The Making of Behavioral Development Economics...economics adopted a different theory of the...

38
Policy Research Working Paper 8317 e Making of Behavioral Development Economics Allison Demeritt Karla Hoff Development Research Group Macroeconomics and Growth Team January 2018 WPS8317 Public Disclosure Authorized Public Disclosure Authorized Public Disclosure Authorized Public Disclosure Authorized

Transcript of The Making of Behavioral Development Economics...economics adopted a different theory of the...

Page 1: The Making of Behavioral Development Economics...economics adopted a different theory of the economic actor.1 Neoclassical theory assumes an ... political scientist Elinor Ostrom (1990)

Policy Research Working Paper 8317

The Making of Behavioral Development Economics

Allison Demeritt Karla Hoff

Development Research GroupMacroeconomics and Growth TeamJanuary 2018

WPS8317P

ublic

Dis

clos

ure

Aut

horiz

edP

ublic

Dis

clos

ure

Aut

horiz

edP

ublic

Dis

clos

ure

Aut

horiz

edP

ublic

Dis

clos

ure

Aut

horiz

ed

Page 2: The Making of Behavioral Development Economics...economics adopted a different theory of the economic actor.1 Neoclassical theory assumes an ... political scientist Elinor Ostrom (1990)

Produced by the Research Support Team

Abstract

The Policy Research Working Paper Series disseminates the findings of work in progress to encourage the exchange of ideas about development issues. An objective of the series is to get the findings out quickly, even if the presentations are less than fully polished. The papers carry the names of the authors and should be cited accordingly. The findings, interpretations, and conclusions expressed in this paper are entirely those of the authors. They do not necessarily represent the views of the International Bank for Reconstruction and Development/World Bank and its affiliated organizations, or those of the Executive Directors of the World Bank or the governments they represent.

Policy Research Working Paper 8317

This paper is a product of the Macroeconomics and Growth Team, Development Research Group. It is part of a larger effort by the World Bank to provide open access to its research and make a contribution to development policy discussions around the world. Policy Research Working Papers are also posted on the Web at http://econ.worldbank.org. The authors may be contacted at [email protected].

A core insight from early behavioral economics is that much of human judgment and behavior is influenced by “fast thinking” that is intuitive, associative, and automatic; very little human thinking resembles the rational thinking that characterizes homo economicus. What is less well-recog-nized is that innate reliance on cognitive shortcuts means that cultural mental models—categories, concepts, social identities, narratives, and worldviews—profoundly influ-ence judgment and behavior. Individuals have a cultural

“toolkit” or “repertoire” of mental models that they use to perceive and interpret a situation and construct a response.

Many researchers have connected cultural mental models to economic development, yet they rarely identify their research findings as “behavioral” economics. This research constitutes a second strand of behavioral economics that illuminates the tight interlinkages between preferences, culture, and institutions and points to new policy opportu-nities. It brings the discipline almost full circle back to 18th and 19th century perspectives. This essay cautions against strong reductionism in which sociological influences on decision making are squeezed into a rational actor model.

Page 3: The Making of Behavioral Development Economics...economics adopted a different theory of the economic actor.1 Neoclassical theory assumes an ... political scientist Elinor Ostrom (1990)

The Making of Behavioral Development Economics

Allison Demeritt (University of Washington) and Karla Hoff (World Bank)*

 Keywords:      behavioral economics, culture, schema, collective decision making, 

psychological and social influences on decision making 

   JEL codes:  O12, Z13 

 _______ 

*The authors would like to thank Jean Ensminger, Ravi Kanbur, Barry Schwartz, Joseph E. Stiglitz, andtwo anonymous referees for valuable comments.  A shorter version of this essay will appear in History ofPolitical Economy 50 (2018) as part of a special issue on The political economy of development economics: Ahistorical perspective, edited by M. Alacevich and M. Boianovsky.

Page 4: The Making of Behavioral Development Economics...economics adopted a different theory of the economic actor.1 Neoclassical theory assumes an ... political scientist Elinor Ostrom (1990)

 

2  

Table of Contents

1.  Behavioral development economics in historical perspective 

2.  Connections of behavioral development economics to broader social science 

3.  Development economics for the quasi‐rational actor 

Example 1.  Simplifying the ballot process to increase the voice of the poor 

Example 2.  Harnessing loss aversion to amplify teachers’ incentives 

4.  Development economics for the quasi‐rational, enculturated actor 

Example 1.  The plough, patriarchal institutions, and female labor force participation 

Example 2.  Medieval city‐states and modern civic culture in Italy 

Example 3.  Schooling scripts and achievements in learning 

Example 4.  Political reservations in India for women and gender attitudes   

5.  Moving beyond the reductionist quasi‐rational actor 

6.  Conclusion 

REFERENCES 

   

Page 5: The Making of Behavioral Development Economics...economics adopted a different theory of the economic actor.1 Neoclassical theory assumes an ... political scientist Elinor Ostrom (1990)

 

3  

 

1. Behavioral development economics in historical perspective 

 

From the earliest work in economics, many writers recognized that people are not always

rational and that institutions and cultural contexts shape their character (Smith, 1982 [1759];

Hirschman, 1982). Yet with W.S. Jevons’ introduction of mathematical methods into economics

and the creation of neoclassical theory in the 1870s, core research and much of the practice of

economics adopted a different theory of the economic actor.1 Neoclassical theory assumes an

actor with unbounded rationality and exogenous preferences—he is called the rational actor.

Neoclassical theory until the 1970s investigated economic activity independent of institutions

(other than property rights) and independent of culture. Few economists believed that the theory

accurately described how individuals made decisions. Instead, adopting neoclassical

assumptions was widely accepted as the best means of modeling behavior in economic contexts.

In many circles, invoking preference changes as an explanation for behavioral changes was

condemned as bad science (Stigler and Becker, 1977, p. 89).

Development and growth economists could explain a lot with neoclassical theory, and

powerfully so. Central neoclassical applications are capital accumulation and markets with

information problems:

1) Capital accumulation and learning— In the Solow model of growth, the cause of underdevelopment is a shortage of capital and skilled labor. Empirical work drawing on household-level panel data in poor countries

                                                            1 Throughout the 20th century, prominent researchers directed attention to violations of rationality. Keynes discussed “animal spirits” and Simon detailed many aspects of “bounded rationality” (Keynes 1937; Simon 1957). However, this work was often marginalized or ignored because there was little interest in building on a behavioral perspective that lacked a unifying theoretical core. 

Page 6: The Making of Behavioral Development Economics...economics adopted a different theory of the economic actor.1 Neoclassical theory assumes an ... political scientist Elinor Ostrom (1990)

 

4  

demonstrates the additional problem of imperfect knowledge about technology (Foster and Rosenzweig, 1995).

2) The economics of asymmetric information— Introduced by Akerlof (1970) as “a struggling attempt to give structure to the statement: Business in underdeveloped countries is difficult,” the economics of asymmetric information explains inefficiencies in markets in which potential buyers and sellers have different information about what is being exchanged—that is, essentially all markets.

Three extensions of neoclassical theory in the 20th century studied the formation of

institutions . Economists considered institutional responses to asymmetric information,

including sharecropping (Stiglitz, 1974), trade-credit interlinkages (Aleem, 1993), and group

lending (Besley and Coate, 1995). Based on her discovery that common resources, such as

fisheries and grazing lands, are often managed successfully by the people who use them, the

political scientist Elinor Ostrom (1990) developed theoretical underpinnings for institutional

responses to common-pool resources. An adage that shows how her work challenged earlier

beliefs about the “tragedy of the commons” is captured by the eponymous law, “A resource

arrangement that works in practice can work in theory” (Fennell, 2011):

3) The new institutional economics (NIE)— This work investigates how particular institutions emerge and change. Under rational choice theory, it shows that asymmetric information and costly enforcement explain the emergence of non-market institutions. But NIE also shows that individual rationality will not, in general, bring about an efficient global market equilibrium.

NIE focuses on particular institutions. It does not focus on history or power. The

influence of the distribution of power on the kinds of institutions that emerge and the growth that

results was recognized in the analysis of the “quasi-natural experiment” of European

colonialism. Sokoloff and Engerman (2000) and Acemoglu, Johnson, and Robinson (2002)

showed that differences across the colonies in initial inequality of wealth, human capital, and

Page 7: The Making of Behavioral Development Economics...economics adopted a different theory of the economic actor.1 Neoclassical theory assumes an ... political scientist Elinor Ostrom (1990)

 

5  

political influence could explain the differences across the former colonies in economic

performance in the 20th century (a survey is Hoff, 2003): the initially richest areas—rich because

of plantations and mines—were characterized by the highest levels of inequality and became the

poorest in modern times. There was a “reversal of fortune”:

4) The colonial origins of underdevelopment— Across the regions once colonized by European powers, the vast differences in the 18th and 19th centuries in the fraction of the population with access to the vote, schooling, financial markets, and property rights help explain the vast differences in economic performance today. This work focuses on the impact of history on macro-performance.

Research in the colonial origins of underdevelopment draws on a large sample of economies.

But many questions about development cannot be studied across large samples. To make it

possible in those cases to build cumulative knowledge, economic historians introduced an

approach called “analytic narratives.” A theoretical model is built based on a specific historical

problem. For example, Greif (1994) explains why the city-state of Genoa in the early medieval

period established a rule of law to solve the problem of overseas agents behaving

opportunistically during long-distance trade, whereas the Maghribis, who traded all over the

Muslim Mediterranean world, did not. Although based on specific cases, models in analytic

narratives generate testable hypotheses applicable to many cases (Bates et al., 1998).

5) Analytic narratives— Economic historians enlarged neoclassical theory by deductive rational choice modeling of large-scale historical phenomena. History influences the salience of the possible equilibrium outcomes and, therefore, which equilibrium is selected.    

Most work in NIE and analytic narratives retains rational choice theory while bringing

social factors back into economic analysis. As the precision of empirical work in economics

grew, it became increasingly clear that there remained much of importance that rational choice

Page 8: The Making of Behavioral Development Economics...economics adopted a different theory of the economic actor.1 Neoclassical theory assumes an ... political scientist Elinor Ostrom (1990)

 

6  

theory could not explain. There were systematic violations of rational decision-making with

large consequences for welfare, e.g., underuse of fertilizer and under-responsiveness to free

vaccination programs for children (Duflo, Kremer and Robinson, 2008, 2011; Banerjee et al.,

2010).

Esther Duflo put to herself and others the question: when naturally occurring data does

not provide the evidence needed to answer a development question, why not implement an

experiment (Parker, 2010)? To pursue their vision and advise governments on policy design in

all its detail, Duflo and her colleagues founded a lab at MIT. They viewed randomized

controlled trials (RCTs) in field experiments as the best way to learn how to promote economic

development and reduce poverty. The Jameel Poverty Action Lab (JPAL), and many other

organizations, as well, have undertaken RCTs in countries all over the world:

6) RCT-based project evaluations — This approach – in which individuals are randomly allocated to treatment and control groups – has been described as an effort to “transform…development economics, one experiment at a time… Because of the randomness, [treatment and control] groups, if large enough, will have the same complexion: the same mixture of old and young, happy and sad, and every other possible source of experimental confusion. If, at the end of the study, one group turns out to have changed—become wealthier, say—then you can be certain that the change is a result of the treatment...” (Parker, 2010)

Deaton (2010) and other critics contend that RCT-based project evaluation will not lead to a

better understanding of the development process. The success of a treatment may depend on

many mechanisms. Which mechanisms are in place in which contexts is not learned from RCT-

based project evaluation. The critics argue that it is necessary to go back to theory to build a

cumulative research program in economic development. JPAL has indeed increased its use of

“mechanism experiments,” which are RCTs to identify the behavioral mechanisms central to

well-specified policy questions (Deaton, 2010; Jensen, Kling, and Mullainathan, 2011).

Page 9: The Making of Behavioral Development Economics...economics adopted a different theory of the economic actor.1 Neoclassical theory assumes an ... political scientist Elinor Ostrom (1990)

 

7  

In trying to explain behavior, economists had in many cases reached the limit of what they

could do with structural models in rational choice theory. The next approach, which is the focus

of this paper, is based on a psychologically and sociologically more realistic model of decision

making.

It began with the work of two psychologists—Daniel Kahneman and Amos Tversky. In the

1970s and 1980s, they documented predictable violations of the rationality assumption. They

showed that changes in the presentation of choices or in contextual factors that would be

irrelevant to a rational actor could reverse the preferences of experts and non-experts alike

(Tversky and Kahneman, 1981). For example, in two treatments of lung cancer—radiation

treatment and surgery—the same statistics were presented to some respondents in terms of

mortality rates and to others in terms of survival rates. The respondents then indicated their

preferred treatment. The information about the two options was the same, and so neoclassical

economics would predict that the preferences would be the same across formulations. But the

different framing produced a marked effect by changing what automatically came to mind (“fast”

thinking). “The advantage of radiation therapy over surgery evidently looms larger when stated

as a reduction of the risk of immediate death from 10% to 0% rather than as an increase from

90% to 100% in the rate of survival” (p. 596). Kahneman and Tversky’s research led to new

bodies of work, including ‘behavioral finance,’ ‘behavioral macroeconomics,’ and ‘behavioral

game theory.’ Most recently, it has given rise to ‘behavioral development economics’:

7) Behavioral development economics— Behavioral development economics studies problems of economic development using psychologically realistic models of both decision making and preference formation, rather than rational choice theory. Some of the work is informed by the sociological

Page 10: The Making of Behavioral Development Economics...economics adopted a different theory of the economic actor.1 Neoclassical theory assumes an ... political scientist Elinor Ostrom (1990)

 

8  

perspective that “take[s] it as obvious that individuals’ preferences are formed by society and that society, so to speak, exists within persons.”2

For the first time, research across disciplines is producing rigorous evidence that context,

history, and culture affect decision-making. New techniques have expanded the ability to infer

causality from non-experimental data. Research findings are that preferences are influenced by

social networks and experience and exposure through which individuals learn mental models

(such as categories, identities, and narratives) that they use to process information. Myopic

preferences can explain why the wrong types of leaders emerge and well-intentioned reformers

fail to obtain legitimacy (Khemani, 2017).

Table 1: Frameworks to explain economic development outcomes

* Douglass North’s work beginning in the 1990s recognizes the influence of bounded rationality, ideo-logy, and cultural mental models to process information, which makes it an outlier in the category of NIE.

                                                            2 Personal communication from the sociologist, Peter Hedstrom, cited in Fehr and Hoff (2011). An early survey of work on endogenous preferences is Bowles (1998). A history of behavioral economics is Heukelom (2014).

                                                Focus on:  

Approach  

Rational choice with fixed preferences 

Institutions  Culture  Empirical validation of individuals’ intentions 

- Early economics No  Yes  Yes  No 

- Neoclassical growth theory

- Neoclassical price theory, including the economics of asymmetric information

 Yes 

 No 

 No 

 No 

- NIE* and the colonial origins of underdevelopment

- Analytic narratives

 Yes 

 Yes 

 Some 

authors, not others 

 No 

- RCT-based evaluation of projects No  No  No  

Yes 

- Behavioral development economics No  Yes  Yes  Yes 

Page 11: The Making of Behavioral Development Economics...economics adopted a different theory of the economic actor.1 Neoclassical theory assumes an ... political scientist Elinor Ostrom (1990)

 

9  

Table 1 lists the approaches to development economics that we have discussed. The table

makes it easy to see one of the themes of this essay: modern development economics has circled

back to insights made in the 18th and 19th centuries about the limits on rationality and the impact

of institutions and culture on preferences. With the obvious exception of ‘early economics,’ the

approaches listed in Table 1 are alive and well today. Thus, development economics is

fragmented, as it has always been. Even the individual approaches listed in Table 1 are

fragmented. There is no agreement on what constitutes an institution nor, as we discuss later, on

the degree to which culture (under various definitions) is a part of behavioral economics.

Today, the central focus of research and teaching in development economics is on micro-

economics—market failures and RCT-based mechanism evaluations. Graduate students may

read everything from the foundational works in neoclassical economics to research on the

psychology of poverty. Many are steeped in instruction on RCTs. Within development

economics, behavioral development economics is gaining momentum. It is producing a coherent

set of principles to improve the design of development projects and policies. The first journal

symposium on behavioral development economics was published in 2014 (in the Review of

Income and Wealth). In 2015, Harvard University introduced a PhD-level course in behavioral

development economics, and the World Bank presented the first book-length synthesis of work

in this field (World Development Report 2015: Mind, Society, and Behavior). Kremer and Rao

(in progress) are writing the first Handbook survey, entitled “Behavioral Economics and

Development.” Development practitioners have applied behavioral insights in many low- and

middle-income countries and in poor communities of rich countries. Extended discussions of the

successes of these interventions are Datta and Mullainathan (2012), Demeritt and Hoff (2015),

Page 12: The Making of Behavioral Development Economics...economics adopted a different theory of the economic actor.1 Neoclassical theory assumes an ... political scientist Elinor Ostrom (1990)

 

10  

and the World Development Report 2015. The successes launched behavioral development

economics.

2. Connections of behavioral development economics to broader 

social science  

In terms of methodology, behavioral development economics mirrors changes in the

economics discipline as a whole. Hamermesh (2013) studied historical patterns in the

methodologies of papers published in the top three general economic journals (Figure 1). The

share of theory papers declined from 62% in 1983 to 28% in 2011. In the same period, the share

of empirical papers rose from 38% to 64%. Experiments became an important part of the field

for the first time in the mid-1980s and comprised 8% of the papers in 2011.

Figure 1: Methodologies of papers in the top three economics journals, 1983-2011

Source: Data compiled from Hamermesh (2013)

61.6

27.9

37.6

63.9

0.8

8.2

0

10

20

30

40

50

60

70

1983 2011

Percentage of Pap

ers

Type of Paper

Share of Paper by Methodology

Theory Empirical Experiment

Page 13: The Making of Behavioral Development Economics...economics adopted a different theory of the economic actor.1 Neoclassical theory assumes an ... political scientist Elinor Ostrom (1990)

 

11  

Within the field of development economics, the current generation of researchers has

focused on empirics (Ray, 2008). At the Richard T. Ely lecture at the 2017 American Economic

Association Annual Meeting, Duflo (2017) urged economists who are helping governments

design new policies to act not only like scientists and engineers, but also like plumbers.

Plumbers lay pipes and fix leaks and get things to work properly on the ground by adopting an

experimental mindset. Economists who design policy need to recognize that humans are

boundedly rational and are embedded in cultural contexts. Therefore, what worked “there” may

not work “here.”

We next turn to the relationship between behavioral development economics and other

social sciences with respect to “grand theory.” Behavioral development economics does not

offer a new grand theory as an alternative to neoclassical theory. What it offers instead are

realism-improving middle-range theories. Rabin (2013) calls them “PEEMS”—portable

extensions of existing models. They incorporate features of psychology— e.g., limited attention,

limited will power, framing effects, salience (the details that leap out at you), loss aversion,

social identity, and concern with fairness and morality— into an otherwise standard economic

model that translates them into testable predictions. PEEMs address an inconsistency that

Kenneth Arrow noted over 30 years ago:

[A]n economic theorist …toils for months to drive the optimal solution to some complex economic problem, and then blithely assumes that the agents in his model behave as if they are capable of solving the same problem. (Thaler, 2016, p. 162)

A few subfields of behavioral economics, with an example of a PEEM or middle-range theory in

that field in parenthesis, are behavioral finance (prospect theory), behavioral macroeconomics

Page 14: The Making of Behavioral Development Economics...economics adopted a different theory of the economic actor.1 Neoclassical theory assumes an ... political scientist Elinor Ostrom (1990)

 

12  

(present bias), behavioral game theory (limited strategic thinking), and behavioral law and

economics (the availability heuristic).

While an expressed need for mid-level generalizations is relatively new in economics, it has

long propelled work in other social sciences. Robert Merton, one of the ‘founding fathers’ of

modern sociology, penned an essay in 1949 titled “On Sociological Theories of the Middle-

Range.” The essay was a reaction to scholars’ desire for a “total system of sociological theory,”

which Merton argued offered “the same exhilarating challenge and the same small promise as

those many philosophical systems which have fallen into deserved disuse” (p.453). He

advocated “middle-range theory” firmly tethered to empirical data and hypothesis testing.

Modern-day social theorists build on this idea (e.g., Hedstrom and Swedberg, 1998; Elster, 2007;

Hedstrom and Ylikoski, 2010; an argument particular to development is Deaton, 2009). The

behavioral sciences are converging on a shared view of the value of middle-range theory. Such

theories do not match the scope and power of rational choice theory but are necessary for

understanding many behaviors. They provide a framework within which policy tools are

designed, as discussed later.

Many economists have been wary about treading into this territory. The concept of

choice is very ingrained in economists’ thinking. One way of thinking about behavioral

economics is that it tries to clarify the domain of choice. Choice is influenced by the context of

decision making, over which the decision-maker has limited control, and by the categories,

concepts, and narratives through which an individual processes information, over which he has

limited awareness. We will later present four examples (on female labor force participation,

civic culture, learning in education systems,, and gender attitudes) to illustrate how social

constructs emerge and how they constrain or enable choice.

Page 15: The Making of Behavioral Development Economics...economics adopted a different theory of the economic actor.1 Neoclassical theory assumes an ... political scientist Elinor Ostrom (1990)

 

13  

This essay distinguishes two strands of behavioral development economics, following

Camerer (2005) and Hoff and Stiglitz (2016). Strand 1 investigates the ‘quasi-rational’ aspects

of the decision maker in which he ‘thinks fast’ and uses rules of thumb as cognitive shortcuts

that cause him to make errors (Section 3). This strand links economics primarily with work in

psychology and ignores the social and cultural factors that shape important aspects of

psychology. Strand 2 investigates the ‘enculturated’ aspects of the decision maker, examining

how individuals are jointly constituted with their social environments, with consequences for

both individual decision making and group outcomes (Section 4): “modes of interpreting

situations…become characteristic of a given culture…[A]t a given moment in history it is a

group’s beliefs and ideology, rather than immediate features of its objective circumstances, that

may hold the key to its subsequent development” (Ross and Nisbett, 1991, 176).3 Strand 2 links

economics with key ideas in sociology and anthropology.

Although many people associate Strand 1 with the term ‘behavioral economics,’ this line

of work is fundamentally linked with Strand 2. The “fast thinking” of Strand 1 requires for

many of its operations the cultural material of Strand 2. For example, experimenters can induce

dishonesty among bankers by reminding them of their banking identity before they play a game

(Cohn et al. 2014). The identity prime shifts bankers’ minds from one socio-cultural frame (in

which their banking identity is not salient) into another (in which it is) and this shift recruits new

associations, meanings, behavior patterns, preferences, and norms that govern behavior. The

reason the shift happens seamlessly and without individuals’ conscious awareness is their long

history of experience operating in the cultural milieu of banking. Absent that experience, the

                                                            3 Guiso, Sapienza, and Gonzales (2016), discussed below, and Mokyr (2017) provide examples. 

Page 16: The Making of Behavioral Development Economics...economics adopted a different theory of the economic actor.1 Neoclassical theory assumes an ... political scientist Elinor Ostrom (1990)

 

14  

authors show that the prime has no effect. Many Strand 1 effects rely on culturally-specific

mental architecture that is now being investigated as part of Strand 2 behavioral economics.

Whether fast thinking leads you automatically to, for example, overlook women for

leadership roles, or to respond aggressively to an assertion of authority, depends on the

experience and exposure you have had (e.g., Alesina et al., 2013; Heller et al., 2017). “People

think and feel and act in…ways that are shaped by particular patterns of historically derived

meanings, practices, products and institutions” (DiMaggio and Markus, 2010, p. 348). Only

some features of Strand 1 of behavioral economics, such as procrastination, are common to all

known cultures. People universally do not meet the assumptions of homo economicus that

preferences are consistent and fixed, but the mechanisms and manifestations of the departures

are, in part, culturally specific.

Perception entails construction. The anthropologist Mary Douglas (1966, 45-46) writes

that

Whatever we perceive is organised into patterns for which we, the perceivers, are largely responsible. Perceiving is not a matter of passively allowing an organ—say of sight or hearing—to receive a ready-made impression from without, like a palette receiving a spot of paint….As perceivers we select from all the stimuli falling on our senses only those which interest us, and our interests are governed by a pattern-making tendency, sometimes called schema [or equivalently, mental model]…In perceiving we are building, taking some cues and rejecting others. The most acceptable cues are those which fit most easily into the pattern that is being built up…Ambiguous ones tend to be treated as if they harmonised with the rest of the pattern. Discordant ones tend to be rejected...

A cultural toolkit of concepts, categories, identities, narratives, and worldviews, allows people to

“locate, perceive, identify, and label” events in the world around them (Goffman, 1974). A

greater appreciation of the effects of culture on cognition has led scholars in sociology,

Page 17: The Making of Behavioral Development Economics...economics adopted a different theory of the economic actor.1 Neoclassical theory assumes an ... political scientist Elinor Ostrom (1990)

 

15  

psychology, and anthropology to abandon the “entity” view of culture, in which culture

determines a stable and consistent set of preferences, in favor of a dynamic view of culture as

something that happens “in action” as individuals interpret a situation using a cultural “toolkit”

or “repertoire” of concepts, categories, meanings, identities, and narratives and construct a

response (Swidler 1986; DiMaggio 1997). In contrast, most modern economic work that takes

culture into account adopts the entity view of culture. Behavioral economics is beginning to

embrace the toolkit approach, as we discuss below.

The cognitive toolkits people use to assess situations and solve problems can affect

institutional persistence and change. When members of a group share monolithic cultural

experiences, the beliefs and attitudes associated with those experiences can become entrenched

even as available information and technologies change; since attention and perception are shaped

by an individuals’ limited experiences, and since beliefs themselves affect self-confidence and

performance, “fictions” can be sustained in equilibrium, hampering societal development (Hoff

and Stiglitz 2010). Individuals and culture are mutually constituted (Markus and Kitayama

2010), and culture and institutions interact and evolve in complementary ways (Alesina and

Guiliano 2015). Thus culture, preferences, and institutions are all closely related (overviews

from the perspective of behavioral economics are North, 1994; Fehr and Hoff, 2011; and Hoff

and Stiglitz, 2016). North (1990, p. 8) discusses how culture’s effect on individual judgment can

block development:

Incremental change comes from the perceptions of the entrepreneurs in political and economic organizations that they could do better by altering the existing institutional frameworks at some margin. But the perceptions crucially depend on both the information that the entrepreneurs receive and the way they perceive it. If political and economic markets were efficient (i.e., there were zero transaction costs), then the choices made would always be efficient. That is, the actors would always possess true models or if they initially possessed incorrect models, the information feedback would

Page 18: The Making of Behavioral Development Economics...economics adopted a different theory of the economic actor.1 Neoclassical theory assumes an ... political scientist Elinor Ostrom (1990)

 

16  

correct them. But that version of the rational actor model has simply led us astray. The actors frequently must act on incomplete information and process the information that they do receive through mental constructs that can result in persistently inefficient paths. Transaction costs in political and economic markets make for inefficient property rights, but the imperfect subjective models of the players as they attempt to understand the complexities of the problems they confront can lead to the persistence of such property rights.” [emphasis added]

Section 5 of this essay critiques the reductionist tendency in behavioral development

economics, which reduces culture to shared values and rules of thumb. This narrow definition

leaves out of account that culture also provides the cognitive toolkit for perceiving and

interpreting a situation—including categories, concepts, identities, causal narratives, and

worldviews. The cognitive toolkit influences decision making at three levels: perception,

construal, and preferences.

3.  Development economics for the quasi‐rational actor  

Richard Thaler (2000, 136), a founder of Stramd 1 of behavioral economics, views the individual

as “quasi-rational, meaning trying hard but subject to systematic error”: he has fixed preferences

but does not always take actions to achieve his objectives because he is “thinking fast.” What

comes automatically to mind (including associations and narratives that make some things salient

or meaningful) drives his behavior. In general, the pressures of competitive markets do not

correct his mistakes and can make them worse, as when a ‘phisher’ manipulates mental frames

— “the stories people are telling themselves”—to promote sales (Akerlof and Shiller, 2015, p.

172). A hard-to-forget example coming from Akerlof and Shiller is the Cinnabon®. This roll is

cooked in the mall or airport shop that sells it so that its aroma penetrates the surroundings,

attracting potential buyers. People may find it hard to resist the sweet-smelling, 880 calorie bun,

which would undermine any plan to eat healthfully. “Much effort and expertise went into

understanding our weak moments and developing a strategy to take advantage of them” (p. 2).

Page 19: The Making of Behavioral Development Economics...economics adopted a different theory of the economic actor.1 Neoclassical theory assumes an ... political scientist Elinor Ostrom (1990)

 

17  

In middle-income countries, there has been a rapid expansion of door-to-door sales of high-

sweetened, low nutritional foods to poor people, expanding rates of obesity, diabetes, and

undernourishment (New York Times, Sept. 19, 2017, p. A1).

A book titled Nudge (Thaler and Sunstein, 2008) became “the spearhead of behavioral

economics” (The Economist, March 24, 2012). The authors define a nudge as a policy that

changes behavior without substantially changing incentives or information. One way a nudge

works is by changing how easy it is to choose a particular option and by giving immediate

feedback that permits individuals to correct their mistakes. We use two examples to illustrate

how a nudge can promote economic development.

Example 1.  Simplifying the ballot process to increase the voice of the poor    

There is often a high return to public investments in the poor, but relatively little is known about

how to induce governments to increase such investments. The introduction of electronic voting

technology in Brazil in 1998 showed that making it easier for voters to communicate their

preferred choices greatly increased the voice of the poor by reducing the number of error-ridden

votes, particularly by the less educated. The limited number of the devices available in 1998

meant that the electronic voting technology was introduced only in municipalities with more than

a threshold number of voters, while the rest used paper ballots. Brazil requires all adult citizens

to vote. Fujiwara (2015) identifies the impact of the machines by comparing outcomes for

municipalities just above and just below the threshold. By reducing the number of error-ridden

ballots that had to be thrown away, electronic balloting effectively enfranchised 11% of the

voters. Political power in municipalities shifted to the Left. One of the things that legislators

Page 20: The Making of Behavioral Development Economics...economics adopted a different theory of the economic actor.1 Neoclassical theory assumes an ... political scientist Elinor Ostrom (1990)

 

18  

could quickly affect was funding for health care, which is free in Brazil. Funding for public

health care increased by 34% over eight years. The number of pregnant women receiving

regular pre-natal care increased by 20 percent and the number of low-weight births decreased by

6%. As the World Bank Group (2015, 37) notes, “[t]his is a major development success, since

newborn health, controlling for other factors, predicts lifetime health, education, and income.”

Example 2.  Harnessing loss aversion to amplify teachers’ incentives  

Poor education of disadvantaged students contributes to the intergenerational transmission of

poverty. Better performance by their teachers can help children escape poverty as adults. The

rational actor responds to incentive pay, but there is scant evidence that merit pay for teachers is

effective. In a disadvantaged community near Chicago, Fryer et al. (2012) investigated how to

amplify the effect of incentives. They ran a field experiment that involved 150 teachers of

kindergarten through eighth grade in disadvantaged communities. The teachers were randomly

assigned to a control group or one of the two treatment groups, which we will call ‘winners’ and

‘losers.’ The ‘winners’ worked under a traditional year-end bonus scheme, under which they

could make up to $8,000 extra at year-end for strong performance of the students on year-end

standardized tests. The ‘losers’ were given $4,000 at the beginning of the academic year and

were told that at year-end, poor performers would have to return a portion and that the strongest

performers would receive an additional bonus of up to $4,000. The ‘winners’ and ‘losers’ faced

identical financial incentives. Only the framing of the incentive payments differed between the

two groups.

Page 21: The Making of Behavioral Development Economics...economics adopted a different theory of the economic actor.1 Neoclassical theory assumes an ... political scientist Elinor Ostrom (1990)

 

19  

Who performed better? The ‘losers’ did. The improvement in their students’ achievement

was the equivalent of an increase in teachers’ skills by one standard deviation. In contrast,

students with teachers in the ‘winners’ treatment made no achievement gains.

4. Development economics for the quasi‐rational, enculturated actor  

The second strand of behavioral economics focuses on how individuals are enculturated

(in addition to being quasi-rational). Extended exposure to social patterns of, e.g., patriarchy,

racism, or corruption, shapes the categories, identities, narratives, and worldviews that mediate

an individual’s perception of the world. Following North (1994, 2005) and Denzau and North

(1994), we call these cognitive tools mental models. They are “the intuitive set of principles or

ideas of how things work, which govern people’s predictions about the effects of change”

(Camerer, 2005, 72). They matter for decision-making because problems must be represented

in the mind before an individual can solve them. There is always a gap between objective

reality and subjective perception since the experience of reality is mediated by mental models.

The behavioral economist Michael Bacharach (2003; 63, 71) describes the consequence for

economic theory aptly: “one does not just see, one sees as…. [A]n empirically adequate theory

of economic decision-making must model the decision-maker’s problem as she herself sees

it….”

Mental models often enable people to act quickly and effectively (Goldstein and

Gigerenzer, 2002). But sometimes they impede the ability to seize opportunities. A striking

example are seaweed farmers in Indonesia (Hanna, Mullainathan, and Schwartzstein, 2014).

In a random sample of nearly 500 seaweed farmers, nearly all thought that the size of the pod

that they planted did not affect productivity. Depending on how pod size was measured,

farmers’ average estimated loss of income from using an incorrect pod size on their fields was

Page 22: The Making of Behavioral Development Economics...economics adopted a different theory of the economic actor.1 Neoclassical theory assumes an ... political scientist Elinor Ostrom (1990)

 

20  

7% or 38%. Researchers invited farmers to participate in an experiment held on the farmers’

own plots. Farmers were present for the planting and helped with weighing the seaweed and

recording the results. Yet simply having access to data on the relationship between pod size

and yield did not change farmers’ behavior. Only after the experimenters presented each

farmer with a simple summary table of the relationship between pod size and income on his

own fields did a significant number of farmers correct their mistake. This experiment shows

that the farmers’ way of conceptualizing seaweed farming blocked learning. Their mistake

had persisted over many years: the farmers had on average 18 years’ experience and were

descendants of seaweed farmers.

By expanding individuals’ repertoire of mental models—an outcome that is distinct

from simply exposing individuals to new information, as the seaweed example demonstrates—

an intervention can make people much better off.

North (1994) lamented economists’ failure to study the mental models that hinder

economic development. He argued that by distorting perception, mental models may foster the

underdevelopment of a subculture or entire society. Consider as an example the problem

learning to cooperate. All experiments with U.S. subjects have shown that fixed pairs of

players in a repeated assurance game called the Stag Hunt will remarkably quickly form the

Pareto efficient convention. It was believed that this pattern would apply universally. In order

to test that, a repeated Stag Hunt game was played in India. In the experiment in 10 villages in

North India, low-caste men generally formed the efficient convention, as the findings in prior

experiments with U.S. subjects would predict, but high-caste men generally did not. High-

caste men in North India have inherited from earlier socioeconomic regimes a high concern

with status and honor and “acting tough” to deter predators. In the experiment, they seemed to

Page 23: The Making of Behavioral Development Economics...economics adopted a different theory of the economic actor.1 Neoclassical theory assumes an ... political scientist Elinor Ostrom (1990)

 

21  

interpret the loss they bore from miscoordination as an insult, rather than as the innocent

outcome of not-yet-convergent expectations (Brooks, Hoff, and Pandey, 2017). Retaliation to

the perceived insult led to the unraveling of the expectations needed to sustain the efficient

convention.

Institutions possess a “schematizing power” (Bruner, 1990, p. 58): they are a major

source of mental models, the templates needed to interpret situations and construct responses.

Although many institutions are born out of rational needs to reduce uncertainty and improve

coordination, over time they become part of the fabric of society (naturalized, typified) and

provide a ‘taken-for-granted’ reality that frames decision contexts; subjective meanings become

objective facticity (Berger and Luckmann, 1966). Thus, institutions not only reflect cognition

but also shape it by informing “common sense,” which at times is far from common or sensible.

Mary Douglas (1986, 10) describes how institutions create epistemological resources: 

Classifications, logical operations, and guiding metaphors are given to individuals by society. Above all, the sense of a priori rightness of some ideas and the nonsensicality of others are handed out as part of the social environment… Epistemological resources may be able to explain what cannot be explained by the theory of rational behavior.

We next present four examples in which institutions and scripts have influenced

perceptions, with large impacts on economic development.

Example 1.  The plough, patriarchal institutions, and female labor force participation   

Pre-industrial agriculture relied primarily on either shifting cultivation or plough cultivation.

Unlike the hoe or digging stick used to prepare the soil in shifting cultivation, the plough

requires significant strength either to pull it or control the animal that pulls it. In areas that were

topographically well-suited to use of the plough (that is, well-suited to grow wheat, barley, and

rye as opposed to maize, sorghum, and millet), men had an advantage in farming relative to

Page 24: The Making of Behavioral Development Economics...economics adopted a different theory of the economic actor.1 Neoclassical theory assumes an ... political scientist Elinor Ostrom (1990)

 

22  

women, and adoption of the plough created gendered occupations: male specialization in

agriculture and female specialization in domestic activities.

Ethnic groups that historically relied on plough-based agriculture continue in modern

times to have more unequal gender norms towards employment outside the home. In surveys,

individuals from such groups indicate stronger beliefs in gender inequality. In areas well-suited

to use of the plough, compared to areas that are not, female labor force participation in 2000 was

more than 20 percentage points lower; there was also lower participation of women in firm

ownership and politics (Alesina, Guiliano, and Nunn, 2013). The basic trends hold even among

children of immigrants to the U.S. or Europe who are from historically plough-using ethnic

groups. This indicates that cultural beliefs and values are at least partly responsible for the

effects.

Example 2.  Medieval city‐states and modern civic culture in Italy   

In The Moral Basis of a Backward Society, Edward Banfield (1958) argued that a culture of

nepotism and the absence of public-spirited norms kept southern Italy undeveloped compared to

northern Italy. Putnam (1993) took advantage of a natural experiment to show that although the

formal institutions of 15 new Italian regional governments created in the 1960s and 1970s were

identical under national law, their performance was not. Instead, their performance was

correlated with regional differences in civic community which, Putnam argues, date back to the

late Middle Ages. Around the turn of the last millennium, southern regions of Italy were brought

under Norman rule, with political power based on hierarchical religious authority or divine right.

In contrast, northern regions experienced the collapse of the Holy Roman Empire and the rise of

Page 25: The Making of Behavioral Development Economics...economics adopted a different theory of the economic actor.1 Neoclassical theory assumes an ... political scientist Elinor Ostrom (1990)

 

23  

free city-states, which encouraged the growth of horizontal networks and early forms of

participatory democracy.

Guiso, Sapienza, and Gonzales (2016) formally tested Putnam’s hypothesis, measuring

civic culture in modern Italian towns by the number of non-profit organizations, the existence of

an organ donation organization, and the frequency of cheating on a national exam by fifth-grade

students. Looking across 400 Italian cities, they find that civic culture is increasing in the

occurrence, duration, and intensity of an area’s medieval experience as a free city-state. Further,

children in towns with a free city-state legacy have higher self-efficacy than their peers in towns

without such a legacy. The authors suggest that participating in the public life of a free city-state

may have bolstered beliefs about self-efficacy, which were passed down across generations.

Historical events and institutional shocks influence a “nation’s psyche” (p. 1434).

Example 3.  Schooling scripts and achievements in learning   

Institutions provide scripts of appropriate structure and action. The scripts carry normative

obligations that can spur behavior more consistent with a ‘logic of legitimacy’ than a ‘logic of

efficiency.’ In some countries, school systems are driven more by the need to ‘look right’ (i.e.,

to adopt the legitimated formal structures and scripts of schooling, such as a national ministries

and commissions, standardized curricula, enrollment indicators, and record-keeping and

inspection systems) than with producing learning (Meyer and Rowan 1977; an application to

Botswana is Meyer et al., 1993). The result can be an extensive set of structures and practices

associated with education delivery that are nevertheless almost completely decoupled from real

learning.

Page 26: The Making of Behavioral Development Economics...economics adopted a different theory of the economic actor.1 Neoclassical theory assumes an ... political scientist Elinor Ostrom (1990)

 

24  

In India, the information management and state report card system, which was designed

to provide a ‘comprehensive’ and ‘unified’ set of statistics for public schools, is an example:

In the 2011/12 report card for Tamil Nadu, I counted 817 distinct pieces of information reported. But of the 817 pieces of information not a single one could be construed as a direct measure of learning of any kind…In the section called ‘Performance Indicators’ there are 24 distinct measures including the ‘per cent of schools approachable by all-weather road,’ ‘per cent with boundary wall,’ ‘per cent with ramp,’ ‘Pupil teacher ratio.’ There was data on teachers…by gender, by caste, by age, by ‘per cent trained’, by formal qualification. But [a measure of] learning—of any subject, at any age, measured in any way? Not a single number. (Pritchett, 2014)

India’s school system is far from alone in having succumbed to institutionalized scripts at

the expense of productive activity. The primary message of the World Bank’s World

Development Report 2018 is that “schooling is not the same as learning.” Its central policy

recommendation is the astoundingly simple yet deeply important recommendation that

developing countries must begin to act in ways that show that “learning really matters to them”

(World Bank, 2017).

Political and economic forces can create incentives to maintain inefficient institutions and

not take actions to produce learning. But there are also cognitive factors at play: institutional

scripts shape judgments of appropriate behaviors and goals, individuals orient their actions

towards the scripted goals, and this reinforces the strength and legitimacy of the institution.

Societies may get stuck with institutions and systems that few people recognize are broken.

Example 4.  Political reservations in India for women and gender attitudes  

A 1993 amendment to the Constitution of India reserved for a female, in a randomly selected

one-third of village governments, the position of village council head (pradhan). Seven years of

experience of living under a woman pradhan erased male villagers’ prejudice against women

Page 27: The Making of Behavioral Development Economics...economics adopted a different theory of the economic actor.1 Neoclassical theory assumes an ... political scientist Elinor Ostrom (1990)

 

25  

leaders by many measures—an Implicit Association Test, the evaluation of political speeches,

and the assessment of the quality of actual village female pradhans. In villages that had been

exposed to women pradhans, parents’ aspirations for their teenage daughters, and teenage girls’

aspirations for themselves, were higher; and girls went to school somewhat longer and did

somewhat fewer hours of housework. Political reservations for women as pradhan also made

female victims of crime much more willing to report the crimes to the police, and made the

police much more willing to record the reports (Iyer et al., 2012).

5. Moving beyond the reductionist quasi‐rational actor   

One of the strengths of neoclassical theory is its extreme reductionism: with a few principles, it

explains a massive amount of behavior. Since this feature catapulted economics to the top of the

social science status hierarchy, it is not surprising that reductionism also influences the newest

field in economics. Despite growing recognition that social and cultural factors profoundly

influence decision making, economists are generally inclined to squeeze the effects into the

conceptual and linguistic parameters of rational choice theory. However, doing so may limit the

potential of this new field.

We will consider a few examples of reductionist tendencies. Nunn (2012, p. S108) defines

culture as “heuristics or rules of thumb that aid in decision making.” This definition seems too

narrow. Heuristics and rules of thumb can certainly improve decision making. For instance, an

experiment in the Dominican Republic showed that lower-skilled entrepreneurs benefit more

from a training program based on rules of thumb such as ‘keep business and household money in

separate purses’ than training in a standard accounting program (Drexler et al., 2014). But

people cannot be given a ‘heuristic’ or ‘rule of thumb’ to increase community trust, promote

women’s agency, reduce corruption, or end discrimination. The mental models that sustain these

Page 28: The Making of Behavioral Development Economics...economics adopted a different theory of the economic actor.1 Neoclassical theory assumes an ... political scientist Elinor Ostrom (1990)

 

26  

behaviors are too entrenched – they are socially reinforced and psychologically taken-for-

granted—and so they often resist simple attempts at change.

Datta and Mullainathan (2014, 15) recommend condensing principles in behavioral

economics into a framework of “constraints”:

To help navigate the large set of findings, we condense the behavioral literature using one simple perspective about the constraints under which people make decisions. Economists and policymakers – indeed all of us – understand constraints all too well. Resources are limited: there is only so much money, time, staff, or even enthusiasm to go around. Yet we often do not realize that mental resources are also limited…. we often design programs assuming that people have unbounded cognitive capacity.…

Behavioral economics can be interpreted as identifying a few more limited resources. (italics in original)

We will argue that it is too narrow to classify the cognitive effects of psychological, sociological,

and anthropological factors only as resources that enable or limit decision making, since

cognitive resources cannot be handed to an individual. They usually must be acquired through

experience (sometimes repeated experience) to catch hold in the mind.

Consider the authors’ example of diarrhea, which kills over half a million infants in

developing countries each year, with most of the deaths easily preventable through the use of a

sugar and salt water solution (Oral Rehydration Solution (ORS)). The authors ask, why isn’t

ORS used enough? Since parents see a child with diarrhea as leaking fluids, 35-50% of them say

that the best treatment is to keep the child ‘dry’ by reducing fluid intake. Datta and Mullainathan

describe the failure to use ORS as a “scarcity of understanding” (arising from a false mental

model). This statement is true. But the terminology underplays the cognitive shifts that need to

happen for behavior to change, and the interventions required to change a mental model.

Page 29: The Making of Behavioral Development Economics...economics adopted a different theory of the economic actor.1 Neoclassical theory assumes an ... political scientist Elinor Ostrom (1990)

 

27  

Gawande (2013) describes how Bangladesh attacked the problem. A pilot project team

set out to reach 60,000 women in 600 villages:

They travelled on foot, pitched camp near each village, fanned out door to door, and stayed until they had talked to women in every hut…Initially, the workers taught up to 20 mothers per day. But monitors visiting the villages a few weeks later found that the quality of teaching suffered on this larger scale, so the workers were restricted to 10 households a day. Then a new salary system was devised to pay each worker according to how many of the messages the mothers retained when the monitor followed up. The quality of teaching improved substantially. The field workers soon realized that having the mothers make the solution themselves was more effective than just showing them. The workers began looking for diarrhea cases when they arrived in a village, and treating them to show how effective and safe the remedy was.

When the Government of Bangladesh took the program nationwide, it hired, trained, and

deployed thousands of workers, region by region, who went door-to-door to show 12 million

families how to save their children. As Gawande describes it, “The program was stunningly

successful…the knowledge became self-propagating. The program had changed the norms.”

Surveys showed that nearly 80 percent of recent diarrhea episodes were treated with the solution.

Most women in Bangladesh now teach their children about oral rehydration, eliminating the need

for repeated campaigns. But in countries that adopted an arm’s-length approach, the information

campaign failed almost entirely. Policy makers who are asked to remedy a “scarcity of

understanding” about diarrhea treatment might reasonably assume that they need simply to get

the right information to the right people; it is not clear that the policy makers would come up

with anything close to what happened in Bangladesh.

Our concerns could be dismissed as a quibble over language, but a theme of behavioral

economics is that language and labels make a difference for understanding. This is especially

true in fields that are closely tied to policy. In an academic setting, common training and

frequent interaction among individuals means that a nuanced understanding of ideas can more

Page 30: The Making of Behavioral Development Economics...economics adopted a different theory of the economic actor.1 Neoclassical theory assumes an ... political scientist Elinor Ostrom (1990)

 

28  

easily be assumed, and reductionism simplifies communication in useful ways. But in a field

that depends on collaboration among people with different backgrounds and priorities, common

understanding should not be assumed, and ‘short-hand’ communication can impede

comprehension and backfire. One need not look far to find well-designed programs that failed

during implementation because too little attention was paid to the socio-psychological

mechanisms behind behavior change. A rule of thumb is a simple tool that is normally easy to

teach; and sometimes understanding is impeded by a simple knowledge ‘constraint’ (e.g., the fact

that water can be contaminated after it is chlorinated). In contrast, mental models are often

deeply intertwined with cultural values and expectations regarding the actions and judgments of

others (e.g., the social roles of men and women). Reducing the latter (cultural values and

expectations) to the former (a simple knowledge constraint) belies what it takes to change mental

models.

Akerlof has noted that ideas that fall outside the typical province of economics are

generally regarded as “taboo” within the discipline. He argued that although rational choice

theory is probably adequate for analyzing most types of economic behavior, a new field of

“psycho-socio-anthropo-economics” is “probably applicable to the big problems, to the really big

things that we don’t yet understand in economics…it is probably applicable to the question of

why underdeveloped countries are so poor” (interview in Swedberg, 1990, p. 68). Studies

associated with 21st century behavioral economics borrow ideas from these disciplines, but

sometimes screen out useful interpretations and causal connections (Davis, 2013). Successfully

addressing dysfunctional organizations and institutions around the world requires recognizing a

quasi-rational, enculturated actor. In many ways, the interventions at the frontier of behavioral

Page 31: The Making of Behavioral Development Economics...economics adopted a different theory of the economic actor.1 Neoclassical theory assumes an ... political scientist Elinor Ostrom (1990)

 

29  

development economics are as much ‘development sociology’ and ‘development psychology’ as

they are development economics.

6. Conclusion 

Behavioral development economics is an emerging subfield that is generating increasing interest

among researchers and policy makers. This essay covers its brief history, mostly in the 21st

century. Many of its insights, by incorporating multiple dimensions of human behavior, can be

traced back to the earliest work in economics—by Adam Smith, Vilfredo Pareto, J.S. Mill., Max

Weber, and others. What is new in the 21st century is the strength of the evidence behind these

insights, produced by recent work using RCT and econometric analysis of naturally occurring

data. In recent years, research that sheds light on the mechanisms behind human behavior has

increased. From that perspective, development economics has gone micro, instead of the

prevailing macro stance of the 1950s and 1960s. The goal of behavioral economists is not to

replace the powerful theory of rational choice, but to supplement it with mid-level theories that

improve explanation and policy design.

The approach is not yet a cohesive field. Some people associate it only with the work of

Kahneman and Tversky and the ‘nudge’ paradigm, whereas this essay points to a rapidly

growing body of work demonstrating that (1) experience and exposure shape preferences and

bias perception; and (2) interventions that harness this power can improve well-being. Some

economists would like to see the framework of behavioral economics expanded (for example, by

incorporating emotions more fully). But many also feel compelled to squeeze behavioral

findings into a reductionist framework in which neoclassical economics is augmented only with

Page 32: The Making of Behavioral Development Economics...economics adopted a different theory of the economic actor.1 Neoclassical theory assumes an ... political scientist Elinor Ostrom (1990)

 

30  

shared preferences and rules of thumb. Like development economics, behavioral development

economics itself encompasses a diverse array of approaches that remain fragmented.

Behavioral development economics is trying to answer many of the same questions

investigated in two earlier bodies of work –NIE and research on the colonial origins of

underdevelopment. NIE explained, for example, the existence of sharecropping contracts but

could not explain why the terms of the contracts within villages or regional “patches” were

nearly uniform (despite variable soil quality), separated by boundaries where contractual terms

were variable or jumped substantially from one set of terms to another. Young and Burke (2001)

explained the puzzle by bringing in the psychology of bargaining: the focal power of particular

shares, such as one-half or one-third, and concerns to conform to choices that other contracting

parties had made. The work on colonial origins of underdevelopment explained the 19th century

differences in growth rates across former European colonies, but could not easily explain the

durability of the effect of colonial origins.

Behavioral development economics points to the importance of increasing our

understanding of the historically derived social machinery that affords certain psychological

tendencies that from the perspective of the global North seem irrational, lawless, deficient, and

immoral (e.g., pervasive mistrust, protection of family honor, nepotism, cronyism, and

corruption). Investigating this social machinery can illuminate the cultural logic of these

tendencies and how and why they persist; it can also suggest where and how it might be possible

to intervene (personal communication from Hazel Rose Markus).

There used to be a clear boundary in economics between what was changeable and what

was not—the hardware of the brain versus its software, genetics versus culture. But the

boundary is no longer clear. Epigenetics shows that the environment can determine which genes

Page 33: The Making of Behavioral Development Economics...economics adopted a different theory of the economic actor.1 Neoclassical theory assumes an ... political scientist Elinor Ostrom (1990)

 

31  

are expressed and which ones are not. Culture determines how we process information—what is

absorbed and what is misinterpreted or blocked. The fact that beliefs affect what individuals pay

attention to and how they process information can explain why some mistakes are not corrected

in a generation (Hanna et al., 2017) or even over generations (Hoff and Stiglitz, 2010 and 2016).

Economics is about explaining and predicting change and designing policies to foster

welfare-increasing change. The old view of development economics, with strict boundaries

separating it from other social sciences, explained development and growth in terms of changes

in physical and human capital while human beings and institutions stayed the same. A later view

allowed for endogenous institutions. Behavioral economics allows people to change, too.

Behavioral development economics can explain the possibility of large social and economic

changes without shifts in capital stocks or economic incentives, but it cannot yet predict when

they will occur. And it does not know yet what are the limits of change.

 

   

Page 34: The Making of Behavioral Development Economics...economics adopted a different theory of the economic actor.1 Neoclassical theory assumes an ... political scientist Elinor Ostrom (1990)

 

32  

REFERENCES  

Acemoglu, Daron, Simon Johnson, and James A. Robinson. 2002. “Reversal of Fortune” Quarterly Journal 

of Economics 117 (4):1231–94. 

Akerlof, George. 1970. “The Market for ‘Lemons’: Quality Uncertainty and the Market Mechanism.” 

Quarterly Journal of Economics 84(3):488‐500. 

_________ 1984. An Economic Theorist’s Book of Tales, Cambridge: Cambridge University Press. 

_________ and Robert J. Shiller.  2015.  Phishing for Phools. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press. 

Aleem, Irfan.  1993. Imperfect information, screening, and the costs of informal lending.  In:  Hoff, K., 

Braverman, A., and J.E.Stiglitz. Oxford University Press, 131‐153. 

Alesina, Alberto and Paola Giuliano. 2015. “Culture and Institutions.” Journal of Economic Literature 

53(4): 898–944 

Alesina, Alberto, Paola Giuliano, and Nathan Nunn. 2013. "On the Origins of Gender Roles: Women and 

the Plough." Quarterly Journal of Economics 128(2): 469‐530. 

Bacharach, Michael. 2003. “Framing and cognition in economics:  The bad new and the good.” In 

Cognitive Processes and Economic Behaviour.  Eds N. Dimitri, M. Basili, and I. Gilboa.  London: Routledge.   

Banerjee, Abhijit, Esther Duflo, Rachel Glennerster, and Dhruva Kothari. 2010. “Improving immunization 

coverage in rural India.” British Medical Journal 340 

Banfield, Edward C. 1958. The Moral Basis of a Backward Society. Free Press. 

Bates, Robert, Avner Greif, Margaret Levi, Jean‐Laurent Rosenthal, Barry Weingast. 1998. Analytic 

Narratives. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press. 

Berger, Peter and Thomas Luckmann. 1966. The Social Construction of Reality. New York:  Anchor. 

Besley, Timothy and Stephen Coate. 1995. “Group lending, repayment incentives and social collateral.  

Journal of Development Economics 46(1):1‐18. 

Bowles, Samuel. 1998. “Endogenous Preferences: The Cultural Consequences of Markets and Other 

Economic Institutions.” Journal of Economic Literature 36(1): 75‐111 

Brooks, Benjamin, Karla Hoff, and Priyanka Pandey. 2017.  "High‐caste culture in North India impedes 

learning to cooperate.” Manuscript, World Bank.        

Bruner, Jerome. 1990. Acts of Meaning. Cambridge: Harvard University Press. 

Camerer, Colin F. 2005. "Comments on ‘Development Economics through the Lens of Psychology’ by 

Sendhil Mullainathan” in Lessons of Experience: Annual World Bank Conference on Development 

Economics, World Bank. 

Cohn, Alain, Ernst Fehr, and Michel Andre Marechal. 2014. “Business culture and dishonesty in the 

banking industry.” Nature  516, 86–89 (04 December 2014) 

Page 35: The Making of Behavioral Development Economics...economics adopted a different theory of the economic actor.1 Neoclassical theory assumes an ... political scientist Elinor Ostrom (1990)

 

33  

Datta, Saugato and Mullainathan, Sendhil. 2014. "Behavioral Design: A New Approach to Development 

Policy." Review of Income and Wealth Series 60(1) 

Davis, John B., 2013. “Economics Imperialism under the Impact of Psychology: The Case of Behavioral 

Development Economics.” OEconomia, 3‐1: 119‐138. 

Deaton, Angus. 2010. “Instruments, Randomization, and Learning about Development.” Journal of 

Economic Literature 48(2):424‐455 

Demeritt, Allison and Karla Hoff. 2015. “Small Miracles – Behavioral Insights to Improve Development 

Policy: World Development Report 2015” in Contemporary Issues in Development Economics, edited by 

Tim Besley, Palgrave Macmillan, Chapter 3, pp. 19‐43.   

Denzau, Arthur T. and Douglass C. North. 1994. “Shared mental models: Ideologies and Institutions.” 

Kyklos 47(1), pp. 3‐31. 

DiMaggio, Paul, 1997. “Culture and cognition.” Annual Review of Sociology 23: 263‐287   

DiMaggio, Paul and Hazel Markus. 2010. “Culture and Social Psychology: Converging Perspectives” Social Psychology Quarterly 73(4): 347‐352  Douglas, Mary. 1966.  Purity and Danger.  New York: Routledge. 

____________. 1986.  How Institutions Think. Syracuse, NY: Syracuse University Press. 

Drexler, Alejandro, Greg Fischer, and Antoinette Schoar. 2014. "Keeping It Simple: Financial Literacy and 

Rules of Thumb." American Economic Journal: Applied Economics, 6(2):1‐31. 

Duflo, Esther, Michael Kremer and James Robinson. 2008. “How High Are Rates of Return to Fertilizer? 

Evidence from Field Experiments in Kenya.” American Economic Review 98(2): 482‐488.  

Duflo, Esther, Michael Kremer and James Robinson. 2011. “Nudging Farmers to Use Fertilizer: Theory 

and Experiments Evidence from Kenya.” American Economic Review 10(6): 2350‐2390 

Duflo, Esther. 2017. "Richard T. Ely Lecture: The Economist as Plumber." American Economic Review, 

107(5): 1‐26 

Elster, Jon. 2007. Explaining Social Behavior. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press 

Fehr, Ernst and Karla Hoff. 2011. “Introduction—Tastes, Castes and Culture: The Influence of Society on 

Preferences.” Economic Journal 121(556): F396‐F412 

Fennell, Lee Anne (2011). "Ostrom's Law: Property rights in the commons". International Journal of the 

Commons. 5 (1): 9–27. 

Foster, Andrew and Mark Rosenzweig.  1995.  “Learning by doing and learning from others: Human 

capital and technical change in agriculture.”  Journal of Political Economy 103(6):1176‐1209. 

Fryer, Roland G., Steven D. Levitt, John List and Sally Sadoff. 2012. “Enhancing the Efficacy of Teacher 

Incentives through Loss Aversion: A Field Experiment.” NBER Working Paper No. 18237. 

Page 36: The Making of Behavioral Development Economics...economics adopted a different theory of the economic actor.1 Neoclassical theory assumes an ... political scientist Elinor Ostrom (1990)

 

34  

Fujiwara, Thomas. 2015. “Voting technology, political responsiveness, and infant health:  Evidence from 

Brazil.” Econometrica 83(2):423‐64. 

Gawande, Atul. 2013. “Slow Ideas.” The New Yorker, July 29. 

Goldstein, Daniel G. and Gerd Gigerenzer. 2002. “Models of Ecological Rationality: The Recognition 

Heuristic.” Psychological Review 109(1): 75‐90 

Goffman, Erving. 1974. Frame Analysis: An Essay on the Organization of Experience. Cambridge: Harvard 

University Press 

Greif, Avner. 1994. “Cultural Beliefs and the Organization of Society.” Journal of Political Economy 

102(5): 912‐950 

Guiso, Luigi, Paola Sapienza, and Luigi Gonzales. 2016. “Long‐term persistence.” Journal of the European 

Economic Association 14(6):1401–1436 

Hamermesh, Daniel. 2013. "Six decades of top economics publishing: Who and how?" Journal of 

Economic Literature, 51(1):162‐172. 

Hanna, Rema, Sendhil Mullainathan and Joshua Schwartzstein. 2014. “Learning Through Noticing: 

Theory and Evidence from a Field Experiment.” Quarterly Journal of Economics 129(3):1311‐1353 

Hedstrom, Peter and Richard Swedberg. 1998. Social Mechanisms: An Analytical Approach to Social 

Theory (Studies in Rationality and Social Change). Cambridge: Cambridge University Press 

Hedstrom, Peter and Petri Ylikoski. 2010. “Causal Mechanisms in the Social Sciences.” Annual Review of 

Sociology 36: 49‐67  

Heller, S. B., Shah, A. K., Guryan, J., Ludwig, J., Mullainathan, S., & Pollack, H. A. (2017). “Thinking, fast 

and slow? Some field experiments to reduce crime and dropout in Chicago.” Quarterly Journal of 

Economics. 132(1):1‐54. 

Heukelom, Floris. 2014. Behavioral Economics: A History. Cambridge, UK:  Cambridge University Press. 

Hirschman, Albert O. 1982.  “Rival interpretations of market society:  Civilizing, destructive, or feeble?”  

Journal of Economic Literature 20:1463‐1484. 

Hoff, Karla. 2003. “Paths of institutional development:  A view from economic history.” World Bank 

Research Observer 19(2): 205‐226. 

Hoff, Karla and Joseph. E. Stiglitz. 2010. “Equilibrium fictions.” American Economic Review100: 141‐146.   

Hoff, Karla and Joseph E. Stiglitz. 2016.  “Striving for balance in economics:  Towards a theory of the 

social determination of behavior.” Journal of Economic Behavior and Organization 126(B):25‐57. 

Iyer, Lakshmi, Anandi Mani, Prachi Mishra, and Petia Topalova. 2012. "The power of political voice: 

Women's political representation and crime in India." American Economic Journal: Applied Economics, 

4(4): 65‐193. 

Page 37: The Making of Behavioral Development Economics...economics adopted a different theory of the economic actor.1 Neoclassical theory assumes an ... political scientist Elinor Ostrom (1990)

 

35  

Kahneman, Daniel. 2011. Thinking, Fast and Slow.  New York:  Farrar, Straus, and Giroux.Keynes, John 

Maynard. 1936. The General Theory of Employment, Interest, and Money. London: Macmillan and Co., 

limited 

Khemani, Stuti. 2017. “Political economy of reform.” World Bank, manuscript.  

Kremer, Michael and Gautam Rao.” In progress.  “Behavioral economics and development.” In 

Bernheim, DellaVigna, and Laibson (eds.), Handbook of Behavioral Economics, in progress 

Ludwig, Jens, Jeffrey Kling, and Sendhil Mullainathan. 2011. "Mechanism experiments and policy 

evaluations." Journal of Economic Perspectives, 25(3):17‐38. 

Markus, Hazel and Shinobu Kitayama. 2010. “Cultures and selves:  A cycle of mutual constitution.” 

Perspectives on Psychological Science 5(4):420‐430 

Merton, Robert. 1949. Social Theory and Social Structure. New York:  Free Press. 

Meyer, John W. and Brian Rowan. 1977. “Institutionalized Organizations: Formal Structure as Myth and 

Ceremony.” American Journal of Sociology 83(2): 340‐363  

Meyer, John W., Joane Nagel and Conrad W. Snyder Jr. 1993. “The Expansion of Mass Education in 

Botswana: Local and World Society Perspectives.” Comparative Education Review 37(4): 454‐475 

Mokyr, Joel. 2017.A Culture of Growth:  The Origins of the Modern Economy. Princeton:  Princeton 

University Press. 

New York Times. 2017. “How Big Business Got Brazil Hooked on Junk Food.” Sept. 17,  A1. 

North, Douglass C. 1990. Institutions, institutional Change and Economic Performance, Cambridge: Cambridge University Press 

North, Douglass C.  1994. “Economic performance through time.” American Economic Review 84(3):359‐68. 

North, Douglass C. 2005.  Understanding the Process of Economic Change.  Princeton: Princeton University Press.  

Nunn, Nathan. 2012. “Culture and the historical process,” Economic History of Developing Regions, Vol. 

27, Supplement 1:108‐126. 

Ostrom, Elinor (1990). Governing the Commons: The Evolution of Institutions for Collective Action. 

Cambridge, UK: Cambridge University Press. 

Parker, Ian. 2010. “The Poverty Lab: Transforming development economics, one experiment at a time.” 

The New Yorker, May 7. 

Pritchett, Lant. 2014. “The Risks to Education Systems from Design Mismatch and Global Isomorphism” 

Center for International Development Working Paper No. 277.  

Putnam, Robert. 1993. Making Democracy Work: Civic Traditions in Modern Italy. Princeton: Princeton 

University Press. 

Page 38: The Making of Behavioral Development Economics...economics adopted a different theory of the economic actor.1 Neoclassical theory assumes an ... political scientist Elinor Ostrom (1990)

 

36  

Rabin, Matthew.  2013. “An approach to incorporating psychology into economics.”  American Economic 

Review 103(3): 617‐622. 

Ray, Debraj. 2008. “Development Economics”, in The New Palgrave Dictionary of Economics, eds. 

Lawrence Blume and Steven Durlauf. Palgrave Macmillan 

Ross, Lee, and Richard E. Nisbett. 1991. The Person and the Situation.  London:  McGraw‐Hill 

Simon, Herbert A. 1957 [1947]. Administrative Behavior: A Study of Decision‐Making Processes in 

Administrative Organization (2nd ed.). New York: Macmillan. 

Smith, Adam. 1982 [1759]. The Theory of Moral Sentiments. Indianapolis: Liberty Fund. 

Sokoloff, Kenneth and Stanley Engerman. 2000. "Institutions, factor endowments, and paths of 

development in the New World." Journal of Economic Perspectives, 14(3):217‐232.  

Stigler, G. J. and Becker, G. 1977. De gustibus non est disputandum, American Economic Review 

67(2):76–90. 

Stiglitz, Joseph E. 1974. “Incentives and risk sharing in sharecropping. Review of Economic Studies 41:219‐255. 

Swedberg, Richard.  1990.  Economics and Sociology. Princeton: Princeton University Press 

Swidler, Ann. 1986. “Culture in Action: Symbols and Strategies.” American Sociological Review 51(2): 

273‐286. 

Thaler, Richard.  2000. Misbehaving: The Making of Behavioral Development Economics. W.W.Norton. 

______ and Cass Sunstein. 2008. Nudge. New York: Penguin Books.  

Tversky, Amos and Daniel Kahneman. 1981. “The Framing of Decisions and the Psychology of Choice.” 

Science. 211(30):453‐457 

___________________. 1986. “Rational Choice and the Framing of Decisions” Journal of Business  59(4: 

Part 2). S251‐S278. 

World Bank Group. 2015. World Development Report: Mind, Society and Behavior, Washington DC. 

World Bank Group. 2017. World Development Report 2018: LEARNING to Realize Education’s Promise, 

Washington DC. 

Young, H., Peyton, and Mary A. Burke. 2001. "Competition and Custom in Economic Contracts: A Case Study of Illinois Agriculture." American Economic Review, 91(3): 559‐573.