The Incentives of Hedge Fund Fees and High-Water Marks

113
Problem Model Solution Welfare Implications The Incentives of Hedge Fund Fees and High-Water Marks Paolo Guasoni (Joint work with Jan Obloj) Boston University and Dublin City University Workshop on Foundations of Mathematical Finance January 12 th , 2010

Transcript of The Incentives of Hedge Fund Fees and High-Water Marks

Page 1: The Incentives of Hedge Fund Fees and High-Water Marks

Problem Model Solution Welfare Implications

The Incentives ofHedge Fund Fees and High-Water Marks

Paolo Guasoni(Joint work with Jan Obłoj)

Boston University and Dublin City University

Workshop on Foundations of Mathematical FinanceJanuary 12th, 2010

Page 2: The Incentives of Hedge Fund Fees and High-Water Marks

Problem Model Solution Welfare Implications

Background

Paul Krugman, How Did Economists Get It So Wrong?NY Times Magazine, September 2, 2009“...the economics profession went astray because economists,as a group, mistook beauty, clad in impressive-lookingmathematics, for truth.”“Economics, as a field, got in trouble because economists wereseduced by the vision of a perfect, frictionless market system.”

John Cochrane, How Did Krugman Get It So Wrong?“No, the problem is that we don’t have enough math.”“Frictions are just bloody hard with the mathematical tools wehave now.”

Make Frictions Tractable.One Step at a Time.

Page 3: The Incentives of Hedge Fund Fees and High-Water Marks

Problem Model Solution Welfare Implications

Background

Paul Krugman, How Did Economists Get It So Wrong?NY Times Magazine, September 2, 2009“...the economics profession went astray because economists,as a group, mistook beauty, clad in impressive-lookingmathematics, for truth.”“Economics, as a field, got in trouble because economists wereseduced by the vision of a perfect, frictionless market system.”

John Cochrane, How Did Krugman Get It So Wrong?“No, the problem is that we don’t have enough math.”“Frictions are just bloody hard with the mathematical tools wehave now.”

Make Frictions Tractable.One Step at a Time.

Page 4: The Incentives of Hedge Fund Fees and High-Water Marks

Problem Model Solution Welfare Implications

Background

Paul Krugman, How Did Economists Get It So Wrong?NY Times Magazine, September 2, 2009“...the economics profession went astray because economists,as a group, mistook beauty, clad in impressive-lookingmathematics, for truth.”“Economics, as a field, got in trouble because economists wereseduced by the vision of a perfect, frictionless market system.”

John Cochrane, How Did Krugman Get It So Wrong?“No, the problem is that we don’t have enough math.”“Frictions are just bloody hard with the mathematical tools wehave now.”

Make Frictions Tractable.

One Step at a Time.

Page 5: The Incentives of Hedge Fund Fees and High-Water Marks

Problem Model Solution Welfare Implications

Background

Paul Krugman, How Did Economists Get It So Wrong?NY Times Magazine, September 2, 2009“...the economics profession went astray because economists,as a group, mistook beauty, clad in impressive-lookingmathematics, for truth.”“Economics, as a field, got in trouble because economists wereseduced by the vision of a perfect, frictionless market system.”

John Cochrane, How Did Krugman Get It So Wrong?“No, the problem is that we don’t have enough math.”“Frictions are just bloody hard with the mathematical tools wehave now.”

Make Frictions Tractable.One Step at a Time.

Page 6: The Incentives of Hedge Fund Fees and High-Water Marks

Problem Model Solution Welfare Implications

Outline

High-Water Marks:Performance Fees for Hedge Funds Managers.

Model:Power Utility with Long Horizon.Solution:Effective Risk Aversion and Drawdown Constraints.Fees and Welfare:Stackelberg Equilibrium between Investor and Manager

Page 7: The Incentives of Hedge Fund Fees and High-Water Marks

Problem Model Solution Welfare Implications

Outline

High-Water Marks:Performance Fees for Hedge Funds Managers.Model:Power Utility with Long Horizon.

Solution:Effective Risk Aversion and Drawdown Constraints.Fees and Welfare:Stackelberg Equilibrium between Investor and Manager

Page 8: The Incentives of Hedge Fund Fees and High-Water Marks

Problem Model Solution Welfare Implications

Outline

High-Water Marks:Performance Fees for Hedge Funds Managers.Model:Power Utility with Long Horizon.Solution:Effective Risk Aversion and Drawdown Constraints.

Fees and Welfare:Stackelberg Equilibrium between Investor and Manager

Page 9: The Incentives of Hedge Fund Fees and High-Water Marks

Problem Model Solution Welfare Implications

Outline

High-Water Marks:Performance Fees for Hedge Funds Managers.Model:Power Utility with Long Horizon.Solution:Effective Risk Aversion and Drawdown Constraints.Fees and Welfare:Stackelberg Equilibrium between Investor and Manager

Page 10: The Incentives of Hedge Fund Fees and High-Water Marks

Problem Model Solution Welfare Implications

Two and Twenty

Hedge Funds Managers receive two types of fees.

Regular fees, like Mutual Funds.Unlike Mutual Funds, Performance Fees.Regular fees:a fraction ϕ of assets under management. 2% typical.Performance fees:a fraction α of trading profits. 20% typical.High-Water Marks:Performance fees paid after losses recovered.

Page 11: The Incentives of Hedge Fund Fees and High-Water Marks

Problem Model Solution Welfare Implications

Two and Twenty

Hedge Funds Managers receive two types of fees.Regular fees, like Mutual Funds.

Unlike Mutual Funds, Performance Fees.Regular fees:a fraction ϕ of assets under management. 2% typical.Performance fees:a fraction α of trading profits. 20% typical.High-Water Marks:Performance fees paid after losses recovered.

Page 12: The Incentives of Hedge Fund Fees and High-Water Marks

Problem Model Solution Welfare Implications

Two and Twenty

Hedge Funds Managers receive two types of fees.Regular fees, like Mutual Funds.Unlike Mutual Funds, Performance Fees.

Regular fees:a fraction ϕ of assets under management. 2% typical.Performance fees:a fraction α of trading profits. 20% typical.High-Water Marks:Performance fees paid after losses recovered.

Page 13: The Incentives of Hedge Fund Fees and High-Water Marks

Problem Model Solution Welfare Implications

Two and Twenty

Hedge Funds Managers receive two types of fees.Regular fees, like Mutual Funds.Unlike Mutual Funds, Performance Fees.Regular fees:a fraction ϕ of assets under management. 2% typical.

Performance fees:a fraction α of trading profits. 20% typical.High-Water Marks:Performance fees paid after losses recovered.

Page 14: The Incentives of Hedge Fund Fees and High-Water Marks

Problem Model Solution Welfare Implications

Two and Twenty

Hedge Funds Managers receive two types of fees.Regular fees, like Mutual Funds.Unlike Mutual Funds, Performance Fees.Regular fees:a fraction ϕ of assets under management. 2% typical.Performance fees:a fraction α of trading profits. 20% typical.

High-Water Marks:Performance fees paid after losses recovered.

Page 15: The Incentives of Hedge Fund Fees and High-Water Marks

Problem Model Solution Welfare Implications

Two and Twenty

Hedge Funds Managers receive two types of fees.Regular fees, like Mutual Funds.Unlike Mutual Funds, Performance Fees.Regular fees:a fraction ϕ of assets under management. 2% typical.Performance fees:a fraction α of trading profits. 20% typical.High-Water Marks:Performance fees paid after losses recovered.

Page 16: The Incentives of Hedge Fund Fees and High-Water Marks

Problem Model Solution Welfare Implications

High-Water Marks

Time Gross Net High-Water Mark Fees0 100 100 100 01 110 108 108 22 100 100 108 23 118 116 116 4

Fund assets grow from 100 to 110.The manager is paid 2, leaving 108 to the fund.

Fund drops from 108 to 100.No fees paid, nor past fees reimbursed.Fund recovers from 100 to 118.Fees paid only on increase from 108 to 118.Manager receives 2.

Page 17: The Incentives of Hedge Fund Fees and High-Water Marks

Problem Model Solution Welfare Implications

High-Water Marks

Time Gross Net High-Water Mark Fees0 100 100 100 01 110 108 108 22 100 100 108 23 118 116 116 4

Fund assets grow from 100 to 110.The manager is paid 2, leaving 108 to the fund.Fund drops from 108 to 100.No fees paid, nor past fees reimbursed.

Fund recovers from 100 to 118.Fees paid only on increase from 108 to 118.Manager receives 2.

Page 18: The Incentives of Hedge Fund Fees and High-Water Marks

Problem Model Solution Welfare Implications

High-Water Marks

Time Gross Net High-Water Mark Fees0 100 100 100 01 110 108 108 22 100 100 108 23 118 116 116 4

Fund assets grow from 100 to 110.The manager is paid 2, leaving 108 to the fund.Fund drops from 108 to 100.No fees paid, nor past fees reimbursed.Fund recovers from 100 to 118.Fees paid only on increase from 108 to 118.Manager receives 2.

Page 19: The Incentives of Hedge Fund Fees and High-Water Marks

Problem Model Solution Welfare Implications

High-Water Marks

20 40 60 80 100

0.5

1.0

1.5

2.0

2.5

Page 20: The Incentives of Hedge Fund Fees and High-Water Marks

Problem Model Solution Welfare Implications

Risk Shifting?

Manager shares investors’ profits, not losses.Does manager take more risk to increase profits?

Option Pricing Intuition:Manager has a call option on the fund value.Option value increases with volatility. More risk is better.Static, Complete Market Fallacy:Manager has multiple call options.High-Water Mark: future strikes depend on past actions.Option unhedgeable: cannot short (your!) hedge fund.

Page 21: The Incentives of Hedge Fund Fees and High-Water Marks

Problem Model Solution Welfare Implications

Risk Shifting?

Manager shares investors’ profits, not losses.Does manager take more risk to increase profits?Option Pricing Intuition:Manager has a call option on the fund value.Option value increases with volatility. More risk is better.

Static, Complete Market Fallacy:Manager has multiple call options.High-Water Mark: future strikes depend on past actions.Option unhedgeable: cannot short (your!) hedge fund.

Page 22: The Incentives of Hedge Fund Fees and High-Water Marks

Problem Model Solution Welfare Implications

Risk Shifting?

Manager shares investors’ profits, not losses.Does manager take more risk to increase profits?Option Pricing Intuition:Manager has a call option on the fund value.Option value increases with volatility. More risk is better.Static, Complete Market Fallacy:Manager has multiple call options.

High-Water Mark: future strikes depend on past actions.Option unhedgeable: cannot short (your!) hedge fund.

Page 23: The Incentives of Hedge Fund Fees and High-Water Marks

Problem Model Solution Welfare Implications

Risk Shifting?

Manager shares investors’ profits, not losses.Does manager take more risk to increase profits?Option Pricing Intuition:Manager has a call option on the fund value.Option value increases with volatility. More risk is better.Static, Complete Market Fallacy:Manager has multiple call options.High-Water Mark: future strikes depend on past actions.

Option unhedgeable: cannot short (your!) hedge fund.

Page 24: The Incentives of Hedge Fund Fees and High-Water Marks

Problem Model Solution Welfare Implications

Risk Shifting?

Manager shares investors’ profits, not losses.Does manager take more risk to increase profits?Option Pricing Intuition:Manager has a call option on the fund value.Option value increases with volatility. More risk is better.Static, Complete Market Fallacy:Manager has multiple call options.High-Water Mark: future strikes depend on past actions.Option unhedgeable: cannot short (your!) hedge fund.

Page 25: The Incentives of Hedge Fund Fees and High-Water Marks

Problem Model Solution Welfare Implications

Questions

Portfolio:Effect of fees and risk-aversion?

Welfare:Effect on investors and managers?High-Water Mark Contracts:consistent with any investor’s objective?

Page 26: The Incentives of Hedge Fund Fees and High-Water Marks

Problem Model Solution Welfare Implications

Questions

Portfolio:Effect of fees and risk-aversion?Welfare:Effect on investors and managers?

High-Water Mark Contracts:consistent with any investor’s objective?

Page 27: The Incentives of Hedge Fund Fees and High-Water Marks

Problem Model Solution Welfare Implications

Questions

Portfolio:Effect of fees and risk-aversion?Welfare:Effect on investors and managers?High-Water Mark Contracts:consistent with any investor’s objective?

Page 28: The Incentives of Hedge Fund Fees and High-Water Marks

Problem Model Solution Welfare Implications

Answers

Goetzmann, Ingersoll and Ross (2003):Risk-neutral value of management contract (future fees).Exogenous portfolio and fund flows.

High-Water Mark contract worth 10% to 20% of fund.Panageas and Westerfield (2009):Exogenous risky and risk-free asset.Optimal portfolio for a risk-neutral manager.Fees cannot be invested in fund.Constant risky/risk-free ratio optimal.Merton proportion does not depend on fee size.Same solution for manager with Hindy-Huang utility.

Page 29: The Incentives of Hedge Fund Fees and High-Water Marks

Problem Model Solution Welfare Implications

Answers

Goetzmann, Ingersoll and Ross (2003):Risk-neutral value of management contract (future fees).Exogenous portfolio and fund flows.High-Water Mark contract worth 10% to 20% of fund.

Panageas and Westerfield (2009):Exogenous risky and risk-free asset.Optimal portfolio for a risk-neutral manager.Fees cannot be invested in fund.Constant risky/risk-free ratio optimal.Merton proportion does not depend on fee size.Same solution for manager with Hindy-Huang utility.

Page 30: The Incentives of Hedge Fund Fees and High-Water Marks

Problem Model Solution Welfare Implications

Answers

Goetzmann, Ingersoll and Ross (2003):Risk-neutral value of management contract (future fees).Exogenous portfolio and fund flows.High-Water Mark contract worth 10% to 20% of fund.Panageas and Westerfield (2009):Exogenous risky and risk-free asset.Optimal portfolio for a risk-neutral manager.Fees cannot be invested in fund.

Constant risky/risk-free ratio optimal.Merton proportion does not depend on fee size.Same solution for manager with Hindy-Huang utility.

Page 31: The Incentives of Hedge Fund Fees and High-Water Marks

Problem Model Solution Welfare Implications

Answers

Goetzmann, Ingersoll and Ross (2003):Risk-neutral value of management contract (future fees).Exogenous portfolio and fund flows.High-Water Mark contract worth 10% to 20% of fund.Panageas and Westerfield (2009):Exogenous risky and risk-free asset.Optimal portfolio for a risk-neutral manager.Fees cannot be invested in fund.Constant risky/risk-free ratio optimal.Merton proportion does not depend on fee size.Same solution for manager with Hindy-Huang utility.

Page 32: The Incentives of Hedge Fund Fees and High-Water Marks

Problem Model Solution Welfare Implications

This Paper

Manager with Power Utility and Long Horizon.Exogenous risky and risk-free asset.Fees cannot be invested in fund.

Optimal Portfolio:

π =1γ∗

µ

σ2

γ∗ =(1− α)γ + α

γ =Manager’s Risk Aversionα =Performance Fee (e.g. 20%)

Manager behaves as if owned fund, but were more myopic(γ∗ weighted average of γ and 1).Performance fees α matter. Regular fees ϕ don’t.

Page 33: The Incentives of Hedge Fund Fees and High-Water Marks

Problem Model Solution Welfare Implications

This Paper

Manager with Power Utility and Long Horizon.Exogenous risky and risk-free asset.Fees cannot be invested in fund.Optimal Portfolio:

π =1γ∗

µ

σ2

γ∗ =(1− α)γ + α

γ =Manager’s Risk Aversionα =Performance Fee (e.g. 20%)

Manager behaves as if owned fund, but were more myopic(γ∗ weighted average of γ and 1).Performance fees α matter. Regular fees ϕ don’t.

Page 34: The Incentives of Hedge Fund Fees and High-Water Marks

Problem Model Solution Welfare Implications

This Paper

Manager with Power Utility and Long Horizon.Exogenous risky and risk-free asset.Fees cannot be invested in fund.Optimal Portfolio:

π =1γ∗

µ

σ2

γ∗ =(1− α)γ + α

γ =Manager’s Risk Aversionα =Performance Fee (e.g. 20%)

Manager behaves as if owned fund, but were more myopic(γ∗ weighted average of γ and 1).

Performance fees α matter. Regular fees ϕ don’t.

Page 35: The Incentives of Hedge Fund Fees and High-Water Marks

Problem Model Solution Welfare Implications

This Paper

Manager with Power Utility and Long Horizon.Exogenous risky and risk-free asset.Fees cannot be invested in fund.Optimal Portfolio:

π =1γ∗

µ

σ2

γ∗ =(1− α)γ + α

γ =Manager’s Risk Aversionα =Performance Fee (e.g. 20%)

Manager behaves as if owned fund, but were more myopic(γ∗ weighted average of γ and 1).Performance fees α matter. Regular fees ϕ don’t.

Page 36: The Incentives of Hedge Fund Fees and High-Water Marks

Problem Model Solution Welfare Implications

Three Problems, One Solution

Power utility, long horizon. No regular fees.

1 Manager maximizes utility of performance fees.Risk Aversion γ.

2 Investor maximizes utility of wealth. Pays no fees.Risk Aversion γ∗ = (1− α)γ + α.

3 Investor maximizes utility of wealth. Pays no fees.Risk Aversion γ. Maximum Drawdown 1− α.

Same optimal portfolio:

π =1γ∗

µ

σ2

Page 37: The Incentives of Hedge Fund Fees and High-Water Marks

Problem Model Solution Welfare Implications

Three Problems, One Solution

Power utility, long horizon. No regular fees.1 Manager maximizes utility of performance fees.

Risk Aversion γ.

2 Investor maximizes utility of wealth. Pays no fees.Risk Aversion γ∗ = (1− α)γ + α.

3 Investor maximizes utility of wealth. Pays no fees.Risk Aversion γ. Maximum Drawdown 1− α.

Same optimal portfolio:

π =1γ∗

µ

σ2

Page 38: The Incentives of Hedge Fund Fees and High-Water Marks

Problem Model Solution Welfare Implications

Three Problems, One Solution

Power utility, long horizon. No regular fees.1 Manager maximizes utility of performance fees.

Risk Aversion γ.2 Investor maximizes utility of wealth. Pays no fees.

Risk Aversion γ∗ = (1− α)γ + α.

3 Investor maximizes utility of wealth. Pays no fees.Risk Aversion γ. Maximum Drawdown 1− α.

Same optimal portfolio:

π =1γ∗

µ

σ2

Page 39: The Incentives of Hedge Fund Fees and High-Water Marks

Problem Model Solution Welfare Implications

Three Problems, One Solution

Power utility, long horizon. No regular fees.1 Manager maximizes utility of performance fees.

Risk Aversion γ.2 Investor maximizes utility of wealth. Pays no fees.

Risk Aversion γ∗ = (1− α)γ + α.3 Investor maximizes utility of wealth. Pays no fees.

Risk Aversion γ. Maximum Drawdown 1− α.

Same optimal portfolio:

π =1γ∗

µ

σ2

Page 40: The Incentives of Hedge Fund Fees and High-Water Marks

Problem Model Solution Welfare Implications

Three Problems, One Solution

Power utility, long horizon. No regular fees.1 Manager maximizes utility of performance fees.

Risk Aversion γ.2 Investor maximizes utility of wealth. Pays no fees.

Risk Aversion γ∗ = (1− α)γ + α.3 Investor maximizes utility of wealth. Pays no fees.

Risk Aversion γ. Maximum Drawdown 1− α.

Same optimal portfolio:

π =1γ∗

µ

σ2

Page 41: The Incentives of Hedge Fund Fees and High-Water Marks

Problem Model Solution Welfare Implications

Price Dynamics

dSt

St= (r + µ)dt + σdWt (Risky Asset)

dXt = (r − ϕ)Xtdt + Xtπt

(dStSt− rdt

)− α

1−αdX ∗t (Fund)

dFt = rFtdt + ϕXtdt +α

1− αdX ∗t (Fees)

X ∗t = max0≤s≤t

Xs (High-Water Mark)

One safe and one risky asset.

Gain split into α for the manager and 1− α for the fund.Performance fee is α/(1− α) of fund increase.

Page 42: The Incentives of Hedge Fund Fees and High-Water Marks

Problem Model Solution Welfare Implications

Price Dynamics

dSt

St= (r + µ)dt + σdWt (Risky Asset)

dXt = (r − ϕ)Xtdt + Xtπt

(dStSt− rdt

)− α

1−αdX ∗t (Fund)

dFt = rFtdt + ϕXtdt +α

1− αdX ∗t (Fees)

X ∗t = max0≤s≤t

Xs (High-Water Mark)

One safe and one risky asset.Gain split into α for the manager and 1− α for the fund.

Performance fee is α/(1− α) of fund increase.

Page 43: The Incentives of Hedge Fund Fees and High-Water Marks

Problem Model Solution Welfare Implications

Price Dynamics

dSt

St= (r + µ)dt + σdWt (Risky Asset)

dXt = (r − ϕ)Xtdt + Xtπt

(dStSt− rdt

)− α

1−αdX ∗t (Fund)

dFt = rFtdt + ϕXtdt +α

1− αdX ∗t (Fees)

X ∗t = max0≤s≤t

Xs (High-Water Mark)

One safe and one risky asset.Gain split into α for the manager and 1− α for the fund.Performance fee is α/(1− α) of fund increase.

Page 44: The Incentives of Hedge Fund Fees and High-Water Marks

Problem Model Solution Welfare Implications

Dynamics Well Posed?

Problem: fund value implicit.Find solution Xt for

dXt = XtπtdSt

St− ϕXtdt − α

1− αdX ∗t

Yes. Pathwise construction.

Proposition

The unique solution is Xt = eRt−αR∗t , where:

Rt =

∫ t

0

(µπs −

σ2

2π2

s − ϕ)

ds + σ

∫ t

0πsdWs

is the cumulative log return.

Page 45: The Incentives of Hedge Fund Fees and High-Water Marks

Problem Model Solution Welfare Implications

Dynamics Well Posed?

Problem: fund value implicit.Find solution Xt for

dXt = XtπtdSt

St− ϕXtdt − α

1− αdX ∗t

Yes. Pathwise construction.

Proposition

The unique solution is Xt = eRt−αR∗t , where:

Rt =

∫ t

0

(µπs −

σ2

2π2

s − ϕ)

ds + σ

∫ t

0πsdWs

is the cumulative log return.

Page 46: The Incentives of Hedge Fund Fees and High-Water Marks

Problem Model Solution Welfare Implications

Dynamics Well Posed?

Problem: fund value implicit.Find solution Xt for

dXt = XtπtdSt

St− ϕXtdt − α

1− αdX ∗t

Yes. Pathwise construction.

Proposition

The unique solution is Xt = eRt−αR∗t , where:

Rt =

∫ t

0

(µπs −

σ2

2π2

s − ϕ)

ds + σ

∫ t

0πsdWs

is the cumulative log return.

Page 47: The Incentives of Hedge Fund Fees and High-Water Marks

Problem Model Solution Welfare Implications

Fund Value Explicit

Lemma

Let Y be a continuous process, and α > 0.Then Yt +

α1−αY ∗t = Rt if and only if Yt = Rt − αR∗t .

Proof.Follows from:

R∗t = sups≤t

(Ys +

α

1− αsupu≤s

Yu

)= Y ∗t +

α

1− αY ∗t =

11− α

Y ∗t

Apply Lemma to cumulative log return.

Page 48: The Incentives of Hedge Fund Fees and High-Water Marks

Problem Model Solution Welfare Implications

Fund Value Explicit

Lemma

Let Y be a continuous process, and α > 0.Then Yt +

α1−αY ∗t = Rt if and only if Yt = Rt − αR∗t .

Proof.Follows from:

R∗t = sups≤t

(Ys +

α

1− αsupu≤s

Yu

)= Y ∗t +

α

1− αY ∗t =

11− α

Y ∗t

Apply Lemma to cumulative log return.

Page 49: The Incentives of Hedge Fund Fees and High-Water Marks

Problem Model Solution Welfare Implications

Fund Value Explicit

Lemma

Let Y be a continuous process, and α > 0.Then Yt +

α1−αY ∗t = Rt if and only if Yt = Rt − αR∗t .

Proof.Follows from:

R∗t = sups≤t

(Ys +

α

1− αsupu≤s

Yu

)= Y ∗t +

α

1− αY ∗t =

11− α

Y ∗t

Apply Lemma to cumulative log return.

Page 50: The Incentives of Hedge Fund Fees and High-Water Marks

Problem Model Solution Welfare Implications

Long HorizonThe manager chooses the portfolio π which maximizesexpected power utility from fees at a long horizon.

Maximizes the long-run objective:

maxπ

limT→∞

1pT

log E [F pT ] = λ

Dumas and Luciano (1991), Grossman and Vila (1992),Grossman and Zhou (1993). Risk-Sensitive Control:Bielecki and Pliska (1999) and many others.Certainty Equivalent Rate:λ as risk-free rate above which the manager would preferto retire and invest at such a rate, and below which wouldrather keep his job.

λ = r + 1γ

µ2

2σ2 for Merton problem with risk-aversionγ = 1− p.

Page 51: The Incentives of Hedge Fund Fees and High-Water Marks

Problem Model Solution Welfare Implications

Long HorizonThe manager chooses the portfolio π which maximizesexpected power utility from fees at a long horizon.Maximizes the long-run objective:

maxπ

limT→∞

1pT

log E [F pT ] = λ

Dumas and Luciano (1991), Grossman and Vila (1992),Grossman and Zhou (1993). Risk-Sensitive Control:Bielecki and Pliska (1999) and many others.Certainty Equivalent Rate:λ as risk-free rate above which the manager would preferto retire and invest at such a rate, and below which wouldrather keep his job.

λ = r + 1γ

µ2

2σ2 for Merton problem with risk-aversionγ = 1− p.

Page 52: The Incentives of Hedge Fund Fees and High-Water Marks

Problem Model Solution Welfare Implications

Long HorizonThe manager chooses the portfolio π which maximizesexpected power utility from fees at a long horizon.Maximizes the long-run objective:

maxπ

limT→∞

1pT

log E [F pT ] = λ

Dumas and Luciano (1991), Grossman and Vila (1992),Grossman and Zhou (1993). Risk-Sensitive Control:Bielecki and Pliska (1999) and many others.

Certainty Equivalent Rate:λ as risk-free rate above which the manager would preferto retire and invest at such a rate, and below which wouldrather keep his job.

λ = r + 1γ

µ2

2σ2 for Merton problem with risk-aversionγ = 1− p.

Page 53: The Incentives of Hedge Fund Fees and High-Water Marks

Problem Model Solution Welfare Implications

Long HorizonThe manager chooses the portfolio π which maximizesexpected power utility from fees at a long horizon.Maximizes the long-run objective:

maxπ

limT→∞

1pT

log E [F pT ] = λ

Dumas and Luciano (1991), Grossman and Vila (1992),Grossman and Zhou (1993). Risk-Sensitive Control:Bielecki and Pliska (1999) and many others.Certainty Equivalent Rate:λ as risk-free rate above which the manager would preferto retire and invest at such a rate, and below which wouldrather keep his job.

λ = r + 1γ

µ2

2σ2 for Merton problem with risk-aversionγ = 1− p.

Page 54: The Incentives of Hedge Fund Fees and High-Water Marks

Problem Model Solution Welfare Implications

Long HorizonThe manager chooses the portfolio π which maximizesexpected power utility from fees at a long horizon.Maximizes the long-run objective:

maxπ

limT→∞

1pT

log E [F pT ] = λ

Dumas and Luciano (1991), Grossman and Vila (1992),Grossman and Zhou (1993). Risk-Sensitive Control:Bielecki and Pliska (1999) and many others.Certainty Equivalent Rate:λ as risk-free rate above which the manager would preferto retire and invest at such a rate, and below which wouldrather keep his job.

λ = r + 1γ

µ2

2σ2 for Merton problem with risk-aversionγ = 1− p.

Page 55: The Incentives of Hedge Fund Fees and High-Water Marks

Problem Model Solution Welfare Implications

Solving ItSet r = 0 and ϕ = 0 to simplify notation.

Cumulative fees are a fraction of the increase in the fund:

Ft =α

1− α(X ∗t − X ∗0 )

Thus, the manager’s objective is equivalent to:

maxπ

limT→∞

1pT

log E [(X ∗T )p]

Finite-horizon value function:

V (x , z, t) = supπ

1p

E [X ∗Tp|Xt = x ,X ∗t = z]

dV (Xt ,X ∗t , t) = Vtdt + VxdXt +12

Vxxd〈X 〉t + VzdX ∗t

= Vtdt +(

Vz − α1−αVx

)dX ∗t +

(VxXt(πtµ− ϕ)dt + Vxx

σ2

2 π2t X 2

t

)dt

Page 56: The Incentives of Hedge Fund Fees and High-Water Marks

Problem Model Solution Welfare Implications

Solving ItSet r = 0 and ϕ = 0 to simplify notation.Cumulative fees are a fraction of the increase in the fund:

Ft =α

1− α(X ∗t − X ∗0 )

Thus, the manager’s objective is equivalent to:

maxπ

limT→∞

1pT

log E [(X ∗T )p]

Finite-horizon value function:

V (x , z, t) = supπ

1p

E [X ∗Tp|Xt = x ,X ∗t = z]

dV (Xt ,X ∗t , t) = Vtdt + VxdXt +12

Vxxd〈X 〉t + VzdX ∗t

= Vtdt +(

Vz − α1−αVx

)dX ∗t +

(VxXt(πtµ− ϕ)dt + Vxx

σ2

2 π2t X 2

t

)dt

Page 57: The Incentives of Hedge Fund Fees and High-Water Marks

Problem Model Solution Welfare Implications

Solving ItSet r = 0 and ϕ = 0 to simplify notation.Cumulative fees are a fraction of the increase in the fund:

Ft =α

1− α(X ∗t − X ∗0 )

Thus, the manager’s objective is equivalent to:

maxπ

limT→∞

1pT

log E [(X ∗T )p]

Finite-horizon value function:

V (x , z, t) = supπ

1p

E [X ∗Tp|Xt = x ,X ∗t = z]

dV (Xt ,X ∗t , t) = Vtdt + VxdXt +12

Vxxd〈X 〉t + VzdX ∗t

= Vtdt +(

Vz − α1−αVx

)dX ∗t +

(VxXt(πtµ− ϕ)dt + Vxx

σ2

2 π2t X 2

t

)dt

Page 58: The Incentives of Hedge Fund Fees and High-Water Marks

Problem Model Solution Welfare Implications

Solving ItSet r = 0 and ϕ = 0 to simplify notation.Cumulative fees are a fraction of the increase in the fund:

Ft =α

1− α(X ∗t − X ∗0 )

Thus, the manager’s objective is equivalent to:

maxπ

limT→∞

1pT

log E [(X ∗T )p]

Finite-horizon value function:

V (x , z, t) = supπ

1p

E [X ∗Tp|Xt = x ,X ∗t = z]

dV (Xt ,X ∗t , t) = Vtdt + VxdXt +12

Vxxd〈X 〉t + VzdX ∗t

= Vtdt +(

Vz − α1−αVx

)dX ∗t +

(VxXt(πtµ− ϕ)dt + Vxx

σ2

2 π2t X 2

t

)dt

Page 59: The Incentives of Hedge Fund Fees and High-Water Marks

Problem Model Solution Welfare Implications

Dynamic ProgrammingHamilton-Jacobi-Bellman equation:

Vt + supπ

(xVx(πµ− ϕ) + Vxx

σ2

2 π2x2)

)x < z

Vz = α1−αVx x = z

V = zp/p x = 0V = zp/p t = T

Maximize in π, and use homogeneityV (x , z, t) = zp/pV (x/z,1, t) = zp/pu(x/z,1, t).

ut − ϕxux − µ2

2σ2u2

xuxx

= 0 x ∈ (0,1)ux(1, t) = p(1− α)u(1, t) t ∈ (0,T )

u(x ,T ) = 1 x ∈ (0,1)u(0, t) = 1 t ∈ (0,T )

Page 60: The Incentives of Hedge Fund Fees and High-Water Marks

Problem Model Solution Welfare Implications

Dynamic ProgrammingHamilton-Jacobi-Bellman equation:

Vt + supπ

(xVx(πµ− ϕ) + Vxx

σ2

2 π2x2)

)x < z

Vz = α1−αVx x = z

V = zp/p x = 0V = zp/p t = T

Maximize in π, and use homogeneityV (x , z, t) = zp/pV (x/z,1, t) = zp/pu(x/z,1, t).

ut − ϕxux − µ2

2σ2u2

xuxx

= 0 x ∈ (0,1)ux(1, t) = p(1− α)u(1, t) t ∈ (0,T )

u(x ,T ) = 1 x ∈ (0,1)u(0, t) = 1 t ∈ (0,T )

Page 61: The Incentives of Hedge Fund Fees and High-Water Marks

Problem Model Solution Welfare Implications

Long-Run Heuristics

Long-run limit.Guess a solution of the form u(t , x) = ce−pβtw(x),forgetting the terminal condition:{

−pβw − ϕxwx − µ2

2σ2w2

xwxx

= 0 for x < 1wx(1) = p(1− α)w(1)

This equation is time-homogeneous, but β is unknown.Any β with a solution w is an upper bound on the rate λ.Candidate long-run value function:the solution w with the lowest β.

w(x) = xp(1−α), for β = 1−α(1−α)γ+α

µ2

2σ2 − ϕ(1− α).

Page 62: The Incentives of Hedge Fund Fees and High-Water Marks

Problem Model Solution Welfare Implications

Long-Run Heuristics

Long-run limit.Guess a solution of the form u(t , x) = ce−pβtw(x),forgetting the terminal condition:{

−pβw − ϕxwx − µ2

2σ2w2

xwxx

= 0 for x < 1wx(1) = p(1− α)w(1)

This equation is time-homogeneous, but β is unknown.

Any β with a solution w is an upper bound on the rate λ.Candidate long-run value function:the solution w with the lowest β.

w(x) = xp(1−α), for β = 1−α(1−α)γ+α

µ2

2σ2 − ϕ(1− α).

Page 63: The Incentives of Hedge Fund Fees and High-Water Marks

Problem Model Solution Welfare Implications

Long-Run Heuristics

Long-run limit.Guess a solution of the form u(t , x) = ce−pβtw(x),forgetting the terminal condition:{

−pβw − ϕxwx − µ2

2σ2w2

xwxx

= 0 for x < 1wx(1) = p(1− α)w(1)

This equation is time-homogeneous, but β is unknown.Any β with a solution w is an upper bound on the rate λ.

Candidate long-run value function:the solution w with the lowest β.

w(x) = xp(1−α), for β = 1−α(1−α)γ+α

µ2

2σ2 − ϕ(1− α).

Page 64: The Incentives of Hedge Fund Fees and High-Water Marks

Problem Model Solution Welfare Implications

Long-Run Heuristics

Long-run limit.Guess a solution of the form u(t , x) = ce−pβtw(x),forgetting the terminal condition:{

−pβw − ϕxwx − µ2

2σ2w2

xwxx

= 0 for x < 1wx(1) = p(1− α)w(1)

This equation is time-homogeneous, but β is unknown.Any β with a solution w is an upper bound on the rate λ.Candidate long-run value function:the solution w with the lowest β.

w(x) = xp(1−α), for β = 1−α(1−α)γ+α

µ2

2σ2 − ϕ(1− α).

Page 65: The Incentives of Hedge Fund Fees and High-Water Marks

Problem Model Solution Welfare Implications

Long-Run Heuristics

Long-run limit.Guess a solution of the form u(t , x) = ce−pβtw(x),forgetting the terminal condition:{

−pβw − ϕxwx − µ2

2σ2w2

xwxx

= 0 for x < 1wx(1) = p(1− α)w(1)

This equation is time-homogeneous, but β is unknown.Any β with a solution w is an upper bound on the rate λ.Candidate long-run value function:the solution w with the lowest β.

w(x) = xp(1−α), for β = 1−α(1−α)γ+α

µ2

2σ2 − ϕ(1− α).

Page 66: The Incentives of Hedge Fund Fees and High-Water Marks

Problem Model Solution Welfare Implications

Verification

Theorem

If ϕ− r < µ2

2σ2 min{

1γ∗, 1γ2∗

}, then for any portfolio π:

limT→∞

1pT

log E[(Fπ

T )p] ≤ max

{(1− α)

(1γ∗

µ2

2σ2 + r − ϕ), r}

Under the nondegeneracy condition ϕ+ α1−α r < 1

γ∗µ2

2σ2 , theunique optimal solution is π̂ = 1

γ∗µσ2 .

Martingale argument. No HJB equation needed.Show upper bound for any portfolio π (delicate).Check equality for guessed solution (easy).

Page 67: The Incentives of Hedge Fund Fees and High-Water Marks

Problem Model Solution Welfare Implications

Verification

Theorem

If ϕ− r < µ2

2σ2 min{

1γ∗, 1γ2∗

}, then for any portfolio π:

limT→∞

1pT

log E[(Fπ

T )p] ≤ max

{(1− α)

(1γ∗

µ2

2σ2 + r − ϕ), r}

Under the nondegeneracy condition ϕ+ α1−α r < 1

γ∗µ2

2σ2 , theunique optimal solution is π̂ = 1

γ∗µσ2 .

Martingale argument. No HJB equation needed.

Show upper bound for any portfolio π (delicate).Check equality for guessed solution (easy).

Page 68: The Incentives of Hedge Fund Fees and High-Water Marks

Problem Model Solution Welfare Implications

Verification

Theorem

If ϕ− r < µ2

2σ2 min{

1γ∗, 1γ2∗

}, then for any portfolio π:

limT→∞

1pT

log E[(Fπ

T )p] ≤ max

{(1− α)

(1γ∗

µ2

2σ2 + r − ϕ), r}

Under the nondegeneracy condition ϕ+ α1−α r < 1

γ∗µ2

2σ2 , theunique optimal solution is π̂ = 1

γ∗µσ2 .

Martingale argument. No HJB equation needed.Show upper bound for any portfolio π (delicate).

Check equality for guessed solution (easy).

Page 69: The Incentives of Hedge Fund Fees and High-Water Marks

Problem Model Solution Welfare Implications

Verification

Theorem

If ϕ− r < µ2

2σ2 min{

1γ∗, 1γ2∗

}, then for any portfolio π:

limT→∞

1pT

log E[(Fπ

T )p] ≤ max

{(1− α)

(1γ∗

µ2

2σ2 + r − ϕ), r}

Under the nondegeneracy condition ϕ+ α1−α r < 1

γ∗µ2

2σ2 , theunique optimal solution is π̂ = 1

γ∗µσ2 .

Martingale argument. No HJB equation needed.Show upper bound for any portfolio π (delicate).Check equality for guessed solution (easy).

Page 70: The Incentives of Hedge Fund Fees and High-Water Marks

Problem Model Solution Welfare Implications

Upper Bound (1)Take p > 0 (p < 0 symmetric).

For any portfolio π:

RT = −∫ T

0σ2

2 π2t dt +

∫ T0 σπtdW̃t

W̃t = Wt + µ/σt risk-neutral Brownian MotionExplicit representation:

E [(XπT )

p] = E [ep(1−α)R∗T ] = EQ

[ep(1−α)R∗T e

µσ

W̃T− µ2

2σ2 T]

For δ > 1, Hölder’s inequality:

EQ

[ep(1−α)R∗T e

µσ

W̃T− µ2

2σ2 T]≤ EQ

[eδp(1−α)R∗T

] 1δ EQ

[e

δδ−1

(µσ

W̃T− µ2

2σ2 T)] δ−1

δ

Second term exponential normal moment. Just e1

δ−1µ2

2σ2 T .

Page 71: The Incentives of Hedge Fund Fees and High-Water Marks

Problem Model Solution Welfare Implications

Upper Bound (1)Take p > 0 (p < 0 symmetric).For any portfolio π:

RT = −∫ T

0σ2

2 π2t dt +

∫ T0 σπtdW̃t

W̃t = Wt + µ/σt risk-neutral Brownian MotionExplicit representation:

E [(XπT )

p] = E [ep(1−α)R∗T ] = EQ

[ep(1−α)R∗T e

µσ

W̃T− µ2

2σ2 T]

For δ > 1, Hölder’s inequality:

EQ

[ep(1−α)R∗T e

µσ

W̃T− µ2

2σ2 T]≤ EQ

[eδp(1−α)R∗T

] 1δ EQ

[e

δδ−1

(µσ

W̃T− µ2

2σ2 T)] δ−1

δ

Second term exponential normal moment. Just e1

δ−1µ2

2σ2 T .

Page 72: The Incentives of Hedge Fund Fees and High-Water Marks

Problem Model Solution Welfare Implications

Upper Bound (1)Take p > 0 (p < 0 symmetric).For any portfolio π:

RT = −∫ T

0σ2

2 π2t dt +

∫ T0 σπtdW̃t

W̃t = Wt + µ/σt risk-neutral Brownian Motion

Explicit representation:

E [(XπT )

p] = E [ep(1−α)R∗T ] = EQ

[ep(1−α)R∗T e

µσ

W̃T− µ2

2σ2 T]

For δ > 1, Hölder’s inequality:

EQ

[ep(1−α)R∗T e

µσ

W̃T− µ2

2σ2 T]≤ EQ

[eδp(1−α)R∗T

] 1δ EQ

[e

δδ−1

(µσ

W̃T− µ2

2σ2 T)] δ−1

δ

Second term exponential normal moment. Just e1

δ−1µ2

2σ2 T .

Page 73: The Incentives of Hedge Fund Fees and High-Water Marks

Problem Model Solution Welfare Implications

Upper Bound (1)Take p > 0 (p < 0 symmetric).For any portfolio π:

RT = −∫ T

0σ2

2 π2t dt +

∫ T0 σπtdW̃t

W̃t = Wt + µ/σt risk-neutral Brownian MotionExplicit representation:

E [(XπT )

p] = E [ep(1−α)R∗T ] = EQ

[ep(1−α)R∗T e

µσ

W̃T− µ2

2σ2 T]

For δ > 1, Hölder’s inequality:

EQ

[ep(1−α)R∗T e

µσ

W̃T− µ2

2σ2 T]≤ EQ

[eδp(1−α)R∗T

] 1δ EQ

[e

δδ−1

(µσ

W̃T− µ2

2σ2 T)] δ−1

δ

Second term exponential normal moment. Just e1

δ−1µ2

2σ2 T .

Page 74: The Incentives of Hedge Fund Fees and High-Water Marks

Problem Model Solution Welfare Implications

Upper Bound (1)Take p > 0 (p < 0 symmetric).For any portfolio π:

RT = −∫ T

0σ2

2 π2t dt +

∫ T0 σπtdW̃t

W̃t = Wt + µ/σt risk-neutral Brownian MotionExplicit representation:

E [(XπT )

p] = E [ep(1−α)R∗T ] = EQ

[ep(1−α)R∗T e

µσ

W̃T− µ2

2σ2 T]

For δ > 1, Hölder’s inequality:

EQ

[ep(1−α)R∗T e

µσ

W̃T− µ2

2σ2 T]≤ EQ

[eδp(1−α)R∗T

] 1δ EQ

[e

δδ−1

(µσ

W̃T− µ2

2σ2 T)] δ−1

δ

Second term exponential normal moment. Just e1

δ−1µ2

2σ2 T .

Page 75: The Incentives of Hedge Fund Fees and High-Water Marks

Problem Model Solution Welfare Implications

Upper Bound (1)Take p > 0 (p < 0 symmetric).For any portfolio π:

RT = −∫ T

0σ2

2 π2t dt +

∫ T0 σπtdW̃t

W̃t = Wt + µ/σt risk-neutral Brownian MotionExplicit representation:

E [(XπT )

p] = E [ep(1−α)R∗T ] = EQ

[ep(1−α)R∗T e

µσ

W̃T− µ2

2σ2 T]

For δ > 1, Hölder’s inequality:

EQ

[ep(1−α)R∗T e

µσ

W̃T− µ2

2σ2 T]≤ EQ

[eδp(1−α)R∗T

] 1δ EQ

[e

δδ−1

(µσ

W̃T− µ2

2σ2 T)] δ−1

δ

Second term exponential normal moment. Just e1

δ−1µ2

2σ2 T .

Page 76: The Incentives of Hedge Fund Fees and High-Water Marks

Problem Model Solution Welfare Implications

Upper Bound (2)Estimate EQ

[eδp(1−α)R∗T

].

Mt = eRt strictly positive continuous local martingale.Converges to zero as t ↑ ∞.Fact:inverse of lifetime supremum (M∗∞)−1 uniform on [0,1].Thus, for δp(1− α) < 1:

EQ

[eδp(1−α)R∗T

]≤ EQ

[eδp(1−α)R∗∞

]=

11− δp(1− α)

In summary, for 1 < δ < 1p(1−α) :

limT→∞

1pT

log E[(Fπ

T )p] ≤ 1

p(δ − 1)µ2

2σ2

Thesis follows as δ → 1p(1−α) .

Page 77: The Incentives of Hedge Fund Fees and High-Water Marks

Problem Model Solution Welfare Implications

Upper Bound (2)Estimate EQ

[eδp(1−α)R∗T

].

Mt = eRt strictly positive continuous local martingale.Converges to zero as t ↑ ∞.

Fact:inverse of lifetime supremum (M∗∞)−1 uniform on [0,1].Thus, for δp(1− α) < 1:

EQ

[eδp(1−α)R∗T

]≤ EQ

[eδp(1−α)R∗∞

]=

11− δp(1− α)

In summary, for 1 < δ < 1p(1−α) :

limT→∞

1pT

log E[(Fπ

T )p] ≤ 1

p(δ − 1)µ2

2σ2

Thesis follows as δ → 1p(1−α) .

Page 78: The Incentives of Hedge Fund Fees and High-Water Marks

Problem Model Solution Welfare Implications

Upper Bound (2)Estimate EQ

[eδp(1−α)R∗T

].

Mt = eRt strictly positive continuous local martingale.Converges to zero as t ↑ ∞.Fact:inverse of lifetime supremum (M∗∞)−1 uniform on [0,1].

Thus, for δp(1− α) < 1:

EQ

[eδp(1−α)R∗T

]≤ EQ

[eδp(1−α)R∗∞

]=

11− δp(1− α)

In summary, for 1 < δ < 1p(1−α) :

limT→∞

1pT

log E[(Fπ

T )p] ≤ 1

p(δ − 1)µ2

2σ2

Thesis follows as δ → 1p(1−α) .

Page 79: The Incentives of Hedge Fund Fees and High-Water Marks

Problem Model Solution Welfare Implications

Upper Bound (2)Estimate EQ

[eδp(1−α)R∗T

].

Mt = eRt strictly positive continuous local martingale.Converges to zero as t ↑ ∞.Fact:inverse of lifetime supremum (M∗∞)−1 uniform on [0,1].Thus, for δp(1− α) < 1:

EQ

[eδp(1−α)R∗T

]≤ EQ

[eδp(1−α)R∗∞

]=

11− δp(1− α)

In summary, for 1 < δ < 1p(1−α) :

limT→∞

1pT

log E[(Fπ

T )p] ≤ 1

p(δ − 1)µ2

2σ2

Thesis follows as δ → 1p(1−α) .

Page 80: The Incentives of Hedge Fund Fees and High-Water Marks

Problem Model Solution Welfare Implications

Upper Bound (2)Estimate EQ

[eδp(1−α)R∗T

].

Mt = eRt strictly positive continuous local martingale.Converges to zero as t ↑ ∞.Fact:inverse of lifetime supremum (M∗∞)−1 uniform on [0,1].Thus, for δp(1− α) < 1:

EQ

[eδp(1−α)R∗T

]≤ EQ

[eδp(1−α)R∗∞

]=

11− δp(1− α)

In summary, for 1 < δ < 1p(1−α) :

limT→∞

1pT

log E[(Fπ

T )p] ≤ 1

p(δ − 1)µ2

2σ2

Thesis follows as δ → 1p(1−α) .

Page 81: The Incentives of Hedge Fund Fees and High-Water Marks

Problem Model Solution Welfare Implications

Upper Bound (2)Estimate EQ

[eδp(1−α)R∗T

].

Mt = eRt strictly positive continuous local martingale.Converges to zero as t ↑ ∞.Fact:inverse of lifetime supremum (M∗∞)−1 uniform on [0,1].Thus, for δp(1− α) < 1:

EQ

[eδp(1−α)R∗T

]≤ EQ

[eδp(1−α)R∗∞

]=

11− δp(1− α)

In summary, for 1 < δ < 1p(1−α) :

limT→∞

1pT

log E[(Fπ

T )p] ≤ 1

p(δ − 1)µ2

2σ2

Thesis follows as δ → 1p(1−α) .

Page 82: The Incentives of Hedge Fund Fees and High-Water Marks

Problem Model Solution Welfare Implications

High-Water Marks and DrawdownsImagine fund’s assets Xt and manager’s fees Ft in thesame account Ct = Xt + Ft .

dCt = (Ct − Ft)πtdSt

St

Fees Ft proportional to high-water mark X ∗t :

Ft =α

1− α(X ∗t − X ∗0 )

Account increase dC∗t as fund increase plus fees increase:

C∗t −C∗0 =

∫ t

0(dX ∗s +dFs) =

∫ t

0

1− α+ 1)

dX ∗s =1

1− α(X ∗t −X0)

Obvious bound Ct ≥ Ft yields:

Ct ≥ α(C∗t − X0)

X0 negligible as t ↑ ∞. Approximate drawdown constraint.

Ct ≥ αC∗t

Page 83: The Incentives of Hedge Fund Fees and High-Water Marks

Problem Model Solution Welfare Implications

High-Water Marks and DrawdownsImagine fund’s assets Xt and manager’s fees Ft in thesame account Ct = Xt + Ft .

dCt = (Ct − Ft)πtdSt

St

Fees Ft proportional to high-water mark X ∗t :

Ft =α

1− α(X ∗t − X ∗0 )

Account increase dC∗t as fund increase plus fees increase:

C∗t −C∗0 =

∫ t

0(dX ∗s +dFs) =

∫ t

0

1− α+ 1)

dX ∗s =1

1− α(X ∗t −X0)

Obvious bound Ct ≥ Ft yields:

Ct ≥ α(C∗t − X0)

X0 negligible as t ↑ ∞. Approximate drawdown constraint.

Ct ≥ αC∗t

Page 84: The Incentives of Hedge Fund Fees and High-Water Marks

Problem Model Solution Welfare Implications

High-Water Marks and DrawdownsImagine fund’s assets Xt and manager’s fees Ft in thesame account Ct = Xt + Ft .

dCt = (Ct − Ft)πtdSt

St

Fees Ft proportional to high-water mark X ∗t :

Ft =α

1− α(X ∗t − X ∗0 )

Account increase dC∗t as fund increase plus fees increase:

C∗t −C∗0 =

∫ t

0(dX ∗s +dFs) =

∫ t

0

1− α+ 1)

dX ∗s =1

1− α(X ∗t −X0)

Obvious bound Ct ≥ Ft yields:

Ct ≥ α(C∗t − X0)

X0 negligible as t ↑ ∞. Approximate drawdown constraint.

Ct ≥ αC∗t

Page 85: The Incentives of Hedge Fund Fees and High-Water Marks

Problem Model Solution Welfare Implications

High-Water Marks and DrawdownsImagine fund’s assets Xt and manager’s fees Ft in thesame account Ct = Xt + Ft .

dCt = (Ct − Ft)πtdSt

St

Fees Ft proportional to high-water mark X ∗t :

Ft =α

1− α(X ∗t − X ∗0 )

Account increase dC∗t as fund increase plus fees increase:

C∗t −C∗0 =

∫ t

0(dX ∗s +dFs) =

∫ t

0

1− α+ 1)

dX ∗s =1

1− α(X ∗t −X0)

Obvious bound Ct ≥ Ft yields:

Ct ≥ α(C∗t − X0)

X0 negligible as t ↑ ∞. Approximate drawdown constraint.

Ct ≥ αC∗t

Page 86: The Incentives of Hedge Fund Fees and High-Water Marks

Problem Model Solution Welfare Implications

High-Water Marks and DrawdownsImagine fund’s assets Xt and manager’s fees Ft in thesame account Ct = Xt + Ft .

dCt = (Ct − Ft)πtdSt

St

Fees Ft proportional to high-water mark X ∗t :

Ft =α

1− α(X ∗t − X ∗0 )

Account increase dC∗t as fund increase plus fees increase:

C∗t −C∗0 =

∫ t

0(dX ∗s +dFs) =

∫ t

0

1− α+ 1)

dX ∗s =1

1− α(X ∗t −X0)

Obvious bound Ct ≥ Ft yields:

Ct ≥ α(C∗t − X0)

X0 negligible as t ↑ ∞. Approximate drawdown constraint.

Ct ≥ αC∗t

Page 87: The Incentives of Hedge Fund Fees and High-Water Marks

Problem Model Solution Welfare Implications

Certainty equivalent rates

Certainty equivalent rates under parametric restrictions

Manager:1− αγ∗

µ2

2σ2 − (1− α)(ϕ− r)

Investor:

1− αγ∗

µ2

2σ2

(1− (1− α)γI − γM

γ∗

)− (1− α)(ϕ− r)

Dependence on fees?

Page 88: The Incentives of Hedge Fund Fees and High-Water Marks

Problem Model Solution Welfare Implications

Certainty equivalent rates

Certainty equivalent rates under parametric restrictionsManager:

1− αγ∗

µ2

2σ2 − (1− α)(ϕ− r)

Investor:

1− αγ∗

µ2

2σ2

(1− (1− α)γI − γM

γ∗

)− (1− α)(ϕ− r)

Dependence on fees?

Page 89: The Incentives of Hedge Fund Fees and High-Water Marks

Problem Model Solution Welfare Implications

Certainty equivalent rates

Certainty equivalent rates under parametric restrictionsManager:

1− αγ∗

µ2

2σ2 − (1− α)(ϕ− r)

Investor:

1− αγ∗

µ2

2σ2

(1− (1− α)γI − γM

γ∗

)− (1− α)(ϕ− r)

Dependence on fees?

Page 90: The Incentives of Hedge Fund Fees and High-Water Marks

Problem Model Solution Welfare Implications

Certainty equivalent rates

Certainty equivalent rates under parametric restrictionsManager:

1− αγ∗

µ2

2σ2 − (1− α)(ϕ− r)

Investor:

1− αγ∗

µ2

2σ2

(1− (1− α)γI − γM

γ∗

)− (1− α)(ϕ− r)

Dependence on fees?

Page 91: The Incentives of Hedge Fund Fees and High-Water Marks

Problem Model Solution Welfare Implications

Manager

Performance fees affect the manager in two ways.

Income effect.Accrued to manager’s account, but only at safe rate.Positive impact.Drag effect.Reduce fund growth, hence future fees.Negative impact.Because horizon is long, and no participation is allowed,second effect prevails.Manager’s certainty equivalent rate decreases with α.Manager prefers 10% in rapidly growing fund, than 20% inslowly growing fund.

Page 92: The Incentives of Hedge Fund Fees and High-Water Marks

Problem Model Solution Welfare Implications

Manager

Performance fees affect the manager in two ways.Income effect.Accrued to manager’s account, but only at safe rate.Positive impact.

Drag effect.Reduce fund growth, hence future fees.Negative impact.Because horizon is long, and no participation is allowed,second effect prevails.Manager’s certainty equivalent rate decreases with α.Manager prefers 10% in rapidly growing fund, than 20% inslowly growing fund.

Page 93: The Incentives of Hedge Fund Fees and High-Water Marks

Problem Model Solution Welfare Implications

Manager

Performance fees affect the manager in two ways.Income effect.Accrued to manager’s account, but only at safe rate.Positive impact.Drag effect.Reduce fund growth, hence future fees.Negative impact.

Because horizon is long, and no participation is allowed,second effect prevails.Manager’s certainty equivalent rate decreases with α.Manager prefers 10% in rapidly growing fund, than 20% inslowly growing fund.

Page 94: The Incentives of Hedge Fund Fees and High-Water Marks

Problem Model Solution Welfare Implications

Manager

Performance fees affect the manager in two ways.Income effect.Accrued to manager’s account, but only at safe rate.Positive impact.Drag effect.Reduce fund growth, hence future fees.Negative impact.Because horizon is long, and no participation is allowed,second effect prevails.

Manager’s certainty equivalent rate decreases with α.Manager prefers 10% in rapidly growing fund, than 20% inslowly growing fund.

Page 95: The Incentives of Hedge Fund Fees and High-Water Marks

Problem Model Solution Welfare Implications

Manager

Performance fees affect the manager in two ways.Income effect.Accrued to manager’s account, but only at safe rate.Positive impact.Drag effect.Reduce fund growth, hence future fees.Negative impact.Because horizon is long, and no participation is allowed,second effect prevails.Manager’s certainty equivalent rate decreases with α.Manager prefers 10% in rapidly growing fund, than 20% inslowly growing fund.

Page 96: The Incentives of Hedge Fund Fees and High-Water Marks

Problem Model Solution Welfare Implications

Investor

Performance fees affect the investor in two ways.

Cost effect.Reduce fund growth.Negative impact.Agency effect.Shrink manager’s risk aversion towards one.Ambiguous impact.Do observed levels of performance fees serve investors?If investors could choose performance fees themselves, atwhich levels would they set them?

Page 97: The Incentives of Hedge Fund Fees and High-Water Marks

Problem Model Solution Welfare Implications

Investor

Performance fees affect the investor in two ways.Cost effect.Reduce fund growth.Negative impact.

Agency effect.Shrink manager’s risk aversion towards one.Ambiguous impact.Do observed levels of performance fees serve investors?If investors could choose performance fees themselves, atwhich levels would they set them?

Page 98: The Incentives of Hedge Fund Fees and High-Water Marks

Problem Model Solution Welfare Implications

Investor

Performance fees affect the investor in two ways.Cost effect.Reduce fund growth.Negative impact.Agency effect.Shrink manager’s risk aversion towards one.Ambiguous impact.

Do observed levels of performance fees serve investors?If investors could choose performance fees themselves, atwhich levels would they set them?

Page 99: The Incentives of Hedge Fund Fees and High-Water Marks

Problem Model Solution Welfare Implications

Investor

Performance fees affect the investor in two ways.Cost effect.Reduce fund growth.Negative impact.Agency effect.Shrink manager’s risk aversion towards one.Ambiguous impact.Do observed levels of performance fees serve investors?

If investors could choose performance fees themselves, atwhich levels would they set them?

Page 100: The Incentives of Hedge Fund Fees and High-Water Marks

Problem Model Solution Welfare Implications

Investor

Performance fees affect the investor in two ways.Cost effect.Reduce fund growth.Negative impact.Agency effect.Shrink manager’s risk aversion towards one.Ambiguous impact.Do observed levels of performance fees serve investors?If investors could choose performance fees themselves, atwhich levels would they set them?

Page 101: The Incentives of Hedge Fund Fees and High-Water Marks

Problem Model Solution Welfare Implications

Equilibrium Fees

0.0 0.5 1.0 1.5 2.0

0.0

0.5

1.0

1.5

2.0

0.0 0.5 1.0 1.5 2.0

0.0

0.5

1.0

1.5

2.0

Pairs of risk aversions for the manager (x) and the investor (y)such that investors’s optimal α∗ is within 0 and 1, and certaintyequivalent rate greater than r . ϕ = r = 2% (left panel) andϕ = r = 3% (right panel). Optimal fees 20% on solid line.

Page 102: The Incentives of Hedge Fund Fees and High-Water Marks

Problem Model Solution Welfare Implications

Agency Effect Limited

Equilibrium fees require very low risk aversion both for theinvestor and for the manager.

Investor Risk aversion must be lower than 2.Manager’s risk aversion must be lower than 1.Otherwise no equilibrium exists.

Page 103: The Incentives of Hedge Fund Fees and High-Water Marks

Problem Model Solution Welfare Implications

Agency Effect Limited

Equilibrium fees require very low risk aversion both for theinvestor and for the manager.Investor Risk aversion must be lower than 2.

Manager’s risk aversion must be lower than 1.Otherwise no equilibrium exists.

Page 104: The Incentives of Hedge Fund Fees and High-Water Marks

Problem Model Solution Welfare Implications

Agency Effect Limited

Equilibrium fees require very low risk aversion both for theinvestor and for the manager.Investor Risk aversion must be lower than 2.Manager’s risk aversion must be lower than 1.

Otherwise no equilibrium exists.

Page 105: The Incentives of Hedge Fund Fees and High-Water Marks

Problem Model Solution Welfare Implications

Agency Effect Limited

Equilibrium fees require very low risk aversion both for theinvestor and for the manager.Investor Risk aversion must be lower than 2.Manager’s risk aversion must be lower than 1.Otherwise no equilibrium exists.

Page 106: The Incentives of Hedge Fund Fees and High-Water Marks

Problem Model Solution Welfare Implications

Parameter Restrictions ϕ = 1%

ϕ=1%, r = 1%α

µ/σ 10% 15% 20% 25% 30%0.25 3.0 2.9 2.9 2.8 2.70.5 12.4 12.3 12.3 12.2 12.11.0 49.9 49.8 49.8 49.7 49.61.5 112.4 112.3 112.3 112.2 112.1

Maximum risk-aversion γ for which ϕ+ α1−α r < 1

γ∗µ2

2σ2 , andhence the optimal portfolio is π = 1

γ∗µσ2 .

Page 107: The Incentives of Hedge Fund Fees and High-Water Marks

Problem Model Solution Welfare Implications

Parameter Restrictions ϕ = 2%

ϕ=2%, r = 1%α

µ/σ 10% 15% 20% 25% 30%0.25 1.5 1.5 1.5 1.5 1.40.5 6.5 6.6 6.7 6.8 6.91.0 26.2 26.9 27.5 28.2 29.01.5 59.1 60.6 62.3 64.0 65.7

Maximum risk-aversion γ for which ϕ+ α1−α r < 1

γ∗µ2

2σ2 , andhence the optimal portfolio is π = 1

γ∗µσ2 .

Page 108: The Incentives of Hedge Fund Fees and High-Water Marks

Problem Model Solution Welfare Implications

Testable Implications

The model predicts that:Funds with higher fees should have higher leverage,(for γ > 1, and viceversa for γ < 1).

Funds with higher fees should have smaller drawdowns.Leverage may differ across funds, butfor a given fund it should remain constant over time.

Page 109: The Incentives of Hedge Fund Fees and High-Water Marks

Problem Model Solution Welfare Implications

Testable Implications

The model predicts that:Funds with higher fees should have higher leverage,(for γ > 1, and viceversa for γ < 1).Funds with higher fees should have smaller drawdowns.

Leverage may differ across funds, butfor a given fund it should remain constant over time.

Page 110: The Incentives of Hedge Fund Fees and High-Water Marks

Problem Model Solution Welfare Implications

Testable Implications

The model predicts that:Funds with higher fees should have higher leverage,(for γ > 1, and viceversa for γ < 1).Funds with higher fees should have smaller drawdowns.Leverage may differ across funds, butfor a given fund it should remain constant over time.

Page 111: The Incentives of Hedge Fund Fees and High-Water Marks

Problem Model Solution Welfare Implications

Conclusion

Performance fees with High-Water Marks:Make managers more myopic.Higher fees: manager’s preferences matter less.

Akin to Drawdown constraints, for long horizons.Manager’s nonparticipation important assumption.

Page 112: The Incentives of Hedge Fund Fees and High-Water Marks

Problem Model Solution Welfare Implications

Conclusion

Performance fees with High-Water Marks:Make managers more myopic.Higher fees: manager’s preferences matter less.Akin to Drawdown constraints, for long horizons.

Manager’s nonparticipation important assumption.

Page 113: The Incentives of Hedge Fund Fees and High-Water Marks

Problem Model Solution Welfare Implications

Conclusion

Performance fees with High-Water Marks:Make managers more myopic.Higher fees: manager’s preferences matter less.Akin to Drawdown constraints, for long horizons.Manager’s nonparticipation important assumption.