The portfolio ows of international investorsq · The portfolio #ows of international investorsq...

43
q We are grateful to Stan Shelton, Mark Snyder, Matt Conroy, Brian Garvey, Maurice He!ernan, and Lenny Keyser of State Street Bank for their help and support in obtaining data. We are also indebted to Tom Glaessner, Andre H Perold, Linda Tesar, Rene H Stulz, and the referee for helpful comments and conversations. The views expressed here are ours, and we alone bear responsibility for any mistakes and inaccuracies. * Corresponding author. Tel: 617-495-6677; fax: 617-496-7357. E-mail address: kfroot@hbs.edu (K.A. Froot). Journal of Financial Economics 59 (2001) 151}193 The portfolio #ows of international investors q Kenneth A. Froot!,",*, Paul G. J. O'Connell#, Mark S. Seasholes! !Harvard University, Boston, MA 02163 USA "National Bureau of Economics Research, Cambridge, MA 02138 USA #FDO Partners, 5 Revere Street, Cambridge, MA 02138, USA Received 22 July 1998; received in revised form 14 February 2000 Abstract This paper explores daily international portfolio #ows into and out of 44 countries from 1994 through 1998. We "nd several facts concerning the behavior of #ows and their relationship with equity returns. First, we detect regional #ow factors that have increased in importance through time. Second, the #ows appear to be stationary, but far more persistent than returns. Third, #ows are strongly in#uenced by past returns, a "nding consistent with positive feedback trading by international investors. Fourth, in#ows have positive forecasting power for future equity returns, and this power is statistically signi"cant in emerging markets. Fifth, the sensitivity of local stock prices to foreign in#ows is positive and large. Sixth, prices seem consistent with #ow persistence, in that transitory in#ows impact future returns negatively. ( 2001 Elsevier Science S.A. All rights reserved. JEL classixcation: G15; F21; G11 Keywords: International investment; Investor behavior; Portfolio investment; Portfolio #ows 0304-405X/01/$ - see front matter ( 2001 Elsevier Science S.A. All rights reserved. PII: S 0 3 0 4 - 4 0 5 X ( 0 0 ) 0 0 0 8 4 - 2

Transcript of The portfolio ows of international investorsq · The portfolio #ows of international investorsq...

Page 1: The portfolio ows of international investorsq · The portfolio #ows of international investorsq Kenneth A. Froot!,",*, Paul G. J. O’Connell#, Mark S. Seasholes!!Harvard University,

qWe are grateful to Stan Shelton, Mark Snyder, Matt Conroy, Brian Garvey, Maurice He!ernan,and Lenny Keyser of State Street Bank for their help and support in obtaining data. We are alsoindebted to Tom Glaessner, AndreH Perold, Linda Tesar, ReneH Stulz, and the referee for helpfulcomments and conversations. The views expressed here are ours, and we alone bear responsibilityfor any mistakes and inaccuracies.

*Corresponding author. Tel: 617-495-6677; fax: 617-496-7357.

E-mail address: [email protected] (K.A. Froot).

Journal of Financial Economics 59 (2001) 151}193

The portfolio #ows of international investorsq

Kenneth A. Froot!,",*, Paul G. J. O'Connell#,Mark S. Seasholes!

!Harvard University, Boston, MA 02163 USA"National Bureau of Economics Research, Cambridge, MA 02138 USA

#FDO Partners, 5 Revere Street, Cambridge, MA 02138, USA

Received 22 July 1998; received in revised form 14 February 2000

Abstract

This paper explores daily international portfolio #ows into and out of 44 countriesfrom 1994 through 1998. We "nd several facts concerning the behavior of #ows and theirrelationship with equity returns. First, we detect regional #ow factors that have increasedin importance through time. Second, the #ows appear to be stationary, but far morepersistent than returns. Third, #ows are strongly in#uenced by past returns, a "ndingconsistent with positive feedback trading by international investors. Fourth, in#ows havepositive forecasting power for future equity returns, and this power is statisticallysigni"cant in emerging markets. Fifth, the sensitivity of local stock prices to foreignin#ows is positive and large. Sixth, prices seem consistent with #ow persistence, in thattransitory in#ows impact future returns negatively. ( 2001 Elsevier Science S.A. Allrights reserved.

JEL classixcation: G15; F21; G11

Keywords: International investment; Investor behavior; Portfolio investment; Portfolio#ows

0304-405X/01/$ - see front matter ( 2001 Elsevier Science S.A. All rights reserved.PII: S 0 3 0 4 - 4 0 5 X ( 0 0 ) 0 0 0 8 4 - 2

Page 2: The portfolio ows of international investorsq · The portfolio #ows of international investorsq Kenneth A. Froot!,",*, Paul G. J. O’Connell#, Mark S. Seasholes!!Harvard University,

1An important exception to this assertion is Choe et al. (1999). Their work examines all trades onthe Korean stock market from late 1996 through 1997.

1. Introduction

How do international portfolio #ows behave? Do #ows a!ect asset returns?Are emerging market stock prices and exchange rates particularly vulnerable tosuch #ows? These questions have been of perennial interest to investors, eco-nomists, and policy makers, and are posed with greater urgency during times of"nancial upheaval. Frequently, the answers to these questions cast internationalinvestors in a poor light. It is often argued that foreign out#ows lead to priceoverreaction and price contagion. An opposing view, espoused most often by"nancial economists, is that trading is merely the process by which informationis incorporated into asset prices. Out#ows do not create crises, they merelyre#ect the underlying state of fundamentals.

While there are numerous strongly held views, there is surprisingly littleinformation on the behavior of international portfolio #ows and their relation tolocal asset returns. Indeed, what little information there is on aggregate investorpurchases in major capital markets comes from quarterly, or at best monthly,data. For example, Tesar and Werner (1994, 1995a,b), Bohn and Tesar (1996),and Brennan and Cao (1997) examine estimates of aggregate internationalportfolio #ows. They "nd evidence of positive, contemporaneous correlationbetween in#ows and returns. Bohn and Tesar (1996) also "nd evidence that#ows are positively correlated with lagged #ows, and with contemporaneousand lagged measures of expected returns. However, the low frequency of pre-viously available data is a severe limitation, given the poor statistical precision itpermits. Partly as a result of this limitation, few researchers have explored topicsrelated to international #ows, such as the frequency and presence of herding ortrend-following behavior among investors, or the dynamic interaction of inter-national #ows and local asset returns.1

In this paper, we exploit a new and potentially superior source of #ow data tohelp answer these questions. The data come from State Street Bank & Trust, oneof the world's largest custodian banks. Custodians keep detailed records ofworldwide securities holdings, trades, and transaction settlements. State Street'sclients are predominantly large institutional investment pools from developedcountries, including pensions, endowments, mutual funds, and governments.Their clients can be thought of as a large sample of sophisticated internationalinvestors. State Street's aggregated, international settlement data provide uswith net and gross international trades on a daily basis, by country, frommid}1994 through year-end 1998. We are able to track daily gross purchasesinto, and sales out of, as many as 76 countries, although we follow only 44countries in this paper.

152 K.A. Froot et al. / Journal of Financial Economics 59 (2001) 151}193

Page 3: The portfolio ows of international investorsq · The portfolio #ows of international investorsq Kenneth A. Froot!,",*, Paul G. J. O’Connell#, Mark S. Seasholes!!Harvard University,

2Slow incorporation of private information into prices may be the result of informed trader riskaversion, or monopolistic or oligopolistic power. See, for example, Kyle (1985), who derivestransaction costs for a single trader which are quadratic in instantaneous order #ow. See also Frootet al. (1992), who use large, nonstrategic, risk-neutral traders, for a similar result.

Of course, every transaction can be viewed from the perspective of the buyeror the seller. This duality makes the behavior of any #ow data inherentlyambiguous. A randomly selected subsample of buys or sells, is, by de"nition,uncorrelated with similarly obtained subsamples, as well as with returns. Soportfolio #ows in general, and our #ows in particular, are interesting only to theextent that they identify a group that di!ers from other investors. For us, largeinstitutional investors domiciled outside of the local market are that group. Inour data, an in#ow into the local market is de"ned as any purchase bya non-local investor that settles in the local currency. (Typically, local-marketsecurities settle in the local currency. The most commonplace exceptions aredepository receipts that trade and settle in a currency di!erent than the underly-ing shares.) This de"nition of #ow is useful because the pro"le of these transac-tions corresponds closely to the generic de"nition of cross-border #ows. Such#ows are often thought to respond to similar information and misinformation,and, as already mentioned, to give rise to contagion and excessive volatility inlocal-market asset prices.

We put the #ow data to work in a number of ways. First, we examine thebehavior of #ows across countries. We "nd that there is a small, but signi"cant,correlation in contemporaneous cross-country #ows, and that this correlation islarger within regions. We also show how these regional #ow factors have grownover time.

Second, we characterize the #ow data by their persistence. A variety of marketmicrostructure models predict that traders with private information reach theirdesired positions slowly, in order to mitigate transaction costs.2 Thus, the order#ow of informed traders is conditionally, and positively, autocorrelated. Institu-tional factors can also give rise to #ow persistence. For example, structural shiftsin asset allocation can be undertaken on a phased basis. Empirically, we "ndsubstantial evidence that #ows are persistent. We also "nd that gross out#owsare more persistent than gross in#ows.

Third, we examine the covariance of equity returns with cross-border #ows.A major disadvantage of previous studies that use quarterly or monthly data isthat they cannot be precise about whether measured covariance is truly contem-poraneous. The daily data allow for greater precision in determining con-temporaneous versus non}contemporaneous components of quarterlycovariance. We decompose the covariance of quarterly #ows and quarterlyreturns into three components: (a) covariance of #ows and lagged returns; (b) thecovariance of contemporaneous #ows and returns; and (c) the covariance of#ows and future returns.

K.A. Froot et al. / Journal of Financial Economics 59 (2001) 151}193 153

Page 4: The portfolio ows of international investorsq · The portfolio #ows of international investorsq Kenneth A. Froot!,",*, Paul G. J. O’Connell#, Mark S. Seasholes!!Harvard University,

3This "nding is reminiscent of studies of order #ow in other markets. See Warther (1995).Currency results are presented in Froot et al. (1998).

We "nd a statistically positive contemporaneous covariance between netin#ows and both dollar equity and currency returns.3 The data also revealstrong evidence of correlation between net in#ows and lagged equity andcurrency returns, with the sign generally positive. This pattern suggests thatinternational investors engage in positive feedback trading, also called `trendchasing.a Indeed, positive feedback trading behavior, interpreted to mean thatan increase in today's returns leads to an increase in future #ows, withoutholding current and past in#ows constant, seems to explain 60}85% of thequarterly covariance between net in#ows and returns. The #ows are alsocorrelated with future equity and currency returns in emerging markets. Thepredictability of future equity returns explains between 15% and 35% of thecovariance of quarterly returns and #ows. This prediction is consistent withinternational investors having valuable private information on emerging mar-kets. It is also consistent with a story in which price pressure by internationalinvestors, combined with the persistence of their #ows, generates return pre-dictability.

Fourth, we examine the conditional relationships between #ows and returns.This exercise is worthwhile, because the "nding that returns predict futurein#ows may follow from the fact that returns are correlated with current in#owsand, as noted above, in#ows are persistent. In other words, in a world in which#ows are autocorrelated and current #ows move current prices, returns willpredict #ows. In this setting, a more stringent de"nition of trend-chasing wouldlook for predictability of future in#ows over and above that implied by pastin#ows. Alternatively, if current #ows move current prices and if prices arepositively autocorrelated, as we demonstrate to be true of emerging markets,then in#ows are likely to predict returns. This reasoning gives rise to thequestion of whether in#ows can predict returns after conditioning for the e!ectsof past returns.

Using a bivariate VAR model to test these relationships, we "nd that returnshelp to predict #ows over and above the predictability of past #ows. So thetrend-chasing characteristic of the data meets the more stringent test. Past #owsalso remain important for predicting future #ows once lagged returns areincluded. However, the statistical signi"cance of lagged returns falls consider-ably. On the prediction of returns, we "nd that emerging market returns arepredicted by the #ows, after taking into account past returns. The direction ofthis e!ect is the same for developed countries, but with little statistical signi"-cance. One possibility is that the noise in #ows allows lagged for developedcountry returns to pick up any predictive element in the #ows that is incorpor-ated into past return data.

154 K.A. Froot et al. / Journal of Financial Economics 59 (2001) 151}193

Page 5: The portfolio ows of international investorsq · The portfolio #ows of international investorsq Kenneth A. Froot!,",*, Paul G. J. O’Connell#, Mark S. Seasholes!!Harvard University,

Of course, by using the data alone, we can only verify association, notcausality. To understand the implications of a speci"c causal structure, we layout a simple model. In this model, in#ows are driven by past #ows and pastreturns, while returns are driven by current and past #ows. This speci"cationseems reasonable and useful, and allows us to incorporate the commonlyobserved autocorrelation properties of index returns as an endogenous featureof the model. Using this tool, we can trace out the dynamic impact on prices andportfolio holdings of exogenous shocks to in#ows and returns.

Our main "nding here is that the impact of contemporaneous #ows on returnsis strongly signi"cant. Furthermore, we "nd that if the exogenous #ow istransitory, prices tend to decline once the in#ow recedes. In other words, a shockto #ows appears to generate expectations of additional future #ows. The currentprice increase seems to re#ect this expectation, leading to larger increases inanticipation of further future #ows. If the future in#ows do not materialize, thenprices decline. No actual net out#ow is required.

Finally, our data have implications for the recent crisis in Asia. The datareveal that international investors did not abandon emerging markets duringthe crisis. In fact, they remained net buyers of emerging market equities over theJuly 1997}July 1998 period, though at a reduced rate. Daily in#ows into allemerging markets averaged 40% of their pre-crisis (1994}1997) levels, while forAsia the ratio was 30%. This fact may appear puzzling in view of the steepdecline that took place in the equity prices of emerging markets. However, itdovetails with our interpretation of the structural model above. The persistencethat characterizes #ows suggests that prices in the region had been bid up inanticipation of future in#ows. When these in#ows failed to materialize, pricesdeclined.

The rest of the paper is organized as follows. Section 2 provides a briefsummary of related literature. Section 3 discusses the data in more detail, andprovides summary statistics and variance ratios of #ows. Section 4 examines thecorrelation of returns and #ows. It begins by distinguishing several hypothesesof interest, then presents covariance ratios used to test these hypotheses. Ourbivariate, vector auto-regressions are then presented in Section 5. Section 6concludes.

2. Related literature

There are two main areas of work on which this paper builds. The closest isprobably the small literature focused on international portfolio #ows, whichincludes Tesar and Werner (1994, 1995a,b), Bohn and Tesar (1996), and Brennanand Cao (1997). These papers document positive contemporaneous correlationsbetween in#ows and dollar stock returns. There is mixed evidence of correlationbetween in#ows and developed country exchange rates in Brennan and Cao

K.A. Froot et al. / Journal of Financial Economics 59 (2001) 151}193 155

Page 6: The portfolio ows of international investorsq · The portfolio #ows of international investorsq Kenneth A. Froot!,",*, Paul G. J. O’Connell#, Mark S. Seasholes!!Harvard University,

4See also Lakonishok et al. (1992), and Grinblatt et al. (1995).

(1997). Because their papers use quarterly data, they present little consistentevidence of non-contemporaneous correlations.

Brennan and Cao (1997) argue that the contemporaneous correlationbetween in#ows and returns may be attributable to international investorsupdating their forecasts with greater frequency than local investors in responseto public information about local markets. If the prior expectations of interna-tional investors are more di!use than those of local investors, suggesting thatinternational investors have a `cumulative informational disadvantage,a thenpositive information releases will cause asset holdings to be reallocated towardinternational investors. Frankel and Schmukler (1996) provide evidence thatlocal market investors have informational advantages over foreign investorsduring times of crisis. They look at Mexican closed-end funds at the time of therecent Mexican crisis, and "nd that changes in net asset values tend to causechanges in fund prices on the NYSE. The implication is that trades in theunderlying shares by local investors led to price changes that were incorporatedlater in international prices.

An open question is whether current #ows move current prices too much,such that they predict returns negatively, or too little, so that they predictreturns positively. Here the evidence from international #ows is scarce. Clarkand Berko (1996) examine Mexico during the late 1980 s through the crisis in1993. They "nd that unexpected in#ows of 1% of the market's capitalizationdrive prices up by 13%. In spite of the large e!ect, there is no evidence ofnon}contemporaneous correlation. Instead, the price change is permanent, andthere is no further predictability.

There is, of course, a much larger empirical literature examining how thecomposition of investors impacts prices (see Stulz, 1997, for a review). Warther(1995) investigates aggregate monthly in#ows into mutual funds and the impactthey have on stock and bond prices. He "nds unexpected increases in in#ows,which appear to be a shock to in#ows beyond that predicted by past in#ows, arecorrelated with contemporaneous returns, but that expected in#ows are not. Hisdata suggest that a 1% increase in mutual fund equity assets results in a 5.7%increase in stock prices. He also "nds no evidence that such price increases aretransitory. A second strand of literature looks at in#ows into US mutual funds.Here again there is little evidence of non}contemporaneous correlation between#ows and returns.

Wermers (1999) examines the extent of herding by institutional investors inU.S. stocks.4 He "nds that there is considerably greater herding in stocks thathave experienced extreme returns in the prior quarter, with buy-side herdingoccurring most often in stocks that had past extreme positive returns, andsell-side herding occurring most often in stocks that had past extreme negative

156 K.A. Froot et al. / Journal of Financial Economics 59 (2001) 151}193

Page 7: The portfolio ows of international investorsq · The portfolio #ows of international investorsq Kenneth A. Froot!,",*, Paul G. J. O’Connell#, Mark S. Seasholes!!Harvard University,

returns. This "nding is reminiscent of our "ndings of positive-feedback trading.Wermers also "nds that stocks that are purchased in herds have higher sub-sequent quarter returns, and that stocks sold in herds have lower subsequentquarter returns. This "nding is consistent with our results in emerging markets,and suggests that the co-movement of contemporaneous #ows and prices isattributable to private information on the part of institutional investors.Wermers assumes that the private information is about fundamentals because,like us, he "nds no "rm evidence of reversals. We would caution against thisinterpretation, however. If non-fundamental information, like demand shocks, isincorporated relatively quickly into prices, but is dispersed slowly, then stan-dard tests will have little ability to discern private information on fundamentalsfrom price pressure related to #ows (see, for example, Hirshleifer et al., 1994).

Finally, there is considerable evidence in other markets that investor #owsdrive prices. For example, Froot and O'Connell (1997) study catastrophe riskprices and "nd that #uctuations in investor risk-bearing capacity can driveprices away from estimates of fair value. Gompers and Lerner (2000) providesimilar evidence for private equity. As noted above, if prices shoot up in responseto #ows, such e!ects are di$cult to discern in short time series samples of shortduration, such as the one used in this paper.

3. Data

Our #ow data di!er in a number of respects from those used in previousstudies. The data are derived from proprietary information provided by StateStreet Bank & Trust (SSB). SSB is the largest U.S. master trust bank, the largestU.S. mutual fund custodian, with nearly 40% of the industry's funds undercustody, and one of the world's largest global custodians. It has approximately$6 trillion of assets under custody. SSB records all transactions in these secur-ities. From this database, we distinguish cross-border transactions by observingthe currency in which the transactions are settled. For example, transactionsthat are settled in Thai baht encompass purchases and sales of Thai equities, andbaht-denominated debt, transacted by SSB clients. To produce our data, SSBhas extracted all transactions that settle in baht, and removed from them anytransactions initiated by Thai investors. Our measure of cross-border #ows istherefore that of transactions by non-local SSB clients in local securities.

The data identify daily cross-border #ows for 44 countries, of which 16 aredeveloped countries, and 28 are emerging markets. We divide the 44 countriesinto 5 exhaustive categories. These categories are Developed Countries, LatinAmerica, Emerging East Asia, Emerging Europe, and Other Emerging Coun-tries. Developed countries include Australia, Austria, Canada, Denmark, Fin-land, Germany, Ireland, Italy, Japan, Netherlands, New Zealand, Norway,Spain, Sweden, Switzerland, and the U.K. Latin America includes Mexico,

K.A. Froot et al. / Journal of Financial Economics 59 (2001) 151}193 157

Page 8: The portfolio ows of international investorsq · The portfolio #ows of international investorsq Kenneth A. Froot!,",*, Paul G. J. O’Connell#, Mark S. Seasholes!!Harvard University,

Venezuela, Columbia, Peru, Brazil, Argentina, and Chile. Emerging East Asiaincludes Korea, Hong Kong, Taiwan, Philippines, Indonesia, Singapore,Malaysia, Thailand, Pakistan, and India. Emerging Europe includes CzechRepublic, Greece, Hungary, Poland, Portugal, and Turkey. Finally, OtherEmerging Countries are Egypt, Israel, Morocco, South Africa, and Zimbabwe.There are two additional groups, World and All Emerging Markets, thataggregate the above categories. World includes all aforementioned regions, andAll Emerging Markets includes Latin America, East Asia, Emerging Europe,and Other Emerging countries.

These data contain over $960 billion in equity purchases and sales. The dataseparately track daily purchases and sales of equities. For each country, we havethe dollar value of these four measures plus the number of transactions each day.The data begin on August 1, 1994 and continue through December 31, 1998.

Since these data use the currency of settlement as a reference point, they di!erin a number of ways from data used in previous studies. Other work uses datafrom the U.S. Treasury, which reports equity and debt purchases by U.S. entitieswith non-U.S. entities on a quarterly basis. In addition to the higher frequencyof our data, the Treasury data may also miss or misreport the transactions offoreign-based "rms or intermediaries trading on behalf of U.S. investors. Con-sider, for example, a U.S. mutual fund family that has received a deposit into oneof its international stock funds (see Levich, 1994). If this fund purchases foreignequity directly, then the purchase is re#ected in the Treasury accounts. But if themutual fund "rst transfers the deposit to its a$liate in London, which in turnexecutes a third-country equity transaction, then the Treasury data will miss theequity purchase. Furthermore, the data may also misidentify the country receiv-ing the in#ow. In this example, the in#ow from the Treasury's perspective is intothe U.K., even if the ultimate shares are purchased in other countries.

Our data present a signi"cant improvement on this scenario. However, theyalso share several weaknesses with other sources, and these weaknesses shouldbe kept in mind. First, a U.S. mutual fund will show up as the investor in thesecurities ultimately purchased. If the securities happened to be, for example,Thai stocks, then the data will record a U.S. in#ow into Thailand. But clearly, ifthe mutual fund is a Thai equity fund, and if the purchase came from a depositmade by a Thai resident into that fund, then our data would misrepresent theforeign source of the #ow. As a result, the degree of discretion exercised by thefund manager versus the bene"ciary, of unknown origin, is unclear.

A second issue concerns American Depository Receipts (ADRs), and, ina related way, all international equity-linked derivatives. As is well known,ADRs settle in U.S. dollars on a U.S. exchange. So purchases of, say, Thai stockADRs are not counted in our data as #ows into Thailand. However, in mostinstances there is active arbitrage between the local Thai stocks and the U.S.ADRs. This arbitrage makes available su$cient ADR supply in the U.S. to keepthe price essentially equal to that prevailing in Thailand. Thus, net ADR

158 K.A. Froot et al. / Journal of Financial Economics 59 (2001) 151}193

Page 9: The portfolio ows of international investorsq · The portfolio #ows of international investorsq Kenneth A. Froot!,",*, Paul G. J. O’Connell#, Mark S. Seasholes!!Harvard University,

purchases will be funded by some entity going to the local market to buy anequivalent amount of local Thai stock. As a result, the problem with our data is notso much that we leave out ADRs, but that the entity doing the arbitrage is notnecessarily a State Street client. Other equity-linked derivatives, including forward,futures, options, and structured notes, raise exactly the same set of issues. Thebottom line here is that it is perfectly consistent to measure purchases and sales onlyof underlying securities, and to exclude derivatives. However, the Achilles heel ofthis strategy is that small deviations in the makeup of the investor base mayresult in #ows that di!er markedly from total #ows across all foreign investors.

A third important issue is that we receive the #ows dated as of their contrac-tual settlement date, rather than their actual trade date. Since it is the trade datethat is of interest, we must construct it by working backward from contractualsettlement date. To do this calculation, we use the settlement conventions ofeach country. These conventions are easily documented, and are detailed inTable 1. As a result, all tests conducted in this paper use trade dates. However, itis very important to emphasize that we record #ows on the contractual and notthe actual settlement date. While late settlement is a serious problem in manycontexts, a!ecting approximately 10% of developed-country trades and 20% ofemerging-market trades, our dating conventions are immune to late settlements,since the contractual settlement date is established at the time of trade accordingto the settlement conventions of each country. A side e!ect of this issue is thatour data include trades that ultimately fail to settle. Failed settlement a!ectsa very small percentage of trades, and, in any case, it is unclear whether thisdrawback presents a signi"cant problem for us. The information content andprice impact of a trade may be the same regardless of whether it ultimately fails,and failure often occurs after a considerable time lapse. However, to the extentthat failed trades engender additional transactions, such failures could result ina slight upward bias in estimates of #ow persistence.

A fourth important issue concerns the representativeness of these data,prompting the question of how similar State Street's client trades are to those ofother international investors. There are several points to discuss. First, even ifa well-de"ned group of investors is not representative of all internationalinvestors, observing the #ows that arise from the group's trader can lead tointeresting conclusions. For example, the collected #ows of the ten smartest, orthe ten dumbest, cross-border traders would be interesting to review preciselybecause they are not representative. What makes a collection of investorsinteresting, in principal, is that they are relatively more homogenous amongthemselves than they are with other investors, and that there are interestinginteractions between their trades over time, across countries, and with returns.

Second, and not withstanding the previous point, it is still interesting to knowhow representative the SSB data might be, by comparing the size and magnitudeof our #ows to cross-border aggregates. Naturally, as we have already discussed,we would not expect perfect correlation. After all, the SSB data account for only

K.A. Froot et al. / Journal of Financial Economics 59 (2001) 151}193 159

Page 10: The portfolio ows of international investorsq · The portfolio #ows of international investorsq Kenneth A. Froot!,",*, Paul G. J. O’Connell#, Mark S. Seasholes!!Harvard University,

Table 1Settlement, turnover, and SSB holdings, 1997

This table presents settlement conventions, and a comparison of State Street Bank (SSB) #ows andcustody holdings with exchange turnover and market capitalization for 1997. Settlement andholdings data are provided by State Street Bank & Trust. Market capitalization and turnover dataare taken from the IFC Emerging Stock Markets Factbook 1999, for the end-of-year 1997. Thecorrelation coe$cient for both stock and #ow variables is shown for each region. The "rst datacolumn presents the settlement period for each country. The `*a indicates di!erent settlementconvention for buys and sells, with the "rst number showing the period for buys and the secondnumber showing the period for sells. The settlement period is used to change data marked witha settlement date to trade date by subtracting the correct number of days. Data shown is for the 1998settlement period, in U.S. $ millions.

Region

Contractualsettlement

periodExchangeturnover

SSBgross trades

Exchangemarket

capitalizationSSB

holdings

Developed MarketsAustralia T#5 310,869 12,149 696,656 24,201Austria T#3 24,630 1,308 35,724 1,047Canada T#3 355,585 7,955 567,635 46,743Denmark T#3 46,878 1,948 93,766 2,045Finland T#3 36,368 3,308 73,322 4,976Germany T#2 1,029,152 25,364 825,233 21,791Ireland T#5 15,168 660 24,135 NAItaly T#5/10* NA 10,776 344,665 NAJapan T#3 1,251,750 57,938 2,216,699 45,345Netherlands T#3 284,869 15,146 468,736 17,358New Zealand T#5 24,648 1,292 90,483 1,237Norway T#3 46,421 2,351 66,503 1,396Spain T#3 453,016 6,259 290,383 6,788Sweden T#3 176,172 10,614 272,730 9,802Switzerland T#3 494,912 16,577 575,338 21,916U.K. T#5 829,131 43,219 1,996,225 84,373

Correlations:Turnover and trades 0.92Market capitalizationand holdings 0.86

Latin AmericaArgentina T#3 25,702 685 59,252 614Brazil T#3 203,260 8,404 255,478 1,589Chile T#2 7,445 37 72,046 74Colombia T#3 1,894 227 19,530 71Mexico T#2 52,646 3,360 156,595 1,936Peru T#3 4,033 176 17,586 115Venezuela T#5 3,858 126 14,581 17

Correlations:Turnover and trades 0.99Market capitalizationand holdings 0.87

160 K.A. Froot et al. / Journal of Financial Economics 59 (2001) 151}193

Page 11: The portfolio ows of international investorsq · The portfolio #ows of international investorsq Kenneth A. Froot!,",*, Paul G. J. O’Connell#, Mark S. Seasholes!!Harvard University,

Table 1 (continued)

Region

Contractualsettlement

periodExchangeturnover

SSBgross trades

Exchangemarket

capitalizationSSB

holdings

Emerging East AsiaHong Kong T#2 489,365 18,330 413,770 7,122Indonesia T#4 41,650 3,200 29,105 362Korea T#2 170,237 2,726 41,881 1,335Malaysia T#5/4* 147,036 6,783 93,608 825Philippines T#4 19,783 1,919 31,361 624Singapore T#5 63,954 4,909 106,317 2,561Taiwan T#1 1,297,474 1,093 287,813 982Thailand T#3 23,119 2,793 23,538 524

Correlations:Turnover and trades 0.04Market capitalizationand holdings 0.80

Emerging EuropeCzech Republic T#3 7,055 321 12,786 236Greece T#3 21,146 885 34,164 1,156Hungary T#5 7,684 375 14,700 151Poland T#3 7,977 422 12,135 232Portugal T#4 20,932 1,946 38,954 1,914Turkey T#2 59,105 964 61,090 769

Correlations:Turnover and trades 0.38Market capitalizationand holdings 0.59

Other Emerging MarketsEgypt T#4/2* 5,859 320 20,830 245India T#5 53,954 737 128,466 666Israel T#0 10,727 285 45,268 279Morocco T#3 1,048 53 12,177 99Pakistan T#7 11,476 205 10,966 63South Africa T#5 44,893 2,950 232,069 2,058Zimbabwe T#7 532 61 1,969 12

Correlations:Turnover and trades 0.69Market capitalizationand holdings 0.97

12% of the world's securities, and we employ a di!erent de"nition of cross-border #ows than used by other sources of aggregated data. In order tounderstand how representative the data are, we collected monthly net equity#ows for Japan and Thailand. Japan was selected because the Ministry ofFinance is relatively careful in its collection process, and because the data are

K.A. Froot et al. / Journal of Financial Economics 59 (2001) 151}193 161

Page 12: The portfolio ows of international investorsq · The portfolio #ows of international investorsq Kenneth A. Froot!,",*, Paul G. J. O’Connell#, Mark S. Seasholes!!Harvard University,

available monthly rather than quarterly. Among developing countries, Thailandprovides a good example of an emerging market with relatively free capitalmobility and currency convertibility.

Fig. 1 compares the monthly net equity #ow data from Japan and Thailandwith the SSB data set. In the "rst graph, it is clear that the aggregate in#owsrecorded by the Japanese Ministry of Finance are highly correlated at themonthly level with the State Street #ows. For this comparison, the correlationcoe$cient is 0.75. Such a high level of #ow correlation is striking, particularly fora country like Japan. The rich diversity of foreign investors might lead oneforeign investor to trade with another, rather than with local investors, so thattrades made by foreign investors, as a group, are less correlated. This scenario isless likely in emerging markets, where diversity of foreign investors is morelimited. As can be seen from the lower panel of Fig. 1, the correlation forThailand is approximately 68%.

To shed further light on the representativeness of the data, we can examinehow State Street's trade volume and aggregate holdings compare to localmarket turnover and capitalization. The "rst panel of Fig. 2 compares #ows byplotting the cross-section of gross State Street trades, aggregating buys plussells, against total turnover on each country's principal exchange. It is apparentfrom the "gure that the correlation between the two is very high, at 0.89. PanelB of Fig. 2 compares holdings by plotting total State Street custody holdingsagainst the aggregate market capitalization in each country at the end of 1997.Again, the correlation between the two is striking, at 0.91. Table 1 presents thedata underlying these "gures.

To scale the #ows, denoted by Fi,t

, we divide by local market capitalization,M

i,t, so scaled #ows are denoted by f

i,t"F

i,t/M

i,t. While we observe separate

variables for purchases of local equity, sales of local equity, purchases of localdebt, and sales of local debt, we focus primarily on net equity transactions, orpurchases less sales. To measure equity-market capitalization, we use MSCIindexes for 43 of the 44 countries. The exception is Zimbabwe, for which weemploy a broad market index. A complete list of the equity index names is givenin Table 2. We obtained daily currency prices against the U.S. dollar, usingWM/Reuters rates, from Datastream.

4. The behavior of portfolio 6ows

In this section, we examine the univariate behavior of the #ows.

4.1. Descriptive statistics

Table 3 provides general information about the SSB data set. Total transac-tions, the aggregate of buys plus sells, sum over $960 billion, from over 3.8

162 K.A. Froot et al. / Journal of Financial Economics 59 (2001) 151}193

Page 13: The portfolio ows of international investorsq · The portfolio #ows of international investorsq Kenneth A. Froot!,",*, Paul G. J. O’Connell#, Mark S. Seasholes!!Harvard University,

Fig. 1. Comparability of State Street data. The cross-border trades by institutions that use StateStreet Bank & Trust are representative of all cross-border #ows into a given market. Below are twographs that compare the net monthly #ows, calculated as buys less sells, from State Street's clientswith #ows reported by an entire market. The "rst graph uses data provided by the Ministry ofFinance in Japan. The second graph uses data from the Stock Exchange of Thailand. Both sourcestrack all foreign #ows into and out of the local stock markets. The data series have correlationcoe$cients of 74.9% and 68.1%, respectively, within the State Street data.

K.A. Froot et al. / Journal of Financial Economics 59 (2001) 151}193 163

Page 14: The portfolio ows of international investorsq · The portfolio #ows of international investorsq Kenneth A. Froot!,",*, Paul G. J. O’Connell#, Mark S. Seasholes!!Harvard University,

Fig. 2. Worldwide stock market turnover and capitalization compared to State Street trades andholdings. The "rst "gure plots 1997 stock exchange turnover by country, against total cross-bordertrades, aggregating buys plus sells, in 1997 by clients of State Street Bank. All data are in $U.S millions.The data from this graph are from State Street Bank and the IFC. This plot corresponds to the "rst twodata columns in Table 1. The second "gure plots 1997 stock exchange market capitalization by countryagainst total holdings of foreign equities in 1997 by clients of State Street Bank. All data are in $U.S.millions. The data for the second graph are from State Street Bank and the IFC. This plot corresponds todata columns three and four in Table 1. Note: Ireland and Italy are not shown. Panel A: State Street grosstrades vs. stock exchange turnover Panel B: State Street gross holdings vs. exchange market capitalization.

million transactions during the sample period. The daily average of totaltransactions during the sample period is $832 million. The largest number ofthese cross-border transactions took place in Japan, followed by the U.K. andHong Kong. While there are 76 transactions on average per day per country,

164 K.A. Froot et al. / Journal of Financial Economics 59 (2001) 151}193

Page 15: The portfolio ows of international investorsq · The portfolio #ows of international investorsq Kenneth A. Froot!,",*, Paul G. J. O’Connell#, Mark S. Seasholes!!Harvard University,

Table 2Regions, countries, and indexes

This table shows the regional grouping of countries used in this paper. By grouping the countriesinto regions, we can compare trends in di!erent types of markets. A major comparison categoryused is developed markets vs. emerging markets. Emerging markets, as a category, aggregatesLatin America and all other emerging market categories. This table also shows the equityindex used. In every case except Zimbabwe, the index is from Morgan Stanley (MSCI). Theindex is in local currency and is converted to $U.S. by multiplying by the appropriateexchange rate. Exchange rates are from the WMR/Reuters database, and are obtained throughDatastream.

Region Equity index

Developed marketsAustralia MSCI } Australia Price IndexAustria MSCI } Austria Price IndexCanada MSCI } Canada Price IndexDenmark MSCI } Denmark Price IndexFinland MSCI } Finland Price IndexGermany MSCI } Germany Price IndexIreland MSCI } Ireland Price IndexItaly MSCI } Italy Price IndexJapan MSCI } Japan Price IndexNetherlands MSCI } Netherlands Price IndexNew Zealand MSCI } New Zealand Price IndexNorway MSCI } Norway Price IndexSpain MSCI } Spain Price IndexSweden MSCI } Sweden Price IndexSwitzerland MSCI } Switzerland Price IndexU.K. MSCI } U.K. Price Index

Latin AmericaArgentina MSCI } Argentina Price IndexBrazil MSCI } Brazil Price IndexChile MSCI } Chile Price IndexColombia MSCI } Colombia Price IndexMexico MSCI } Mexico Free Price IndexPeru MSCI } Peru Price IndexVenezuela MSCI } Venezuela Price Index

Emerging East AsiaHong Kong MSCI } Hong Kong Price IndexIndonesia MSCI } Indonesia Free Price IndexKorea MSCI } Korea Price IndexMalaysia MSCI } Malaysia Free Price IndexPhilippines MSCI } Philippines Free Price IndexSingapore MSCI } Singapore Free Price IndexTaiwan MSCI } Taiwan Price IndexThailand MSCI } Thailand Free Price Index

K.A. Froot et al. / Journal of Financial Economics 59 (2001) 151}193 165

Page 16: The portfolio ows of international investorsq · The portfolio #ows of international investorsq Kenneth A. Froot!,",*, Paul G. J. O’Connell#, Mark S. Seasholes!!Harvard University,

Table 2 (continued)

Region Equity index

Emerging EuropeCzech Republic MSCI } Czech. Republic Price IndexGreece MSCI } Greece Price IndexHungary MSCI } Hungary Price IndexPoland MSCI } Poland Price IndexPortugal MSCI } Portugal Price IndexTurkey MSCI } Turkey Price Index

Other emerging marketsEgypt MSCI } Egypt Price IndexIndia MSCI } India Price IndexIsrael MSCI } Israel Price IndexMorocco MSCI } Morocco Price IndexPakistan MSCI } Pakistan Price IndexSouth Africa MSCI } South Africa Price IndexZimbabwe Zimbabwe SE Industrials Price Index

our least active countries, Zimbabwe and Morocco, average only about onetransaction per day.

Overall, the transactions account for a net average daily in#ow of $96 million,or approximately $2.2 million into each of our 44 countries. This comes from$20 million into emerging markets, predominantly into Latin America and EastAsia, and $77 million into developed countries. The average trade size rangesbetween about $100,000, for Venezuela, Peru, and Turkey, to about $450,000 forSwitzerland, Germany, and the Netherlands. The standard deviation of tradesize is very large for Brazil, for which we have a small number of very largetransactions in the spring of 1997. But for most countries, the average trade sizeand standard deviation of average daily trade size are a few hundred thousanddollars. We did not exclude or censor any data in our analysis.

Table 4 shows these same descriptive measures for the Tequila and Asiancrises. The rapid growth of the #ows plus the longer Asian crisis leads to total#ows that are nearly an order of magnitude larger for the latter subperiod, whencompared to the overall #ow data. In addition, average trade sizes, particularlythose in emerging markets, have grown considerably since the prior subperiod.

4.2. The cross-correlation of yows

We begin by looking at the correlation matrix of the daily #ows. Fig. 3 showsa `heat mapa of these correlations, e$ciently summarizing nearly 1000 correla-tion coe$cients. Table 5 also provides average pairwise correlation coe$cients

166 K.A. Froot et al. / Journal of Financial Economics 59 (2001) 151}193

Page 17: The portfolio ows of international investorsq · The portfolio #ows of international investorsq Kenneth A. Froot!,",*, Paul G. J. O’Connell#, Mark S. Seasholes!!Harvard University,

by region. It is evident from the "gure and table that the #ow correlations aresmall, but consistently positive. The data strongly reject the hypothesis that thecross correlations are zero. In addition, the correlations are more positive withinregions, particularly in Asia and the European Developed Countries, andsomewhat in Latin America.

It is also useful to compare Fig. 3 with a similar heat map of stock returncorrelations, all reported in U.S. dollars. These stock return correlations areshown in Fig. 4. The regional character of stock returns is far more evident inFig. 4, such that even a small amount of regionalism in #ows appears associatedwith very strong regional return patterns. Note that countries with the lowest#ow correlations with other countries, like the middle-eastern countries, alsoappear to have the lowest return correlations.

It is also interesting that the regional correlations of #ows have increasedsubstantially over time. This pattern is very noticeable in the Asian crisis period,in comparison with the Tequila crisis in Latin America in late 1994 and early1995. The correlation coe$cients can be seen in Table 5, which shows substan-tial increases in every region during the Asian crisis. Note, however, that it ispossible that some of this increase may be attributed to the higher volatility ofreturns during that period (see Forbes and Rigobon, 1999). We doubt this e!ectis substantial, however, because return correlations and volatility also increasedsubstantially in the Tequila crisis period. As a result, it appears that theimportance of regional #ow factors have indeed increased over time.

In view of these regional factors, it is worth comparing how these factorsappear across regions. This comparison is presented in Fig. 5. Fig. 5 depictscumulative in#ows into each of the two major regions, Developed and Emerg-ing, while Panel B of Fig. 5 graphs the two most important emerging regions,East Asia and Latin America. All series are market-capitalization weightedaverages of the underlying country #ows.

The "gures serve to make several points. First, over the sample period, SSBinvestors purchased the same amount, approximately 1%, of both emerging-market and developed-country capitalization. Second, the timeline helps discernthat there are actually three crisis periods during this sample, which are theMexican peso `Tequilaa crisis, the Asian crisis, and the Russian/LTCM crisis.These crises are clearly visible in both the emerging and developed countryin#ows. The Tequila crisis begins with Mexico's sudden devaluation in Decem-ber 1994, and continues through the Spring of 1995. The Asian crisis begins withThailand's devaluation in July 1997, and continues through the Spring of 1998.Finally, there is a crisis in late Summer 1998, with Russia devaluing the ruble inAugust and LTCM failing in September. All crisis episodes are clearly asso-ciated with a strong attenuation of in#ows in general, and of emerging marketin#ows in particular. It appears that foreign investors held fast during theMexican crisis, slightly withdrew some resources in the midst of the Asian crisis,and were hardly fazed by the Brazilian crisis. Interestingly, the LTCM failure

K.A. Froot et al. / Journal of Financial Economics 59 (2001) 151}193 167

Page 18: The portfolio ows of international investorsq · The portfolio #ows of international investorsq Kenneth A. Froot!,",*, Paul G. J. O’Connell#, Mark S. Seasholes!!Harvard University,

Tab

le3

Des

crip

tive

stat

istics

for

inte

rnal#ow

dat

a

The

sam

ple

cons

ists

ofcr

oss

-bor

der

equi

ty#ow

sfrom

Aug

ust

1,19

94to

Dec

embe

r31

,199

8re

pres

enting

1,15

4tr

adin

gday

s.T

heda

taar

eder

ived

from

prop

riet

ary

dat

apro

vide

dby

Stat

eSt

reet

Ban

k&

Tru

st.D

aily#ow

sar

eco

nver

ted

to$U

.S.a

tth

edai

lyex

chan

gera

te.T

he"rs

ttw

odat

aco

lum

nsre

port

the

tota

lvol

um

eoft

rade

sin

$U.S

.mill

ionsan

dnu

mber

oft

rades

.The

third,

fourt

h,an

d"fth

dat

aco

lum

nsre

port

net

trad

ing

activi

ty,i

n$

000,

wher

ene

ttr

adin

gis

de"

ned

asbuy

sm

inus

sells

.Dat

aco

lum

n"ve

divi

des

the

net

amou

nttr

aded

each

day

by

the

prev

ious

day's

mar

ketca

pita

lizat

ion

topr

oduce

aunitle

ssnum

ber,

whic

hw

ere

port

inbas

ispoi

nts

or

hundr

edth

sof

aper

cent.

The

aver

age

frac

tion

ofnet

trad

espe

rday

within

are

gion

isth

esim

ple

aver

age

ofc

ount

ries

within

the

regi

on.T

he"nal

two

colu

mnsre

por

tth

eav

erag

edai

lytr

ade

size

and

the

asso

ciat

edst

andar

dde

viat

ion.A

list

ofc

ountr

ies

and

regi

ons

isgi

ven

inTab

le1.

Reg

ion

Tot

aleq

uity

Tota

leq

uity

tran

sact

ions

Ave

rage

dai

lyne

teq

uity

Stan

dar

dde

viat

ion

Dai

lyne

ttr

ades

tom

arke

tca

p.D

aily

aver

age

trad

esize

Stan

dar

ddev

iation

Pan

elA

:R

egio

nal

aggr

egat

esW

orld

961,

270

3,87

0,00

097

,260

169,

750

0.11

221

5,87

029

8,94

0D

evel

oped

count

ries

768,

870

2,74

8,10

077

,643

143,

390

0.11

628

9,08

029

6,82

0A

llem

ergi

ng

mar

ket

s19

2,40

01,

121,

900

19,6

1761

,168

0.11

016

0,69

028

8,49

0Lat

inA

mer

ica

33,2

1316

2,85

03,

486

42,5

110.

036

154,

730

317,

610

Em

ergi

ngEas

tA

sia

127,

930

773,

990

10,0

7735

,755

0.11

216

8,69

018

9,79

0Em

ergi

ngEuro

pe16

,716

104,

380

2,05

18,

404

0.21

414

8,11

018

0,42

0O

ther

emer

ging

14,5

4380

,644

4,00

38,

281

0.09

416

9,77

048

5,32

0

Pan

elB

:In

divi

dual

coun

trie

sA

rgen

tina

2,38

717

,834

139

1,86

90.

039

137,

740

219,

660

Aust

ralia

34,0

6318

7,72

02,

954

13,6

190.

066

201,

640

131,

900

Aust

ria

5,31

428

,713

342

4,64

30.

108

204,

760

274,

760

Bra

zil

19,9

6274

,621

2,43

441

,873

0.10

424

3,72

061

5,00

0C

anad

a25

,691

110,

090

1,78

215

,341

0.04

024

6,68

024

1,40

0C

hile

169

1,50

810

043

20.

014

129,

110

217,

300

Colu

mbia

494

4,07

543

616

0.02

711

9,23

013

5,03

0C

zech

Rep

ublic

1,14

16,

814

141

1,58

40.

079

173,

540

239,

790

Den

mar

k7,

135

29,1

2761

04,

798

0.09

828

4,75

031

5,45

0Egy

pt

636

5,10

925

598

30.

166

135,

710

159,

420

Fin

land

12,9

0150

,664

1,18

39,

406

0.15

527

7,89

031

6,81

0

168 K.A. Froot et al. / Journal of Financial Economics 59 (2001) 151}193

Page 19: The portfolio ows of international investorsq · The portfolio #ows of international investorsq Kenneth A. Froot!,",*, Paul G. J. O’Connell#, Mark S. Seasholes!!Harvard University,

Ger

man

y87

,795

217,

210

7,23

739

,268

0.10

239

8,61

032

9,81

0G

reec

e3,

392

20,4

5841

84,

424

0.15

814

0,87

015

4,31

0H

ong

Kon

g53

,931

254,

660

1,09

325

,234

0.03

420

4,55

010

2,62

0H

ung

ary

1,08

47,

394

158

1,17

30.

356

159,

530

243,

640

Indi

a2,

117

11,5

8136

62,

358

0.02

418

6,70

020

6,91

0In

dones

ia7,

664

65,9

781,

078

3,50

30.

158

110,

780

77,3

68Ir

elan

d1,

007

8,67

923

81,

477

0.05

812

7,03

013

5,43

0Is

rael

2,54

513

,800

681

2,46

90.

385

223,

950

354,

730

Ital

y38

,362

132,

760

4,34

921

,247

0.16

124

4,03

027

7,89

0Ja

pan

209,

180

911,

850

26,4

1374

,969

0.08

123

7,89

013

6,97

0K

ore

a8,

662

45,6

111,

838

7,64

90.

170

212,

300

223,

730

Mal

aysia

21,4

3815

8,16

01,

648

10,1

170.

067

143,

090

105,

300

Mex

ico

9,15

853

,843

809

4,90

70.

076

168,

660

127,

720

Mor

occo

227

1,69

2!

1146

20.

013

161,

500

217,

370

Net

herlan

ds

51,5

4212

4,56

03,

240

21,9

970.

082

412,

660

252,

490

New

Zea

land

4,65

432

,445

177

3,90

60.

050

167,

080

179,

360

Norw

ay8,

456

41,3

1654

95,

051

0.12

823

9,51

037

9,95

0Pak

ista

n50

94,

722

231

846

0.21

012

9,38

027

7,27

0Per

u76

07,

447

!60

666

!0.

033

104,

720

125,

860

Phili

ppi

nes

5,45

953

,264

1,22

12,

946

0.18

610

8,72

088

,647

Pola

nd1,

286

11,6

7819

11,

197

0.26

311

1,16

010

1,00

0Port

ugal

6,66

730

,636

830

5,99

10.

313

202,

490

188,

860

Singa

pore

17,9

1311

0,29

01,

325

7,42

60.

100

170,

100

109,

320

South

Afric

a9,

906

47,7

242,

907

7,32

00.

116

245,

270

973,

750

Spai

n24

,207

83,1

0988

212

,044

0.04

030

3,28

039

9,29

0Sw

eden

39,9

5611

5,01

01,

673

17,3

730.

116

367,

770

252,

240

Switze

rlan

d60

,376

121,

040

4,48

240

,560

0.11

648

4,99

038

1,60

0Tai

wan

2,93

010

,084

580

3,83

00.

025

337,

850

492,

340

Thai

land

9,93

275

,945

1,29

54,

413

0.15

413

3,60

082

,260

Turk

ey3,

146

27,3

9531

32,

217

0.11

310

4,99

010

8,83

0U

.K.

156,

700

548,

700

21,0

9045

,590

0.12

828

4,09

012

0,26

0V

enez

uela

285

3,52

122

419

0.02

595

,411

130,

360

Zim

bab

we

143

1,13

718

298

0.07

712

2,43

022

1,06

0

K.A. Froot et al. / Journal of Financial Economics 59 (2001) 151}193 169

Page 20: The portfolio ows of international investorsq · The portfolio #ows of international investorsq Kenneth A. Froot!,",*, Paul G. J. O’Connell#, Mark S. Seasholes!!Harvard University,

Tab

le4

Des

crip

tive

stat

istics

dur

ing

the

full

sam

ple

,Teq

uila

and

Asian

crisis

per

iods

Thesa

mpl

eco

nsist

sofc

ross

-bord

ereq

uity#ow

sfrom

Aug

ust

1,19

94to

Dec

embe

r31

,199

8re

pres

enting

1,15

4tr

adin

gda

ys.H

ere,

the

dat

aar

ebr

oke

nup

into

di!er

enttim

eper

iods

.Spe

ci"ca

lly,t

hefo

cusis

onre

centpe

riod

sofm

arket

turb

ule

nce.

The

data

are

derive

dfrom

pro

priet

ary

data

pro

vide

dby

Sta

teSt

reet

Ban

k&

Tru

st.D

aily#ow

sar

eco

nve

rted

to$U

.S.at

the

daily

exch

ange

rate

.T

he"rs

ttw

odat

aco

lum

nsre

port

the

tota

lvo

lum

eoftr

ades

,in

$m

illio

ns,

and

num

beroft

rade

s.T

heth

ird,f

our

th,a

nd"fth

dat

aco

lum

nsre

port

net

trad

ing

activi

ty,i

n$

thou

sands,

whe

renet

trad

ing

isde"ne

das

buy

sm

inusse

lls.D

ata

colu

mn"ve

div

ides

the

netam

ount

trad

edea

chday

byth

epre

viou

sday's

mar

ket

capi

taliz

atio

nto

produce

auni

tles

snu

mbe

rw

hich

we

report

inbas

ispoi

nts

orhu

ndre

dth

sofa

perc

ent.

The

aver

age

frac

tion

ofn

ettr

ades

per

day

within

are

gion

isth

esim

ple

aver

age

ofco

untr

iesw

ithin

the

regi

on.

The"nal

two

colu

mnsre

port

the

aver

age

daily

trad

esize

and

the

asso

ciat

edst

anda

rddev

iation

.Alis

tof

regi

onsan

dco

untr

iesis

give

nin

Tab

le1.

Reg

ion

Tota

leq

uity

Tota

leq

uity

tran

sact

ions

Ave

rage

daily

net

equity

Stan

dar

ddev

iation

Dai

lynet

trad

esto

mar

ket

cap.

Dai

lyav

erag

etr

ade

size

Stan

dar

ddev

iation

Pan

elA

:F

ull

sam

ple

Wor

ld96

1,27

03,

870,

000

97,2

6016

9,75

00.

112

215,

870

298,

940

Dev

elop

edco

unt

ries

768,

870

2,74

8,10

077

,643

143,

390

0.11

628

9,08

029

6,82

0A

llem

ergi

ng

mar

ket

s19

2,40

01,

121,

900

19,6

1761

,168

0.11

016

0,69

028

8,49

0Lat

inA

mer

ica

33,2

1316

2,85

03,

486

42,5

110.

036

154,

730

317,

610

Em

ergi

ngEas

tA

sia

127,

930

773,

990

10,0

7735

,755

0.11

216

8,69

018

9,79

0Em

ergi

ngEuro

pe16

,716

104,

380

2,05

18,

404

0.21

414

8,11

018

0,42

0O

ther

emer

ging

14,5

4380

,644

4,00

38,

281

0.09

416

9,77

048

5,32

0

Pan

elB

:Te

quil

ape

riod

Wor

ld50

,108

248,

370

46,6

0966

,207

0.09

519

2,53

022

1,23

0D

evel

oped

count

ries

38,7

4417

6,89

032

,227

53,7

930.

078

249,

980

254,

800

All

emer

ging

mar

ket

s11

,364

71,4

8014

,381

24,6

260.

105

141,

530

170,

980

Lat

inA

mer

ica

1,53

611

,944

2,40

74,

642

0.03

211

8,49

010

9,08

0Em

ergi

ngEas

tA

sia

9,00

652

,965

8,41

623

,496

0.06

117

0,23

017

8,26

0Em

ergi

ngEuro

pe38

13,

528

983

3,01

10.

238

103,

520

148,

660

Oth

erem

ergi

ng

440

3,04

32,

576

3,91

50.

115

161,

270

254,

660

Pan

elC

:A

sian

cris

isW

orld

457,

570

1,75

2,00

048

,927

210,

780

0.04

622

1,35

034

9,12

0D

evel

oped

count

ries

374,

180

1,24

0,20

044

,749

178,

230

0.04

430

8,16

027

5,00

0A

llem

ergi

ng

mar

ket

s83

,391

511,

800

4,17

882

,318

0.04

615

9,91

038

1,47

0Lat

inA

mer

ica

16,3

0076

,689

!2,

041

57,5

99!

0.03

515

4,52

037

0,95

0Em

ergi

ngEas

tA

sia

47,5

4132

6,23

087

347

,326

0.08

214

1,07

020

2,36

0Em

ergi

ngEuro

pe11

,038

63,7

661,

818

11,4

250.

068

164,

600

176,

590

Oth

erem

ergi

ng

8,51

245

,110

3,52

710

,939

0.06

919

6,03

071

6,54

0

170 K.A. Froot et al. / Journal of Financial Economics 59 (2001) 151}193

Page 21: The portfolio ows of international investorsq · The portfolio #ows of international investorsq Kenneth A. Froot!,",*, Paul G. J. O’Connell#, Mark S. Seasholes!!Harvard University,

Fig. 3. Heatmap of weekly net portfolio #ow correlations. The "gure summarizes over 900 pairwisecorrelations. The net, cross-border #ow of market purchases less sells into and out of one country iscorrelated with the net #ow into and out of a second country. The data are derived from proprietarydata provided by State Street Bank & Trust from August 1, 1994 to December 31, 1998.Table 5 presents the average pairwise correlation and the associated standard error for eachregion.

appears as the only shock that is associated with strong foreign equity selling.Russia's devaluation by itself seems to have left little imprint on #ows. Bycontrast, during the intra-crisis periods, the in#ows come rapidly, at an annualrate of approximately 50 basis points of market capitalization.

4.3. The persistence of yows

We next examine the persistence of order #ow, Using variance ratio statisticsas a measure. This statistic compares the variance of daily #ows with thevariance of #ows measured over k"2, 5, 20, and 60-day intervals. The statisticis given by

<Rki"

+Tt/k

[+k~1s/0

( fi,t~s

!fi]2

k+Tt/1

( fi,t!f

i)2 C

¹!1

(¹!k!1)(1!k/¹)D, (1)

K.A. Froot et al. / Journal of Financial Economics 59 (2001) 151}193 171

Page 22: The portfolio ows of international investorsq · The portfolio #ows of international investorsq Kenneth A. Froot!,",*, Paul G. J. O’Connell#, Mark S. Seasholes!!Harvard University,

Table 5Correlation within regions during the full sample, Tequila and Asian crisis periods

This table presents the average pairwise correlations for both weekly equity returns and weekly netequity #ows. Figs. 3 and 4 provide a graphical depiction of the same statistic. Table 1 displaysa complete list of countries by region. Equity returns are the daily, continuously compoundedreturns expressed in $U.S. We use the MSCI local country indexes and exchange rates fromWMR/Reuters/Datastream. The #ow data come from proprietary data provided by State StreetBank & Trust. Net equity #ows are de"ned as buys minus sells. Standard errors, shown inparentheses, are computed by Monte Carlo simulation under the null hypothesis that the truecorrelations are zero.

Full sample Tequila crisis Asian crisis

Panel A: Average pairwise correlation of equity returnsWorld 0.2521 0.1127 0.3308

(0.0053) (0.0078) (0.0066)

Developed Markets 0.4522 0.2247 0.5242(0.0115) (0.0199) (0.0133)

All Emerging Markets 0.2050 0.0804 0.2773(0.0084) (0.0126) (0.0109)

Latin America 0.3646 0.3743 0.5289(0.0443) (0.0725) (0.0464)

Emerging East Asia 0.4471 0.3943 0.5034(0.0262) (0.0509) (0.0267)

Emerging Europe 0.3875 0.2369 0.5278(0.0212) (0.0531) (0.0234)

Other emerging markets 0.1141 0.0686 0.1257(0.0212) (0.0388) (0.0324)

Panel B: Average pairwise correlation of net equity yowsWorld 0.0772 0.0414 0.0686

(0.0033) (0.0075) (0.0049)

Developed markets 0.1030 0.1108 0.0848(0.0088) (0.0186) (0.0135)

All emerging markets 0.0767 0.0181 0.0730(0.0054) (0.0127) (0.0078)

Latin America 0.1048 0.0252 0.0531(0.0245) (0.0499) (0.0280)

Emerging East Asia 0.1897 0.1323 0.2220(0.0143) (0.0580) (0.0202)

Emerging Europe 0.1190 !0.0579 0.1163(0.0259) (0.0426) (0.0365)

Other emerging markets 0.0826 0.0012 0.1241(0.0235) (0.0523) (0.0285)

172 K.A. Froot et al. / Journal of Financial Economics 59 (2001) 151}193

Page 23: The portfolio ows of international investorsq · The portfolio #ows of international investorsq Kenneth A. Froot!,",*, Paul G. J. O’Connell#, Mark S. Seasholes!!Harvard University,

Fig. 4. Heatmap of weekly equity return correlations. The "gure summarizes over 900 pairwisecorrelations. The equity return in $U.S. of one country is correlated with the equity return ofa second country. The data are from the MSCI local country index, and are multiplied by theexchange rate available from WMR/Reuters from August 1, 1994 to December 31, 1998. Table5 presents the average pairwise correlation and the associated standard error for each region.

where the last term is an adjustment for degrees of freedom. Because of the largenumber of countries, we report variance ratios only for our designated regions.The statistic reported for each region is the variance ratio of the equallyweighted in#ows. We calculated variance ratios using alternative weightingschemes, such as equal weighting, market capitalization weighting, etc., andfound broadly similar results to those reported below. We also calculated thevariance ratios on a country by country basis. Again, we found very persistent#ows, similar to the ones reported.

Table 6 reports variance ratios of equity trades. The data are arranged inthree panels, showing net #ows as buys minus sells, in#ows as buys, andout#ows as sells. Heteroskedastic-consistent standard errors are reportedbeneath the point estimates.

Several facts come out of the data. First, it is clear that the #ows are persistent.All of the variance ratios are statistically greater than one, and the pointestimates display very large magnitudes. First-order correlation coe$cients arein the range of 30% for developed-country and emerging-country groupings.It is worth noting that the ratios are higher for the larger baskets, so that

K.A. Froot et al. / Journal of Financial Economics 59 (2001) 151}193 173

Page 24: The portfolio ows of international investorsq · The portfolio #ows of international investorsq Kenneth A. Froot!,",*, Paul G. J. O’Connell#, Mark S. Seasholes!!Harvard University,

Fig. 5. Cumulative net equity #ows. These "gures show the cumulative net #ows, calculated as buysminus sells, into both emerging markets and developed markets. The sample consists of cross-borderequity #ows from August 1, 1994 to December 31, 1998 representing 1,154 trading days. The data arederived from proprietary data provided by State Street Bank & Trust. Daily #ows are divided bymarket capitalization. To make a regional #ow index, individual country #ows are weighted bymarket capitalization. Panel A: Cumulated daily net equity yows into developed and emerging markets.Panel B: Cumulated daily net yow into Emerging East Asia and Latin America.

the persistence of in#ows for all emerging markets is generally greater thanthat for individual emerging subregions, and the persistence for the worldoverall is considerably greater than that for either developed-country oremergingcountry baskets. This result appears to be the combined result of

174 K.A. Froot et al. / Journal of Financial Economics 59 (2001) 151}193

Page 25: The portfolio ows of international investorsq · The portfolio #ows of international investorsq Kenneth A. Froot!,",*, Paul G. J. O’Connell#, Mark S. Seasholes!!Harvard University,

5See Froot and Perold (1997) for a discussion of how persistence in stock return aggregates relatesto individual stock return persistence.

6See Froot et al. (1998) for these results.

persistent individual country #ows and cross-country non-contemporaneous#ow correlation.5

Second, regional #ows are persistent at low frequencies as well as at highfrequencies. The evidence for this observation is that the variance ratio stat-istics increase strongly with horizon. High-frequency persistence alonewould lead variance ratios to level o! as horizon increases. Our estimatedvariance ratios display no indication of leveling o! at the frequencies wemeasure.

We also compared #ow variance ratios with variance ratio of asset marketexcess returns for this time period and group of countries. The results show thatdeveloped market equity and currency returns show virtually no statisticalevidence that the ratios di!er from one, which represents the null hypothesis ofno persistence.6 Emerging market equities and currencies do show statisticallydetectable positive autocorrelations in excess returns, so that the variance ratiosare above one. However, the magnitude of the deviations is very small incomparison with the deviations for the #ows.

Finally, Table 7 shows the variance ratios computed for the Asian crisis andprior periods. The results suggest that the previously identi"ed crisis periods donot produce detectable changes in persistence.

5. The Interaction between 6ows and returns

In this section we investigate the bivariate behavior of #ows and returns. Are#ows and returns correlated? Do #ows forecast returns, and vice versa? Webegin our exploration by looking at the unconditional co-movement betweenthe two data series at various horizons. We then examine their conditionalcovariation within a vector autoregression framework.

Our "rst evidence on the relationship between #ows and prices is simplyvisual. Fig. 6 shows how the detrended emerging-market #ows compare withdetrended prices, in U.S. dollars, over the sample period. While there is too littledata here to draw any statistical conclusions, the graph does suggest that #owsand prices move together at low frequencies. The co-movement could beascribed to a variety of factors, including overreaction, information shocks, ordemand shocks. However, the presence of a clear regional component in thisco-movement is not supportive of the Brennan and Cao hypothesis, whichexplains positive #ow and price co-movement based on orthogonalized coun-try-speci"c information.

K.A. Froot et al. / Journal of Financial Economics 59 (2001) 151}193 175

Page 26: The portfolio ows of international investorsq · The portfolio #ows of international investorsq Kenneth A. Froot!,",*, Paul G. J. O’Connell#, Mark S. Seasholes!!Harvard University,

Table 6Variance ratio statistics

This table shows the variance ratio (VR) statistic of daily portfolio #ows from August 1994 throughDecember 1998. The statistic is calculated at lags of 2 through 60 days, which amounts toapproximately three months of trading. Results in this table are obtained by making an equal-weighted index of #ows within a given region. Similar results are found using a market capitalizationweighted index, or by reporting the average statistic of the individual countries within a given region.The variance ratio statistics use overlapping intervals and are corrected for bias in the varianceestimators. The "rst panel displays the variance ratios for net #ows, calculated as buys less sells. Thesecond and third panels show the VR results for equity purchases and equity sales, respectively.Standard errors are asymptotic and heteroskedasticity consistent and are shown in parentheses. Fora complete list of regions and countries, please see Table 1.

Region VR(2) VR(5) VR(20) VR(60)

Panel A: Net yowsWorld 1.453 2.691 7.721 16.865

(0.04) (0.09) (0.18) (0.30)

Developed Markets 1.324 2.176 5.113 10.108(0.03) (0.08) (0.17) (0.28)

All emerging markets 1.358 2.349 6.287 13.555(0.05) (0.09) (0.18) (0.30)

Latin America 1.179 1.500 2.838 4.989(0.03) (0.06) (0.14) (0.23)

Emerging East Asia 1.451 2.427 5.642 10.839(0.05) (0.11) (0.22) (0.36)

Emerging Europe 1.138 1.693 3.887 8.324(0.06) (0.12) (0.19) (0.29)

Other emerging 1.062 1.335 2.884 5.712(0.02) (0.06) (0.13) (0.23)

Panel B: Equity buysWorld 1.579 3.089 9.011 20.039

(0.04) (0.09) (0.20) (0.32)

Developed Markets 1.435 2.500 6.482 13.524(0.04) (0.09) (0.18) (0.30)

All emerging markets 1.516 2.850 7.796 17.246(0.05) (0.10) (0.20) (0.33)

Latin America 1.207 1.601 2.973 5.742(0.03) (0.06) (0.16) (0.31)

Emerging East Asia 1.595 3.002 8.469 19.806(0.07) (0.13) (0.26) (0.41)

Emerging Europe 1.309 2.101 4.348 7.499(0.05) (0.11) (0.20) (0.29)

Other emerging 1.030 1.292 2.928 6.287(0.02) (0.06) (0.13) (0.23)

176 K.A. Froot et al. / Journal of Financial Economics 59 (2001) 151}193

Page 27: The portfolio ows of international investorsq · The portfolio #ows of international investorsq Kenneth A. Froot!,",*, Paul G. J. O’Connell#, Mark S. Seasholes!!Harvard University,

Table 6 (continued)

Region VR(2) VR(5) VR(20) VR(60)

Panel C: Equity salesWorld 1.686 3.577 12.043 33.047

(0.04) (0.08) (0.17) (0.29)

Developed Markets 1.464 2.718 7.886 19.011(0.04) (0.08) (0.17) (0.29)

All emerging markets 1.658 3.460 11.486 31.969(0.04) (0.09) (0.18) (0.30)

Latin America 1.201 1.578 2.975 5.229(0.04) (0.06) (0.13) (0.23)

Emerging East Asia 1.692 3.332 9.944 27.017(0.06) (0.12) (0.21) (0.33)

Emerging Europe 1.433 2.633 7.607 20.227(0.04) (0.09) (0.17) (0.28)

Other emerging 1.206 1.872 5.111 12.523(0.03) (0.08) (0.17) (0.30)

5.1. The covariance of yows and returns

As described in the introduction, it is known from prior studies that thequarterly covariance of cross-border in#ows and equity returns is positive. Forexample,

cov[ri,t

(k), fi,t

(k)]'0, for k+60 tradingdays.

where ri,t

(k) is the k-period return on equity, and fi,t

(k) is cumulative sum of daily#ows from t!k#1 to t. Note, however, that the covariance between k-periodreturns and #ows can be broken down into a series of daily cross-covariances.We can think of the quarterly covariance as being comprised of three compo-nents. Component A is the covariance between current #ows and past returns.Component B is the contemporaneous covariance between daily #ows andreturns. Finally, Component C captures the covariance between current #owsand future returns, or past #ows and current returns. Speci"cally,

cov[ri,t

(k), fi,t

(k)]"

k~1+s/1

(k!s) cov[ri,t~s

, fi,t

]#k cov[ri,t

, fi,t

] #

k~1+s/1

(k!s) cov[ri,t`s

, fi,t

] . (3)

hggggiggggjhggiggj

hggggiggggjComponent A Component B Component C

K.A. Froot et al. / Journal of Financial Economics 59 (2001) 151}193 177

Page 28: The portfolio ows of international investorsq · The portfolio #ows of international investorsq Kenneth A. Froot!,",*, Paul G. J. O’Connell#, Mark S. Seasholes!!Harvard University,

Table 7Variance ratio statistics by time period

Table 7 shows the variance ratio statistic of daily portfolio #ows over two time periods, before andduring the Asian "nancial crisis. The pre-crisis period is August 1994-June 1997. The Asian crisisperiod is July 1997 to December 1998. The statistic is calculated at lags of 2 through 60 days,representing approximately three months of trading. Results in this table are obtained by making anequal-weighted index of #ows within a given region. Similar results are found using a marketcapitalization weighted index or by reporting the average statistic of the individual countries withina given region. The variance ratio statistics use overlapping intervals and are corrected for bias in thevariance estimators. The "rst panel displays the variance ratios for net #ows, calculated as buys lesssells. The second and third panels show the VR results for equity purchases and equity sales,respectively. Standard errors are asymptotic and heteroskedasticity-consistent and are shown inparentheses. For a complete list of countries and regions, see Table 1.

Pre-crisis period Asian crisis period

Region VR(2) VR(5) VR(20) VR(60) VR(2) VR(5) VR(20) VR(60)

Panel A: Net yowsWorld 1.292 1.994 4.243 9.105 1.522 2.972 9.341 21.829

(0.05) (0.10) (0.20) (0.33) (0.06) (0.14) (0.30) (0.50)

Developed markets 1.252 1.884 3.892 7.076 1.344 2.199 5.163 11.204(0.04) (0.09) (0.19) (0.33) (0.06) (0.13) (0.29) (0.48)

All emerging markets 1.199 1.704 3.564 8.016 1.464 2.771 7.962 17.907(0.06) (0.13) (0.23) (0.35) (0.07) (0.14) (0.30) (0.49)

Latin America 1.195 1.518 2.573 4.288 1.124 1.306 2.235 2.829(0.04) (0.09) (0.21) (0.35) (0.04) (0.07) (0.17) (0.28)

Emerging East Asia 1.460 2.499 5.052 9.303 1.447 2.387 5.946 13.603(0.06) (0.11) (0.22) (0.36) (0.07) (0.14) (0.29) (0.48)

Emerging Europe 1.044 1.382 2.888 5.922 1.258 2.063 4.743 9.449(0.09) (0.16) (0.25) (0.36) (0.06) (0.14) (0.28) (0.45)

Other emerging 1.017 1.054 1.576 1.867 1.116 1.717 4.538 10.566(0.02) (0.08) (0.16) (0.26) (0.03) (0.09) (0.22) (0.41)

Panel B: Equity buysWorld 1.540 2.935 7.406 14.165 1.536 2.706 6.854 14.023

(0.05) (0.11) (0.24) (0.37) (0.07) (0.15) (0.30) (0.50)

Developed markets 1.433 2.565 6.696 13.682 1.400 2.111 4.484 8.776(0.04) (0.10) (0.21) (0.34) (0.08) (0.15) (0.30) (0.51)

All Emerging markets 1.449 2.577 5.725 9.790 1.491 2.628 5.942 11.882(0.06) (0.13) (0.26) (0.40) (0.08) (0.16) (0.31) (0.50)

Latin America 1.223 1.612 2.825 4.285 1.165 1.512 2.561 2.911(0.04) (0.08) (0.21) (0.41) (0.04) (0.09) (0.24) (0.37)

Emerging East Asia 1.647 3.220 7.468 12.439 1.473 2.386 5.615 12.529(0.06) (0.13) (0.24) (0.38) (0.09) (0.18) (0.35) (0.54)

178 K.A. Froot et al. / Journal of Financial Economics 59 (2001) 151}193

Page 29: The portfolio ows of international investorsq · The portfolio #ows of international investorsq Kenneth A. Froot!,",*, Paul G. J. O’Connell#, Mark S. Seasholes!!Harvard University,

Table 7 (continued)

Pre-crisis period Asian crisis period

Region VR(2) VR(5) VR(20) VR(60) VR(2) VR(5) VR(20) VR(60)

Emerging Europe 1.277 1.987 3.535 6.000 1.324 2.088 3.723 6.060(0.06) (0.14) (0.26) (0.36) (0.07) (0.14) (0.28) (0.46)

Other emerging 1.018 1.149 2.034 2.518 0.952 1.187 2.722 5.520(0.02) (0.06) (0.15) (0.25) (0.04) (0.10) (0.24) (0.41)

Panel C: Equity salesWorld 1.578 3.147 8.927 17.030 1.403 2.137 3.128 3.463

(0.05) (0.11) (0.24) (0.38) (0.06) (0.13) (0.26) (0.43)

Developed markets 1.358 2.272 5.349 9.256 1.326 2.038 3.956 6.507(0.05) (0.11) (0.22) (0.34) (0.06) (0.13) (0.27) (0.45)

All emerging markets 1.559 3.081 8.653 16.612 1.370 2.061 3.030 3.481(0.06) (0.14) (0.28) (0.43) (0.06) (0.12) (0.24) (0.42)

Latin America 1.409 2.277 4.533 6.080 1.091 1.171 1.548 1.172(0.06) (0.12) (0.24) (0.38) (0.04) (0.07) (0.16) (0.26)

Emerging East Asia 1.618 3.145 8.231 14.225 1.507 2.223 2.797 3.044(0.05) (0.11) (0.23) (0.37) (0.09) (0.16) (0.29) (0.45)

Emerging Europe 1.328 2.218 5.204 11.004 1.276 1.917 2.932 3.797(0.06) (0.12) (0.23) (0.36) (0.05) (0.16) (0.29) (0.45)

Other emerging 1.049 1.178 1.983 3.558 1.096 1.489 3.055 4.727(0.02) (0.05) (0.16) (0.27) (0.05) (0.11) (0.25) (0.44)

Note that the three components of quarterly covariance are labeled in Eq. (3). Itis of interest to know which of these components drives quarterly covariance. IfComponent A turns out to be the largest fraction of quarterly covariance, wecan hypothesize that returns can be predicted on the basis of current #ows.

The high frequency of our data allows us to calculate these componentsseparately. As a convenient numeraire, we divide the quarterly covariance byk times the daily variance of the #ows. In doing so, we estimate the followingcovariance ratio statistic, or CVR:

C<Rki"

cov[ri,t

(k), fi,t

(k)]

k var[ fi,t

]"

+Tt/k

[+k~1s/0

(ri,t~s

!ri)] [+k~1

s/0( f

i,t~s!f

i ]k+T

t/1( f

i,t!f

i)2

.

(4)

This is reminiscent of the variance ratio statistic used earlier. However, noticethat the denominator is not k times the covariance between daily #ows and

K.A. Froot et al. / Journal of Financial Economics 59 (2001) 151}193 179

Page 30: The portfolio ows of international investorsq · The portfolio #ows of international investorsq Kenneth A. Froot!,",*, Paul G. J. O’Connell#, Mark S. Seasholes!!Harvard University,

Fig. 6. De-trended cumulative net equity #ows and equity returns: emerging markets. This "gureshows the de-trended cumulative net #ows, calculated as buys minus sells, and equity returns. The#ows are divided by market capitalization. To make a regional index, individual country #ows andequity returns are weighted by market capitalization. For a complete list of countries within thisregion, see Table 1. Equity returns are the daily, continuously compounded returns expressed in$U.S. We use the MSCI local country indexes, and exchange rates from WMR/Reuters/Datastream.The #ow data come from proprietary data provided by State Street Bank & Trust.

returns, but rather k times the variance of #ows. The statistic can therefore bethought of as the coe$cient from a regression of k-period returns on k-period#ows. From the covariance decomposition shown in Eq. (3), it follows directlythat:

C<Rki"

k~1+s/1

(1!sk) b(r

i,t~s, f

i,t) #b(r

i,t, f

i,t)#

k~1+s/1

(1!sk) b(r

i,t`s, f

i,t) , (5)

hggggiggggjhgigj

hggggiggggjComponent A Component B Component C

where b(ri,s

, fi,t

) is the coe$cient from a regression of daily returns at time s ondaily #ows at time t. The formulation of CVR(k) in Eq. (5) allows us todecompose quarterly covariance, and make statistical inferences.

Table 8 presents the decomposition of the quarterly covariance of #ows anddollar equity returns at the regional level. The table reports the results fromequally weighted regional #ow indexes. Similar results are found using indexes

180 K.A. Froot et al. / Journal of Financial Economics 59 (2001) 151}193

Page 31: The portfolio ows of international investorsq · The portfolio #ows of international investorsq Kenneth A. Froot!,",*, Paul G. J. O’Connell#, Mark S. Seasholes!!Harvard University,

7 In Froot et al. (1998), we provided results both for equity and currency returns. To save space,the results on currencies have been eliminated here, but they were generally similar to those ondollar equity returns.

weighted by market capitalization, or by averaging across the covariance ratiosfrom individual countries in each region. The "rst data column reports theactual CVR statistic with k set equal to 60, to represent a quarterly decomposi-tion. For the purposes of inference, the variance of the CVR statistic and itscomponents is estimated from the heteroskedastic consistent variances of thedaily b coe$cient estimates.7

The "rst point to note about the tables is the bene"t of using daily instead ofmonthly or quarterly data. As we can see from Panel B of Table 8, contempor-aneous covariance accounts for at most 8.5% of measured quarterly covariance.On average, less than a quarter of the quarterly covariance between #ows andequity returns can be attributed to the period from 5 days before to 5 days aftertrades are recorded.

Table 8 also shows the decomposition of the lag and lead e!ects. For bothdeveloped markets and emerging markets, it is clear that most of the CVRstatistic is due to component A, described above as the covariance betweencurrent #ows and past returns. As mentioned earlier, the size and signi"cance ofcomponent A suggest positive feedback trading behavior for these internationalinvestors. In other words, positive local stock market returns are associated withfuture international in#ows.

For the world overall, there is a fair amount of predictability of future returnsfrom current #ows. However, most of this e!ect can be attributed to theemerging markets. If we concentrate on developed markets only, Table 8 showsevidence that #ows predict negative future equity returns, a result which sug-gests evidence of overreaction or price pressure. Note, however, that this "ndingis not statistically signi"cant. In addition, this "nding for developed marketsdisappears once we account for the behavior of past returns in the followingsection.

In any case, #ows into emerging markets predict positive equity returns, andseem to do so at short as well as long horizons. Over the upcoming week and therest of the following month, the coe$cients for all emerging market regions arepositive. At the quarterly horizon, Emerging East Asia and Other EmergingMarkets are the only emerging regions that show negative coe$cients. Theemerging markets covariance ratio is largest for the period between 6 and 20days, suggesting that an in#ow is associated with a tendency toward positiveemerging market returns over many days into the future. This "nding isconsistent with the view that international investors may have better marginalinformation than local investors have in emerging markets.

These "ndings seem inconsistent with the Brennan and Cao view that thepositive covariance between emerging market returns and in#ows is attributable

K.A. Froot et al. / Journal of Financial Economics 59 (2001) 151}193 181

Page 32: The portfolio ows of international investorsq · The portfolio #ows of international investorsq Kenneth A. Froot!,",*, Paul G. J. O’Connell#, Mark S. Seasholes!!Harvard University,

Tab

le8

Quar

terly

cova

rian

cede

com

position

This

table

deco

mpo

sesth

eco

varian

cera

tio

stat

istic

for60

-day

equi

tyre

turn

sag

ainst

60-d

aynet

equi

ty#ow

s.The

dat

aar

ede

rive

dfrom

prop

riet

ary

data

prov

ided

by

Sta

teStr

eetB

ank

&T

rust

from

Aug

ust1,

1994

toD

ecem

ber31

,199

8.R

esultsin

this

table

areobt

ained

by

mak

ing

aneq

ual

-wei

ghte

din

dex

of

#ow

sw

ithin

agi

ven

regi

on.S

imila

rre

sults

are

foun

dusing

am

arket

capital

izat

ion

wei

ghte

din

dex

or

byre

port

ing

the

aver

age

stat

istic

ofth

ein

divi

dua

lco

untr

ies

within

are

gion

.The

dec

ompo

sition

isbas

edon

Eq.(5

)in

the

text

,whic

hca

ptu

res

aco

varian

cera

tio

(CV

R)co

mpr

ised

ofth

eco

varian

ceof

curr

ent#ow

san

dpas

tre

turn

s,cu

rren

tda

ily#ow

san

dre

turn

s,an

dcu

rren

t#ow

san

dfu

ture

retu

rns.

Pan

elA

show

sth

eac

tual

CV

Rst

atistic

and

its

com

ponen

ts.Pan

elB

show

sth

eco

mpos

itio

nin

term

sofper

centa

ges.

For

aco

mple

telis

tofre

gion

san

dco

unt

ries

,se

eTab

le1.

Flo

ws

and

lagg

edre

turn

sC

onte

mp.

Flo

ws

and

futu

rere

turn

sco

mpo

nen

tR

egio

nC

VR

(60)

Day

s21}60

Day

s6}

20D

ays

2}5

Day

s2}

5D

ays

6}20

Day

s21}60

Pan

elA

:D

ecom

posi

tion

ofC

VR

Wor

ld1,

555.

3062

9.67

416.

0619

7.67

61.2

553

.21

163.

1934

.26

(15.

17)

(10.

95)

(11.

41)

(10.

64)

(3.3

5)(2

.91)

(4.4

3)(0

.58)

Dev

elop

edm

arket

s41

9.95

248.

8415

5.92

66.7

617

.56

!6.

73!

8.16

!54

.24

(5.9

8)(6

.24)

(6.4

6)(5

.65)

(1.5

2)(!

0.54

)(!

0.31

)(!

1.34

)

All

emer

ging

mar

ket

s1,

380.

3045

8.41

356.

5219

2.67

61.9

656

.87

176.

7177

.08

(14.

70)

(8.6

5)(1

0.61

)(1

0.79

)(3

.45)

(3.4

5)(5

.32)

(1.4

4)

Lat

inA

mer

ica

895.

2221

3.98

215.

2211

5.61

53.1

845

.55

166.

1685

.52

(10.

29)

(5.4

6)(8

.01)

(6.3

0)(3

.65)

(3.5

1)(5

.70)

(1.4

0)

Em

ergi

ngEas

tA

sia

1,03

4.50

348.

8135

1.84

269.

2688

.39

0.43

51.1

7!

75.3

7(6

.71)

(3.9

6)(6

.52)

(9.7

2)(2

.41)

(0.0

2)(0

.96)

(!0.

87)

Em

ergi

ngEuro

pe17

4.06

!3.

2553

.57

40.3

214

.19

4.88

26.0

738

.28

(4.7

0)(!

0.15

)(3

.90)

(5.7

5)(2

.02)

(0.7

6)(2

.07)

(1.8

3)

Oth

erem

ergi

ng

253.

1116

6.19

60.7

422

.13

1.63

12.8

411

.60

!22

.01

(4.7

9)(5

.30)

(3.0

6)(2

.82)

(0.1

7)(1

.41)

(0.6

6)(!

0.75

)

182 K.A. Froot et al. / Journal of Financial Economics 59 (2001) 151}193

Page 33: The portfolio ows of international investorsq · The portfolio #ows of international investorsq Kenneth A. Froot!,",*, Paul G. J. O’Connell#, Mark S. Seasholes!!Harvard University,

Pan

elB

:D

ecom

posi

tion

inpe

rcen

tte

rms

Wor

ld1,

555.

3040

.5%

26.8

%12

.7%

3.9%

3.4%

10.5

%2.

2%

Dev

elop

edm

arket

s41

9.95

59.3

%37

.1%

15.9

%4.

2%!

1.6%

!1.

9%!

12.9

%

All

emer

ging

mar

ket

s1,

380.

3033

.2%

25.8

%14

.0%

4.5%

4.1%

12.8

%5.

6%

Lat

inA

mer

ica

895.

2223

.9%

24.0

%12

.9%

5.9%

5.1%

18.6

%9.

6%

Em

ergi

ngEas

tA

sia

1,03

4.50

33.7

%34

.0%

26.0

%8.

5%0.

0%4.

9%!

7.3%

Em

ergi

ngEuro

pe17

4.06

!1.

9%30

.8%

23.2

%8.

2%2.

8%15

.0%

22.0

%

Oth

erem

ergi

ng

253.

1165

.7%

24.0

%8.

7%0.

6%5.

1%4.

6%!

8.7%

K.A. Froot et al. / Journal of Financial Economics 59 (2001) 151}193 183

Page 34: The portfolio ows of international investorsq · The portfolio #ows of international investorsq Kenneth A. Froot!,",*, Paul G. J. O’Connell#, Mark S. Seasholes!!Harvard University,

to the information disadvantage of international investors. If local, not global,information shocks drive emerging market returns, then we would not expect tosee a large, regional #ow component, nor would we expect it to covary stronglywith returns, as the top panel of Table 8 suggests.

Finally, Fig. 7 shows how the covariance of low-frequency #ows with returnsis a!ected by the sample period. The "gure graphically depicts the results fromTable 8, breaking them up into a pre-Asian crisis period and an Asian crisisperiod. The graph suggests that the character of emerging market #ows wasessentially una!ected by the Asian crisis. Interestingly, much of the negativecovariance in developed-country #ows with future returns comes from thepre-crisis subsample. During the Asian crisis, developed country in#ows betterpredict the direction of future equity returns.

5.2. Vector autoregressions

While the covariance results tell us broadly about predictability, we can learnmore about the structure of #ows and returns from a vector autoregression(VAR). Speci"cally, we ask two questions. First, do returns predict #ows overand above the predictions of lagged #ows? Second, do #ows predict returns overand above the predictions of lagged returns?

To answer these we estimate both an unrestricted VAR and a VAR subject torestrictions. For the unrestricted VAR, we estimate a two-equation systemwhere we cast the joint dynamics of f

itand r

itfor each country as a pth-order

Gaussian vector autoregression:

CfitritD"C

af

arD#C

/11

(¸) /12

(¸)

/21

(¸) /22

(¸)D )Cfit~1rit~1D#C

efit

eritD, (6)

Cefit

efitD+N[0,&

i], &

i"C

p2if

opif

pir

opif

pir

p2ir

D.This system can be written succinctly as

yit"a

i#U

1yi,t~1

#U2

yi,t~2

#2#Upyi,t~p

#eit

(7)

for i"1,2, N, t"1,2,¹, where yit"[f

itrit]@, a

iis a vector of country-speci"c

constants, and the MUiN are 2]2 parameter matrices to be estimated. The

diagonal coe$cients /11

and /22

represent conditional momentum in #ows andreturns. The o!-diagonal coe$cients /

12and /

21represent conditional positive

feedback trading, wherein #ows follow returns, and conditional anticipatione!ects wherein returns follow #ows. The o!-diagonal elements of +

icapture

capture the price-impact e!ect of #ows on returns.

184 K.A. Froot et al. / Journal of Financial Economics 59 (2001) 151}193

Page 35: The portfolio ows of international investorsq · The portfolio #ows of international investorsq Kenneth A. Froot!,",*, Paul G. J. O’Connell#, Mark S. Seasholes!!Harvard University,

Fig. 7. Quarterly covariance decomposition: #ows and equity returns. This "gure shows thedecomposition of the covariance ratio statistic for 60-day equity returns against 60-day netequity #ows. The decomposition is done in percentage terms, as shown on the bottom of Table 8,and based on Eq. (5) in the text. The "rst "gure shows the results for developed markets andemerging markets for the entire sample (see Table 8, Panel B). The next two "gures show thedecomposition from before and during the recent Asian crisis. The data are derived from proprietarydata provided by State Street Bank & Trust from August 1, 1994 to December 31, 1998. Resultsin this table are obtained by making an equal-weighted index of #ows within a given region.Similar results are found using a market capitalization weighted index or by reporting the averagestatistic of the individual countries within a region. For a complete list of regions and countries, seeTable 1.

K.A. Froot et al. / Journal of Financial Economics 59 (2001) 151}193 185

Page 36: The portfolio ows of international investorsq · The portfolio #ows of international investorsq Kenneth A. Froot!,",*, Paul G. J. O’Connell#, Mark S. Seasholes!!Harvard University,

In order to conserve on the number of parameters, we restrict the parametersin Eq. (7) to be equal across countries. In this instance, maximum likelihoodestimates of the MU

iN and X

ican be obtained by iterated least squares. The lag

length is chosen by looking both at the Akake Information Criterion (AIC) andthe likelihood ratio for various choices of p. In general, the data support the useof up to 40 daily lags, which seems consistent with the evidence of persistentunconditional cross-e!ects already discussed.

Table 9 presents F-tests of the hypothesis that the coe$cients on each termare jointly equal to zero. Generalized least squares (GLS) standard errors areused in the calculation. The results show that lagged returns are stronglysigni"cant in predicting both #ows and returns. Lagged #ows are also stronglysigni"cant in predicting future #ows. The evidence for the predictability ofreturns by #ows, is however, more ambiguous. In developed markets, there is nostatistical evidence of predictability. For emerging markets, however, the evid-ence for predictability is strong, although less so for the Emerging Europeregion.

We also use the estimates of U to form impulse response functions (IRFs),shocking #ows or returns and then examining the e!ects. Panel B of Table 9presents tests of the signi"cance of the IRFs for returns following a 1bp shock to#ows, and Figs. 8 and 9 display graphs of the IRF responses along with 90%con"dence intervals.

The impulse responses in Figs. 8A and B make several interesting points.First, for emerging markets overall, a shock of one basis point to #ows generatesan additional 1.5 basis point greater in#ow over the subsequent 45 days. The"gure shows the persistence of #ows to be very pronounced, with the standarderror of the forecasts being very small in relation to the magnitude. Second,the same shock of one basis point results in a 40 basis point increase in equityprices, with most of the increase coming in the "rst 30 or so days. Once again,these results are easily signi"cant at the 5% level. Note that this elasticity of 40is very high, in that it is several times the magnitude found in studies ofthe responses of U.S. stocks to mutual fund in#ow. Third, a shock of 100 basispoints to returns results in about 0.05 basis points in additional in#ow overthe next two or three months. Although this response is economically small,it is statistically signi"cant. Finally, a 100 basis-point shock to equities resultsin a positive equity response of about 25 basis points. The e!ect comesfrom a combination of the autocorrelation in emerging-market index returns,the e!ect of a shock to returns on subsequent #ows, and the e!ect offurther #ows on subsequent returns. In any case, fully half of the response, or12.5 basis points, occurs on the day after the shock, a direct result of the stronglypositive "rst-order autocorrelation coe$cient found in emerging-market indexreturns.

A slightly di!erent perspective can be given to the data by putting morestructure on the estimation problem. To do this, we estimate a model that makes

186 K.A. Froot et al. / Journal of Financial Economics 59 (2001) 151}193

Page 37: The portfolio ows of international investorsq · The portfolio #ows of international investorsq Kenneth A. Froot!,",*, Paul G. J. O’Connell#, Mark S. Seasholes!!Harvard University,

Table 9VAR estimates

This table summarizes results from the following vector autoregression (VAR) with the number oflags (P) set to 40 days. Coe$cients are constrained to be the same for all countries within a givenregion. Estimation is general least squares (GLS) that allows for heterskedasticity by country. f

5is

net, or buy and sell, #ow at time t and rtis equity return at time t. Equity returns are expressed in

U.S.$ and are from MSCI (local) country indexes. Panel A presents F-tests of joint coe$cientsigni"cance from the VAR. Also included is the estimated, contemporaneous correlation coe$cientbetween shocks to net #ows and shocks to equity returns. Panel B presents the cumulative impulseresponse function of returns, in basis points (bp) from a 1bp shock to #ows. Values are shown at 40days and 60 days after the shock. Parameter estimates are from the VAR, below. Diagrams of theimpulse response functions for emerging markets are presented in Fig. 8. FX rates are fromWMR/Reuters and obtained from Datastream. The #ow data come from proprietary data providedby State Street Bank & Trust. Data is from the period August 1, 1994 to December 31, 1998.A complete list of regions and countries is given in Table 1.

ft"a

F#

P+p/1

<11 p

ft~p

#

P+p/1

<12 p

rt~p

#et,F

rt"a

R#

P+

p/1

<21 p

ft~p

#

P+p/1

<22 p

rt~p

#et,R

F-test of joint signi"cance (P-value shown)

<11

<12

<21

<22

Corr(eF,

eT)

Panel A: F-testsWorld * * * * *

Developed markets 0.0000 0.0000 0.4615 0.0000 0.0307All emerging markets 0.0000 0.0000 0.0157 0.0000 0.0444

Latin America 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000 0.0409Emerging East Asia 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000 0.0842Emerging Europe 0.0000 0.0000 0.3337 0.0000 0.0496Other emerging markets 0.0000 0.0000 0.1391 0.0000 !0.0026

Impulse response

40 days later 60 days later

(bp) P-value (bp) P-value

Panel B: Impulse response functions of equity returns from a 1bp shock to yowsWorld * * * *

Developed markets 14.672 0.033 18.753 0.016All emerging markets 34.147 0.008 39.044 0.002

Latin America 54.180 0.065 46.943 0.138Emerging East Asia !22.062 0.230 !31.093 0.810Emerging Europe 37.133 0.000 45.245 0.000Other emerging markets 55.109 0.014 61.423 0.024

K.A. Froot et al. / Journal of Financial Economics 59 (2001) 151}193 187

Page 38: The portfolio ows of international investorsq · The portfolio #ows of international investorsq Kenneth A. Froot!,",*, Paul G. J. O’Connell#, Mark S. Seasholes!!Harvard University,

Fig. 8. Impulse response functions: all emerging markets. Graphs of the cumulative impulseresponse functions for emerging market #ows and equity returns. Parameters are from the VARreported in Table 9. Each impulse response comes from shocking either #ows or returns, whileholding the other variable constant. The IRFs are shown with the 90% con"dence intervals, whichare obtained by Monte Carlo simulation. Parameters values are drawn from the asymptotic jointdistribution of parameters, and the impulse response function is calculated. This procedure is thenrepeated 500 times.

several assumptions about the causality of #ows and returns. First, we assumethat the decision to buy a country's equity depends on past in#ows and pastreturns. Past in#ows matter because they are correlated with the disparitybetween current price and future price, as perceived by investors. Thisperception can be accurate either because investors have information aboutthe true value of the equity investment, or because the investors are largein size and wish to minimize the price impact of their trades. Past returns enterthe equation because some investors are not informed and cannot observein#ows. These investors therefore rely more on past returns as a proxy forinformation.

Second, prices set by market makers are a function of past in#ows and pastreturns, as well as current in#ows. This provision means that we are assumingthat current in#ows a!ect current prices, and that the causality does not runfrom contemporaneous returns to #ows. This case would occur if market makersperceive current in#ows to contain information about value, as in Kyle (1985).However, lagged in#ows may also a!ect current price. They may do so in twoways. First, lagged in#ows a!ect unexpected current #ows. With current in#owsgiven, the larger are past in#ows, the greater will be the anticipated value for the

188 K.A. Froot et al. / Journal of Financial Economics 59 (2001) 151}193

Page 39: The portfolio ows of international investorsq · The portfolio #ows of international investorsq Kenneth A. Froot!,",*, Paul G. J. O’Connell#, Mark S. Seasholes!!Harvard University,

Fig. 9. Impulse response functions: all developed markets. Graphs of the cumulative impulseresponse functions for developed market #ows and equity returns. Parameters are from the VARreported in Table 9. Each impulse response comes from shocking either #ows or returns, whileholding the other variables constant. The IRFs are shown with the 90% con"dence intervals, whichare obtained by Monte Carlo simulation. Parameters values are drawn from the asymptotic jointdistribution of parameters, and the impulse response function is calculated. This procedure is thenrepeated 500 times.

current #ow. Thus, the amount of the unexpected current #ow, is smaller, andprices should therefore fall. By this logic, lagged in#ows have a negative impacton current returns. Second, in#ows may contain more or less information aboutthe future than the market maker expects. If the market maker underestimatesthe information content of current #ow, then lagged in#ow positively forecastsfuture returns. If the market maker overestimates the information content ofcurrent #ow, lagged in#ow will forecast returns negatively.

This more structural model can be summarized in the following way:

CfitritD"C

aif

airD#C

B11

(¸) B12

(¸)

B21

(¸) B22

(¸)D )Cfit~1rit~1D#C

0

BXfitD#C

ufit

uritD, (8)

where B11

and B12

are respective persistence and trend following parametersfor order #ow, B

xdescribes the price impact of unexpected order #ow on

returns, and B21

represents the impact of lagged in#ow on returns. Ourstructural model can be thought of as a restricted version of the reduced formmodel in Eq. (7), with the contemporaneous correlations between the u's equalto zero.

K.A. Froot et al. / Journal of Financial Economics 59 (2001) 151}193 189

Page 40: The portfolio ows of international investorsq · The portfolio #ows of international investorsq Kenneth A. Froot!,",*, Paul G. J. O’Connell#, Mark S. Seasholes!!Harvard University,

This model is estimated in an autoregressive form, similar to that in Eq. (7),but imposing the necessary restrictions on the covariance matrix. Speci"cally,we estimate the exactly identi"ed system:

B0) y

it"!B ) x

it#u

it, (9)

where

!B"[aB1

B2 2B

P],x

t"

1

yit~1

yit~2F

yit~p

, B0"C

1 0

!Bx

1D,Cufit

uritD+N[0,D]

(10)

and

D"Cp2u,f

0

0 p2u,rD (11)

Table 10 reports information on the parameter vectors, B11

, B12

, B21

and thescalar B

9. Our estimates of B

9are all positive, and in some cases are statistically

signi"cant. The emerging markets estimate suggests that a positive shock toin#ows equal to 1 basis point of capitalization results in a contemporaneousincrease in prices of 0.6 basis points. The corresponding coe$cient for developedcountries is less than 0.1 basis points.

The estimates of B21

, the impact of lagged in#ow on returns, are universallynegative for the emerging markets. This result suggests that temporary in#owsresult in temporary price increases. It does not mean, however, that in#owsforecast returns negatively. In#ows are strongly persistent, as we have seen,making it unlikely that in#ows today will subside fully tomorrow.

This story has interesting implications for the crises in emerging markets.Much of the recent debate about the recent crises has focused on whetherinternational investors sold at the beginning or in the midst of the crisis. Whilewe have already shown that net sales are small, these last results suggest thatprices fall when international in#ows were previously high, and then fall. Prices,which were rationally high in expectation of further in#ows, were not justi"ablyonce the in#ows ceased. Thus, our estimates of B

21and B

9suggest how a fall,

but not a reversal, in emerging market in#ows can be associated with pricedeclines. We produced estimates for Tables 9 and 10 for both the pre-Asian andAsian crisis periods. The results are not importantly di!erent, though the powerof the statistical tests, particularly during the relatively short Asian crisis period,is lower.

190 K.A. Froot et al. / Journal of Financial Economics 59 (2001) 151}193

Page 41: The portfolio ows of international investorsq · The portfolio #ows of international investorsq Kenneth A. Froot!,",*, Paul G. J. O’Connell#, Mark S. Seasholes!!Harvard University,

Table 10Structural model estimates

This table summarizes results from the following structural model with the number of lags (P) set to40 days. Coe$cients are constrained to be the same for all countries within a given region.Estimation is by GLS, and allows for heterskedasticity by country. This structural model isa just-identi"ed version of the VAR presented in Table 9. ft is net, buy or sell #ow at time t and r

tis

equity return at time t. Equity returns are expressed in $U.S. and are from MSCI (local) countryindices. FX rates are from WMR/Reuters and obtained from Datastream. The #ow data cover theperiod August 1, 1994 to December 31, 1998. A complete list of regions and countries is given inTable 1.

fit"a

if#

P+p/1

B11p

fit~p

#

P+p/1

B12p

rit~p

#ufit

rit"a

ir#

P+p/1

B21p

fit~p

#

P+

p/1

B22p

rit~p

#BXfit`

urit

Due to the large number of coe$cients estimated, we present only the average coe$cient acrosscountries in a given region. Below the average value is the standard deviation of this average,computed by Monte Carlo simulation. In the case of the contemporaneous parameter (B

x), we

compute a p-value that the average coe$cient in the region is greater than zero.

Average coe$cient value across countries in region

Region B11

B12

B21

B22

BX

Developed markets 1.5E!02 1.9E!03 8.8E!04 !2.3E!03 8.7E!024.6E!03 9.6E!04 1.2E!03 8.7E!04 p"0.31

All emerging markets 1.6E!02 3.7E!04 !6.0E!03 4.6E!03 5.9E!014.5E!03 2.7E!04 5.2E!03 8.2E!04 p"0.15

Latin America 1.6E!02 1.6E!04 !1.0E!02 4.4E!03 8.2E!015.4E!03 2.8E!04 9.3E!03 2.3E!03 p"0.22

Emerging East Asia 1.6E!02 6.9E!06 !8.1E!01 5.1E!03 3.4E#016.0E!03 5.5E!06 4.4E!01 1.7E!03 p"0.03

Emerging Europe 1.5E!02 !7.9E!06 2.2E!01 1.5E!03 1.9E#013.0E!03 1.2E!05 1.0E!01 2.0E!03 p"0.00

Other emerging markets 1.5E!02 1.1E!05 4.3E!01 7.7E!03 2.5E#003.9E!03 5.2E!06 2.0E!01 1.5E!03 p"0.47

6. Conclusions

We have used a new source of high frequency data on international portfolio#ows to learn about how in#ows behave and how they interact with returns.Our "ndings can be summarized as follows:

International portfolio in#ows are slightly positively correlated across coun-tries, and are more strongly correlated within regions. The correlation of #ows

K.A. Froot et al. / Journal of Financial Economics 59 (2001) 151}193 191

Page 42: The portfolio ows of international investorsq · The portfolio #ows of international investorsq Kenneth A. Froot!,",*, Paul G. J. O’Connell#, Mark S. Seasholes!!Harvard University,

in most regions, and particularly within Asia, rises strongly during the Asiancrisis subsample, but not during the Mexican crisis subsample.

In#ows and out#ows are highly persistent. The persistence is complex in thesense that a shock to in#ows today is associated with slightly greater in#owsover a long period of time.

There is very strong trend following in international in#ows. The majority ofthe co-movement of #ows and returns at quarterly or monthly intervals isactually due to returns predicting future #ows.

There is also some ability for international in#ows to forecast returns. Inemerging markets, in#ows predict positive future returns on average. Themajority of price increases do not occur over a short period of time, such as a fewdays. Rather prices seem to rise subsequent to in#ows for a month or two. Thelimited time sample of our data prevents us from saying more about such lowfrequency predictability. We cannot say in this paper whether the predictabilityof future returns is the result of superior information held by internationalinvestors or whether #ows, which are persistent, predict future price pressure.

In developed markets, in#ows do not forecast positive returns. At longerhorizons, returns are negative.

Transitory in#ows lead to partially transitory price increases.The forecasting power of in#ows for future returns occurs because current

in#ows predict future in#ows, and future in#ows drive up prices.Our explanation for the co-movement of returns and #ows is that #ows

contain information about future value. Emerging market prices do not fullyappreciate the implication of an increase in in#ow for future value, so cross-border trades tend to be informed trades. However, price pressure in thesemarkets is substantial, so that a cessation of in#ow can reduce emerging marketprices. This hypothesis is unable to explain the home bias in internationalportfolio allocations, but it better "ts the facts of #ows and returns.

References

Bohn, H., Tesar, L., 1996. U.S. equity investment in foreign markets: portfolio rebalancing or returnchasing? American Economic Review 86, 77}81.

Brennan, M., Cao, H., 1997. International portfolio investment #ows. Journal of Finance 52,1851}1880.

Choe, H., Kho, B., Stulz, R., 1999. Do foreign investors destabilize stock markets? the Koreanexperience in 1997. Journal of Financial Economics 54, 227}264.

Clark, J., Berko, E., 1996. Foreign investment #uctuations and emerging market stock returns: thecase of Mexico. Federal Reserve Bank of New York.

Forbes, K., Rigobon, R., 1999. No contagion, only interdependence: measuring stock market co-movements. National Bureau of Economic Research working paper, No. W7267. Cambridge, MA.

Frankel, J., Schmukler, S., 1996. Country fund discounts, asymmetric information and the Mexicancrisis of 1994: did local residents turn pessimistic before international investors? National Bureauof Economic Research working paper, No 5714. Cambridge, MA.

192 K.A. Froot et al. / Journal of Financial Economics 59 (2001) 151}193

Page 43: The portfolio ows of international investorsq · The portfolio #ows of international investorsq Kenneth A. Froot!,",*, Paul G. J. O’Connell#, Mark S. Seasholes!!Harvard University,

Froot, K., O'Connell, P., 1997. On the pricing of intermediated risk: theory and application tocatastrophe reinsurance. Unpublished working paper. Harvard University, Cambridge, MA.

Froot, K., O'Connell, P., Seasholes, M., 1998. The portfolio #ows of international investors, I. NBERWorking Paper no. 6687.

Froot, K., Perold, A., 1997. New trading practices and short-run market e$ciency. Journal ofFutures Markets 15, 731}766.

Froot, K., Scharfstein, D., Stein, J., 1992. Herd on the street: informational ine$ciencies in a marketwith short-term speculation. Journal of Finance 47, 1461}1484.

Gompers, P., Lerner, J., 2000. Money chasing deals? the impact of fund in#ows on the valuation ofprivate equity investments. Journal of Financial Economics 55, 281}325.

Grinblatt, M., Titman, S., Wermers, R., 1995. Momentum investment strategies, portfolio perfor-mance, and herding: a study of mutual fund behavior. American Economic Review 85,1088}1105.

Hirshleifer, D., Subrahmanyam, A., Titman, S., 1994. Security analysis and trading patterns whensome investors receive information before others. Journal of Finance 49, 1665}1698.

Kyle, A., 1985. Continuous auctions and insider trading. Econometrica 53, 1315}1336.Lakonishok, J., Shleifer, A., Vishny, R., 1992. The impact of institutional trading on stock prices.

Journal of Financial Economics 32, 23}44.Levich, R., 1994. Comment on international equity transactions and U.S. portfolio choice.

In: Frankel, J. (Ed.), The Internationalization of Equity Markets. University of Chicago Press,pp. 221}227.

Stulz, R., 1997. International portfolio #ows and security returns. Unpublished working paper. OhioState University, Columbus, OH.

Tesar, L., Werner, I., 1994. International equity transactions and U.S. portfolio choice. In: Frankel, J.(Ed.), The Internationalization of Equity Markets. University of Chicago Press, pp. 185}220.

Tesar, L., Werner, I., 1995a. Home bias and high turnover. Journal of International Money andFinance 14, 467}492.

Tesar, L., Werner, I., 1995b. U.S. equity investment in emerging stock markets. World BankEconomic Review 9, 109}130.

Warther, V., 1995. Aggregate mutual fund #ows and security returns. Journal of Financial Econ-omics 39, 209}236.

Wermers, R., 1999. Mutual fund herding and the impact on stock prices. Journal of Finance 54,581}622.

K.A. Froot et al. / Journal of Financial Economics 59 (2001) 151}193 193