for instance, that the City of London willretain its pre-eminent position? And what would we doif its earnings fell back significantly?

THE REAL STERLING CRISIS

18

The Real Sterling Crisis Layout.qxp_Layout 1 19/08/2016 10:46 Page 18

Page 36: The Real Sterling Crisis - Civitascivitas.org.uk/content/files/The-Real-Sterling-Crisis.pdf · The fall in the value of sterling since the vote for Brexit has had commentators wringing

We don’t think we can or should lay down whatproportion of the economy should be accounted for by manufacturing. That is for the market to decide –once the exchange rate is roughly at the right level. But,given the importance of manufacturing in internationaltrade, and given the plunge in the UK’s share ofmanufacturing in GDP, and the price sensitivity ofmanufacturing output, we would be surprised if asubstantial improvement in the UK’s trade balancecould be achieved without it being accompanied by asignificant rise in manufacturing’s share in GDP.

The current account

Our weak trade balance is a major contributor to thepoor state of our overall current account position. The table below sets the scene.

19

THE CURRENT POSITION OF OVERSEAS TRADE

Table 1: UK balance of payments breakdown, £bn

Net investment Net transfers

Year Trade balance income from abroad abroad Total

2008 -46.4 5.3 -14.1 -55.0

2009 34.7 5.4 -15.8 -44.8

2010 43.0 20.2 -20.7 -43.1

2011 -26.2 19.6 -21.7 -29.1

2012 -33.9 -2.2 -21.9 -61.4

2013 -34.2 -10.3 -26.9 -76.4

2014 -34.4 -23.8 -25.0 -85.0

2015 -36.7 -37.0 -24.7 -100.3

Source: ONS BNBP Balance of Payments Quarterly Releases

The Real Sterling Crisis Layout.qxp_Layout 1 19/08/2016 10:46 Page 19

Page 37: The Real Sterling Crisis - Civitascivitas.org.uk/content/files/The-Real-Sterling-Crisis.pdf · The fall in the value of sterling since the vote for Brexit has had commentators wringing

While our trade deficit, although substantial, isreasonably stable, our net income from abroad hasrecently seen a very sharp deterioration. From beingnearly £20bn in surplus as recently as 2011, it was anegative £37bn in 2015 – a massive negative swing of£57bn.

There is inevitably some volatility in these figures, andthere may well be some improvement in them over thecoming years. But a significant part of this deteriorationis itself a product of the UK running large currentaccount deficits over many years. Such deficits worsenthe UK’s net asset position and, other things equal, thiswill lead to a weaker investment income balance. This,in turn, leads to an even weaker net asset position.There is, therefore, an underlying highly adverse trendto our net income from abroad which is likely toproduce major problems for us in future. (A higherexchange rate also has the effect of worsening theinvestment income balance as it diminishes the sterlingvalue of income earned abroad, while leaving thesterling value of income earned by foreigners in the UKunchanged. See later.)

The speed of this deterioration has probably beenincreased by the way that our deficits have beenfinanced. Whereas in the past it was normal for the UKto attract fixed interest capital (which was held in bankdeposits and/or bonds), while the UK typicallyinvested abroad in real assets and/or equities, whichtended to have a higher rate of return, in recent decadesthe UK has taken in a higher proportion of directinvestment and equity capital, thereby worsening therelationship between the income earned on foreignassets and the income paid out on foreign assets held inthe UK.

THE REAL STERLING CRISIS

20

The Real Sterling Crisis Layout.qxp_Layout 1 19/08/2016 10:46 Page 20

Page 38: The Real Sterling Crisis - Civitascivitas.org.uk/content/files/The-Real-Sterling-Crisis.pdf · The fall in the value of sterling since the vote for Brexit has had commentators wringing

Net transfers abroad are also on a rising trend. Thelargest component is our net contribution to theEuropean Union, which ran at £11bn in 2015. AfterBrexit this should fall back sharply – hopefully to zero.The remainder is split roughly evenly between netremittances abroad, which are likely to go up ifmigration to the UK continues at its current very highlevel, and foreign aid programmes, to which all ourmajor parties are committed. The net result of all thesetrends is that the UK’s overall balance of paymentsdeficit exhibits a strongly rising trend. In the firstquarter of 2016 it reached 6.9% of GDP. For 2015 as awhole, the deficit was 5.4% of GDP. In percentage termsthis was easily the highest deficit in the whole of thedeveloped world.

Trade not the problem?

Given that the main culprit for the recent deteriorationin the overall current account balance is thedeterioration in net investment income, while the tradedeficit has been broadly stable, there is an argument thatexchange rate policy, which is designed to affect thetrade balance, is otiose. It is to the change in investmentincome that we need to direct attention.

But this argument is misguided on five counts:(i) The surprising thing is not that the investment

income balance has deteriorated recently but ratherthat it held up so well for so long. This may well beexplained by the risky nature of many of the UK’sinternational assets. In any case, although we canhope that it will improve, we cannot take this forgranted. We need to take the current level of theinvestment balance as it is.

21

THE CURRENT POSITION OF OVERSEAS TRADE

The Real Sterling Crisis Layout.qxp_Layout 1 19/08/2016 10:46 Page 21

Page 39: The Real Sterling Crisis - Civitascivitas.org.uk/content/files/The-Real-Sterling-Crisis.pdf · The fall in the value of sterling since the vote for Brexit has had commentators wringing

(ii) As it happens, a lower exchange value for sterlingwould improve the net balance of investmentincome.

(iii) While the size of the trade deficit at about 2% ofGDP is much smaller than the overall currentaccount (about 5%), nevertheless, it is still a deficit.Why is it deemed OK for the UK to be running atrade deficit of ‘only’ 2%, when Germany runs ahuge surplus?

(iv) If the UK is to run at a high level of domesticdemand and to use up all available spare capacity,the trade deficit would be higher.

(v) Much of the wider adverse economic impact of thecurrent account deficit, including the effects on UKmanufacturing, the regional divide and inequality,stem from the trade deficit.

From creditor to debtor nation

The effect of these large and chronic deficits has been toturn the UK from a net creditor to a significant netdebtor. ONS figures do not show a consistent patternyear to year but between decades there has been a verymarked change. Whereas in the 1980s the UK alwayshad assets exceeding liabilities, during the 2000sliabilities exceeded assets by about £82bn throughoutthe decade. By 2015 this figure had risen to almost£270bn.

These figures highlight another major concern aboutthe UK economy which is the volume of debt which itnow sustains, not least that part of it owed by thegovernment. Clearly, the government deficit needs to bereduced to much more manageable proportions. Thekey issue is whether this can be done if the country

THE REAL STERLING CRISIS

22

The Real Sterling Crisis Layout.qxp_Layout 1 19/08/2016 10:46 Page 22

Page 40: The Real Sterling Crisis - Civitascivitas.org.uk/content/files/The-Real-Sterling-Crisis.pdf · The fall in the value of sterling since the vote for Brexit has had commentators wringing

continues to have a foreign payments deficit as large asthe one currently being experienced.

It is a fallacy of composition to believe that whatmight be the obviously sensible way for an individualwhose expenditure was greater than his or her incometo bring the two back into balance - by cuttingexpenditure or increasing income - would work in thesame way for the economy as a whole. What anindividual does has negligible impact on the wholeeconomy, but what the government does – because ofthe scale of its expenditure - is very different. The crucialfact is that if the household and corporate sectors arevery roughly in balance – i.e. neither net borrowers nornet lenders on a very major scale – the governmentdeficit has to be more or less the same size as the foreignpayments deficit. That is roughly the position shown inTable 2. Unless the private sector financial balance canbe squeezed, for the government deficit to be reduced,the overseas deficit has to fall also – and vice versa.

If the government pursues austerity to try to reduce itsdeficit then to the extent that it succeeds, this may wellreduce the current account deficit but the channelthrough which this would happen is by reducedaggregate demand cutting back the demand for imports.

Equally, a spontaneous improvement in the financialposition of the private sector – perhaps through reducedconsumption or investment – would lower the currentaccount deficit but again by reducing aggregate demandand cutting back on demand for imports. But this wouldhardly count as an advance! Quite apart from causing awaste of economic potential, it would worsen thegovernment’s deficit.

What is needed to improve both the current accountbalance and the government’s financial position

23

THE CURRENT POSITION OF OVERSEAS TRADE

The Real Sterling Crisis Layout.qxp_Layout 1 19/08/2016 10:46 Page 23

Page 41: The Real Sterling Crisis - Civitascivitas.org.uk/content/files/The-Real-Sterling-Crisis.pdf · The fall in the value of sterling since the vote for Brexit has had commentators wringing

24

Table 2: UK net lending (+) and net borrowing (-) by sector, £bn

Year Public Non-financial Financial Households Foreign Net sector Corporations Corporations Balance Totals

2000 11.8 -0.8 -56.6 22.7 22.8 0.0

2001 4.1 -4.1 -53.5 31.8 21.7 0.0

2002 -23.4 21.0 -41.7 20.1 24.1 0.0

2003 -40.6 38.1 -24.5 6.4 20.6 0.0

2004 -45.1 46.5 -17.5 -6.9 22.9 0.0

2005 -47.0 47.2 -7.3 -10.4 17.6 0.0

2006 -41.0 36.6 -12.6 -16.9 33.9 0.0

2007 -44.2 29.5 -10.9 -12.1 37.7 0.0

2008 -76.8 40.8 -5.8 -12.9 54.8 0.0

2009 -160.5 59.5 6.0 50.6 44.4 0.0

2010 -150.4 59.5 -23.2 71.1 43.1 0.0

2011 -124.6 69.1 -15.7 41.7 29.5 0.0

2012 -139.4 38.8 2.8 36.2 61.6 0.0

2013 -99.5 34.1 -15.1 3.6 76.9 0.0

2014 -101.7 33.9 -17.9 0.3 85.4 0.0

2015 -80.6 19.5 -25.5 -10.9 101.4 3.9

Source: ONS UK Economic Accounts.

THE REAL STERLING CRISIS

without necessitating damaging domestic adjustmentsis something in the overseas sector itself – animprovement in the terms of trade, an increase in worlddemand for our exports, or a lower exchange rate. Ofcourse, the UK has no control, or even much influence,over the first two of these. But it most assuredly doesover the third.

If the UK were to enjoy a boost to its net exports (forwhatever reason), then the current account deficitwould fall and the government deficit would drop,

The Real Sterling Crisis Layout.qxp_Layout 1 19/08/2016 10:46 Page 24

Page 42: The Real Sterling Crisis - Civitascivitas.org.uk/content/files/The-Real-Sterling-Crisis.pdf · The fall in the value of sterling since the vote for Brexit has had commentators wringing

thanks to increased tax receipts and lower governmentexpenditure caused by a higher level of economicactivity. Moreover, other things being equal, thefinancial position of the private sector would improve(as savings rose, thanks to higher income for bothhouseholds and companies).

The unsustainability of consumer spending

The last serious imbalance in the UK economy is thatfar too much of what additional demand there has been– even though this has pushed up the growth rate andreduced unemployment – has been the result ofincreased consumption, which is itself unsustainable.As well as the increase in employment levels (which has raised total income from employment), the extrademand has been fed by increased consumerconfidence, an explosion in credit, and a rise in assetprices. Over the period 2000 to 2015, house pricesnationally have risen by 140% and in London by 200%.Meanwhile, the increases since 2009 have been 26% and68% respectively, while between 2009 and 2015 the FTSE100 index rose by 40%.

The European dimension

It is possible to overdo the gloom and doom about theUK’s trading position. After all, a significant part of theproblem derives from the weakness of the eurozone,which is still overwhelmingly our largest single tradingpartner. Indeed, over the last four years, our trade withnon-euro countries has improved considerably, to thepoint where it is now running at a substantial surplus.The overall trade account is only in deficit because we

25

THE CURRENT POSITION OF OVERSEAS TRADE

The Real Sterling Crisis Layout.qxp_Layout 1 19/08/2016 10:46 Page 25

Page 43: The Real Sterling Crisis - Civitascivitas.org.uk/content/files/The-Real-Sterling-Crisis.pdf · The fall in the value of sterling since the vote for Brexit has had commentators wringing

have been running a large and increasing deficit withthe eurozone.

There may be certain long-term structural factors thatmake such a state of affairs – i.e. a deficit with theeurozone and a surplus with the rest of the world – thenatural order of things. Even so, two factors haveworsened the situation. First, the eurozone has grownextremely slowly compared to most other parts of theworld, and certainly compared to the UK. This haslimited the growth of its imports – including goods andservices produced in the UK.

Indeed, estimates by Capital Economics suggest thatif the eurozone had grown in line with the US and theUK then UK exports would have been boosted so muchthat, other things being equal, the UK could actuallynow be running an overall trade surplus.

This can be taken encouragingly. After all, if the eurozonereturned to rude economic health, the UK might well beable to see a significant trade surplus without needinga lower exchange rate. On the other hand, there is scantprospect of this happening any time soon. Accordingly,UK economic policy has to take the eurozone as it is andthis implies the need for a lower exchange rate togenerate a much improved trade performance.

Second, although the ECB was slow to adopt a policyof quantitative easing (QE), and slow also to cut interestrates, more recently it has been more overtlyexpansionary with regard to both interest rates and QE.Given the limited effectiveness of QE operating throughthe usual domestic channels, this policy has been widelyinterpreted as a competitive exchange rate strategy.Between January 2007 and February 2016, before Brexitfears really began to build, the pound/euro exchangerate rose by 11%. With the UK growing strongly and not

THE REAL STERLING CRISIS

26

The Real Sterling Crisis Layout.qxp_Layout 1 19/08/2016 10:46 Page 26

Page 44: The Real Sterling Crisis - Civitascivitas.org.uk/content/files/The-Real-Sterling-Crisis.pdf · The fall in the value of sterling since the vote for Brexit has had commentators wringing

operating any sort of exchange rate policy, this hascontributed a substantial amount to the eurozone’srecovery. Indeed, its strategy has relied on takingbusiness from the UK, in the eurozone, the UK and thirdparties. This is indeed a classic case of beggar thyneighbour. And in this instance we are the neighbour.The UK is in sore need of a new policy.

The optimal current account position

In all the discussions about UK economic policy wecannot recall any consideration – in the public or privatesector – of what the optimal current account balance isfor a country such as the UK. It is widely assumed thatabout zero is about right – although it seems also toarouse scant anxiety that the UK balance has beennowhere near this point for a long time.

Moreover, plenty of other developed economies arenowhere near it either. Germany is running a currentaccount surplus of 8% of GDP, while the figures forNorway and Switzerland are 6.9% and 7.2%respectively. Although China’s surplus has fallen a longway, it is still running at 3% of GDP. Japan’s surplus isalso 3% of GDP, while Singapore’s is a staggering 20%of GDP. Of course, there must also be some substantialdeficits to balance these surpluses – and there are.Besides the UK with its deficit of 5.4% in 2015, the UShas a deficit of 2.6% and many countries in Africa andLatin America are running large deficits.

Thinking about the developed countries such asGermany, Switzerland, and Singapore, are they sodifferent from the UK that their optimal current accountposition is radically different from the UK’s? And if not,whose is out of kilter: theirs or the UK’s? Or both?

27

THE CURRENT POSITION OF OVERSEAS TRADE

The Real Sterling Crisis Layout.qxp_Layout 1 19/08/2016 10:46 Page 27

Page 45: The Real Sterling Crisis - Civitascivitas.org.uk/content/files/The-Real-Sterling-Crisis.pdf · The fall in the value of sterling since the vote for Brexit has had commentators wringing

The current account and wealth accumulation

The starting point for an analysis of this issue is therealisation that the current account position reflects thedifference between national saving and investment. Asurplus reflects an excess of domestic saving overdomestic investment while a deficit reflects a shortfall.Equally, a current account surplus, as a matter of logic,always has as its counterpart a capital account deficit,that is to say, a flow of capital abroad. Accordingly,other things equal, a current account surplus adds to thestock of national wealth (in the form of real assetsabroad, or financial claims on other countries) and adeficit diminishes it (as overseas holdings of real assetsor claims on the country increase).

Whether a country should run a surplus or deficittherefore comes down to a decision about the optimumrate of investment (and capital accumulation) and thebalance of advantages and disadvantages about havingthis desired level, whatever it is, financed domesticallyor by overseas wealth holders, as well as the balance ofadvantages and disadvantages from accumulatingwealth in the form of real assets or paper claims onforeigners as opposed to real assets at home.

The Chinese case

China may provide a useful starting point. It has both ahuge level of investment, and a huge level of saving,both close to 50% of GDP, but saving has run ahead ofinvestment, reflected in the current account surplus. It iswidely believed that China’s investment rate is excessivein that much of the investment is wasteful and the poorreturns on it threaten the stability of the banking system.

THE REAL STERLING CRISIS

28

The Real Sterling Crisis Layout.qxp_Layout 1 19/08/2016 10:46 Page 28

Page 46: The Real Sterling Crisis - Civitascivitas.org.uk/content/files/The-Real-Sterling-Crisis.pdf · The fall in the value of sterling since the vote for Brexit has had commentators wringing

But if China reduced investment, other things equal,this would both reduce aggregate demand and causethe current account surplus to widen. What China’seconomy appears to need is reduced saving andincreased consumption, both to make up for reducedinvestment and to close the current account gap. Whyis this not the policy of the Chinese authorities? To someextent it is, certainly in their rhetoric. And China’ssurplus has fallen substantially. But the authorities areconcerned to move slowly in case a collapse ofinvestment causes a hard landing in the economy.Nevertheless, there is a suspicion that elements withinthe authorities have decided that a continued surplus isin China’s interest. They may believe that:(i) Having a strong export sector, building up

surpluses, furthers the long-term growth of China’seconomy;

(ii) Amassing huge foreign exchange reserves putsChina in a strong bargaining position vis-vis therest of the world and gives the Chinese governmentsubstantial international clout;

(iii) The huge reserves protect China and its currencyfrom possible instability in the future.

While conceding somewhat on point (iii), most westernanalysts find China’s continued surplus bizarre.Essentially it involves still poor Chinese people saving(i.e. not consuming) in order to allow rich Americans(and others) to spend and consume.

Demographics

Demographic considerations also have a considerableinfluence on the optimum current account position.Suppose that a country’s population is set to age

29

THE CURRENT POSITION OF OVERSEAS TRADE

The Real Sterling Crisis Layout.qxp_Layout 1 19/08/2016 10:46 Page 29

Page 47: The Real Sterling Crisis - Civitascivitas.org.uk/content/files/The-Real-Sterling-Crisis.pdf · The fall in the value of sterling since the vote for Brexit has had commentators wringing

substantially. When this happens, you would expect asubstantial swing towards dis-saving as retirees carry onspending even though they are no longer working andproducing. In anticipation of this situation, it would beprudent for the country as a whole to build up financialassets through saving. This would take the form ofpersistent current account surpluses, implying the build-up of net overseas assets. So a country about to undergoa significant ageing of its population might readily runa significant current account surplus at first, counter-balanced subsequently by a significant current accountdeficit as retirees spend their accumulated capital.

The demographic factor has been a widely usedargument to justify Japan’s sustained current accountsurplus. It is sometimes also deployed to justifyGermany’s and Switzerland’s (although it is unclearhow well such an argument stands up in their case).

The UK has strong demographics, with the populationset to grow considerably. Nevertheless, this cannotjustify more than a fraction of the UK’s current account deficit.

The UK case

Turning to the UK in more detail, in marked contrast toChina, we appear to have an inadequate rate ofdomestic investment which is not fully funded bydomestic saving, hence the current account deficit.Indeed, it is the low rate of saving that is the appropriatemarker because the need to draw in savings fromabroad to finance such investment as we carry out,reduces the effective rate of capital accumulation, sincepart of whatever is accumulated is owned, or at leastclaimed against, by overseas wealth holders.

THE REAL STERLING CRISIS

30

The Real Sterling Crisis Layout.qxp_Layout 1 19/08/2016 10:46 Page 30

Page 48: The Real Sterling Crisis - Civitascivitas.org.uk/content/files/The-Real-Sterling-Crisis.pdf · The fall in the value of sterling since the vote for Brexit has had commentators wringing

It is easy to get yourself in a pickle by agonising aboutthe direction of causation behind the accountingidentities. Is it low saving that ‘causes’ the currentaccount deficit, or the current account deficit (i.e. theexcess of imports over exports) that causes low saving(because it depresses incomes)? In reality, therelationships are symbiotic. The causation is complex,different between countries and may change over time.But we need not agonise about these complexities.

As regards what needs to change to bring about asatisfactory macroeconomic result for the UK in currentcircumstances there is no doubt. The last thing we needis to reduce investment, while increased saving (eitheror both of which would reduce the current accountdeficit) would, other things equal, reduce aggregatedemand and increase unemployment. What is requiredis a set of policies that reduces or eliminates the currentaccount deficit without depressing aggregate demand.

That means a lower exchange rate than we have beenused to – at least until the Brexit vote caused it to drop.Higher exports and/or lower imports would not onlyreduce the current account deficit but, assuming thatthere are spare resources in the economy, would alsoraise GDP and income and hence increase privatesavings, as well as reducing the fiscal deficit.

No subject for government?

There is a view that, aside from the contribution of theirown fiscal policy, governments should take no interestin the current account. The private sector’s currentaccount balance is a private matter and governmentsshould leave well alone. Accordingly, if a country runsa current account deficit while the public financial

31

THE CURRENT POSITION OF OVERSEAS TRADE

The Real Sterling Crisis Layout.qxp_Layout 1 19/08/2016 10:46 Page 31

Page 49: The Real Sterling Crisis - Civitascivitas.org.uk/content/files/The-Real-Sterling-Crisis.pdf · The fall in the value of sterling since the vote for Brexit has had commentators wringing

position is balanced – that is to say the current accountposition is wholly private – then the government shouldnot turn a hair. It is simply none of its business. Afterall, such a private sector deficit represents the profit andutility maximising decisions of countless ‘economicagents’ who, acting in their own personal best interests,produce an outcome that is the best possible one forthem, given the prevailing circumstances.

Putting the matter slightly differently, with regard tojust about all other markets, most economists believethat markets are best left to their own devices. Themarket prices that are the result of the forces of supplyand demand produce the best possible outcome forproduction and welfare, given the prevailingcircumstances. Why should the foreign exchangemarket be any different?

This argument that balance of payments imbalancesdon’t matter and the foreign exchange market shouldbe left to its own devices is unconvincing, for thefollowing reasons:(i) Significant current account deficits often do occur

side by side with substantial public deficits (this is currently true in the UK, but this is not always the case);

(ii) Private sector ‘agents’ take their decisions,including decisions about overseas transactionsthat then affect the exchange rate, in the context ofa panoply of policies set by the government (andcentral bank);

(iii) It is widely acknowledged that with regard tosaving and investment, the private sector cannotalways be relied upon to take decisions which arein its best interests. Because of the separation of

THE REAL STERLING CRISIS

32

The Real Sterling Crisis Layout.qxp_Layout 1 19/08/2016 10:46 Page 32

Page 50: The Real Sterling Crisis - Civitascivitas.org.uk/content/files/The-Real-Sterling-Crisis.pdf · The fall in the value of sterling since the vote for Brexit has had commentators wringing

ownership from control, managements of businessenterprises may invest significantly too little.Meanwhile, in regard to their saving behaviour,individuals are notably myopic;

(iv) There is no necessary reason why the self-interested decisions of international asset holdersshould coincide with our national self-interest;

(v) There is ample evidence that real exchange ratescan diverge from the underlying fundamentals forlong periods and ample evidence that suchdivergences can do huge damage;

(vi) The foreign exchange market is different frommost other markets because investors and tradersdo not have a clear view of what the right level isfor an exchange rate, and because a misalignedexchange rate can have huge effects on theeconomy, which then affect the appropriate levelof the exchange rate;

(vii) If ‘countries’ mean anything at all, thengovernments have a responsibility that goesbeyond the self-interest of today’s ‘economicagents’. If they don’t, then what is the point of so much economic policy? If current accountdeficits do not matter as long as they are ‘private’,in what sense is it right for governments to striveto boost the rate of economic growth? Why notsimply leave it to be determined as the outcome of‘market forces’?

Conclusion

The upshot is that although it might be extremelydifficult to pin down the size of the optimum current

33

THE CURRENT POSITION OF OVERSEAS TRADE

The Real Sterling Crisis Layout.qxp_Layout 1 19/08/2016 10:46 Page 33

Page 51: The Real Sterling Crisis - Civitascivitas.org.uk/content/files/The-Real-Sterling-Crisis.pdf · The fall in the value of sterling since the vote for Brexit has had commentators wringing

account surplus or deficit, in the UK’s case we may be pretty sure that its current huge deficit is seriouslysub-optimal. What’s more, bearing in mind theconsequences for both the real economy and thefinancial markets, this is most assuredly something for the policy authorities to be concerned about. Indeed,we suspect that there is scarcely any other country inthe developed world (apart possibly from the US, which is a special case) that would have regarded itsexchange rate and balance of payments with suchblithe insouciance.

THE REAL STERLING CRISIS

34

The Real Sterling Crisis Layout.qxp_Layout 1 19/08/2016 10:46 Page 34

Page 52: The Real Sterling Crisis - Civitascivitas.org.uk/content/files/The-Real-Sterling-Crisis.pdf · The fall in the value of sterling since the vote for Brexit has had commentators wringing

3 The historical background

to the UK’s current account

During the 19th century, Britain had a huge currentaccount surplus, balanced by equally large capitalexports. Our surplus was not achieved by Britain enjoyinga positive visible trade balance over most of this period.Despite Britain’s pre-eminence, at least during the firsthalf of the century, as ‘the workshop of the world’, theavailable statistics show Britain generally running avisible trade deficit only partially offset by a surplus inservices. The reason why Britain had a major overallcurrent account surplus during the 19th century was thatthe country enjoyed the benefit of a huge accumulation ofnet assets abroad, which generated a massive net income.

The beginning of competitiveness problems

The pre-eminence of Britain at least in terms of livingstandards, up to the outbreak of World War I, thereforerelied only to a limited extent on the competiveness ofour manufactures. Certainly, for the early decades of the19th century, Britain enjoyed a major benefit in thatthere was little international competition for the goodswhich British industry was making at the time, but thiswas always a fragile advantage.

35

The Real Sterling Crisis Layout.qxp_Layout 1 19/08/2016 10:46 Page 35

Page 53: The Real Sterling Crisis - Civitascivitas.org.uk/content/files/The-Real-Sterling-Crisis.pdf · The fall in the value of sterling since the vote for Brexit has had commentators wringing

Some loss of market share for Britain was inevitableas other countries caught up with the prime mover.Nevertheless, it is difficult to argue that the level of the pound did not contribute to the relatively slowgrowth in British manufacturing compared to whathappened in other countries in the run-up to the FirstWorld War.

If Britain was dogged by the strength of sterling up to1914, worse was to follow when the war was over.Following the precedent set at the end of the NapoleonicWars, the Cunliffe Committee recommended that theparity between the pound and the dollar should be re-established at the pre-War rate - $4.86 to the pound –even though inflation in Britain had been much higherduring the war than in the USA – about 80% in Britaincompared to 50% in the USA. This objective waseventually attained in 1925, but at the expense ofstagnation during nearly all of the 1920s. By 1931, GDPwas still slightly lower than it had been in 1919.

The 1930s, however, told a very different story. In1931, sterling was allowed to be driven off its previousparity and to fall in value by 31% against the dollar, andby 24% against all other major currencies. The resultwas a dramatic improvement in the country’s economicperformance. By 1938 GDP had grown by 24% andmanufacturing output by 45%. By the end of the decade,however, after the USA had devalued the dollar by 41%in 1934 and the gold bloc countries had followed suit in1936, Britain’s competitive edge had disappeared andthe economy was moving back towards depression,only to be rescued by rearmament as World War IIapproached. In 1948, the Economic Commission forEurope estimated that sterling was as overvalued in1938 as it had been in 1929.

THE REAL STERLING CRISIS

36

The Real Sterling Crisis Layout.qxp_Layout 1 19/08/2016 10:46 Page 36

Page 54: The Real Sterling Crisis - Civitascivitas.org.uk/content/files/The-Real-Sterling-Crisis.pdf · The fall in the value of sterling since the vote for Brexit has had commentators wringing

Post-war problems

The UK was on the winning side during World War II,but emerged from the conflict heavily over-extendedand with its currency yet again substantially over-valued – initially against the US dollar but subsequentlyagainst a basket of currencies, including those of manycountries recovering strongly from the war. The resultwas devaluation in 1949 and 1967. Nevertheless, theUK’s share of world trade continued to declineremorselessly, from 10.7% in 1950, to 5.7% in 1980, andthen to 2.7% by 2010. Again, to some extent this wasinevitable as many countries around the worlddeveloped rapidly. But the UK also lost market share tocountries that were similar to it, particularly Germany.

The China issue

Thanks to a series of reforms begun in 1979, Chinagreatly increased its productive capacity and its role inworld trade. Not only did its nominal exchange rate fallbut, because of rapid increases in productivity (notoffset by rises in the nominal exchange rate), China’sreal exchange rate fell by some 75% over the nextdecade, producing an enormous disparity between thecosts of manufacturing almost anything in the UK – andindeed in most of the West – compared to China andother countries along the Pacific Rim, most of whichalso devalued heavily following the 1997 Asian crisis.

Two extremely important consequences have flowedfrom these developments. The first is that, as a result ofthe cost base being so much lower in the East than it hasbeen in the West, there has been a huge transfer ofmanufacturing capacity from the western world to thePacific Rim.

37

HISTORICAL BACKGROUND TO THE UK’S CURRENT ACCOUNT

The Real Sterling Crisis Layout.qxp_Layout 1 19/08/2016 10:46 Page 37

Page 55: The Real Sterling Crisis - Civitascivitas.org.uk/content/files/The-Real-Sterling-Crisis.pdf · The fall in the value of sterling since the vote for Brexit has had commentators wringing

The cost base is made up of all production costsincurred in the domestic currency. Typically formanufacturing operations, about one third of total costsare for raw materials and plant and machinery, forwhich there are world prices. The other two thirds ismade up of costs incurred in sterling in the UK andrenminbi in China – mostly wages, but also includingeverything from audit charges to taxi fares, fromcleaning costs to interest charges, from gettingstationery printed to getting vehicles repaired. Thesecosts are all charged out to the rest of the world in thedomestic currency and the higher its valuation, via theexchange rate, the more expensive domestic output willappear to be to the rest of the world. It is because thecost base became so much lower in the East than theWest that, on a massive scale, manufacturing capacitymigrated eastwards.

The second crucial result of this change is that theWest – unable to compete with the East over a very widerange of manufacturing output – began to run hugebalance of payments deficits with countries such asChina. By the 2000s, China was running a currentaccount surplus which averaged about 5% of its GDPfor the whole of the decade, peaking at a staggering 10%in 2007, while the USA ran a deficit of 4.5%. During thesame decade, the trade deficit between the UK andChina averaged about £10bn per annum, but in recentyears the overall UK current account position, includingthe UK’s trade balance with China, has deterioratedvery sharply.

The overall result has been that the West has becomemore and more deeply indebted to the East at the sametime as the enormous benefit of increased productivitythat well-run manufacturing operations always bring in

THE REAL STERLING CRISIS

38

The Real Sterling Crisis Layout.qxp_Layout 1 19/08/2016 10:46 Page 38

Page 56: The Real Sterling Crisis - Civitascivitas.org.uk/content/files/The-Real-Sterling-Crisis.pdf · The fall in the value of sterling since the vote for Brexit has had commentators wringing

train has generated massive growth rates along thePacific Rim. Since 2007, the aggregate growth for the lasteight years in the West has been not much above zerowhile in the East it has been close to 77%. In the UK, theeconomy during these eight years has grown by 7.3%,but the population has increased by 6.5%, so that GDPper head, a good proxy for living standards, has hardlyincreased at all. In China, by contrast, over the sameeight years, GDP has risen by about 93% and GDP perhead by almost 85%.

What this brief history of the make-up of UK exportsand imports shows is that our performance has alwaysbeen price sensitive and that the exchange rate hasalways been a crucial factor in determining what ourtrading position will be. With occasional exceptions suchas in the 1930s, there has been a pronounced tendencyfor sterling to be too strong, with the consequence that our manufactured exports have tended to beuncompetitive and importing too attractive.

The result has been to make manufacturing in the UKgenerally unprofitable; to discourage able people fromtaking up a career making and selling things in the UK;to ensure that we have kept losing our share of worldtrade; to make us suffer from chronic balance ofpayments problems; and to discourage investment.Moreover, the overall result has been to make oureconomy grow more slowly than it should have doneas a result of a combination of both deflationary policiesto protect the balance of payments and foregoing muchof the growth in productivity which a highercontribution from manufacturing would have allowedus to achieve.

There are many reasons why a high value for sterlinghas been popular in the UK – from holiday makers

39

HISTORICAL BACKGROUND TO THE UK’S CURRENT ACCOUNT

The Real Sterling Crisis Layout.qxp_Layout 1 19/08/2016 10:46 Page 39

Page 57: The Real Sterling Crisis - Civitascivitas.org.uk/content/files/The-Real-Sterling-Crisis.pdf · The fall in the value of sterling since the vote for Brexit has had commentators wringing

getting a good rate of exchange for their trips abroad tothe City liking a strong exchange rate because itprovides those working there with more internationalleverage. And there are further reasons – discussed later– why policy makers have favoured a strong pound. Butthe overall impact of our over-valued currency has beento leave our economy much weaker and moreunbalanced than it needed to be.

THE REAL STERLING CRISIS

40

The Real Sterling Crisis Layout.qxp_Layout 1 19/08/2016 10:46 Page 40

Page 58: The Real Sterling Crisis - Civitascivitas.org.uk/content/files/The-Real-Sterling-Crisis.pdf · The fall in the value of sterling since the vote for Brexit has had commentators wringing

4 How could the current account gap be closed?

If the exchange rate were appreciably lower than it hasbeen in recent years and the UK’s trade balanceimproved substantially, what would be the nature of theexports that now appeared?

A pound is a pound is a pound. In principle, we couldclose the gap between overseas income and expenditurein several different ways. However, a number of factors,outlined below, suggest that increased manufacturingoutput, and indeed an increased share of manufacturingin GDP, will have to play an important part.

Productivity and costs

It is important to realise that countries are notcompetitive simply as a result of wages being low. It iswage costs per unit of output, not wage levelsconsidered in isolation, that are crucial. In economiessuch as Germany, Japan and Switzerland, hourly wagerates in manufacturing industry are high but becausethese economies have very large accumulations ofcapital and skills, output per head is also very high and wages as a component of costs are correspondinglylow. This is why it is possible for countries such asSingapore, which also has a well-paid labour force, to

41

The Real Sterling Crisis Layout.qxp_Layout 1 19/08/2016 10:46 Page 41

Page 59: The Real Sterling Crisis - Civitascivitas.org.uk/content/files/The-Real-Sterling-Crisis.pdf · The fall in the value of sterling since the vote for Brexit has had commentators wringing

remain highly competitive and to continue to growrapidly – by almost 3% in 2014 and by an average of6.4% per annum for the last 10 years.

It is true that, as economies get richer, they tend toconcentrate production on more complicated productsand their industries tend to become more high-tech. Thisis the result of their growth success, however, and not thecause. That is why it is an illusion for UK policy-makersto believe that moving the UK economy to higher-techmanufacturing will make us more competitive. This willtend to happen as we succeed but we cannot jumpseveral stages of development in one go.

While we await our ‘high-tech transformation’, theUK simply cannot produce enough high-tech exports toenable it to pay its way in the world. Moreover,although high-tech is more difficult than low- ormedium-tech to attack from low cost base economies, itis not impossible. In the long-term, high-tech is likely tobe almost as vulnerable as less sophisticated industriesas the Chinese learn to build aircraft and their engines,the Indians to produce world class drugs and theKoreans to produce better cars.

In the medium term, therefore, if the UK is ever to getits balance of payments problems under control, we willhave both to nurture those industries we still retain andto re-establish more medium-tech activity. There is noknowing the industry structure that would best enablethe UK to return to something like current accountbalance. But it seems likely that, bearing in mind thestructure of UK exports, balance in our current accountwould require manufacturing as a proportion of UKGDP to get back to somewhere around 15% of GDP. Todo this, we will have to have a much lower exchangerate than we have been used to.

THE REAL STERLING CRISIS

42

The Real Sterling Crisis Layout.qxp_Layout 1 19/08/2016 10:46 Page 42

Page 60: The Real Sterling Crisis - Civitascivitas.org.uk/content/files/The-Real-Sterling-Crisis.pdf · The fall in the value of sterling since the vote for Brexit has had commentators wringing

The service sector to the rescue?

There are two well-worn counter-arguments to thisapproach. One is that, because we are better atproducing services than manufactured goods, weshould put our effort behind developing our serviceindustries where we have a competitive advantage. Theother is that we should move up market into high-skilled occupations and thus be able to keep sufficientlyfar ahead of world competition to keep paying our way.We consider these two arguments in turn.

The UK is good at producing services and sellingthem on world markets – and it always has been.Financial services, including insurance, banking, legaland accounting services and ship broking – as well asother invisible export earnings from tourism andintellectual property – are responsible for the UK havinga large services export surplus every year – £89bn in2015, but averaging £59bn per annum for the previous10 years.

This has happened partly by luck – the pre-eminenceof English as the world’s business language and ourposition geographically in the world half way betweenthe USA and the Far East – and partly by goodmanagement. The UK has a reliable legal system, a longaccumulated depth of expertise and an attractiveenvironment all of which have stood its serviceindustries in good stead. Services are also, in general,less price sensitive than manufactured goods becausethey are less easy to compare. There is, therefore,everything to be said for protecting and enhancing theUK’s services exports wherever we reasonably can.

The problem is that most exports – even for the UK –are not services but goods and it is extremely difficult –

43

HOW COULD THE CURRENT ACCOUNT GAP BE CLOSED?

The Real Sterling Crisis Layout.qxp_Layout 1 19/08/2016 10:46 Page 43

Page 61: The Real Sterling Crisis - Civitascivitas.org.uk/content/files/The-Real-Sterling-Crisis.pdf · The fall in the value of sterling since the vote for Brexit has had commentators wringing

and indeed historical experience has shown it to beimpossible – to close the gap between our exportsurplus on services and our deficit on goods solely byincreasing services exports. Our visible deficit was£126bn in 2015 and an average of £97bn for the previous10 years, with the corresponding figures for the overalltrade deficit being £39bn and an average of £38bn forthe previous decade.

Relatedly, does moving upmarket with a bettereducated and trained labour force look as though itmight solve our trade deficit problem, through bothhelping to bolster still further our service sector andhelping us to produce more high-end manufacturedoutput? Despite the obvious intuitive appeal that itwould, it is hard to see how it might happen in a waywhich would make more than a marginal difference inthe relevant time-frame. And, in the long-run, bettereducational and training standards will only improveour competitive position if they are not accompanied byhigher earnings expectations. The situation might be abit better on services, some of which, at least, dependmore than manufacturing on the intellectual capacity ofthe workforce, but it is difficult to see there being aquantum leap in net trade performance as a result.

Actually, what has happened is that for many decades,the lack of profitability and the poor prospects inmanufacturing have led to low earnings and lowprestige, with the result that this vital sector of oureconomy has been starved of talent. Faced with apoisonous mixture of poor management andunmanageable competition, UK industry, especially itslow- and medium-tech varieties, has withered anddeclined. This is the price paid by economies whoseexchange rate is too high for its manufacturing

THE REAL STERLING CRISIS

44

The Real Sterling Crisis Layout.qxp_Layout 1 19/08/2016 10:46 Page 44

Page 62: The Real Sterling Crisis - Civitascivitas.org.uk/content/files/The-Real-Sterling-Crisis.pdf · The fall in the value of sterling since the vote for Brexit has had commentators wringing

industries to bear. The trade deficits thus generatedrequire deflationary policies to contain. Investment as a proportion of GDP declines. Economic growth is reduced.

A less dramatic answer

All that said, it shouldn’t be forgotten that with a lower exchange rate there are all sorts of ways that netexports might recover without a dramatic turnaroundin the UK’s industrial structure. We could achieve theresult, or at least part of it, simply by expanding the production and sales abroad of those things wherewe already have a significant presence.

Motor cars are a good example. There is no reason tosuppose that the demand for particular brands/typesof cars is not price sensitive to some degree. If sterlingwere maintained at an appreciably lower rate than it hasbeen then British exports of cars would be higher – and,just as importantly, for the same reason, our imports ofcars would be lower.

This leads on to a more general point. Improving thetrade balance can be achieved just as effectively throughreduced imports as it can through increased exports. Ofcourse, we are not going to suddenly start producingbananas to substitute for the imported variety. But inmany cases we both produce domestically and importbroadly similar products. Cars are not the only example.Moving down the value-added chain, take bottledmineral water as an example. Or, with admittedly moreproduct discrimination, cheese.

Nor does effective substitution of domestic for foreign have to involve the whole product. It maysimply mean more of a production process beingconducted domestically as opposed to abroad.

45

HOW COULD THE CURRENT ACCOUNT GAP BE CLOSED?

The Real Sterling Crisis Layout.qxp_Layout 1 19/08/2016 10:46 Page 45

Page 63: The Real Sterling Crisis - Civitascivitas.org.uk/content/files/The-Real-Sterling-Crisis.pdf · The fall in the value of sterling since the vote for Brexit has had commentators wringing

For example, it has recently been suggested that Rolls-Royce may relocate some of its production processesabroad, including to India because of lower costs. If thesterling exchange rate were substantially lower, suchpressure would be appreciably reduced.

Naturally, where producers need to switch thesourcing for their output from abroad to here in the UK– and even more so if they are to decide to relocatewhole areas of production here – they need more thana transitory move of the exchange rate to encouragethem to do so. Accordingly, time lags are likely to besignificant, and probably longer than in the past beforea response is forthcoming. Moreover, the response willbe greater the more the producers believe that the newexchange rate will be long-lived. They are more likelyto take this view if a competitive exchange rate is anavowed policy objective. (More on this below.)

Another twist on services

Some of the adjustment can also come from services. Itis widely believed that services exports are not veryprice-sensitive. That may be true of some services butnot all. It is difficult to believe, for instance, that our nettourism balance would not improve as a result of asubstantial drop in the exchange rate, thereby makingUK holidays cheaper compared to foreign alternatives,for both UK and foreign holiday-makers alike.

But suppose it is true that the demand for UK serviceexports is not particularly price sensitive. Accordingly,after a devaluation of sterling the profit maximisingoption for UK service providers would be to keep theforeign currency price the same, thereby yielding ahigher sterling price. Meanwhile, with regard to our

THE REAL STERLING CRISIS

46

The Real Sterling Crisis Layout.qxp_Layout 1 19/08/2016 10:46 Page 46

Page 64: The Real Sterling Crisis - Civitascivitas.org.uk/content/files/The-Real-Sterling-Crisis.pdf · The fall in the value of sterling since the vote for Brexit has had commentators wringing

imports of manufactured goods, which are pricesensitive, the profit-maximising decision for importersmight well be to keep the sterling price unchanged,implying a drop in the foreign currency price. If thishappened then, although UK trade volumes might notrespond to the lower exchange rate, there would be animprovement in the terms of trade which, in regard toits effect on the trade balance, would be just as good.

Whether something like this will happen woulddepend on the competitive conditions in the UK’sservice exporting businesses. To the extent that theseindustries are oligopolistic then something like theabove result should stand. If these industries are fully competitive, however, then the foreign currencyprices should be competed down, leaving the sterlingprices (more or less) unaltered and thereby risking aterms of trade loss, which would serve to worsen thetrade balance.

The exchange rate and theinvestment income balance

The UK has a huge balance sheet, with overseas assetsand domestic liabilities to overseas asset holders eachof the order of 500% of GDP. The assets, and the incomeon them, are predominantly denominated in foreigncurrencies, while the liabilities, and the payments madeon them, are largely in sterling. In other words, the UKis ‘long’ on foreign currencies.

Accordingly, a depreciation raises the sterling valueof income flows from abroad, while leaving the sterlingvalue of payments to overseas asset holders unchanged.Alternatively, you could say that the depreciation leaves the foreign currency value of the income flows

47

HOW COULD THE CURRENT ACCOUNT GAP BE CLOSED?

The Real Sterling Crisis Layout.qxp_Layout 1 19/08/2016 10:46 Page 47

Page 65: The Real Sterling Crisis - Civitascivitas.org.uk/content/files/The-Real-Sterling-Crisis.pdf · The fall in the value of sterling since the vote for Brexit has had commentators wringing

on our assets unchanged, while diminishing the foreigncurrency value of the payments we send overseas.

If the amounts of assets and liabilities are the same,and the returns earned on assets are the same as thosepaid on liabilities (it won’t be), then, supposing that the return is 2%, with assets and liabilities of 500% ofGDP, a 20% fall of sterling would bring about a boost to our investment income balance of 2% of GDP (500%x 20% x 2%) – about £36bn.

Trade, growth, productivity and inequality

To what extent is our weak trade performanceresponsible for our relatively low rate of productivityincrease, economic growth and living standards, andthe rises we have seen in both socio-economic andregional inequality? Why has our performance in these key respects been so much worse than in manyother parts of the world? What does the differingperformance of other countries have to tell us?

Evidence from across the planet shows that there is apattern which we decline to follow at our peril.Economies, large and small, which have grown quickly– and which are still doing so – perform best when they have strong export-orientated manufacturingsectors. There are exceptions – countries in the MiddleEast, for instance, whose wealth comes from naturalresources such as oil – but these countries tend to berelatively poorly diversified and to suffer from extremesof inequality.

The countries which offer all their populations thebest outcomes and which appear to have the mostsecure future prosperity are those whose economies are

THE REAL STERLING CRISIS

48

The Real Sterling Crisis Layout.qxp_Layout 1 19/08/2016 10:46 Page 48

Page 66: The Real Sterling Crisis - Civitascivitas.org.uk/content/files/The-Real-Sterling-Crisis.pdf · The fall in the value of sterling since the vote for Brexit has had commentators wringing

based on a wide variety of manufacturing industries,supporting a thriving service sector, with increasingdemand in the economy unconstrained by balance ofpayments problems. These are the conditions which ledto the huge increase in prosperity in continental Europebetween 1950 and 1970, which prevailed in Japan untilthe 1980s and which drove the rise in prosperity formany years in the Asian Tiger economies – South Korea,Hong Kong, Taiwan and Singapore. They are still veryevident in China today and indeed in many of the othereconomies stretched out along the Pacific Rim.

With slow growth goes increasing inequality. It is nocoincidence that relatively slow growing, heavilyservice-orientated economies, such as the USA andthe UK, have some of the highest indices of inequality

and that these have become more pronounced in recent years.

49

HOW COULD THE CURRENT ACCOUNT GAP BE CLOSED?

The Real Sterling Crisis Layout.qxp_Layout 1 19/08/2016 10:46 Page 49

Page 67: The Real Sterling Crisis - Civitascivitas.org.uk/content/files/The-Real-Sterling-Crisis.pdf · The fall in the value of sterling since the vote for Brexit has had commentators wringing

The Real Sterling Crisis Layout.qxp_Layout 1 19/08/2016 10:46 Page 50

Page 68: The Real Sterling Crisis - Civitascivitas.org.uk/content/files/The-Real-Sterling-Crisis.pdf · The fall in the value of sterling since the vote for Brexit has had commentators wringing

Part Two

Exchange Rates and Exchange Rate Policy

The Real Sterling Crisis Layout.qxp_Layout 1 19/08/2016 10:46 Page 51

Page 69: The Real Sterling Crisis - Civitascivitas.org.uk/content/files/The-Real-Sterling-Crisis.pdf · The fall in the value of sterling since the vote for Brexit has had commentators wringing

5 How British exchange rate

policy has evolved over the last 100 years

Over the last 100 years, UK exchange rate policy hasveered between obsessive control and benign (or malign)neglect. During the 19th century, the UK was at the centreof the gold standard, which was a fixed exchange ratesystem between different currencies, based upon eachcurrency’s fixed link with gold. This system severelyconstrained domestic policy. Indeed, monetary policyhardly existed in any independent sense, while fiscalpolicy was constrained by the perceived need to paydown the national debt. In order to maintain the fixedlink, when gold was draining out of the Bank of England,the Bank had to raise interest rates. And when it waspouring in, it had the scope to cut them.

A critical decision

This system came to an end with the suspension of goldconvertibility during the First World War. In 1925,however, the then Chancellor of the Exchequer, WinstonChurchill, was persuaded that it was essential that theUK should return to the gold standard at the pre-warparity, notwithstanding the fact that in the interim, UK

52

The Real Sterling Crisis Layout.qxp_Layout 1 19/08/2016 10:46 Page 52

Page 70: The Real Sterling Crisis - Civitascivitas.org.uk/content/files/The-Real-Sterling-Crisis.pdf · The fall in the value of sterling since the vote for Brexit has had commentators wringing

costs and prices had risen faster than their equivalentsabroad. This condemned the country to a prolongedperiod of deflation and depression. The general strikeof 1926 was a direct result of this policy decision.

Keynes lambasted it in his pamphlet The EconomicConsequences of Mr Churchill, so titled to chime in withhis international best-seller, The Economic Consequencesof the Peace, a devastating critique of the Versailles peacetreaty at the end of the First World War.

This exchange rate policy of Churchill’s – adopted,with some misgivings by the great man, on the adviceof Treasury and Bank of England officials – can be seenas the first of a series of British establishment decisionswhich put the objective of financial stability – and thesupposed interests of the City of London – above theobjective of international competitiveness and theinterests of the wider economy outside the Square Mile.

Putting the economic situation then in today’seconomic parlance, the UK’s faster rate of inflationduring the First World War had raised its real exchangerate. A lower nominal rate to offset the higher inflation,and therefore return the real rate to where it had beenearlier, might have seemed appropriate. Instead,however, the former nominal rate was adhered to,which implied a policy of austerity and deflation toreduce costs and prices in order to push the realexchange rate back to where it had been. In other words,the British authorities had chosen a policy of ‘internaldevaluation’. This has been mirrored, almost a centurylater, in the policies adopted within the eurozone to tryto make its peripheral countries competitive again,without recourse to exchange rate devaluation, whichwould require a break-up of the euro.

53

HOW BRITISH EXCHANGE RATE POLICY HAS EVOLVED

The Real Sterling Crisis Layout.qxp_Layout 1 19/08/2016 10:46 Page 53

Page 71: The Real Sterling Crisis - Civitascivitas.org.uk/content/files/The-Real-Sterling-Crisis.pdf · The fall in the value of sterling since the vote for Brexit has had commentators wringing

The lessons of the 1930s

In 1931, however, matters came to a head. It wasn’t so much a case of the government deciding that the gold standard parity was no longer worth adhering to,but rather a case of it finding that the current positionwas no longer sustainable. The UK was effectivelyforced off the gold standard, not knowing whatdisasters might ensue.

What ensued, thanks to a lower exchange rate andvery low interest rates, was the fastest period ofeconomic growth in our industrial history. As oneLabour minister said at the time of the gold standardexit: ‘No one told us that we could do that.’ Thisexperience was to be repeated some sixty years laterwhen the pound was ejected from the ERM (see below.)

Such was the UK’s weight in the global economy thenthat many other countries immediately followedsterling’s lead to leave the gold standard. Othersfollowed later. As a result, the 1930s became a period ofexchange rate instability. It is often alleged that thisresulted from countries trying to gain advantage overeach other through ‘competitive devaluation’. In thecontext of depressed demand – a problem that had begunin America with the Wall Street Crash of 1929, but whichwas intensified by the global financial crisis of 1931 –countries could bolster their own position by gaining agreater share of markets, both at home and abroad.

In practice, though, most countries were forced intodevaluation when they lost control of monetary andexchange rate policy. One notable exception is Germanywhich, under the economic leadership of HjalmarSchacht, actively sought to gain competitive advantageby operating with a lower exchange rate.

THE REAL STERLING CRISIS

54

The Real Sterling Crisis Layout.qxp_Layout 1 19/08/2016 10:46 Page 54

Page 72: The Real Sterling Crisis - Civitascivitas.org.uk/content/files/The-Real-Sterling-Crisis.pdf · The fall in the value of sterling since the vote for Brexit has had commentators wringing

Hand in hand with currency instability wentprotectionist trade policies. The result was a majorcontraction of global trade. Essentially, the open tradingsystem that had characterised the first era ofglobalisation, before the First World War, collapsed.

The return to fixed exchange rates – and the relapse

At the end of World War II, John Maynard Keynes waskeen to ensure that the post-war world would not bedamaged by the exchange rate instability andprotectionism that had characterised the 1930s.Accordingly, together with his US counterpart, HarryDexter White, he set about constructing a post-wareconomic regime that would provide for fixed, butadjustable, exchange rates. This Bretton Woods system(named after the hotel in New Hampshire where it wasconcocted) lasted from 1946 until 1971. Afterwards, thepound, in common with other currencies, floated.

At first, governments welcomed the sense of freedomthat floating exchange rates seemed to bring. At lastthey could set domestic policy in pursuit of domesticobjectives without fear of the consequences for thebalance of payments, or the reaction in the foreignexchange markets.

But this freedom coincided with the onset of highinflation. Some economists would argue this was due tothe operation of lax monetary and fiscal policy in thecontext of over-full employment; others would point tothe oil price hikes of 1973/4 and the role of trade unions.Whatever the relative weight of these two explanations,the phenomenon of high inflation, higher than anythingthat had been experienced in developed economies

55

HOW BRITISH EXCHANGE RATE POLICY HAS EVOLVED

The Real Sterling Crisis Layout.qxp_Layout 1 19/08/2016 10:46 Page 55

Page 73: The Real Sterling Crisis - Civitascivitas.org.uk/content/files/The-Real-Sterling-Crisis.pdf · The fall in the value of sterling since the vote for Brexit has had commentators wringing

except for brief periods during the Napoleonic Wars, theFirst World War and the Korean War, convinced bothacademic economists and policy-makers that the worldneeded some sort of nominal anchor. If not gold – andvery few wanted a return to the ‘barbarous relic’ – orsome sort of fixed exchange rate system, then what?

Monetarism triumphant – for a time

The first port of call was the monetary aggregates, insome shape or form. This was far from accidental. Thearch-advocate of floating exchange rates, MiltonFriedman, was also the high priest of monetarism. Headvocated fixed annual targets for the rate of increaseof the money supply. His thinking provided theintellectual ballast for a completely new macroeconomicpolicy, focused on control of the money supply.

In contrast to popular opinion, the adoption of someform of monetarism in the UK began before the adventof Mrs Thatcher’s government. In 1976, the Chancellorof the Exchequer, Denis Healey, adopted a moneysupply framework. When the Conservatives took powerin 1979, they installed a formal target for the growth ofthe monetary aggregate called Sterling M3.

What ensued was one of the most ideologically drivenbouts of economic policy in the UK’s history. Someproponents and defenders of the government’smonetarist policies argued that the exchange rate didn’tmatter. It was merely a relative price. The work ofgetting inflation to fall was to be done by the significantplanned reduction in the growth rate of the moneysupply (defined as £M3).

THE REAL STERLING CRISIS

56

The Real Sterling Crisis Layout.qxp_Layout 1 19/08/2016 10:46 Page 56

Page 74: The Real Sterling Crisis - Civitascivitas.org.uk/content/files/The-Real-Sterling-Crisis.pdf · The fall in the value of sterling since the vote for Brexit has had commentators wringing

Paradoxically, at the same time, others, including thegovernment’s Chief Economic Adviser, Terry (nowLord) Burns, saw a strong exchange rate as absolutelyvital to bringing inflation down. It was the tool throughwhich a tough monetary policy did its work. These twopositions were, of course, polar opposites. Nevertheless,their proponents could unite behind the idea that thesharp rise of the pound was nothing to worry about,still less to take policy action to resist.

From today’s perspective, three key points (that wereperceived at the time by the present co-authors) areclear to almost all economists:

• Control of the money supply had next to nothing todo with the reduction of inflation by Mrs Thatcher’sfirst government – not least because the moneysupply was not tightly controlled. The governmentdiscovered that it could declare monetary targetsuntil it was blue in the face but what actuallyhappened to the money supply was determined inthe private sector, and especially in the banks.

• This did not matter for the achievement of lowinflation because the high interest rates deemednecessary for the control of the money supply, andthe concomitant surge of the pound, buoyed also byNorth Sea Oil, did the job anyway.

• Opinions will differ as to whether this was necessaryand/or desirable, but the result of this policy was amajor collapse of manufacturing activity and indeeda substantial fallback in the UK’s long-termmanufacturing capacity. The UK’s already sharp fallin manufacturing’s share of GDP plumbed newdepths – but subsequently continued further (seeFigure 6).

57

HOW BRITISH EXCHANGE RATE POLICY HAS EVOLVED

The Real Sterling Crisis Layout.qxp_Layout 1 19/08/2016 10:46 Page 57

Page 75: The Real Sterling Crisis - Civitascivitas.org.uk/content/files/The-Real-Sterling-Crisis.pdf · The fall in the value of sterling since the vote for Brexit has had commentators wringing

The interregnum

Eventually the penny dropped – and so did the pound.For a time the government dabbled with the idea thatmonetarism was basically sound; it was merely that ithad adopted the wrong definition of the money supply.A panoply of other monetary aggregates followed, eachin time abandoned in favour of some new concoction, butbringing no greater reliability. After a while, it becameclear that the game was up and quietly the governmentdowngraded, and then abandoned, monetarism.

So it was that, having effectively ditched monetarismat some point in the 1980s, the UK authorities were leftwith the familiar problem of what to use as an anchorfor nominal values. Surprise, surprise, they opted forthe exchange rate. In 1987, Nigel Lawson, the thenChancellor of the Exchequer, began a policy of covertlyshadowing the Deutschemark, although this exchangerate policy was subsequently abandoned after strongopposition from the Prime Minister.

THE REAL STERLING CRISIS

58

Figure 6: UK manufacturing as a share of GDP, %,1970–2014 (nominal GVA, annual)

70 75 80 85 90 95 00 05 10 15

35

30

25

20

15

10

5

0

The Real Sterling Crisis Layout.qxp_Layout 1 19/08/2016 10:46 Page 58

Page 76: The Real Sterling Crisis - Civitascivitas.org.uk/content/files/The-Real-Sterling-Crisis.pdf · The fall in the value of sterling since the vote for Brexit has had commentators wringing

In 1990 this exchange rate policy was taken to itslogical conclusion when Lawson’s successor, JohnMajor, took sterling into the European Exchange RateMechanism (ERM), the forerunner of the euro. In the bynow familiar pattern, the UK authorities had a seriousproblem with inflation, which had risen significantly.Accordingly, it was thought necessary to fix the poundat a rate against the Deutschemark that would beardown on inflation. Unfortunately, of course, as before,it would also bear down on the UK economy, and onexporters in particular.

For two years until the pound’s ejection from the ERMin September 1992, UK macroeconomic policy wasdominated by the overriding requirement to keep thepound in its designated fluctuation band against theDeutschemark. The result was that the authoritieseffectively had no freedom to set an independentmonetary policy. Even though the UK housing marketwas in the midst of a meltdown, interest rates had to be kept high to protect sterling’s position in the ERM.In other words, the authorities were in exactly the same position that their equivalents had foundthemselves in sixty years earlier. And, once again, theywere delivered from this mess by escape from theexchange rate constraint.

The emergence of inflation targets

Nevertheless, it did not feel like an escape when sterlingwas ejected from the ERM on September 16th 1992.Indeed, the UK authorities were in a funk. They were inno mood to embrace any other form of exchange ratetarget. Nevertheless, they needed some sort of nominalanchor. Bearing in mind the experience of the 1980s,

59

HOW BRITISH EXCHANGE RATE POLICY HAS EVOLVED

The Real Sterling Crisis Layout.qxp_Layout 1 19/08/2016 10:46 Page 59

Page 77: The Real Sterling Crisis - Civitascivitas.org.uk/content/files/The-Real-Sterling-Crisis.pdf · The fall in the value of sterling since the vote for Brexit has had commentators wringing

going back to monetary targets was not an attractiveoption. What on earth should they do? They opted forinflation targets.

Inflation targeting was really an adaptation ofmonetarism. Whereas the latter had pre-supposed areliable link between an intermediate variable, i.e. themoney supply (however defined), and the price level,and recommended targets for the growth of thisvariable, given the experience of huge monetaryinstability and the likely unreliability of any monetaryaggregate designated as a target, inflation targetingsimply by-passed this intermediate stage and set targetsfor the ultimate policy objective, namely the rate ofincrease of the price level, i.e. inflation.

In the event, for about 15 years, the inflation targetingregime worked pretty well. Certainly, the inflation rate remained very low, and indeed, close to the target,albeit accompanied by largely anaemic rates ofeconomic growth.

But then came the financial crisis. Afterwards, it cameto be believed that the inflation targeting regime hadcontributed to the previous financial boom andsubsequent crash, since, provided that inflation stayedlow, the regime obliged the monetary authorities tokeep interest rates low, even though signs of financialexcess were building up. Moreover, with economicpolicy focussed exclusively on the inflation rate, thepolicy regime paid no attention to the maintenance of acompetitive exchange rate.

More recently, it has become abundantly clear thatwith inflation significantly subdued, if not conquered,the obsessive pursuit of inflation targets withoutconcern for other desiderata is damaging. Wheninflation is public enemy number one it makes a certain

THE REAL STERLING CRISIS

60

The Real Sterling Crisis Layout.qxp_Layout 1 19/08/2016 10:46 Page 60

Page 78: The Real Sterling Crisis - Civitascivitas.org.uk/content/files/The-Real-Sterling-Crisis.pdf · The fall in the value of sterling since the vote for Brexit has had commentators wringing

amount of sense to put inflation targets centre-stage.Moreover, in some simple views of the world, if theauthorities get the inflation rate reliably under control,everything else falls into place. Yet the financial crisis of2008/9 surely taught us that: (a) Low and stable inflation is not the be-all and

end-all;

(b) Setting interest rates solely in relation to theimmediate prospects for inflation can beprofoundly destabilising for the financial system,indeed even for the medium-term outturn forinflation;

(c) Evidently, the markets do not always ‘know best’.Indeed, for their own sakes, as well as for ours, theyneed to be saved from their own excesses.

Interestingly, although there has been a shift in theclimate of opinion towards the policy authoritiesneeding to exercise some surveillance over the financialsystem’s valuations for equities, bonds, property andother financial instruments, and not just as an input intothe determination of inflation, no such conclusion hasbeen embraced about the exchange rate – except as aninput into the determination of inflation.

The pound’s roller-coaster ride

Since 1992 the pound has been on a rollercoaster ride,as the markets have gyrated from one extreme to theother, with next to no guidance from the policyauthorities, let alone intervention, as to where theexchange rate should be.

Initially, the pound sank to a much more competitivelevel. Moreover, to the surprise of most commentatorsand the authorities – but not the authors of this

61

HOW BRITISH EXCHANGE RATE POLICY HAS EVOLVED

The Real Sterling Crisis Layout.qxp_Layout 1 19/08/2016 10:46 Page 61

Page 79: The Real Sterling Crisis - Civitascivitas.org.uk/content/files/The-Real-Sterling-Crisis.pdf · The fall in the value of sterling since the vote for Brexit has had commentators wringing

pamphlet – the lower exchange rate was not offset by asharp rise in domestic costs and prices. Not surprisingly,the UK economy responded with one of its best periodsof well-balanced and sustainable growth spurts – albeithelped by a revival of the global economy.

This came to an end in 1997. The pound started to risewell before the election of the Labour government in1997 but it carried on afterwards. Then, as Figure 7shows, the pound enjoyed a period of remarkablestability, lasting about a decade. But this was stabilityat the wrong level, as evidenced by the UK’s growingcurrent account deficit.

The pound then plunged again in 2008/9, taking iteven lower than the levels experienced after 1992. Butthis was comparatively short-lived. After a few years, thepound was on the rise again and it had lost more thanhalf of the improvement in competitiveness gained after2008/9 up to the point at which Brexit worries started tobuild. After the Brexit vote, the pound fell sharply.

THE REAL STERLING CRISIS

62

Figure 7: The nominal and real effective exchangerate 1985–2016 (monthly, Aug 1992 = 100)

85 90 95 00 05 10 15

120

115

110

105

100

95

90

85

80

75

70

*Author estimates for Jun. & Jul. 2016

Nominal effective exchange rate

Real effective exchange rate

The Real Sterling Crisis Layout.qxp_Layout 1 19/08/2016 10:46 Page 62

Page 80: The Real Sterling Crisis - Civitascivitas.org.uk/content/files/The-Real-Sterling-Crisis.pdf · The fall in the value of sterling since the vote for Brexit has had commentators wringing

During the last 24 years, despite these major moves inthe pound’s value, and despite continuing belief in thepound’s importance for the economy, chastened by theirexperience in the ERM in 1990-92, the UK authoritiesstood well back from anything that smacked of anexchange rate policy. The prevailing wisdom was that: (a) It was impossible for the authorities to know what

the exchange rate should be;

(b) Nevertheless, this wisdom is available to themarkets. They know best;

(c) If the markets were to be wrong, there is no way inwhich the exchange rate could plausibly be corrected.

So, mirroring the so-called Greenspan doctrine aboutbubbles in financial markets, the conclusion was drawnthat the government should leave the exchange ratesolely to the market. Accordingly, whereas for much ofour history, the exchange rate has provided the lodestarfor economic management, over the last quarter centuryit has been left hanging in the wind. It is just one of thefactors, along with things like the growth of consumercredit and the latest Bank of England agents’ reports onthe state of confidence, and umpteen other factors, to betaken into account when setting interest rates.

Admittedly, circumstances change over time.Nevertheless, one can’t help thinking that if it hassometimes been deemed overwhelmingly important tokeep the exchange rate at some reasonable level inrelation to the UK’s economic fundamentals, leaving itto go hang must be a case of going from one misguidedextreme to another. It is a case of malign neglect.

It would be instructive to see how other countries viewtheir exchange rates. Do they simply leave them to ‘marketforces’? Or is this another example of British eccentricity?

63

HOW BRITISH EXCHANGE RATE POLICY HAS EVOLVED

The Real Sterling Crisis Layout.qxp_Layout 1 19/08/2016 10:46 Page 63

Page 81: The Real Sterling Crisis - Civitascivitas.org.uk/content/files/The-Real-Sterling-Crisis.pdf · The fall in the value of sterling since the vote for Brexit has had commentators wringing

6Other countries’ attitudes toexchange rate management,

past and present

By and large, since the collapse of the Bretton Woodssemi-fixed exchange rate regime in 1971, mostcountries’ economic policies have still put the exchangerate centre-stage. In some cases, they have operatedfairly rigid exchange rate policies; in others they havemerely attributed a great deal of importance to theexchange rate when setting policy. But in very few caseshave they been indifferent to it.

The American exception

The single biggest exception is the United States, whichhas a continental economy, and has traditionally hadcomparatively low exposure to international trade.(Even now, exports account for only about 13% of USGDP, and imports about 15%.) Moreover, as the dollaris the world’s money, when the US has experiencedsubstantial current account disequilibrium, of the sortthat would have destabilised many an ordinarycurrency, the consequences for it have been far fromdramatic. Accordingly, the exchange rate has notfigured large in American policy discussions.

64

The Real Sterling Crisis Layout.qxp_Layout 1 19/08/2016 10:46 Page 64

Page 82: The Real Sterling Crisis - Civitascivitas.org.uk/content/files/The-Real-Sterling-Crisis.pdf · The fall in the value of sterling since the vote for Brexit has had commentators wringing

This is not to say, however, that it does not matter atall. In particular, from time to time the US authoritieshave become especially concerned about the supposedundervaluation of the currencies of countries withwhich the US was in close competition – Germany,Japan, and now China. But the exchange rate has never been as important for the US as it is for manyother countries.

Outside the US, for almost every other country theexchange rate has been at the very centre of economicpolicy. For many small countries, the appropriate policyhas been to peg, or at least closely manage, their owncurrencies against the US dollar. Even for biggercountries, like China and Japan, getting the exchangerate at the right level has been fundamental to themanagement of economic policy.

In Japan, although the country’s obligations to the G7and various concomitant diplomatic niceties prevent itfrom openly saying this, aiming for a weaker yen is akey part of its current government’s strategy forincreasing the inflation rate as a way of bringingeconomic recovery. What’s more, other governments,including those of Japan’s G7 partners, have apparentlyaccepted this strategy.

As for China, throughout the period of itsindustrialisation and rise to global power status it hasmanaged the exchange rate. Most observers would go further: since the Asian financial crisis of 1997, it has deliberately sought to keep the exchange rateundervalued so as to boost the performance of Chineseexports and ensure a large current account surplus. AsFigure 8 shows, it has succeeded in achieving this goal.And Figure 9 attests to the concomitant success in

65

OTHER COUNTRIES’ ATTITUDES

The Real Sterling Crisis Layout.qxp_Layout 1 19/08/2016 10:46 Page 65

Page 83: The Real Sterling Crisis - Civitascivitas.org.uk/content/files/The-Real-Sterling-Crisis.pdf · The fall in the value of sterling since the vote for Brexit has had commentators wringing

amassing huge foreign exchange reserves, built up bythe persistent selling of renminbi for foreign currencies.

The German illusion

Interestingly, much the same has been true of Germany,pretty much throughout the post-war period – althoughyou would not think so from reading the financial press.The predominant view is that since the establishment ofthe Deutschemark in 1948, the German authoritieseither did not care about the exchange rate or welcomedcurrency strength. The evident success of the Germaneconomy, despite the tendency for the Deutschemark torise on the exchanges, has been taken by many asconfirmation that the German authorities a) didn’t careabout the exchange rate and b) didn’t need to.

THE REAL STERLING CRISIS

66

The truth is exactly the opposite. When theDeutschemark was established in 1948, it wassignificantly undervalued. The western allies were keento ensure that the German economy recovered, and

$bn (RHS)

% of GDP (LHS)

Figure 8: China’s current account surplus 1990-2015 (% of GDP)

90 92 94 96 98 00 02 04 06 08 10 12 14

12

10

8

6

4

2

0

-2

600

500

400

300

200

100

0

-100

The Real Sterling Crisis Layout.qxp_Layout 1 19/08/2016 10:46 Page 66

Page 84: The Real Sterling Crisis - Civitascivitas.org.uk/content/files/The-Real-Sterling-Crisis.pdf · The fall in the value of sterling since the vote for Brexit has had commentators wringing

export success was a key part of this. The subsequenttendency of the Deutschemark to rise – often becauseother currencies fell – does not promote a case for theirrelevance of the exchange rate. All along, the exchangerate strengthened behind Germany’s economic success –on exports, productivity growth and cost control. The result is that Germany’s real exchange rate neverreached challenging levels.

Indeed, despite appearances, the Bundesbank wasdesperately anxious that this should be so. Monetarist in appearance, this institution was in reality a closet‘exchange rate’ central bank, of the classic type.Interestingly, this position has continued under the euro.With the exchange rate fixed between Germany and itsEuropean competitors, if Germany outperformed in thecontainment of domestic costs, it would improve itscompetitiveness, even if the euro held steady. If the euroweakened then German competitiveness would improvestill more. This is exactly what has happened, with theresult that the German current account surplus is nowrunning at about 8% of GDP.

67

OTHER COUNTRIES’ ATTITUDES

DebtEquitiesDirect Inv.OtherFX Reserves

Private sector

PBOC

Figure 9: China’s international assets, 2004–2015 ($trn)

04 05 06 07 08 09 10 11 12 13 14 15

7

6

5

4

3

2

1

0

}

The Real Sterling Crisis Layout.qxp_Layout 1 19/08/2016 10:46 Page 67

Page 85: The Real Sterling Crisis - Civitascivitas.org.uk/content/files/The-Real-Sterling-Crisis.pdf · The fall in the value of sterling since the vote for Brexit has had commentators wringing

What has happened to the German surplus istestament to the power of exchange rates. Before theadvent of the euro, there was always a tendency forGermany to run surpluses, but this was kept in checkby the tendency of the Deutschemark to rise and forother currencies to fall. The record speaks for itself. AsFigure 10 shows, between 1970 and 1998, the last yearof the Deutschemark, the average German currentaccount surplus was less than 1% of GDP. From 1999,the first year of the euro, until 2014, the average Germancurrent account surplus was 4%. In 2015 it was over 8%.

THE REAL STERLING CRISIS

68

Moreover, this change in Germany’s current accountposition is mirrored by a change in the behaviour of itsconsumers. Before the advent of the euro, despite themyth that German consumers never spend and run veryhigh savings rates, in fact the growth of Germanconsumer spending was roughly in line with the Anglo-Saxon economies, the US and the UK. By contrast, fromthe advent of the euro in 1999 to 2014, although thingsperked up in 2015, the average rate of increase ofGerman consumer spending has been just over ½%,compared to over 2% in 1970-1998 (see Figure 11).

Figure 10: Germany’s current account surplus (% of GDP)

1970–1998 1999–2014 2015

9.08.07.06.05.04.03.02.01.00.0

The Real Sterling Crisis Layout.qxp_Layout 1 19/08/2016 10:46 Page 68

Page 86: The Real Sterling Crisis - Civitascivitas.org.uk/content/files/The-Real-Sterling-Crisis.pdf · The fall in the value of sterling since the vote for Brexit has had commentators wringing

69

OTHER COUNTRIES’ ATTITUDES

Peripheral Europe

The five peripheral economies of the eurozone – Ireland,Portugal, Spain, Italy and Greece – also provide ampleevidence of the power of exchange rates. After joining themonetary union they carried on inflating faster than coreEurope, led by Germany. The result was a sharpdeterioration in their current account performance, asshown in Figure 12. The subsequent recession diminishedthe deficits – and in some cases turned them into

Figure 11: Germany’s consumer spending (ave. % growth y/y)

1970–1998 1999–2014 2015

2.5

2.0

1.5

1.0

0.5

0

Figure 12: Current Account Balance of Peripheraleurozone countries, 1999–2014 (% of GDP, annual)

99 00 01 02 03 04 05 06 07 08 09 10 11 12 13 14 15

10

5

0

-5

-10

-15

-20

Ireland

Italy

Spain

Surplus

Deficit

Portugal

Greece

The Real Sterling Crisis Layout.qxp_Layout 1 19/08/2016 10:46 Page 69

Page 87: The Real Sterling Crisis - Civitascivitas.org.uk/content/files/The-Real-Sterling-Crisis.pdf · The fall in the value of sterling since the vote for Brexit has had commentators wringing

surpluses – but this merely transferred the problem fromthe external accounts to the state of the domestic economy.

Subsequently, as domestic deflation proceeded, theevidence is that in some cases – notably Ireland andSpain – there has been a distinct improvement incompetitiveness which has produced the classicresponse of an improvement in trading performance.This does not contradict the thrust of this pamphlet. Farfrom it. Our contention is that exchange rates are centralto economic performance and should be central toeconomic policy. What happened in the peripheralmembers of the eurozone is that their real exchange rateappreciated significantly in the early years of euromembership, thanks to rapid growth of domestic wagesand prices, and then subsequently depreciated again,thanks to domestic deflation. This performance istestament to the power of real exchange rates, not the opposite.

The debate about management of the real rate throughnominal exchange rate management versus fluctuationsin the domestic price level is another issue. We wouldargue that a policy of domestic deflation to regaincompetitiveness is both slow and dangerous. Thedomestic deflation in the peripheral countries hasworsened the debt ratios of those countries. It remainsto be seen how their economic predicaments pan out.For our purposes here, though, the critical thing is thedemonstration that real exchange rates really matter.

Exchange rate policy

Under Mario Draghi, President of the ECB, although theeurozone’s central bank was initially slow to loosenmonetary policy, more recently it has implicitly pursued

THE REAL STERLING CRISIS

70

The Real Sterling Crisis Layout.qxp_Layout 1 19/08/2016 10:46 Page 70

Page 88: The Real Sterling Crisis - Civitascivitas.org.uk/content/files/The-Real-Sterling-Crisis.pdf · The fall in the value of sterling since the vote for Brexit has had commentators wringing

a policy of depreciation. The policy was not so called,of course, but this was its purpose. For the evidenceshould by now be fairly clear that in a broken financialsystem, quantitative easing (QE) does not work verywell through the conventional domestic channels. Whatit may do, however, provided that other countries arenot operating the policy to the same degree, is to putdownward pressure on the exchange rate. This iscertainly what appears to have happened in the case ofthe euro, which, since January 2008, has weakenedagainst the dollar by 32%.

This weaker exchange rate will have been welcomedby the ECB for two reasons:(i) It will have delivered a temporary boost to the

inflation rate and thereby helped to stave off thethreat of deflation and, for, any given level ofnominal interest rates, it will have reduced the realrate of interest;

(ii) It will have boosted eurozone net exports andthereby increased aggregate demand, with all theusual beneficial effects, including on employment.

As it happens, the statistics suggest that this policy –aided and abetted by domestic deflation in theperipheral countries – has worked. The eurozone’scurrent account position has moved from a deficit of$223 bn in 2008 to a surplus of $365bn in 2015. What hashappened is that with regard to the roles of externalsurpluses and domestic demand the whole eurozonehas been turning Germanic. Interestingly, despite theG7’s apparent forbidding of an explicit exchange ratepolicy, three of its European members – Germany,France and Italy – have been allowed to get away withan implicit policy amounting to much the same thing.

71

OTHER COUNTRIES’ ATTITUDES

The Real Sterling Crisis Layout.qxp_Layout 1 19/08/2016 10:46 Page 71

Page 89: The Real Sterling Crisis - Civitascivitas.org.uk/content/files/The-Real-Sterling-Crisis.pdf · The fall in the value of sterling since the vote for Brexit has had commentators wringing

Meanwhile, the G7’s second largest member, Japan, hasbeen trying to do much the same (although, recently,without much success.) Of the G7’s members only theUS, UK and Canada have not been aiming to boost theireconomies through a lower exchange rate.

In the rest of the world, exchange rate targeting iscommon. Hong Kong’s currency, of course, is pegged tothe US dollar, while Singapore’s is managed accordingto a basket of currencies. In other Asian economies, amanaged float regime is operated. In the Middle East,the oil exporters manage their currencies in relation tothe dollar. In Africa, South Africa operates a free float,Nigeria a managed float and Morocco a currency peg. InLatin America, Brazil operates a free float, Argentina amanaged float and Bolivia a currency peg. In Australia,the RBA operates a floating exchange rate policy.

Reasons for doubting the importance of real exchange rates

Over the last couple of decades – i.e. during a period ofBritish (malign) neglect of the exchange rate – it hasbecome common for economists and others to believethat exchange rates (nominal and real) have become lessimportant as a determinant of trade flows and thereforethat their comparative unimportance as a determinantof UK policy does not matter much.

There are two good reasons for believing thatexchange rates may now be less important than theywere; (a) the increasing importance of trade in services,which are less price sensitive; (b) the increasedimportance of global supply chains in manufacturing,which may render even trade in manufactures lesssensitive to exchange rate changes.

THE REAL STERLING CRISIS

72

The Real Sterling Crisis Layout.qxp_Layout 1 19/08/2016 10:46 Page 72

Page 90: The Real Sterling Crisis - Civitascivitas.org.uk/content/files/The-Real-Sterling-Crisis.pdf · The fall in the value of sterling since the vote for Brexit has had commentators wringing

But the evidence is that these two concerns areseriously overdone. The sensitivity of trade performanceto exchange rate changes was recently examined in anIMF study (‘Exchange rates and Trade Flows:Disconnected?’ Global Economic Outlook, May 2015).Its main conclusions were:(i) A 10% real effective depreciation in a country’s

currency is associated with a rise of, on average,1.5% of GDP;

(ii) The boost is found to be the largest in countrieswith a high initial degree of slack, and wheredomestic financial systems are operating normally;

(iii) There is some evidence that the rise of globalsupply chains has weakened the effect of exchangerate changes. However, the bulk of internationaltrade still consists of conventional trade and thereis little evidence of a general trend towardsdisconnect between exchange rates and totalexports and imports.

Recent evidence

Nor does the notion that trade flows are no longer verysensitive to exchange rates gel very well with the recentexperience of the world’s two largest economies, theUSA and the eurozone. Since January 2007 thedollar/euro exchange rate has increased by 28%. Thedollar’s trade-weighted index has risen by 30% and theeuro’s has fallen by 14%. The results are plain to see inthe US trade balance, and worry about the effect of thestrong US dollar on US trade was a leading factor behindthe Fed’s reluctance to raise interest rates during 2015.

Meanwhile, (admittedly aided by depressed domesticdemand in countries using the single currency) the

73

OTHER COUNTRIES’ ATTITUDES

The Real Sterling Crisis Layout.qxp_Layout 1 19/08/2016 10:46 Page 73

Page 91: The Real Sterling Crisis - Civitascivitas.org.uk/content/files/The-Real-Sterling-Crisis.pdf · The fall in the value of sterling since the vote for Brexit has had commentators wringing

eurozone has moved from deficit to surplus as even theweaker, peripheral economies of the monetary unionhave been forced to become Teutonic in their spendingand saving habits, and in their search for GDP growththrough competitive internal devaluation.

THE REAL STERLING CRISIS

74

The Real Sterling Crisis Layout.qxp_Layout 1 19/08/2016 10:46 Page 74

Page 92: The Real Sterling Crisis - Civitascivitas.org.uk/content/files/The-Real-Sterling-Crisis.pdf · The fall in the value of sterling since the vote for Brexit has had commentators wringing

7Is it possible to vary the realexchange rate by changing

the nominal rate?

In order to have any effect on a country’s tradingperformance it is not enough for the exchange rate – thenominal rate – to be lower. The real rate, that is thenominal rate adjusted for changes in the price level,must be lower also. In other words, the rise in thegeneral level of prices that sometimes follows adepreciation of the currency must not advance so far asto equal the amount by which the exchange rate hasfallen. If that happens then the real exchange rate willnot have fallen at all and accordingly no lasting benefitto economic performance can be expected – exceptanything that derives from a burst of higher inflation,which may end up being more than a burst, as the higherinflation comes to be expected and becomes ingrained.(More likely, of course, this burst of higher inflation willbring welfare losses, for all the usual reasons.)

Indeed, given the time lags involved there may noteven be any fleeting benefit. After a currencydepreciation, it takes time for households and firms toadapt their behaviour to the new set of relative prices.Moreover, depreciation often leads to a deterioration inthe terms of trade (the ratio of export prices to importprices) so that the country’s real income falls.

75

The Real Sterling Crisis Layout.qxp_Layout 1 19/08/2016 10:46 Page 75

Page 93: The Real Sterling Crisis - Civitascivitas.org.uk/content/files/The-Real-Sterling-Crisis.pdf · The fall in the value of sterling since the vote for Brexit has had commentators wringing

Accordingly, you can readily imagine circumstanceswhen, following a depreciation, inflation proceeds so rapidly that the initial fall in the real exchange rate has been wiped out before it has had time to bringany benefits.

Equally, there are cases when a depreciation bringshardly any increase in the general price level – or evena decrease – as higher output brings lower average costsand increased investment. Sometimes any initialupward impulse to the price level may also be offset byreductions in indirect taxes (such as VAT).

Sorting out how inflation in the UK is likely todevelop following a drop in the UK nominal exchangerate – such as the one that occurred after the UK’s Brexitvote – is key to understanding whether the lowercurrency will do anything to improve the trade balanceand boost GDP. This requires a brief trot through some theoretical considerations and a review of theempirical evidence.

Exchange rates in theory

There are many factors that should influence a country’sequilibrium real exchange rate, and these factors arechanging over time. Accordingly, the equilibrium rate isliable to change over time. In general, the more successfula country is in producing things (and non-things) that therest of the world wants to buy then, other things equal,the higher will be its equilibrium real exchange rate.Countries that move from a state of under-developmentexperience a rise in their real exchange rates. Countriesthat experience a loss of overseas markets, or a fall in theprice of their leading exports, undergo a fall in theirequilibrium exchange rates.

THE REAL STERLING CRISIS

76

The Real Sterling Crisis Layout.qxp_Layout 1 19/08/2016 10:46 Page 76

Page 94: The Real Sterling Crisis - Civitascivitas.org.uk/content/files/The-Real-Sterling-Crisis.pdf · The fall in the value of sterling since the vote for Brexit has had commentators wringing

But the word ‘equilibrium’ should be treated withcare. Economists usually take the equilibrium exchangerate to mean the exchange rate that will give roughbalance in a country’s overseas trade, while the domesticeconomy is at ‘full employment’. But it may beappropriate for countries sometimes to run sustainedsurpluses, and for other countries, or the same countriesat other times, to run sustained deficits.

Moreover, the full employment condition is not alwaysobvious to identify. After all, there is a mini-industry atwork trying to estimate the size of the output gap, or, inother words, the amount of under-employment ofresources, including labour but also comprising otherfactors of production. If there is a higher output gap thanpreviously estimated then aggregate demand needs to bestronger to eliminate this gap and achieve fullemployment of resources, and thereby realise maximumpossible output. Other things being equal this wouldraise the level of imports and probably require a lowerexchange rate to achieve balanced trade.

A country may operate with a real exchange rate wellabove its equilibrium rate for a prolonged period. Thismay occur because the economy operates for anextended time below full employment. Or it may operatebelow its equilibrium rate because of the constellation ofgovernment policies. A policy to prevent capital inflowsand/or stimulate outflows would deliver this result.Equally, if the government ran a very restrictive fiscalpolicy (perhaps in order to reduce the ratio ofgovernment debt to GDP) this would, other things beingequal, decrease the level of GDP and justify a lower realexchange rate in order to achieve full employment.

It is worth asking why, if the equilibrium realexchange rate is higher or lower than the existing rate,

77

IS IT POSSIBLE TO VARY THE REAL EXCHANGE RATE?

The Real Sterling Crisis Layout.qxp_Layout 1 19/08/2016 10:46 Page 77

Page 95: The Real Sterling Crisis - Civitascivitas.org.uk/content/files/The-Real-Sterling-Crisis.pdf · The fall in the value of sterling since the vote for Brexit has had commentators wringing

the market does not deliver that result itself, either byforcing changes in the nominal rate, or by bringingabout changes in the price level that, for any given levelof the nominal exchange rate, change the real rate.

The answer is that there is such a mechanism in theory– but it doesn’t work well in practice. If the economy isoperating below full capacity with balanced trade, thereis no force operating to send the nominal exchange ratelower. On all the usual assumptions, in the usual neo-classical model, however, if the economy is operatingbelow full capacity then the price and wage level shouldfall, thereby reducing the real exchange rate.

But we know the practical limitations to this. Exceptin extreme circumstances, price and wage levels aresticky downwards. Accordingly, it may be difficult, andat least take a very long time, for the required reductionin the real exchange rate to be delivered by domesticdeflation.

Meanwhile, if effective controls are in place to limitcapital outflows, or encourage inflows, then the realexchange rate does not need to fall. In other words, theterm ‘equilibrium’ has to be interpreted accordingly tothe policies in place at the time.

Can the exchange rate ever be too low?

If a country deliberately engineered a very low realexchange rate this would result in disturbances to itsdomestic economy. At first, inflationary pressure wouldbe stronger and other policy settings would have to be tighter in order to prevent a low exchange rate (and a current account surplus) from causingcontinuing inflation.

Equally, there is an idea that a certain amount ofpressure exerted on producers from a high and rising

THE REAL STERLING CRISIS

78

The Real Sterling Crisis Layout.qxp_Layout 1 19/08/2016 10:46 Page 78

Page 96: The Real Sterling Crisis - Civitascivitas.org.uk/content/files/The-Real-Sterling-Crisis.pdf · The fall in the value of sterling since the vote for Brexit has had commentators wringing

exchange rate is a good thing as it forces them to makeproductivity gains. To the extent that this is true, thenhaving a much lower exchange rate will disincentivisefirms from making such gains. (Strictly speaking, theywould still have the incentive but they may not feel thateffort in this direction is imperative.)

In practice, we suspect that there is a major differencebetween a ‘high’ and a ‘rising’ exchange rate. Anexchange rate can be so high that it wipes out virtuallyall domestic production in certain sectors. At this pointno stimulus to secure efficiency gains is felt. By contrast,if the exchange rate begins at a level competitiveenough to enable a significant domestic presence in arange of activities, then a rising rate may well bringbenefits of the sort described above. But the pace atwhich the exchange rate rises is vital. If the currencyrises by 20-30% in a year – which has happened with thepound on more than one occasion – it is surelyimpossible for industries to make efficiency gains thatoffset this.

Nominal and real rates

Accordingly, if a fall in the real exchange rate iswarranted there are often good reasons why this maynot occur naturally. Equally, there are conditions whena fall in the nominal rate will succeed, and others whenit will not succeed, in reducing the real rate. We need toexamine these various conditions.

We can analyse when a depreciation of the nominalrate can be expected to achieve a sustained fall in thereal rate and when it cannot. Essentially, the best chanceto get and keep the real exchange rate low after adepreciation in the nominal rate occurs when there isslack in the domestic economy. In these conditions, it is

79

IS IT POSSIBLE TO VARY THE REAL EXCHANGE RATE?

The Real Sterling Crisis Layout.qxp_Layout 1 19/08/2016 10:46 Page 79

Page 97: The Real Sterling Crisis - Civitascivitas.org.uk/content/files/The-Real-Sterling-Crisis.pdf · The fall in the value of sterling since the vote for Brexit has had commentators wringing

possible to increase net exports and the overall level ofGDP by utilising unemployed and under-employedresources of labour and capital.

By contrast, when the economy is fully employed, bydefinition it is impossible to increase GDP overall.Accordingly, if net exports are to increase, othercomponents of aggregate demand have to be squeezed.So it is that devaluations have tended to work best inthe context of recession.

When recessionary conditions do not exist, it is stillpossible for a devaluation to improve the trade balance,but only if domestic demand falls. Usually this requiresthe government deliberately to set out to squeezedomestic demand by raising taxes and/or cutting its ownexpenditure to ‘make room’ for an improvement inoverseas trade. For understandable, largely political,reasons, governments are often loathe to squeezedemand hard enough, with the result that thedevaluation disappoints, or perhaps even fails altogether.

Exchange rates in practice

So much for the theory. We also have considerablepractical evidence on this matter. In the UK, thedevaluation of 1967 had a major impact on markets’ andpolicymakers’ views and prejudices about exchangerate changes. The move was widely believed to havefailed. It was certainly followed by higher inflation,eventually culminating in the inflationary blow-off of the mid-1970s. The result was that the gain tocompetitiveness was short-lived, as Figures 13 and 14 show.

So it was that when the UK again found itself in a fixedexchange rate system during its brief sojourn in the ERM

THE REAL STERLING CRISIS

80

The Real Sterling Crisis Layout.qxp_Layout 1 19/08/2016 10:46 Page 80

Page 98: The Real Sterling Crisis - Civitascivitas.org.uk/content/files/The-Real-Sterling-Crisis.pdf · The fall in the value of sterling since the vote for Brexit has had commentators wringing

from 1990-92, the Treasury view at the time was that wehad to stay in the system because, if we chose to leave,the result would be higher inflation, which wouldnecessitate higher interest rates, without creating anyboost to net trade or GDP. In the event, as forecast byboth of the present co-authors, when we did leave theERM in September 1992, the result was exactly the

81

IS IT POSSIBLE TO VARY THE REAL EXCHANGE RATE?

Figure 13: The nominal effective exchange rate and the retail price index, 1966-1972

Figure 14: The real effective exchange rate, 1964-1982

1966 1967 1968 1969 1970 1971 1972

75

80

85

90

95

100

105

110

Devaluation 19th November 1967

Nominal effective exchange rate (inverted, LHS)RPI Index

£ lower

150

140

130

120

110

100

90

80

64 66 68 70 72 74 76 78 80

180

170

160

150

140

130

120

110

100

90

Devaluation 19th November 1967

£ lower

The Real Sterling Crisis Layout.qxp_Layout 1 19/08/2016 10:46 Page 81

Page 99: The Real Sterling Crisis - Civitascivitas.org.uk/content/files/The-Real-Sterling-Crisis.pdf · The fall in the value of sterling since the vote for Brexit has had commentators wringing

opposite. Inflation fell, interest rates were cut, bondyields fell, and the economy embarked upon a sustained,and well-balanced recovery. And the real exchange rate stayed down – until the nominal rate rose again in 1996-7, as Figure 15 shows. (More about this later.)

THE REAL STERLING CRISIS

82

When thinking about the consequences of a lowerexchange rate, the previous episode that the Treasury –and the markets – should have borne in mind in 1992was not 1967 but 1931, when the UK left the goldstandard. After 1931, the real exchange rate wassignificantly reduced and stayed down for severalyears. Admittedly, by 1938 the real rate was more or lessback to where it had been in 1930, or even a bit higher.But this was not due mainly to higher domesticinflation. Rather, it was largely due to an appreciationof the nominal rate brought about by other countriesdevaluing (see Figure 16). Immediately after the breakwith Gold in 1931, the price level continued to fall. From1934 onwards it was rising again but only modestly.

Figure 15: The nominal and real effective exchangerate, 1991–1999 (1991=100)

91 92 93 94 95 96 97 98 99

115

110

105

100

95

90

85

80

75

Exit from ERM 16th September 1992

Real

Nominal

The Real Sterling Crisis Layout.qxp_Layout 1 19/08/2016 10:46 Page 82

Page 100: The Real Sterling Crisis - Civitascivitas.org.uk/content/files/The-Real-Sterling-Crisis.pdf · The fall in the value of sterling since the vote for Brexit has had commentators wringing

A more recent failure?

It is widely believed that the sharp fall of sterling in2008/9 was another case of devaluation failing todeliver the goods. During this period, the exchange ratefell by more than 25% (see Figure 17). Although theinflation rate did subsequently pick up, there was noprice explosion so the real exchange rate stayed down.Again, although the real rate subsequently rose againquite sharply, this was mainly due to a rise in thenominal rate rather than to much higher domesticinflation (see Figures 17 and 18). Yet despite the earlysubstantial fall in the real exchange rate, the currentaccount barely budged. Indeed, in 2014 it was runningat 5% of GDP, and in some periods reached 6%, apeacetime record.

So this was an episode that appeared to demonstrate,not that it was impossible to lower the real exchangerate by reducing the nominal rate, but rather thatreductions in the real exchange rate don’t seem to have

83

IS IT POSSIBLE TO VARY THE REAL EXCHANGE RATE?

Figure 16: Nominal and real effective exchange rate,1920-1938 (quarterly, Q3 1931 = 100)

1924 1926 1928 1930 1932 1934 1936 1938

120

110

100

90

80

70

60

Departure from Gold Standard19th September 1931

Nominal effectiveexchange rate

Real effective exchange rate

£ weaker

The Real Sterling Crisis Layout.qxp_Layout 1 19/08/2016 10:46 Page 83

Page 101: The Real Sterling Crisis - Civitascivitas.org.uk/content/files/The-Real-Sterling-Crisis.pdf · The fall in the value of sterling since the vote for Brexit has had commentators wringing

much effect. On this occasion, it can hardly be said that this was because of an absence of spare capacity.Indeed, the financial crisis of 2008/9 caused GDP to plummet and unemployment to rise. Accordingly,many commentators have suggested that this period isevidence of the waning power of exchange rates toinfluence the trade balance, and hence the real economy.

THE REAL STERLING CRISIS

84

Figure 17: The nominal effective exchange rate and theconsumer price index, 2006-2016 (monthly, Jan 2007=100)

2006 2007 2008 2009 2010 2011 2012 2013 2014 2015 2016

70

75

80

85

90

95

100

105

110

145140135130125120115110105100959085

Nominal effective exchange rate (inverted, LHS)

CPI Index (RHS)

£ lower

Figure 18: Nominal and effective exchange rates ofthe pound, 2007-2016 (monthly, Jan 2007=100)

2007 2008 2009 2010 2011 2012 2013 2014 2015 2016

105

100

95

90

85

80

75

70

Real

Nominal

The Real Sterling Crisis Layout.qxp_Layout 1 19/08/2016 10:46 Page 84

Page 102: The Real Sterling Crisis - Civitascivitas.org.uk/content/files/The-Real-Sterling-Crisis.pdf · The fall in the value of sterling since the vote for Brexit has had commentators wringing

In fact, this is not quite the conclusion that emergesfrom a careful interpretation of this episode. For a start,if you focus on the UK’s trade balance rather than theoverall current account, as shown in Figure 19, thenthere was some sign of improvement after thecurrency’s sharp fall.

85

IS IT POSSIBLE TO VARY THE REAL EXCHANGE RATE?

Second, sterling fell sharply against the backdrop of aglobal recession, with our main markets on thecontinent particularly hard hit. These were not theconditions in which to expect a major improvement inthe trade balance. If it did not deteriorate that may wellhave been evidence enough of a significant beneficialeffect from the lower exchange rate.

Third, after the financial crisis, the banking systemwas in shut-down mode, with bank credit difficult tocome by. In these circumstances businesses findexpansion difficult, including expanding exports.Accordingly, exporting firms may well have reacted tothe lower exchange rate by leaving foreign currency

Figure 19: Breakdown of current account balance,2008-2015 (quarterly, % of GDP)

08 09 10 11 12 13 14 15 16

2

0

-2

-4

-6

-8

Surplus

Deficit

Trade in goods and services

Current account

The Real Sterling Crisis Layout.qxp_Layout 1 19/08/2016 10:46 Page 85

Page 103: The Real Sterling Crisis - Civitascivitas.org.uk/content/files/The-Real-Sterling-Crisis.pdf · The fall in the value of sterling since the vote for Brexit has had commentators wringing

prices largely unchanged, thereby opting for higherprofit margins over increased volumes. (This effect hasbeen confirmed in a recent IMF study on exchange ratedepreciation: ‘Exchange Rates and Trade Flows:Disconnected?’ in IMF, World Economic Outlook,Chapter 3, October 2015.)

Fourth, before very long the real exchange rate beganto rise again, not because inflation took off (although fora time it was higher in the UK that in most advancedcountries) but because the nominal rate started to climb.Not only did this retard the improvement in net trade butthe perception that the reduction in the exchange ratemight be temporary (and that it might even be resistedby the authorities) will have inhibited investment.

Brexit wobbles

In early 2016 the pound fell on fears that the UK mightvote to leave the EU. After the vote it again fell sharply.It remains to be seen whether it falls further. But beforethis episode the pound was unhelpfully strong. On 18June 2016, just a few days before the UK’s EUreferendum, held on 23 June, the IMF said that thepound was over-valued by 12-18%.

The true extent of the pounds over-valuation has oftenbeen obscured by movements of the pound against thedollar. A strong dollar means that sterling’s exchangerate against that currency has recently been in territorythat most of British industry finds reasonable. Bycontrast, in 2015/16 the pound’s rate against the eurohad climbed inexorably to the point that it was tradingonly some 10% below the peak reached before the2007/8 financial crisis (see Figure 20). The euro is muchmore important for Britain’s trade. The best way ofmeasuring the pound’s value is by reference to its trade-

THE REAL STERLING CRISIS

86

The Real Sterling Crisis Layout.qxp_Layout 1 19/08/2016 10:46 Page 86

Page 104: The Real Sterling Crisis - Civitascivitas.org.uk/content/files/The-Real-Sterling-Crisis.pdf · The fall in the value of sterling since the vote for Brexit has had commentators wringing

weighted index, often referred to as the ‘effectiveexchange rate’. On this measure, by late 2015 the poundhad given up more than 80% of the fall in its realexchange rate achieved in 2008/9.

87

IS IT POSSIBLE TO VARY THE REAL EXCHANGE RATE?

Examples outside the UK

The relevance of conditions in the domestic economywhen the currency is devalued is borne out by evidencefrom outside the UK. Countries that have a high initialdegree of slack tend to be able to sustain a largerdepreciation in the real exchange rate. This is the lessonof the experience of several countries shown in Figure21. The experience of Argentina with the break of thepeso’s link with the dollar in 2001 is a clear example.

Argentina

Argentina abandoned its uncompetitive currency peg to the US dollar in early 2002, and the pesosubsequently dropped by almost 70%. This caused

Figure 20: The pound against the US dollar and the euro (2007–2015)

2007 2008 2009 2010 2011 2012 2013 2014 2015 2016

2.2

2.0

1.8

1.6

1.4

1.2

1.0

GBP to USD

GBP to EUR

The Real Sterling Crisis Layout.qxp_Layout 1 19/08/2016 10:47 Page 87

Page 105: The Real Sterling Crisis - Civitascivitas.org.uk/content/files/The-Real-Sterling-Crisis.pdf · The fall in the value of sterling since the vote for Brexit has had commentators wringing

substantial short-term pain for many creditors,households and firms, and led to widespreadbankruptcies and bank failures. But by improvingcompetitiveness at a stroke, it set the scene for adramatic recovery. GDP growth averaged 9% perannum between 2003 and 2007, while employment rose by over 20% over this period (see Figure 22).

THE REAL STERLING CRISIS

88

Figure 21: Real exchange rates and unemployment

20181614121086420

Change in Real Effective Exchange Rate After Three Years (%)

Un

em

plo

ym

en

t R

ate

in Y

ea

r o

f D

eva

lua

tio

n (

%)

Higher unemployment Argentina (2002)

GDP (Q1 2000=100, LHS)

Employment (urban, millions, RHS)

Figure 22: Argentina real GDP and employment

2000 2001 2002 2003 2004 2005 2006

0 -10 -20 -30 -40

125

120

115

110

105

100

95

90

85

80

16

15

14

13

12

11

Larger devaluation

Devaluationand default

Russia (1998)

Mexico (1994)Indonesia (2000)

Malaysia (1997)South Korea (1997)

Thailand (1996)Iceland (2008)

The Real Sterling Crisis Layout.qxp_Layout 1 19/08/2016 10:47 Page 88

Page 106: The Real Sterling Crisis - Civitascivitas.org.uk/content/files/The-Real-Sterling-Crisis.pdf · The fall in the value of sterling since the vote for Brexit has had commentators wringing

Crucially, Argentina was able to benefit from a morecompetitive currency because the weakness of theeconomy in the years prior to the devaluation hadcaused large amounts of spare capacity to open up.These underutilised resources could then be employedto raise output quickly as net exports picked up andlower real interest rates laid the foundations for a surgein investment.

Iceland

Iceland’s healthy economic recovery after its financialcollapse in 2008 also illustrates the potential attractionsof currency depreciation. Between July 2007 and August2009, Iceland’s real effective exchange rate (adjusted forCPI) fell by over 40%. Admittedly, this caused inflationto surge to over 18% in late 2008. But inflation has sincebeen tamed and GDP has risen in every year since 2010.A key driver of this recovery has been net trade, whichbetween Q1 2008 and Q3 2015 made a very healthycontribution to Icelandic GDP to the tune of 16.5percentage points (see Figures 23 and 24).

89

IS IT POSSIBLE TO VARY THE REAL EXCHANGE RATE?

Exports

Imports

Figure 23: Icelandic export and import volumes (Q4 = 2007)

03 04 05 06 07 08 09 10 11 12 13 14

120

110

100

90

80

70

60

50

Krona starts to fall

The Real Sterling Crisis Layout.qxp_Layout 1 19/08/2016 10:47 Page 89

Page 107: The Real Sterling Crisis - Civitascivitas.org.uk/content/files/The-Real-Sterling-Crisis.pdf · The fall in the value of sterling since the vote for Brexit has had commentators wringing

Conclusion

There are circumstances when an economy needs alower exchange rate. In these circumstances adepreciation of the nominal rate need not be fully offsetby an upsurge of the price level. What’s more, there area number of instances when such a result, that is to saya depreciation of the real exchange rate, has beenachieved, in both the UK and other countries.

There is ample evidence that before pre-Brexit worriesand the drop of the pound after the Brexit vote broughtthe exchange rate to substantially lower levels, sterlingwas significantly over-valued. In these circumstances,there is no reason why the real exchange rate cannot bekept down – with enduring benefit to the economy.

The key worry in today’s UK situation is surely notthat an upsurge of inflation will cause the real exchangerate to return to where it began but rather that, as sooften before, the nominal exchange rate will be allowedto climb yet again. That is where exchange rate policycomes in.

THE REAL STERLING CRISIS

90

Figure 24: Icelandic trade balance (% of GDP)

surplus

deficit

03 04 05 06 07 08 09 10 11 12 13 14

5

0

-5

-10

-15

-20

Krona starts to fall

The Real Sterling Crisis Layout.qxp_Layout 1 19/08/2016 10:47 Page 90

Page 108: The Real Sterling Crisis - Civitascivitas.org.uk/content/files/The-Real-Sterling-Crisis.pdf · The fall in the value of sterling since the vote for Brexit has had commentators wringing

Part Three

Policy Proposals

The Real Sterling Crisis Layout.qxp_Layout 1 19/08/2016 10:47 Page 91

Page 109: The Real Sterling Crisis - Civitascivitas.org.uk/content/files/The-Real-Sterling-Crisis.pdf · The fall in the value of sterling since the vote for Brexit has had commentators wringing

8 Exchange rates and

policy objectives

The policy issues raised in this pamphlet can bedecomposed into two parts:(i) If needed, how can the UK authorities get the

exchange rate down?

(ii) How can policy be structured so as to keep it down?In the right circumstances, a one-off fall of the poundcould be achieved without the policy authorities doinganything at all. In early 2016, for instance, the pound fellsharply on fears that the UK would vote to leave the EU.After the Brexit vote, it fell further. In the wake of thefinancial crisis of 2008/9 the pound fell precipitately –by some 25% on average. On neither occasion did thisarise from anything that the policy authorities said ordid, or threatened or even intimated. The moveoccurred solely because the market changed its view ofthe fundamentals such that what now seemed to be theappropriate value for sterling was a good deal lowerthan it had been.

If the exchange rate is too high, it is better that anadjustment should occur ‘naturally’, because this avoidsthe distortions that might arise from deliberate policyactions and because this overcomes the difficulties,discussed below, posed by having to adhere to the G7’s

92

The Real Sterling Crisis Layout.qxp_Layout 1 19/08/2016 10:47 Page 92

Page 110: The Real Sterling Crisis - Civitascivitas.org.uk/content/files/The-Real-Sterling-Crisis.pdf · The fall in the value of sterling since the vote for Brexit has had commentators wringing

undertaking not to pursue exchange rate policies.Nevertheless, if the policy authorities wished to keep the pound at its new level they might have toresort to definite policy measures of the sort describedin the next chapter.

If, in an ideal world, the pound could fall of its ownaccord, also in an ideal world it could keep at its lowlevel without further manipulation of policy – whetherits new level had been arrived at naturally, throughmarket forces, or whether it had been nudged therethrough deliberate policy action.

This might seem fanciful but in fact it is moreplausible than you might imagine. Once established atthe ‘right’ level, markets might well perceive that thepound was appropriately valued and that departuresfrom that range were unjustified. Across most of theindustrialised world, central banks are aiming forroughly the same rate of inflation, namely 2% and intoday’s world it is unlikely that the UK’s inflation ratewill diverge markedly from the average of othercountries. Once the exchange rate is at a competitivelevel, there is no reason why it should need to fallcontinually or repeatedly.

Nevertheless, often policy action will be required, eitherto get the pound lower to start with, to keep it lower, orboth. Such policy action is discussed in the next chapter.But before that, there are some key issues concerning thetheory of economic policy that need to be discussed.

Exchange rate management and inflation targets

Suppose that the government wanted to manage theexchange rate. What would that imply for the rate of

93

EXCHANGE RATES AND POLICY OBJECTIVES

The Real Sterling Crisis Layout.qxp_Layout 1 19/08/2016 10:47 Page 93

Page 111: The Real Sterling Crisis - Civitascivitas.org.uk/content/files/The-Real-Sterling-Crisis.pdf · The fall in the value of sterling since the vote for Brexit has had commentators wringing

inflation and its control? If the authorities set theirsights on a lower exchange rate this would, for all theusual reasons, tend to raise the domestic price level –although, for the reasons spelled out elsewhere in thispamphlet, this tendency may not be acute and, in somecases, especially if assisted by a cut in indirect taxation,the price level could even fall. But where the price levelis driven up there is no need for this to cause acontinuing boost to the inflation rate. In the rightcircumstances, the inflation rate will flick up, reflectingthe temporary boost to the price level, and then subsideback to where it was in the first place.

But what are the right circumstances? Either theeconomy begins with a significant margin of under-used resources (under-employment) or if it doesn’t thenother components of aggregate demand fall back(perhaps induced by policy) to make room for theincrease in demand from abroad brought about by thelower exchange rate.

But after this one-off result, how would an exchangerate target interact with anti-inflation policy? In manycircumstances this would not be a problem. If theinflation rate in other countries were broadly the sameas the inflation objective in this country – and at themoment just about all countries seem to be aiming atsomething close to 2% - then exchange rate fixity coulddeliver a reasonable basis for meeting our own inflationobjective. (This was evidently believed by the UKTreasury during the period in the late 1980s when theauthorities covertly operated a policy of shadowing theDeutschemark.) One can think of a number ofcircumstances, however, in which a clash could occur:-(i) A sharp rise in import prices, perhaps driven by oil

and commodity prices causes the domestic price

THE REAL STERLING CRISIS

94

The Real Sterling Crisis Layout.qxp_Layout 1 19/08/2016 10:47 Page 94

Page 112: The Real Sterling Crisis - Civitascivitas.org.uk/content/files/The-Real-Sterling-Crisis.pdf · The fall in the value of sterling since the vote for Brexit has had commentators wringing

level to rise. If domestic interest rates were being used to maintain the exchange rate, theycould not be raised in these circumstances tosuppress inflation.

(ii) For whatever reason, UK domestic demand surges,requiring some form of restraint to prevent inflationfrom rising.

(iii) For whatever reason, there is a surge in UK exportsand given the state of domestic demand, thisthreatens higher inflation.

In practice, case (i) is less of a problem than it mayappear. Under the present regime of inflation targetingthe Bank of England (along with other central banks)has in the recent past ‘looked through’ such temporaryspikes in the inflation rate and did not move interestrates in response. There need be no difference under apolicy regime that gave weight to the exchange rate.

Both cases (ii) and (iii), however, are very different inan exchange rate targeting world. Under an inflationtarget, in both cases interest rates would be raised tosqueeze demand. This is precisely what cannot easily bedone in an exchange rate management world, withoutrecourse to other policy instruments, about which morein a moment. Mind you, if higher inflation is allowed toresult this need not be permanent in that the higherinflation would itself, with the given nominal exchangerate target adhered to, cause a rise in the real exchangerate, which would cause a deterioration in the net tradebalance which would reduce aggregate demand andthereby stop the forces making for accelerating inflation.

Even so, this is far from being a panacea. It would be more appropriate in case (iii) in that, ex hypothesi,

95

EXCHANGE RATES AND POLICY OBJECTIVES

The Real Sterling Crisis Layout.qxp_Layout 1 19/08/2016 10:47 Page 95

Page 113: The Real Sterling Crisis - Civitascivitas.org.uk/content/files/The-Real-Sterling-Crisis.pdf · The fall in the value of sterling since the vote for Brexit has had commentators wringing

what sets off the inflationary danger is an incipientimprovement in the trade balance. Accordingly, it is notinappropriate that this is reversed by a rise in the realexchange rate that brings the trade balance back towhere it was in the first place.

In case (ii), however, the result would be relying on adeterioration in the external account to offset a surge indomestic demand, which is hardly in accordance withthe objective of having an exchange rate target in thefirst place, namely to ensure a healthy trade balance.Moreover, once a higher rate of inflation has beenestablished, it might well become ingrained (expected),with all the usual welfare costs, even after the realexchange rate had risen sufficiently to choke off enoughaggregate demand to stabilise the exchange rate.

Furthermore, with a higher rate of inflation in place,the nominal exchange rate would have to be regularlyshifted down in order to maintain the real exchange rateat the target level.

More instruments to meet more targets

It is widely accepted that the authorities need to haveat least as many policy instruments as there areobjectives. It is frequently argued that this means that, given that we have an inflation target, centralbanks cannot simultaneously pursue an exchange rate policy. Implicitly, the assumption is that theauthorities have only one instrument, namely theofficial short term interest rate, and that is set in orderto hit the inflation target.

In fact, the problem applies more generally than just inrelation to the exchange rate. Indeed, in most countriesthe central bank has not one objective but two, namely,

THE REAL STERLING CRISIS

96

The Real Sterling Crisis Layout.qxp_Layout 1 19/08/2016 10:47 Page 96

Page 114: The Real Sterling Crisis - Civitascivitas.org.uk/content/files/The-Real-Sterling-Crisis.pdf · The fall in the value of sterling since the vote for Brexit has had commentators wringing

not only to achieve a specified inflation objective, but alsoto achieve objectives for the real economy, defined as amixture of growth and employment. In the US this otherobjective has equal weight to the inflation objective; inthe UK, the growth and employment objective issubsidiary. In neither country, however, has it been madeexplicitly clear how the central bank is to pursue thesetwo objectives simultaneously.

We discuss what extra instruments might be availableto meet extra policy objectives in the next chapter.

Doing without an inflation target

One option, of course, is to do without an inflationtarget altogether. Provided that conditions in the worldare fairly stable and the overall inflation rate is low thisis not such a daft option as it might seem. After all, itwould represent a return to pretty much the regime thatoperated in most countries before the advent of inflationtargets. Indeed, under the Bretton Woods system, everycountry except the United States relied on the fixedexchange rate to provide an anchor for nominal values.But this system depended, of course, on the UnitedStates pursuing something like price stability itself. If itdidn’t, then the fixed exchange rate system wouldensure that price instability was transmitted around the world.

Meanwhile, the option of deploying a Keynesianexpansion in the event of a major shortfall of aggregatedemand – and indeed dropping interest rates and evenreducing the exchange rate target – would still be there.Again, though, operating policy according to an explicitexchange rate target would run counter to our G7undertakings which we discuss later.

97

EXCHANGE RATES AND POLICY OBJECTIVES

The Real Sterling Crisis Layout.qxp_Layout 1 19/08/2016 10:47 Page 97

Page 115: The Real Sterling Crisis - Civitascivitas.org.uk/content/files/The-Real-Sterling-Crisis.pdf · The fall in the value of sterling since the vote for Brexit has had commentators wringing

What other countries do

Although we like to think that we live in a world offloating currencies, in fact a substantial number of theworld’s economies operate an exchange rate policy, orrather policies. There is a considerable range.

At one extreme is the currency peg operated by HongKong. Although it issues its own currency – the HongKong dollar – not only is the rate of exchange betweenthe HK$ and the US$ fixed by the HK authorities butthe country operates a currency board system underwhich changes in the domestic money supply (themonetary base) exactly correspond to inflows andoutflows of US dollars. To all intents and purposesunder this system the Hong Kong authorities havegiven up all independence of monetary policy. HongKong is effectively a full part of the US dollar zone.Hong Kong dollars are a mere token; they are US dollarsin disguise.

At the other extreme is Singapore’s exchange ratepolicy. This is not a fixed rate of exchange; rather theauthorities seek to manage the Singapore dollar againsta basket of other currencies within a pre-determinedrange. But Singapore does not have an inflation target.Accordingly, the inflation rate does fluctuateconsiderably, with drops into deflation, alternating withbursts of inflation.

Conflict with inflation targeting?

There are many ways to skin a cat. It would be possiblefor the exchange rate to play a greater role in economicpolicy without it necessarily figuring prominently in theobjectives of economic policy. Nevertheless, withoutsome formal acknowledgement, there is a risk that it

THE REAL STERLING CRISIS

98

The Real Sterling Crisis Layout.qxp_Layout 1 19/08/2016 10:47 Page 98

Page 116: The Real Sterling Crisis - Civitascivitas.org.uk/content/files/The-Real-Sterling-Crisis.pdf · The fall in the value of sterling since the vote for Brexit has had commentators wringing

would continue to be some flabbily acknowledged otherfactor lurking in the background, while prominence wasgiven to other variables. If the exchange rate really isthat important, then surely it should figure moreprominently in policy objectives, just as it has done inthe case of so many other countries throughout theworld, as discussed in the previous chapter. Moreover,if the exchange rate does not figure as a policy objectiveit is difficult for domestic producers to be confident thattheir competitive position will not soon be underminedby a surge in the exchange rate.

Over recent decades, the idea of putting exchangerates in a prominent position has conflicted with thewidespread adherence to inflation targets. And witheffective policy instruments thin on the ground, this hasseverely constrained the authorities from pursuingother objectives.

Yet surely we can all acknowledge that the inflationtargeting regime is due for improvement. It came intoexistence after a period when inflation was rampant andthreatened to destabilise the whole capitalist system.This time has long passed. More or less everywhere,inflation is low to non-existent – or even negative.Moreover, if it ends up being plus or minus one, two orthree per cent, so what? The notion that central banksshould devote every effort to fine-tuning thesupposedly likely outcome of inflation in two or threeyears’ time is for the birds. They used not to behave thisway and they should not be doing so now.

Nevertheless, there would still have to be some sortof nominal anchor, as there was under both the goldstandard and the Bretton Woods system. We discusswhat that might be below. It should be possible tofashion a regime in which objectives for the exchange

99

EXCHANGE RATES AND POLICY OBJECTIVES

The Real Sterling Crisis Layout.qxp_Layout 1 19/08/2016 10:47 Page 99

Page 117: The Real Sterling Crisis - Civitascivitas.org.uk/content/files/The-Real-Sterling-Crisis.pdf · The fall in the value of sterling since the vote for Brexit has had commentators wringing

rate sit easily with inflation targets. In short, althoughthey are not the be-all and end-all of economic policy,we need inflation targets – as well as a policy ofexchange rate management.

An exchange rate target?

As far as exchange rate management is concerned, it iswidely assumed that the natural alternative to totalneglect is complete fixity, or at least single-mindedtargeting of a level or range for the exchange rate. Butthis need not be so. The important thing is that thepolicy authorities should have a clear idea, announcedin public and communicated to the markets, of what theexchange rate should reasonably be. If it veers outsidethis range, then there should be a presumption thatsomething is wrong and perhaps policy needs to beadjusted accordingly.

This can be compared with the situation facing theFederal Reserve in the United States. It has a dualmandate – to achieve both price stability and fullemployment. And it effectively only has one policyinstrument, namely the short term official interest rate.

The role of an explicit statement about the exchangerate is threefold: first, to influence the expectations ofmarket participants; second, to constrain and influencegovernment policy with regard to both interest ratesand the fiscal balance – as well as other factors thatinfluence the attractiveness of UK assets; third, to giveconfidence to firms that they can invest and plan for thefuture on the back of a competitive exchange rate.

THE REAL STERLING CRISIS

100

The Real Sterling Crisis Layout.qxp_Layout 1 19/08/2016 10:47 Page 100

Page 118: The Real Sterling Crisis - Civitascivitas.org.uk/content/files/The-Real-Sterling-Crisis.pdf · The fall in the value of sterling since the vote for Brexit has had commentators wringing

9 How to get the

exchange rate lower

Suppose that the authorities decide that the exchangerate should be lower. What could they do to bring thisabout? Possible policies fall into five broad types:(i) Changes to the macroeconomic policy mix, e.g.

running a tighter fiscal policy in order to make a possible looser monetary policy (i.e. lower interest rates and/or more quantitative easing (QE)than otherwise);

(ii) Prudential policy tools, including reserverequirements and capital requirements;

(iii) Intervention on the foreign exchanges;

(iv) Talk and guidance, perhaps even extending to thepublication of targets;

(v) Micro policies designed to make UK assets lessattractive to overseas investors.

In principle, of course, it would also be possible todeploy capital controls, and many countries do –including China. But capital controls are distortionary,as well as being against our undertakings to both the EU and the G7. They don’t have any practical appealfor a country like the UK. Accordingly, we do notinclude them in the list of five types of instrument,described above.

101

The Real Sterling Crisis Layout.qxp_Layout 1 19/08/2016 10:47 Page 101

Page 119: The Real Sterling Crisis - Civitascivitas.org.uk/content/files/The-Real-Sterling-Crisis.pdf · The fall in the value of sterling since the vote for Brexit has had commentators wringing

1. The Macroeconomic Policy Mix

In principle, fiscal policy could provide the extra policyinstrument. In theory it would be possible to usechanges in fiscal policy to constrain the growth ofaggregate demand to the growth of productive capacityand therefore forestall and/or correct a movement ofinflation away from the target.

In practice, though, fiscal fine tuning is not a viableproposition. It is not economically desirable orpolitically attractive to make short-term adjustments tothe fiscal balance, through either tax changes or changesto planned expenditure. Nor do short-term fiscaladjustments have predictable effects on aggregatedemand. Nevertheless, it is a viable proposition to setfiscal policy on a course that would facilitate themaintenance of a competitive exchange rate.

Running a tight fiscal policy would certainly help toestablish and sustain a policy of low interest rateswithout necessarily landing the country with aninflation problem. But it does not really constitute asecond policy instrument that would allow theauthorities to pursue two policy objectives. Firstly, inmost countries, including the UK, fiscal policy is setwith regard to another objective, namely reducing theratio of government debt to GDP on a path that isdeemed optimal, balancing the need to reduce the total,and retain bond market confidence, against the need toavoid delivering a shock to aggregate demand throughtightening too quickly.

In the UK there has been a fervent debate about theappropriate degree of fiscal tightening, with critics ofthe government arguing that it is planning to tightentoo much. But in this debate scant regard has been paid

THE REAL STERLING CRISIS

102

The Real Sterling Crisis Layout.qxp_Layout 1 19/08/2016 10:47 Page 102

Page 120: The Real Sterling Crisis - Civitascivitas.org.uk/content/files/The-Real-Sterling-Crisis.pdf · The fall in the value of sterling since the vote for Brexit has had commentators wringing

to the exchange rate. It deserves much more attention. Some of the criticism of the government’s fiscal stance

derives from the idea that there is considerable sparecapacity in the economy and that the tight fiscal policythereby leads to unnecessary waste of resources. Thismay or may not be true but what matters for policy iswhat the Bank of England believes.

If the Bank believes that there is no margin of unusedcapacity then, if fiscal policy were to be looser, the Bankwould set interest rates above where they wouldotherwise have been. Other things equal, that wouldtend to increase the exchange rate for sterling, with theusual adverse consequences for our competitivenessand hence for the current account.

Even without the assumption of unused resources, ofcourse, the critics of current fiscal policy may have apoint with regard to with the unfair/unjust/unnecessary/inefficient squeeze on the public sectorrelative to what is going on in the private sector. In particular, they could point to the squeeze on public investment.

But without the unused resources assumption theyshould surely take account of the potential damage toour current account that a looser fiscal policy wouldimply, recognising that a larger current account deficitwould imply a worsened national wealth positionwhich would offset at least some of the gain from higherpublic investment.

So what role can fiscal policy play with regard tomanagement of the UK exchange rate? Taking it as agiven that the position of public investment should beprotected, concern to improve the current accountposition argues for a tighter fiscal stance. In ordinaryconditions this would be demanding enough politically

103

HOW TO GET THE EXCHANGE RATE LOWER

The Real Sterling Crisis Layout.qxp_Layout 1 19/08/2016 10:47 Page 103

Page 121: The Real Sterling Crisis - Civitascivitas.org.uk/content/files/The-Real-Sterling-Crisis.pdf · The fall in the value of sterling since the vote for Brexit has had commentators wringing

and it is so now. But in current circumstances at leasttighter policy fits in with the objective of reducing theratio of government debt to GDP. Operating a tighterpolicy would result in a lower ratio being achieved, orthe same ratio being achieved sooner.

In this regard, it is important to recognise a potentialchange in circumstances. When interest rates were atrock bottom (and the authorities appear to haveregarded 0.5% as rock bottom for the UK) and there weredoubts about the wisdom and/or effectiveness of moreQE, a tighter fiscal policy would not have deliveredlooser monetary policy, and therefore would not havehelped to sustain a weaker exchange rate. These havebeen the conditions for the last several years.

Very low rates are now likely to continue for anextended period. But thereafter we will enter a periodwhen interest rates are set to rise. In thesecircumstances, a tighter fiscal policy could put back arise in rates, and continue to keep rates lower than theywould have been under the original fiscal policy. Theycould also justify more QE, whether this is conductedacross the exchanges (foreign exchange intervention) ornot. (See below.)

2. Prudential policy tools

In practice, in the UK there has over recent years beensome amelioration of potential policy conflict throughthe development of a prudential policy toolkit. This hasassuredly not been developed in order to allow policyto pay explicit regard to the exchange rate but rather toallow the central bank to pursue objectives for both theinflation rate and financial stability.

In principle, this extra set of tools would be availableto help manage the exchange rate. For instance,

THE REAL STERLING CRISIS

104

The Real Sterling Crisis Layout.qxp_Layout 1 19/08/2016 10:47 Page 104

Page 122: The Real Sterling Crisis - Civitascivitas.org.uk/content/files/The-Real-Sterling-Crisis.pdf · The fall in the value of sterling since the vote for Brexit has had commentators wringing

suppose that a burgeoning inflation problem seemed torequire higher interest rates to head it off; it might bepossible to address this by deploying a tightening ofprudential policy without requiring higher interestrates, which might threaten to send the pound higheron the exchanges.

But, of course, if prudential policy is there to addressconcerns of financial stability, it cannot be usedsimultaneously, except by happy coincidence, to helpmanage the exchange rate. So another instrument is needed.

3. Foreign exchange intervention

Foreign exchange intervention has acquired a bad name– along with the policy of exchange rate management.There are good reasons for this. Usually, interventionhas been employed to stop a currency from falling. This involves selling foreign currency and buyingdomestic currency.

This has a clear limitation. The domestic monetaryauthorities can run out of supplies of foreign currencyto sell (the foreign exchange reserves) and their access to further supplies through borrowing will alsobe limited.

There are countless examples of countries finding itimpossible to hold the exchange rate up againstapparently limitless waves of selling. Perhaps the bestexample is when the Bank of England tried and failedto keep the pound in the European Exchange RateMechanism (ERM) in September 1992.

But the position is different when central banks aretrying to keep their currencies down. In this case theyhave to sell domestic currency and buy foreign currency.

105

HOW TO GET THE EXCHANGE RATE LOWER

The Real Sterling Crisis Layout.qxp_Layout 1 19/08/2016 10:47 Page 105

Page 123: The Real Sterling Crisis - Civitascivitas.org.uk/content/files/The-Real-Sterling-Crisis.pdf · The fall in the value of sterling since the vote for Brexit has had commentators wringing

In principle, there is no limit to the amount of domesticcurrency that they can issue – and therefore no limit tothe amount that they can sell.

In practice, though, there is a limit of sorts. Issuingmore domestic currency inflates the money supply andif this is continued without offsetting policies then itthreatens to cause an upsurge of inflation.

The obvious offsetting policy is to sell extra domesticassets to absorb the inflow of money. This is the policyknown as sterilisation. In principle, this can continuewithout limit but it too has complications. A centralbank has a limited range of assets that it can sell in orderto absorb currency inflows – usually some sort of fixedinterest instruments such as bonds or quasi-deposits.But money pouring in from abroad may seekemployment in a whole panoply of assets, including not only bonds and bank deposits but also residentialand commercial property and equities. In that case, selling large amounts of bonds and quasi-deposit type instruments may cause distortions infinancial markets.

There is also the issue of the profitability of the centralbank intervention. This can limit the extent of the gainsfrom the policy – and certainly curtail central banks’appetite for pursuing it. The effect on profitabilitydepends, as usual, on two elements: capital gains and income.

If the central bank sells domestic currency to acquireforeign currency assets and is eventually obliged to letthe currency rise then it will incur a capital loss.

The income element depends upon the relative cost of the domestic currency bonds that the centralbank has to issue to raise the money to sell on theexchanges versus the interest income that can be earned

THE REAL STERLING CRISIS

106

The Real Sterling Crisis Layout.qxp_Layout 1 19/08/2016 10:47 Page 106

Page 124: The Real Sterling Crisis - Civitascivitas.org.uk/content/files/The-Real-Sterling-Crisis.pdf · The fall in the value of sterling since the vote for Brexit has had commentators wringing

on foreign currency assets. As it happens, in currentcircumstances, the UK government can borrow at verylow interest rates.

The clearest example of a country finding it next toimpossible to hold the exchange rate down isSwitzerland in 2015. The Swiss National Bank tried tohold the Swiss franc down by dint of huge sales of Swissfrancs on the exchanges. But in January 2015 it decidedthat it could hold on no longer and let the currency rise.This episode supposedly revealed that foreign exchangeintervention is ultimately ineffective, even when thecentral bank is selling (and issuing) its own currency.

But the Swiss case is potentially highly misleading. In 2015, Switzerland ran a current account surplus of11.4% of GDP, roughly 1.6 times the surplus(proportionately) of Germany, and 3.8 times that ofChina. The scale of this surplus indicated that withouta radical change of circumstances or policy, the Swissfranc was substantially under-valued. Accordingly, it isno wonder that the Swiss National Bank could not holdthe currency down.

There are also some clear examples of countriesimposing substantial and painful distortions on theireconomies by operating policies that kept theirexchange rates artificially low with the result that theyran substantial current account surpluses, whilstreducing consumption below what it could otherwisebe. China and Japan fall into this category and so,arguably, does Germany. These examples do not set ahappy precedent for the UK.

Needless to say, however, the UK is in a very differentposition. It has been running a huge current accountdeficit and there has been clear evidence that thecurrency has been over-valued. Accordingly, intervention

107

HOW TO GET THE EXCHANGE RATE LOWER

The Real Sterling Crisis Layout.qxp_Layout 1 19/08/2016 10:47 Page 107

Page 125: The Real Sterling Crisis - Civitascivitas.org.uk/content/files/The-Real-Sterling-Crisis.pdf · The fall in the value of sterling since the vote for Brexit has had commentators wringing

to hold it down would be working with the grain of theeconomic fundamentals, not against them.

Quantitative easing could be deployed across theexchanges, that is to say, the Bank of England couldpurchase overseas assets. (This is good old fashionedintervention in the foreign exchange market.)

Perhaps this could even be done via the establishmentof a UK sovereign wealth fund. Suppose that a countryestablishes a funded pension scheme by means ofenforced deductions from pay. The funds received needto be invested somewhere. As with private schemes, itwould be normal (and good) practice to invest aproportion of these funds abroad. The smaller thecountry in question, other things equal, the greatershould be the proportion invested abroad. This may ormay not result in downward pressure on the exchangerate, depending upon the response of individuals to thedeductions from their pay (lower saving or lowerspending) and the balance of domestic versus overseasin whatever individuals’ responses are.

In current circumstances, it would be impossible toraise extra money through taxation, and/or enforcedeductions from pay (over and above those already intrain under the government’s new pension policy).Might it be possible to establish such a fund byborrowing? The UK government could establish anoverseas investment fund, with money invested inoverseas securities, funded by the issue of gilts. This would definitely exert downward pressure on the exchange rate. It would be the equivalent of apolicy of QE but with foreign rather than domesticassets purchased.

A more discreet way of achieving the same thingwould be to establish a fund to receive existing national

THE REAL STERLING CRISIS

108

The Real Sterling Crisis Layout.qxp_Layout 1 19/08/2016 10:47 Page 108

Page 126: The Real Sterling Crisis - Civitascivitas.org.uk/content/files/The-Real-Sterling-Crisis.pdf · The fall in the value of sterling since the vote for Brexit has had commentators wringing

insurance contributions, or at least a fraction of them,to be invested abroad. Of course the funds thuschannelled into overseas investment would not beavailable for ordinary domestic expenditure and thiswould therefore create a domestic financial shortfall,which would have to be covered by borrowing.Accordingly, it amounts to the same idea as the onediscussed above. But it may be presentationally andpractically attractive, including in the way that it ispresented to our G7 partners.

Under this suggestion, the official figures for netborrowing would be unaltered since extra grossborrowing would be offset by asset purchases. Thiswould be the equivalent of a bout of ordinary sterilisedforeign exchange intervention. To make this equivalentto unsterilised intervention the Bank of England wouldbuy gilts equivalent to the extra ones issued. This wouldproduce a situation akin to ordinary QE, except thatthere would now be extra gilts in issue, mirroring (andfinancing) the foreign securities held by the newSovereign (Pension/National Insurance) fund.

4. Verbal direction and encouragement

Talk and guidance might seem attractive since this maybe thought to have the smallest cost in regard to thedistortion of policies in order to achieve an exchangerate objective. But unless it is backed up by one or moreof the other policy instruments it is also unlikely to bevery effective. Moreover, it is the policy lever that mostobviously conflicts with our G7 obligations.

Equally, unless there is some verbal articulation of anew exchange rate policy, deployment of each of theother instruments may not be as effective as it might be

109

HOW TO GET THE EXCHANGE RATE LOWER

The Real Sterling Crisis Layout.qxp_Layout 1 19/08/2016 10:47 Page 109

Page 127: The Real Sterling Crisis - Civitascivitas.org.uk/content/files/The-Real-Sterling-Crisis.pdf · The fall in the value of sterling since the vote for Brexit has had commentators wringing

since businesses might not perceive the change of policyand therefore might not fully believe that whateverexchange rate change happens is going to last. Soideally a policy to reduce the pound and or to keep it atits new lower level would involve a combination of allof the above instruments – and the perception that theauthorities potentially have more of the same up theirsleeve to deploy if necessary.

The power of words should not be under-estimated,particularly with regard to keeping a currency down,given that such words are backed up by the full panoplyof macro and micro policy. Even if they stop short ofdeclaring a formal range within which they intend thepound to trade (which would be against current G7rules), the UK policy authorities could make it clear thatthey aim to keep the exchange rate competitive and thatthis objective will occupy a central place in their policydeliberations and policy settings.

5. Micro policies designed to make UK assets less attractive

(i) A different policy on foreign acquisition of UK companiesMost countries are wary of allowing overseas intereststo own and control more than a limited proportion oftheir major companies for strategic or other reasons. Byboth formal and informal methods, making unwantedtake-overs difficult to accomplish, they have ways ofdiscouraging overseas acquisition of businesses whichthey think are of national significance. In 2005, theFrench government drafted a law to protect ‘strategicindustries’ from being purchased by companies ownedelsewhere, thus protecting Danone, best known for its

THE REAL STERLING CRISIS

110

The Real Sterling Crisis Layout.qxp_Layout 1 19/08/2016 10:47 Page 110

Page 128: The Real Sterling Crisis - Civitascivitas.org.uk/content/files/The-Real-Sterling-Crisis.pdf · The fall in the value of sterling since the vote for Brexit has had commentators wringing

yoghurts, from being purchased by Pepsi-Cola orNestle. In the same year, the US Senate passed a billblocking the purchase of a number of US ports by DubaiPorts World on the grounds that this might compromiseUS security.

In the UK, the old Monopolies and MergersCommission was able to apply a public interest test totakeover proposals and the UK was therefore able tobehave in a similar way to most other countries.

This changed in 1999, however, when the Monopoliesand Mergers Commission was replaced by theCompetition Commission which had no such remit. In the then prevailing UK climate of opinion – themarket knows best and who owns or controls UKcompanies does not matter as long as competition is not impaired – the Competition Commission had norole to play in taking a view as to whether UKcompanies being acquired by overseas interests mighthave a wider national significance. As a result, the UK– encouraged by the City, which made large sums fromthe fees involved – became a happy hunting ground forany international company wanting to expand itsforeign interests.

While direct investment in plant and machinery from foreign-owned business tends to be stronglyadvantageous to the UK economy, the overseaspurchasing and ownership of existing companies hasnone of these advantages. It also has major downsides.Control goes abroad, and with it are inclined to go key research and investment decisions. Much of the taxbase of such companies also goes abroad – certainlycorporate tax. Also, often, the tax of non-domexecutives. For entirely understandable reasons,international companies are bound to have a special

111

HOW TO GET THE EXCHANGE RATE LOWER

The Real Sterling Crisis Layout.qxp_Layout 1 19/08/2016 10:47 Page 111

Page 129: The Real Sterling Crisis - Civitascivitas.org.uk/content/files/The-Real-Sterling-Crisis.pdf · The fall in the value of sterling since the vote for Brexit has had commentators wringing

regard for their home markets. With ownership goes theflow of profits and capital gains.

For all these reasons, a first step to take would be toreintroduce a public interest test for all takeovers,particularly those involving ownership and controlfrom abroad, with these tests designed to take the widerinterests of the UK economy as a whole into account,and not just narrow issues about competition.

The sums involved in allowing complete freedom foroverseas takeovers are significant. In 2015, totaloverseas participation in the acquisition of UKcompanies amounted to just over £30bn. This comparesto an overall current account deficit of £100bn. Between2000 and 2007 the average annual inflow was £44bn. (Ofcourse, we need to bear in mind that the UK is alsohighly active in purchasing companies overseas.)

(ii) Foreign acquisition of UK propertyNet sales of UK property assets on a major scale havestemmed from a different source. The UK in general andLondon in particular provide a safe and secureenvironment for those in less stable parts of the world.Purchasing properties in the UK has increasinglybecome an attractive – and prestigious - way of investingfootloose funds which might otherwise be at risk.Especially recently, the scale on which residentialproperty is being bought by overseas residents ratherthan UK residents is staggering. A recent reportindicated that about 75% of all new build houses andflats in London were being bought by overseas residents,while about half of all property transactions in Londonof more than £1m again involved overseas purchasers.(Admittedly, this total includes UK purchasers usingforeign/offshore corporate structures.)

THE REAL STERLING CRISIS

112

The Real Sterling Crisis Layout.qxp_Layout 1 19/08/2016 10:47 Page 112

Page 130: The Real Sterling Crisis - Civitascivitas.org.uk/content/files/The-Real-Sterling-Crisis.pdf · The fall in the value of sterling since the vote for Brexit has had commentators wringing

The result of this huge external demand on top of afaltering supply, combined with the UK’s rapidly risingpopulation and very low interest rates for those in aposition to borrow, has been a very rapid increase inhouse prices, freezing many potential first time buyersout of the market.

It is difficult to get hard and fast aggregate figures onthe extent of overseas purchases of UK property. Weestimate that since 2008, overseas companies andindividuals may have bought about £150bn of UKcommercial property and have sold about £90bn worth.So, in net terms, overseas asset purchases haveamounted to about £60bn, some 17% of the value of allUK commercial property transactions over this period.

Data on residential sales are even sketchier. From thereports of leading estate agents it seems as though,between 2008 and mid-2014, about 10% of centralLondon residential sales were to overseas buyers. Onreasonable assumptions that would translate to a totalinflow of just over £20bn.

As regards purchases of residential property, againthere are fairly obvious routes to containing the scale onwhich this currently occurs. There could be muchheavier taxation of foreign-owned houses and flats,especially those with very high value, where much ofthe problem resides. As most of the propertiesconcerned are at the expensive end of the market, majortax increases focused on those owned by foreignregistered companies or individuals domiciled abroadwould only affect a limited number of housing units.This would be a further development of the policiesalready deployed by HM Treasury. But these have beenpretty crudely designed to raise revenue and/or slowthe top end of the market, rather than to target

113

HOW TO GET THE EXCHANGE RATE LOWER

The Real Sterling Crisis Layout.qxp_Layout 1 19/08/2016 10:47 Page 113

Page 131: The Real Sterling Crisis - Civitascivitas.org.uk/content/files/The-Real-Sterling-Crisis.pdf · The fall in the value of sterling since the vote for Brexit has had commentators wringing

specifically the foreign purchase of UK property.(Interestingly, Australia prohibits foreigners frombuying existing property but not from adding to thehousing stock.)

Policies along these lines would not only reduce the upward pressure on the exchange rate, but they would also ease the strain on the UK propertymarket generally, allowing more resources to bedevoted to satisfying the housing needs of theindigenous population.

Conclusions on micro policyWe don’t need to lift up the drawbridge and to isolateourselves from world capital markets, but equally wedo not need to have most of our ports, airports, largemanufacturing companies, utilities, energy companies,rail franchises, football clubs and much of our housingand real estate in foreign ownership. We need areasonable balance, in the same way that applies inalmost all other countries.

Nor would such a policy necessarily be to thedisadvantage of the rest of the world, broadlyconsidered. When Russian capital flows out of Russiaand into UK assets, real and financial, whatever thismight do to the prosperity of individual Russianwealth-holders, is it really in the interests of Russia?

Admittedly, in normal circumstances, it would notmake sense to use micro measures, such as restrictionson overseas investments in UK assets, as a substitute formacro measures in order to achieve macro objectives.But it makes sense to temper the overseas appetite for our real assets for soundly-based other reasons. The fact that such action would tend to weaken the

THE REAL STERLING CRISIS

114

The Real Sterling Crisis Layout.qxp_Layout 1 19/08/2016 10:47 Page 114

Page 132: The Real Sterling Crisis - Civitascivitas.org.uk/content/files/The-Real-Sterling-Crisis.pdf · The fall in the value of sterling since the vote for Brexit has had commentators wringing

forces that put upward pressure on our exchange rateis an added bonus.

The policy regime

The policy instruments discussed above are of verydifferent sorts. The tightness of fiscal policy and theattractions of UK assets to overseas wealth holders arenot things that can be deployed at a moment’s notice tomanage or influence the exchange rate. Rather, thesettings of these variables can be made in regard to their impact on the exchange rate and then left there for extended periods. For short-term influence, the authorities would need to rely on extensive foreign exchange intervention, perhaps backed up byverbal guidance.

Equally, on their own, these two may not be veryeffective if they are deployed to try to achieve andsustain an exchange rate out of line with the economicfundamentals and with the stance of fiscal andmonetary policy, and the relative attractiveness of UKassets to foreigners. What is needed is a policy regimewhich includes all these facets.

115

HOW TO GET THE EXCHANGE RATE LOWER

The Real Sterling Crisis Layout.qxp_Layout 1 19/08/2016 10:47 Page 115

Page 133: The Real Sterling Crisis - Civitascivitas.org.uk/content/files/The-Real-Sterling-Crisis.pdf · The fall in the value of sterling since the vote for Brexit has had commentators wringing

10 Objections to a lower exchangerate policy – and the answers

1. Currency devaluation (or depreciation) inevitablyleads to higher inflation. There are many examples of countries experiencingcurrency depreciation and rapid inflation interactingwith each other, indeed, feeding off each other. Theseexamples, usually involving developing countries, oftenburdened by weak and ineffectual governments, havebeen widely assumed to reveal a general truth about the linkages between the currency and the price level.They do not. In fact, for developed countries they canbe extremely misleading.

It is true that even for developed countries, followingcurrency depreciation, the price of imports is bound torise. Indeed, this is a necessary part of switchingdemand from international to domestic suppliers. Itdoes not follow, however, that the overall price levelgenerally will rise more quickly than it would havedone without a devaluation. A wealth of evidence fromthe dozens of devaluations and depreciations whichhave occurred among relatively rich and diversifiedeconomies such as ours in recent decades shows that infact, although lower exchange rates usually lead to arise in the price level, sometimes they produce a bit of a

116

The Real Sterling Crisis Layout.qxp_Layout 1 19/08/2016 10:47 Page 116

Page 134: The Real Sterling Crisis - Civitascivitas.org.uk/content/files/The-Real-Sterling-Crisis.pdf · The fall in the value of sterling since the vote for Brexit has had commentators wringing

reduction, and sometimes little if any change comparedto what would have occurred anyway.

Moreover, even when the price level does increase, sothat the measured rate of inflation rises, at least for atime, generally the increase in inflation is short-lived.After the once-and-for-all price shock has passedthrough the system, the inflation rate may readily fallback to roughly where it was to begin with.

One of the clearest examples is when the UK left theExchange Rate Mechanism in 1992. Sterling fell by atrade-weighted 17%, but inflation fell from 3.2% inAugust 1992 to 1.5% in September 1994.

The reason why inflation may not pick up much, if atall, is that, while higher import prices push up the pricelevel, many factors to do with a lower exchange ratetend to bring it down. Interest rates tend to be lower andproduction runs become longer, bringing down averagecosts. Investment, especially in the most productiveparts of the economy may rise, increasing output perhead, reducing costs and producing a wage climatemore conducive to keeping income increases in linewith productivity growth.

2. In today’s economy it is impossible to change theexchange rate. It is frequently contended that the parity of sterling isdetermined by market forces over which the authoritieshave little control, so that any policy to change theexchange rate in any direction is bound to fail. Again,historical experience indicates that this propositioncannot be correct. The Japanese, to provide a recentexample, brought the parity of the yen down by 10%between April 2013 and October 2014 as a result of

OBJECTIONS TO A LOWER EXCHANGE RATE POLICY

117

The Real Sterling Crisis Layout.qxp_Layout 1 19/08/2016 10:47 Page 117

Page 135: The Real Sterling Crisis - Civitascivitas.org.uk/content/files/The-Real-Sterling-Crisis.pdf · The fall in the value of sterling since the vote for Brexit has had commentators wringing

deliberate policy (although the yen has sincerebounded, partly because of safe haven demand).Further back, the Plaza Accord, negotiated in 1985,produced a massive change in parities among the majortrading nations of the world at the time, causing thedollar to fall against the yen by 40% in the two yearsfollowing the agreement.

Of course, market forces determine exchange rates butthe authorities can influence the factors whichdetermine what market forces are. If the UK pursuespolicies which make it very easy for overseas intereststo buy British assets, for example, this will exert upwardpressure on sterling’s exchange rate. If the marketsthink that the Bank of England is going to raise interestrates, this will also push sterling higher.

Nor is it true that it is impossible to change the realexchange rate by altering the nominal rate. This is theperspective that whatever gain is achieved by a lowerexchange rate is soon offset by a higher domestic price level.Accordingly, it is addressed by the remarks under 1 above.

3. Any benefit from depreciation would be lostthrough retaliation. There is no doubt that this is a significant issue. Yet theeurozone has been able to benefit from a hugedepreciation of the euro without suffering retaliation.And the UK, of course, is much less important in worldtrade than the eurozone.

Moreover, the case for retaliation depends, in part, onthe position from which the devaluing country starts.The problem of overseas payments imbalances starts,not with countries like the UK, with massive deficits,but with economies such as Germany and Switzerlandwith huge surpluses – in 2014 running at about 8% of

THE REAL STERLING CRISIS

118

The Real Sterling Crisis Layout.qxp_Layout 1 19/08/2016 10:47 Page 118

Page 136: The Real Sterling Crisis - Civitascivitas.org.uk/content/files/The-Real-Sterling-Crisis.pdf · The fall in the value of sterling since the vote for Brexit has had commentators wringing

GDP in Germany’s case and 7% for Switzerland. Thesesurpluses have to be matched by deficits somewhereelse in the world economy.

Unfortunately, surplus countries are never under anyimmediate pressure to reduce the beggar-thy-neighbourimpact of their surpluses by revaluing their currenciesand this leaves economies such as ours, carrying bigdeficits, with no alternative but devaluation to get thesituation under control. There is thus a very strong,principled case for countries such as the UK to make.

Actually, the boot should be on the other foot. It is notthat the UK would encounter retaliation if she tookaction to reduce her exchange rate but rather that she isthe sufferer from other countries’ competitivedepreciations, principally the eurozone’s. It is the UKthat needs to respond in order to preserve her ownposition. After the Brexit-inspired fall of the pound, thenecessary response may simply amount to maintainingthe new, competitive value for the pound.

4. Devaluation must make us all poorer. Since import prices rise, depreciations tend to reducethe real incomes and living standards of many people.But this is not the end of the story. If a depreciationproduces higher GDP then GDP per head will rise.Many people who did not have jobs will now have themand thus average incomes will rise. It is true that, for thedepreciation to benefit the trade balance, there has to bean increase in net exports. While this will generateincreased income it will not, directly, generate increasedconsumption. That is, after all, the point. Net exportsrepresent consumption foregone.

Nevertheless, average living standards could rise ifthe increase in GDP, brought about by the depreciation,

OBJECTIONS TO A LOWER EXCHANGE RATE POLICY

119

The Real Sterling Crisis Layout.qxp_Layout 1 19/08/2016 10:47 Page 119

Page 137: The Real Sterling Crisis - Civitascivitas.org.uk/content/files/The-Real-Sterling-Crisis.pdf · The fall in the value of sterling since the vote for Brexit has had commentators wringing

exceeds the increase in net exports plus anydeterioration in the terms of trade (the ratio of exportprices to import prices) and any redistribution of realincome from workers to employers.

Many people assume that the terms of trade mustdeteriorate after a depreciation. They think this waybecause they reason that the depreciation ‘raises theprice of imports but reduces the price of exports’.Indeed, this change in relative prices, they reason, is thechannel through which the depreciation is supposed toimprove the trade balance.

But when they reason this way they are thinking indifferent currencies for imports and exports. This ismisleading. If you think in the same currency for bothexports and imports then you can readily see that adeterioration in the terms of trade is not inevitable.

Let us assume that we are dealing with a smallcountry that cannot influence the world price of itsimports and exports. Then a depreciation will have noeffect on the foreign currency price of its imports andexports and the domestic price of both will rise by thefull percentage of the depreciation, leaving the ratio ofexport to import prices unchanged. Whether adepreciation improves or worsens the terms of tradedepends upon the relative monopoly/monopsonypower of the country in the various markets in which it trades.

When Britain devalued the pound in 1967, the thenPrime Minister, Harold Wilson, told the British publicthat ‘the pound in your pocket has not been devalued’.The idea was that their purchasing power would not bereduced by the devaluation, or at least, not to the fullextent. This statement was partly true – and partlyhighly misleading. At the very least, as import prices

THE REAL STERLING CRISIS

120

The Real Sterling Crisis Layout.qxp_Layout 1 19/08/2016 10:47 Page 120

Page 138: The Real Sterling Crisis - Civitascivitas.org.uk/content/files/The-Real-Sterling-Crisis.pdf · The fall in the value of sterling since the vote for Brexit has had commentators wringing

rose, other things equal, people’s real incomes wouldfall. In the extreme, if there were no excess capacity thenprices would rise beyond the increase in import prices.

In the end, the major determinants of whether peopleon average will be better or worse off in regard to theirlevel of consumption as a result of devaluation will be:the extent of excess capacity; the extent of the need to cut back consumption in order to boost exports; the size of any deterioration in the terms of trade; andthe size of any swing against real wages and towardsreal profits.

5. Past devaluations have not worked. This is not true. Some devaluations that have takenplace in the past have been too little and too late andhave not worked. They might have made the situationbetter than it otherwise would have been but they havenot transformed matters. The UK’s devaluation of 1967 falls into this category. But some drops of theexchange rate have had a powerful effect – notably in1931 and 1992.

Moreover, there are plenty of examples from othercountries of depreciations having a major beneficialeffect. Furthermore, umpteen countries around theworld carefully manage their exchange rates preciselybecause they know that their exchange rates have amajor bearing on their trade performance, and hence ontheir GDP.

6. The UK has no bent for manufacturing.While it is true that a wide swathe of low- and medium-tech manufacturing is uneconomic in the UK at present,because the exchange rate and the cost base for them are much too high, there is no evidence whatever

OBJECTIONS TO A LOWER EXCHANGE RATE POLICY

121

The Real Sterling Crisis Layout.qxp_Layout 1 19/08/2016 10:47 Page 121

Page 139: The Real Sterling Crisis - Civitascivitas.org.uk/content/files/The-Real-Sterling-Crisis.pdf · The fall in the value of sterling since the vote for Brexit has had commentators wringing

that if more favourable conditions prevailed, UKentrepreneurs would not be just as good as thoseanywhere else in the world at taking advantage of thenew opportunities which would then open up. There isno evidence that the UK lacks entrepreneurial peoplewho would be willing to try their hands at makingmoney out of making and selling if the rightopportunities were there. The problem with the UK asa manufacturing environment is that these conditionssimply do not exist at the moment, because the cost baseis too high, and entrepreneurs rightly shun investing inventures which they can see from the beginning havepoor prospects of being profitable and successful.

It is true that it is normal for rich and successfulcountries like the UK to experience a fall in the share of GDP accounted for by manufacturing. But this is notthe be-all and end-all. Germany is at roughly the samelevel of development as the UK but its share ofmanufacturing is roughly twice the UK’s. In part thisreflects the different experience of the exchange rate ofthe two countries. Although Germany’s nominalexchange rate, under the Deutschemark, tended to riseover time, it hardly ever experienced the sharp rises ofthe real exchange rate that UK manufacturers havesuffered several times. And after the advent of the euro,Germany’s real exchange rate has been kept low.

7. We should leave the exchange rate to bedetermined by market forces. Market forces do not exist in a vacuum. They respond,in part, to the policy settings, macro and micro, imposedby the authorities.

To the extent that the UK exchange rate is sustainedby overseas wealth holders’ preferences for UK assets,

THE REAL STERLING CRISIS

122

The Real Sterling Crisis Layout.qxp_Layout 1 19/08/2016 10:47 Page 122

Page 140: The Real Sterling Crisis - Civitascivitas.org.uk/content/files/The-Real-Sterling-Crisis.pdf · The fall in the value of sterling since the vote for Brexit has had commentators wringing

it could be argued that this is just a particularmanifestation of the ‘market forces’ to which the UK atpresent submits – and should do so. Yet the interests offoreign asset holders are not naturally congruent withthe interests of UK citizens. The UK ‘provides’ someintangible things that overseas wealth holders value –political stability, the rule of law, liquidity. Other thingsbeing equal, the UK should be able to charge a fee forproviding these things. It is frequently argued that thisis just what the United States does in that it is able toborrow more cheaply than it otherwise would withouthaving the ‘exorbitant privilege’ of issuing the world’smoney. To a lesser extent this should also be true of the UK.

But where is the comparable ‘fee’ secured by sellingreal assets to overseas wealth holders? And what if theattractions of UK (or US) assets to foreigners have theresult of increasing the amount that needs to befinanced? After all, if foreign capital inflows drive upthe exchange rate and thereby induce an increasedcurrent account deficit then both the public sector(thanks to lower tax revenues) and the private sector(thanks to reduced incomes from net exports) will haveto borrow more. In these circumstances it seems asthough it is the host country that ends up paying a feeto attract overseas capital.

The key issue here is what the capital drawn into acountry actually finances. If it is productive investmentthen that will bring a return that may offset – and morethan offset – the cost. But if it merely financesconsumption this will not be true. Worse than this, itwill diminish total national income by pushing up theexchange rate. If we assume that other components ofmacroeconomic policy (interest rates, QE, tax policy)

OBJECTIONS TO A LOWER EXCHANGE RATE POLICY

123

The Real Sterling Crisis Layout.qxp_Layout 1 19/08/2016 10:47 Page 123

Page 141: The Real Sterling Crisis - Civitascivitas.org.uk/content/files/The-Real-Sterling-Crisis.pdf · The fall in the value of sterling since the vote for Brexit has had commentators wringing

take up the slack so as to maintain full employment,then the overall loss of income will be avoided but itwill remain the case that total national investment willhave been reduced, and the overall national wealthdiminished compared to what it would otherwise havebeen. This hardly seems to be to our national advantage.

Of course, it is not easy to tell the ultimate use towhich a capital inflow is put. It is possible, for instance,that when an overseas company buys real assets –perhaps an existing UK company – from its currentowners that the proceeds are invested in newproductive ventures. It may be possible but it isunlikely, even by a circuitous route.

In some ways this discussion carries echoes of theevents that led up to the Asian financial crisis of 1997.In the year before the crisis, international funds pouredinto the Asian emerging markets but in only a fewcountries did this extra portfolio investment lead toincreased real investment in the domestic economy. On the contrary, it fed an upsurge in domestic credit anda burst of property speculation.

When the money washed out again this left many ofthe receiving countries in a hopeless mess. Some ofthem endured falls in output that rivalled whatGermany and the United States had suffered during the 1930s. In the wake of the crisis, the stance taken by Malaysia to control capital inflows – which hadpreviously been widely regarded as both antediluvianand deeply damaging – was now widely regarded as the appropriate way to deal with footlooseinternational capital.

In view of this experience, and countless otherepisodes, why should we leave our exchange rate – and

THE REAL STERLING CRISIS

124

The Real Sterling Crisis Layout.qxp_Layout 1 19/08/2016 10:47 Page 124

Page 142: The Real Sterling Crisis - Civitascivitas.org.uk/content/files/The-Real-Sterling-Crisis.pdf · The fall in the value of sterling since the vote for Brexit has had commentators wringing

hence our international competitiveness – at the mercyof international capital holders? Of course, if theyshould some day fall out of love with UK assets thenthis would, other things equal, bring about the verydrop in sterling that this pamphlet is advocating. But bythe time that this happens huge damage may have beendone to the UK’s manufacturing and exportingbusinesses. Moreover, as and when international capitalholders pull out, the change may be sudden andunpredictable, thereby causing serious problems in boththe real economy and the financial system. (Arguably,this has already happened with the sharp fall of thepound induced by the Brexit vote.) It would surely befar better to discourage such inflows in the first placeand thereby keep the exchange rate at a competitive andsustainable level.

Why the need for an exchange rate policy can easily be disparaged

1. Most British experience of exchange rate policy hasinvolved trying to stop the pound from falling. Thishas inevitably led to crises as either the limitedstock of international reserves has run low and/orinterest rates have had to be increased, which isboth unpopular and damaging to the domesticeconomy. By contrast, we are advocating a policythat can be used to reduce the pound and keep itlow. This requires being prepared to build upinternational reserves and keeping interest rateslow. Such a policy is much more readily sustainableand much more popular. There is no limit to theamount of your own currency that you can print tobuild up foreign currency reserves.

OBJECTIONS TO A LOWER EXCHANGE RATE POLICY

125

The Real Sterling Crisis Layout.qxp_Layout 1 19/08/2016 10:47 Page 125

Page 143: The Real Sterling Crisis - Civitascivitas.org.uk/content/files/The-Real-Sterling-Crisis.pdf · The fall in the value of sterling since the vote for Brexit has had commentators wringing

2. It is often argued that for the UK to adopt an exchange rate policy would be against ourcommitments to the G7. This is understandable. The obligations have been explicitly stated, as below:

Statement by G7 Finance Ministers and CentralBank Governors, February 12, 2013:‘We, the G7 Ministers and Governors, reaffirm ourlongstanding commitment to market determinedexchange rates and to consult closely in regard toactions in foreign exchange markets. We reaffirmthat our fiscal and monetary policies have been andwill remain oriented towards meeting ourrespective domestic objectives using domesticinstruments, and that we will not target exchangerates. We are agreed that excessive volatility anddisorderly movements in exchange rates can haveadverse implications for economic and financialstability. We will continue to consult closely onexchange markets and cooperate as appropriate.’

G20 Communique, November 15-16, 2015:‘We reaffirm our previous exchange ratecommitments and will resist all forms ofprotectionism.’

Yet of the G7 grouping, three countries, namelyGermany, France and Italy, are involved in a de factopolicy of trying to depreciate the euro in an attemptto stimulate the eurozone economy. A fourth, Japan,is widely acknowledged to be doing the samethrough its policy of QE in pursuit of higherdomestic inflation. Only the three Anglo-Saxoneconomies, the US, Canada and the UK, are left.Neither of the other two have significant currentaccount problems in the way that the UK does.

THE REAL STERLING CRISIS

126

The Real Sterling Crisis Layout.qxp_Layout 1 19/08/2016 10:47 Page 126

Page 144: The Real Sterling Crisis - Civitascivitas.org.uk/content/files/The-Real-Sterling-Crisis.pdf · The fall in the value of sterling since the vote for Brexit has had commentators wringing

3. Operating with a strong exchange rate issuperficially very attractive for a government. Inthe short-term at least, it keeps inflation low,enriches consumers and seems to offer a vote ofconfidence from the markets in the government’spolicies. The latter can seem particularly valuable,and is well appreciated, when governments have ahistory of being plagued by currency weakness andfixed exchange rate crises. This is surely true ofNew Labour. The Labour Party had previouslyendured the gold standard crisis of 1931, thedevaluation of 1949, and the devaluation of 1967. Ithad also witnessed the Conservative Party tearingitself apart after the ERM crisis of 1992. So, to havethe exchange markets apparently approving ofyour policy/country, as they did in the years after1997, was a source of great joy.

4. The language used to describe exchange ratemovements makes it sound as though a highexchange rate is better. Not only do discussionscontrast ‘higher’ with ‘lower’ but currencies areoften described as ‘strengthening’ or ‘weakening’.This language seems to suggest that a higherexchange rate is better.

5. The effects of exchange rate misalignments taketime to come through. Companies do not withdrawfrom markets or dismantle plant – still less investin new markets and new plant – at the drop of a hat.Accordingly, the sharp fluctuations in the UK’s realexchange rate have meant that the response to eventhe periods of low exchange rates has been muchweaker than it might otherwise have been.

OBJECTIONS TO A LOWER EXCHANGE RATE POLICY

127

The Real Sterling Crisis Layout.qxp_Layout 1 19/08/2016 10:47 Page 127

Page 145: The Real Sterling Crisis - Civitascivitas.org.uk/content/files/The-Real-Sterling-Crisis.pdf · The fall in the value of sterling since the vote for Brexit has had commentators wringing

6. It is frequently argued by successful businesses thatthey can ‘cope’ with the current exchange rate. Suchassertions are otiose. We know that they can cope.They are there. They are the survivors. But asuitable exchange rate policy has to cater also forthe businesses that are no longer there – and eventhose that are as yet unborn. The objective ofeconomic management should not be to ensure thehighest average batting score but rather to ensurethe highest score overall. This objective is notsecured by deciding not to play your weakest sixbatsmen on the grounds that they are not as goodas the others.

THE REAL STERLING CRISIS

128

The Real Sterling Crisis Layout.qxp_Layout 1 19/08/2016 10:47 Page 128

Page 146: The Real Sterling Crisis - Civitascivitas.org.uk/content/files/The-Real-Sterling-Crisis.pdf · The fall in the value of sterling since the vote for Brexit has had commentators wringing

Conclusion The case for action

The authors of this pamphlet are far from being enemiesof market forces. On the contrary, both of us aresupporters of the capitalist system and believe that, ingeneral, market forces encourage people andinstitutions to behave in a way that maximises outputand hence living standards.

But, especially in the realm of finance, markets cansometimes go awry. Moreover, market forces do notemerge from a vacuum. They are themselves a responseto the economic conditions of the time and to theconstellation of government and central bank policies,both here and abroad.

Exchange markets are particularly prone tomisalignment with the economic fundamentals. In thewake of the collapse of the Bretton Woods system in1971, many economists argued that the system’scollapse created a brave new world in which marketforces would push exchange rates to levels appropriateto the economic fundamentals.

These hopes were misplaced. The internationalmonetary system is a mess and the misalignment ofexchange rates and huge international paymentsimbalances have been a prime contributor (amongstothers) to the world’s recently poor economic growth.We hope that political leaders will again come to

129

The Real Sterling Crisis Layout.qxp_Layout 1 19/08/2016 10:47 Page 129

Page 147: The Real Sterling Crisis - Civitascivitas.org.uk/content/files/The-Real-Sterling-Crisis.pdf · The fall in the value of sterling since the vote for Brexit has had commentators wringing

develop an international monetary system that dealswith these problems and enables the world to reach itsfull potential. But you shouldn’t hold your breath. Inthe meantime, the UK policy authorities have to fashionpolicy as best they can in the UK’s interests, taking theworld’s monetary system as it is.

For most of the last 100 years the exchange rate hasbeen at the centre of UK economic policy. For the lastquarter century, however, it has been on the periphery.During this period, the UK’s overseas tradingperformance has been poor, with the country runningpersistent current account deficits. The result has beena huge deterioration in the UK’s international financialposition. It has moved from being a substantial netcreditor to being a substantial net debtor. This might notmatter that much if the UK were also investing heavilyat home. But it is not. Indeed, by international standardsit is investing very little.

This situation has not developed as the result of adeliberate policy decision by UK governments. At nostage have the UK authorities deliberately set out to rundown the UK’s international assets or build up the UK’sinternational liabilities. They have simply had no policyon this issue at all. Accordingly, what has happened tothis important variable has simply been the passiveresponse to other factors and policy decisions. The UKauthorities have sleep-walked into a situation where theUK has sold many of its key assets to fund a short-termconsumption binge and continues to grow more andmore in hock to overseas asset holders. This situationhas emerged as the incidental by-product of otherpolicy decisions. The contribution of the UK authoritieshas simply been to ignore it.

THE REAL STERLING CRISIS

130

The Real Sterling Crisis Layout.qxp_Layout 1 19/08/2016 10:47 Page 130

Page 148: The Real Sterling Crisis - Civitascivitas.org.uk/content/files/The-Real-Sterling-Crisis.pdf · The fall in the value of sterling since the vote for Brexit has had commentators wringing

The evidence is clear that the exchange rate for sterlinghas been too high. This has had major consequences forthe whole UK economy and for its future. The strengthof sterling has had three main sources:

(i) The structure of UK macro policies which, unlikethose in most of the rest of the world, takes nodirect account of the exchange rate;

(ii) Policies adopted in our main trading partner, theeurozone, deliberately to depreciate its currency,the euro;

(iii) The attractions of UK assets to overseas wealthholders.

The UK cannot do anything directly to correct thesecond of these. But it can and should take action on theother two. We favour a two-pronged approach: a macropolicy that accords a bigger role for the exchange rate;and a set of micro policies to diminish the attraction ofUK assets to foreigners.

The point of having a more competitive currencywould not be to take market share from rapidlydeveloping countries, such as China or India, still lessto seek to undermine their success. Admittedly, a lowerpound would make UK exports more competitiveagainst China and other emerging market countries,and thereby limit, deter, and even in some cases, reversethe leeching of manufacturing away from the UK.Nevertheless, the rise of the emerging markets has notbeen primarily due to the advantages of operating withan under-valued currency (although at times China hasassuredly done so).

The really striking phenomenon, though, is the UK’sloss of market share relative to other advanced

CONCLUSION: THE CASE FOR ACTION

131

The Real Sterling Crisis Layout.qxp_Layout 1 19/08/2016 10:47 Page 131

Page 149: The Real Sterling Crisis - Civitascivitas.org.uk/content/files/The-Real-Sterling-Crisis.pdf · The fall in the value of sterling since the vote for Brexit has had commentators wringing

countries. Here an over-valued exchange rate hasplayed a definite role – and a competitive exchange ratecould reverse much of the loss.

There is a view that if a low exchange rate is neededfor the UK economy, then the markets will deliver it oftheir own accord. Yet this cannot be taken for granted –even after the sharp drop of the pound after the Brexitvote. We believe that, in the majority of cases, marketforces do work – in the end. But the end can be a verylong time in coming. In the meantime, the damage doneto the economy by a severely misaligned exchange ratecan be very severe. Indeed, the forces that areestablished by a misaligned exchange rate can be soserious that it may be impossible to return to theoriginal growth path for decades subsequently.

Moreover, an exchange rate that is eventually drivenby market forces to roughly the right level will notnecessarily stay there. This is our profound worry afterthe Brexit vote has reduced the pound to a much morecompetitive level. Moreover, businesspeople involvedin exporting and importing will not have the confidencethat it will stay there. Accordingly, even if the exchangerate is established at a competitive level this may nothave the full beneficial effect that it would do if the ratewere believed in.

A policy of deliberately encouraging a competitivevalue for the currency is frequently inhibited by theauthorities’ fear that this may unleash a burst ofinflation. In fact, in many cases those fears areunjustified. They would be unjustified now. The UK isin an era of ultra-low inflation and the Bank of Englandhas evidently had difficulties in getting inflation up toits 2% target. It is hard to imagine a more propitioustime for a successful depreciation of the currency.

THE REAL STERLING CRISIS

132

The Real Sterling Crisis Layout.qxp_Layout 1 19/08/2016 10:47 Page 132

Page 150: The Real Sterling Crisis - Civitascivitas.org.uk/content/files/The-Real-Sterling-Crisis.pdf · The fall in the value of sterling since the vote for Brexit has had commentators wringing

After the Brexit vote produced a much lower exchangerate, many members of the commentariat fretted aboutthe effects of the drop and discussed what theauthorities might need to do to reverse it and ‘stabilisethe pound.’ The right answer is: ‘Nothing at all’. Indeed,the prime task now facing them is how to ensure thatthe pound stays at its new competitive level.

This is the latest – and most pressing – example thatconfirms the fundamental message of this pamphlet: the UK authorities need to put the exchange rate back where it belongs – at the centre of economicpolicy–making.

CONCLUSION: THE CASE FOR ACTION

133

The Real Sterling Crisis Layout.qxp_Layout 1 19/08/2016 10:47 Page 133

Page 151: The Real Sterling Crisis - Civitascivitas.org.uk/content/files/The-Real-Sterling-Crisis.pdf · The fall in the value of sterling since the vote for Brexit has had commentators wringing

The Real Sterling Crisis Layout.qxp_Layout 1 19/08/2016 10:47 Page 134

Page 152: The Real Sterling Crisis - Civitascivitas.org.uk/content/files/The-Real-Sterling-Crisis.pdf · The fall in the value of sterling since the vote for Brexit has had commentators wringing

The Real Sterling Crisis Layout.qxp_Layout 1 19/08/2016 10:47 Page 135

Page 153: The Real Sterling Crisis - Civitascivitas.org.uk/content/files/The-Real-Sterling-Crisis.pdf · The fall in the value of sterling since the vote for Brexit has had commentators wringing

The Real Sterling Crisis Layout.qxp_Layout 1 19/08/2016 10:47 Page 136

Page 154: The Real Sterling Crisis - Civitascivitas.org.uk/content/files/The-Real-Sterling-Crisis.pdf · The fall in the value of sterling since the vote for Brexit has had commentators wringing

£9.00

Institute for the Study of Civil Society

55 Tufton Street, London, SW1P 3QL Tel: 020 7799 6677

Email: [email protected] Web: www.civitas.org.uk

ISBN 978-1-906837-83-9 Cover design: lukejefford.com

T he fall in the value of sterling since the vote for Brexit has had commentatorswringing their hands with concern. But why are so many so quick to assumethat a cheaper pound is a bad thing?

The truth, as leading economists Roger Bootle and John Mills explain here, isthat the British economy has suffered from an overvalued pound for many years.It has restricted exports by making them more expensive and stimulated importsby making them cheaper; it has therefore been a leading cause of the UK’s largecurrent account deficit.

But it has also reduced profits in relation to real wages, which has led to lowerinvestment, lower productivity growth and lower living standards. And becausethe effects of a high exchange rate fall disproportionately on manufacturing thishas helped create an unbalanced economy in which the winners are mostly located in financial services and the South-East.

The real sterling crisis, then, is not that the pound has fallen in recent months –but that it had previously been priced too high for many years.

This was allowed to happen by policymakers overly fixated with keeping downinflation and overly confident that ‘the markets know best’. In fact, markets maysystematically misprice financial variables, as is widely acknowledged now inrelation to equity and property.

In this pamphlet, Bootle and Mills – whose political sympathies, with the Rightand the Left respectively, cross the political divide – argue that the governmentshould now devise a new economic framework that has at its centre an exchange rate policy designed to ensure the pound continues to trade at a competitive level in the years ahead.

They outline the steps that might be undertaken towards such an approach andaddress head on the anxieties many have about a cheaper pound.

‘With the British people having voted to leave the EU, this is an ideal time for thegovernment to pursue an alternative policy framework. Indeed, setting a policythat would establish and maintain a competitive exchange rate for sterling is thesingle most important thing that a government can do for the promotion of aprosperous Britain.’

Roger B

ootle and John M

ills

The Real Sterling CrisisWhy the UK needs a policy to keep the exchange rate down

Roger Bootle and John Mills

Th

e Real S

terling

Crisis

W X