Tax Reform and Investment: Blessing or Curse?

11
FEDERAL RESERVE BANK OF ST LOUIS JUNE/JULY if? Tax Reform and Investment: Blessing or Curse? Steven Al. Fazzari number of recent studies have concluded that the Tax Reform Act of 1986 will reduce capital spend- ing incentives in the United States.’ Many analysts fear this result. There is, however, an alternative view. By removing special subsidies for various kinds of investment, tax reform may encourage firms to invest in projects be- cause they have high economic returns, rather than large tax benefits. Jf economic returns more closely reflect social values than the previous tax subsidies, investments could be better suited under tax reform to produce goods and services that people want and enhance the productivity of the economy. Thus, the recent reform of capital taxation may actually improve econothic welfare, even though it reduces the aggre- gate capital stock and investment. This paper investi- gates the welfare implications of the new capital tax system. THE EFFICIENT ALLOCATION OF CAPITAL RESOURCES In many popular discussions of taxes and invest- ment lurks an implicit assumption that more invest- ment is always better than less. After all, investment causes the capital stock to expand, increases potential output growth and enhances labor productivity. While these outcomes are undoubtedly desirable, the simple view that investment is always beneficial ignores the costs imposed by greater capital accumulation. By investing resources in more productive capital, people forego the opportunity to consume some goods and services. Thus, investment generates opportunity costs.’ To evaluate whatever changing levels of investment improve social welfare, one needs a criterion that incorporates both the costs and benefits of changes in Steven M. Fanari~ an assistant professor of economics at Washington University in St. Louis, was a visiting scholar at the Federal Reserve Sank of St. Louis. The author thanks James C. Poletti for research assistance and Chris Varvares for helpful discussion. ‘See, for example, Prakken (1986), Henderson (1986), Aaron (1987), the Economic Report of the President (1987) and Fazzari (1987). ‘The opportunity costs associated with investment may be best illustrated by an extreme case. Suppose all of a society’s output were invested in capital goods. Growth would be maximized, but there would be no current consumption at all. This perspective emphasizes the trade-offs between investment and consumption. One could also consider the efficiency of the allocation of total investment among different capital projects; this topic, however, is outside the scope of this article. 23

Transcript of Tax Reform and Investment: Blessing or Curse?

Page 1: Tax Reform and Investment: Blessing or Curse?

FEDERAL RESERVE BANK OF ST LOUIS JUNE/JULY if?

Tax Reform and Investment:Blessing or Curse?Steven Al. Fazzari

number of recent studies have concluded thatthe Tax Reform Act of 1986 will reduce capital spend-

ing incentives in the United States.’ Many analysts fearthis result.

There is, however, an alternative view. By removingspecial subsidies for various kinds of investment, taxreform may encourage firms to invest in projects be-

cause they have high economic returns, rather thanlarge tax benefits. Jf economic returns more closelyreflect social values than the previous tax subsidies,investments could be better suited under tax reform toproduce goods and services that people want andenhance the productivity of the economy. Thus, therecent reform of capital taxation may actually improveeconothic welfare, even though it reduces the aggre-gate capital stock and investment. This paper investi-gates the welfare implications of the new capital taxsystem.

THE EFFICIENT ALLOCATION OFCAPITAL RESOURCES

In many popular discussions of taxes and invest-ment lurks an implicit assumption that more invest-ment is always better than less. After all, investment

causes the capital stock to expand, increases potentialoutput growth and enhances labor productivity. While

these outcomes are undoubtedly desirable, the simpleview that investment is always beneficial ignores thecosts imposed by greater capital accumulation. Byinvesting resources in more productive capital, peopleforego the opportunity to consume some goods andservices. Thus, investment generates opportunity

costs.’

To evaluate whatever changing levels of investmentimprove social welfare, one needs a criterion thatincorporates both the costs and benefits of changes in

Steven M. Fanari~an assistantprofessor ofeconomics at WashingtonUniversity in St. Louis, was a visiting scholar at the Federal ReserveSank of St. Louis. The author thanks James C. Poletti for researchassistance and Chris Varvares forhelpful discussion.‘See, for example, Prakken (1986), Henderson (1986), Aaron(1987), the Economic Report of the President (1987) and Fazzari(1987).

‘The opportunity costs associated with investment may be bestillustrated by an extreme case. Suppose all of a society’s outputwere invested in capital goods. Growth would be maximized, butthere would be no current consumption at all. This perspectiveemphasizes the trade-offs between investment and consumption.One could also consider the efficiency of the allocation of totalinvestment among different capital projects; this topic, however, isoutside the scope of this article.

23

Page 2: Tax Reform and Investment: Blessing or Curse?

FEDERAL RESERVE BANK OF ST. LOUIS JUNE/JULY 1987

the capital stock. The most widely used criterion thatmeets this objective is economic efficiency.’ A particu-lar level of investment is efficient if the benefits of allprojects undertaken exceed their cost while thebenefits of investment projects foregone fall short oftheir costs. Let us consider this concept in moredetail.

The benefit gained from a marginal investment hastwo dimensions: the amount of new output the in-vestment produces and the length of time it takes forthis additional output to become available. Consideran investment project that increases output by Y unitsat the end of its first year of production. Assume thatthe project depreciates at a constant annual i-ated < 1, so that it produces (1 —dl Y units of output atthe end of the second year, (1 — d)’Yunits at the end ofthe third year, etc. In general, the project will produce(1 — d)’’Y units of additional output at the end ofyear t.

Let P represent the market price of the output thatindividuals are willing to pay for additional units ofthis good. According to the economic efficiency cri-terion, this price represents the current value of a unitof output.’ Thus, the social value of an investmentproject in any year will be the quantity of additionaloutput it produces multiplied by the goods’ marketprice.

The concept of time preference implies that for avariety of reasons (impatience, uncertainty and atti-tude toward risk, for example), individuals would pre-fer to have goods and services sooner rather than later.Thus, the value of a given bundle of goods is smallerthe further in the future it becomes available.

A simple way of expressing this idea formally is toassume that individuals discount the value of outputavailable in the future, relative to the value of currentoutput, at a constant rate r, where r is a positivefraction. Thus, if a bundle ofconsumption goods avail-able today has a value of $10, the present value of thesame bundle delivered a year from now will be $10~11 + r). If it is delivered in two years, it will have a lowerpresent value, $10/(1 + r)’. In general, the present value

‘Although efficiency is the most widely used welfare criterion, it doesnot address some significant welfare issues. Most important, theefficiency criterion does not deal with the equity ofchanges in wealthdistributions caused by policy changes.‘There are important limitations to the view that the market pricemeasures the value of output because this measure does notincorporate any concept of distributional equity. The efficiency crite-rion remains meaningful for any given distribution of wealth, but itcannot be used to evaluate the implications of changing wealthdistributions.

of output that is worth PY at a time t years in the futureis PY/(1+r)’.

These concepts allow us to construct an expressionfor the present value (VI of an investment project thatincreases output in each future period t by (1— d)’’Yunits. The output has a constant market price of P. Thepresent value is:

V = ~ (1—d)’’ PY(1+r)t=1

which simplifies to:

V = PY/(r+d).’

To attain economic efficiency, any project should beundertaken that has a present value exceeding itspresent cost, the market price of the capital projectdenoted by P0. Thus, efficiency requires investment upto the point where the least-valued project under-taken has a productivity Y that satisfies:

= V = PY/(r+d), or

(1) (r+d) p, =

The efficiency condition given by equation 1 has anatural graphical interpretation. Rewrite equation 1 as:

(2) PY—dP,rP0.

The right side represents the cost of deferring con—sumption. In figure 1, this cost rises as the capitalstock expands because the more resources that aredeferred away from consumption into capital, thegreater the premium individuals require to compen-sate them for their time preference. The left side ofequation 2 represents the net output created by aninvestment project after allowing for the depreciationof capital. In figure 1, this net marginal benefit from theleast productive investment falls as the capital stockincreases.

‘This simplification is based on the fact that the geometric series‘S

is (1 —a)’. Thus,t’So

1—dt PY ~: (1—d)t11— ~t=1 ~i;-P T~d~tO1 +r

1—d [(1_1~~)_1—1] = f’~aTr= PY/(d+r).

24

Page 3: Tax Reform and Investment: Blessing or Curse?

FEDERAL RESERVE BANK OF ST. LOUIS JUNE/JULY 1987

F,gure I

Capital Stock and Economic EfficiencyDollars

Suppose the capital stock is K1 as shown in figure 1.New investment, on net, will produce new outputvalued at V,, in the market, but individuals are willingto release the current resources necessary to carry outthe investment for a payment of only V

1. Unexploited

gains to new investment exist, therefore, and K1 is notthe efficient capital stnck. On the other hand, themarginal costs of the least-valued investment projectexceed its net benefits at a capital stock of KB. Ef-ficiency then requires a decrease in investment andcapital. Only at K’, where equation 2 is satisfied, haveall gains from changing the capital stock been ex-ploited. This level gives an economically efficient capi-tal stock.

Profits and Firm Investment Decisions

A market economy has an efficient rate of invest-ment and level of capital stock if firms undertakeprojects up to the point where the least productiveinvestment satisfies equation 1. Firms, of course, aremotivated by profit; they will invest in projects thatincrease their shareholders’ wealth. An investmentproject will be profitable if its net revenue exceeds itscost to the firm. The revenue gained from investmentwill be the net output produced by the new capital (Y,initially) multiplied by the price of output (P1. The costto the firm consists of depreciation and real interest

earnings foregone by investing funds in fixed capitalrather than financial assets.’

A firm’s capital investment will be profitable if:

PY> P0d + P0i,

where i represents the real rate of interest the firmforegoes by investing in fixed capital. Thus, firms willinvest up to the point where

(3) I’Y = P~(d+i).’

Note that equation 3 looks almost the same as equa-tion 1. They will be the same if the real market rate ofinterest (i in equation 3) equals individuals’ discountrate (r in equation 1). This point will be addressed

Net Marginalbelow.

In spite of their close similarity, it is important tounderstand the conceptual distinction between equa-tions I and 3. Equation I defines a welfare standard forinvestment and the capital stock according to theefficiency criterion. On the othei hand, equation 2describes the level of investment profit-maximizingfirms will undertake in the market.

Much economic analysis has been devoted to un-derstanding the conditions under which economicefficiencywill be attained by the market. To obtain thisresult for the market analyzed here, the interest ratemust equal individuals’ discount rate. The real inter-est i—ate represents the opportunity cost to firms ofborrowing funds for capital investment. It also is thereturn to savers who give up the chance to consumetoday by lending, either directly or through financialintermediaries.

Suppose individuals decide that they want to con-sume more today. They reduce their saving, decreas-ing the supply of funds flowing into credit markets,drivingup interest rates. This continues until individ-uals are satisfied with the current level of saving at theprevailing market interest rate. Thus, the interest ratemeasures individuals’ discount rate at the margin, thepremium they require to exchange some consump-tion now for consumption in the future in the absenceof personal taxes on interest income. Under thesecircumstances, the interest rate equals the discountrate (i’ r), and equations 1 and 3 determine identicallevels of the capital stock. That is, firms will have profit

‘For a further discussion of the revenues and costs that determinethe profitability of investment, see Fazzari (1987).

‘This condition is equivalent to the maximization of net present value,under the assumptions made here. I have also assumed that thefirm is a price-taker, in both input and output markets.

25

Marginal cost(rP.)

v ~1-

K1

K~ K,,

Page 4: Tax Reform and Investment: Blessing or Curse?

FEDERAL RESERVE BANK OF ST. LOUIS JUNE/JULY 1987

incentives to invest in capital just up to the efficientlevel!

EFFICIENCY AND NEUTRAL TAXATION

The main result of the previous section suggeststhat the market outcome of firms’ independent, self-interested investment choices leads to an efficientcapital stock. The analysis that led to this result, how-ever, ignores the effect of corporate taxes on invest-ment incentives. This section introduces the in-fluences of corporate taxes; it provides a theoreticalbasis for evaluating the implications of tax reform forefficient capital investment.

As a general rule, taxes change the economic incen-tives faced by firms. In the case of the corporateincome tax, however, it is possible, at least in theory, tostructure the tax so that capital investment decisionsdo not change. Rewriting equation 3, we see that firmswill invest up to the point where the economic profitsfrom a marginal investment project equal zero:

(4) 0=PY—Pji+d).

The right side of equation 4 represents the eco-nomic profits from a marginal investment. Supposethese profits are taxed at a rate ‘r. Then firms will investup to the point where after-tat profits from a marginalinvestment aie zero,

0 = (1—i) (PY — Pji + dl], or

(5) (1—tI P1’ = (I —t)[P,Ai + dl]

The level of capital investment that satisfies equation 4will also satisfy 5; the same actions that maximize 100percent of profits will maximize 80 percent, 60 per-cent, or any non-zero proportion of profits. In thiscase, the corporate tax rate affects the portion of afirm’s profits that go to the government, but it does not

‘The result that unrestricted market interaction leads to efficientoutcomes is often used to argue for the normative position thatmarket results are socially desirable. This conclusion, however, islimited in general. Again, the idea that the willingness of individualsto save at the margin represents the social discount rate takes thedistribution of wealth as given. The efficient capital stock level wouldlikely change for different wealth distributions. Also, investment mayhave external social costs or benefits not recognized by the privatefirms that make investment decisions. Thus, private market invest-ment incentives might differ from social incentives. Finally, thisanalysis applies only to general economic equilibrium with fullutilization of resources. Existence of involuntary unemployment oridle capacity would change the structure of the analysis. Despitethese qualifications, efficiency analysis is widely regarded as rele-vant to evaluate the long-term impact of the tax system.

affect the firm’s incentives to invest efficiently.’

Economists call this kind of tax neutral. A neutraltax does not change the allocation of economic re-sources. The key to neutral taxation in this context isthat all revenues are taxed while all economic ex-penses are fully deductible.” This result is clear intheory, but difficult to implement in practice, as wewill now discuss.

U.S. CORPORATE TAXATION

The U.S.corporate tax system is not nearly as simpleas the tax analyzed above. In general, it is not neutral.The next section summarizes the effect of the tax codeon the cost of capital. Then, three important non-neutral aspects of U.S. tax law are discussed: tax de-preciation schedules, the investment tax credit, andthe deductions allowed for the opportunity cost ofinvested capital. Some non-neutralities arising frompersonal taxes are considered later.

The Cost of Capital in theU.S. Tax System

The efficient capital stock condition given by equa-tion 5 under neutral taxation assumes that the eco-nomic costs of capital are fully deductible from taxableincome. For a variety of reasons, however, the U.S. taxcode does not allow deductions based strictly on.economic costs. This introduces a number of non-neutral aspects into the tax code. To understand thesource of these non-neutralities, we must comparethe determination of capital investment under the U.S.tax law with the efficiency standard of a neutral taxgiven by equation S.

Let k represent the investment tax credit rate, z thepresent value of a one-dollar tax deduction for depre-ciation, and L the proportion ofa marginal investmentfinanced with debt (the debt leverage ratio). Supposethe expected inflation rate is ire. Profit-maximizingfirms will invest up to the point where the least-valued

‘This result assumes that the firm is indifferent between internal andexternal sources of finance. If this is not the case, investment maybe affected by reduced cash flow caused by higher corporate taxes,even if the tax is neutral in the sense discussed in the text. SeeFazzari (1987) and Fazzari and Athey (1987) for further discussion.

“Economic expenses include all the opportunity costs of buying andusing capital. They may differ in important respects from accountingcosts used by firms in their financial statements. Interest foregoneon shareholders’ equity, for example, represents an economic op-portunity cost but is not deducted from the firm’s accounting profit.

26

Page 5: Tax Reform and Investment: Blessing or Curse?

FEDERAL RESERVE SANK OF ST. LOUIS JUNE/JULY 1987

unit of capital purchased satisfies,

(6) (1—’r)PY = P~(I—k—’rz)[i+ d — ‘rL(i + li,)]”

The left side of equation 6 is the after-tax benefitgained from investment, as presented earlier. Theterm P,(1 — k — ‘It) on the right side represents the factthat each dollar spent on investment generates aninvestment tax credit of k and a depreciation deduc-tion with a present value of z.

The other change in equation 6 relative to the neu-tral tax case in equation 5 is that only explicit interestcosts are deductible from taxable income. Thus, if thefirm finances investment with debt, the explicit inter-est expense can be deducted from taxable income, butthe opportunity cost of interest foregone on rein-vested internal funds or proceeds from new equity

issues cannot be deducted. Furthermore, becausenominal interest is deducted, changes in the inflationrate will affect the value of the interest tax deduction,to the extent that markets anticipate inflation in thenominal interest rate.

As equation 6 indicates, the U.S. tax system may

introduce non-neutralities. The complicated expres-sion on the right side of equation 6 reduces to theefficient neutral tax given by equation 5 only underspecial circumstances. We shall now consider thispoint in greater detail.

Depreciation Allowances

In the neutral tax equation 5, economic deprecia-tion is deducted from taxable income in every period.In equation 6, the present value of depreciation allow-ances (z) is treated as a lump-sum deduction thatreduces the after-tax price of capital goods up front.The two approaches will lead to equivalent results,however, if the depreciation schedule underlying thecalculation of z is the same as economic depreciation.

To find the present value of depreciation allow-ances that leads to neutral taxation, suppose thatthere is no investment tax credit (k=0), the firmfinances marginal investment with debt alone (L~r1)and expected inflation is zero (‘ii. = 0). Then equation6 reduces to:

(7) (1— r)PY = P,(1 — i-z)fl1 — rh + d].

“The original reference for the form of the cost of capital given inequation 6 is Hall and Jorgenson (1967). Further references and amore-detailed explanation of the components of equation 6 can befound in Fazzari (1987).

To make equation 7 equivalent to the condition de-scribing efficient investment from equation 5, the mar-ginal cost of a new unit of capital must be the same ineach case.This implles that the right side of equation 4equals the right side of equation 6:

(l—’r)P, (i + dl = P,(l—tz)[(1—’r)i + d].

This equation can be solved for the efficient presentvalue of depreciation allowances (z’), that is,

(8) z’ = d/[(1—’r)i + d].”

Intuitively, C is the present value of a perpetualdepreciation flow d per dollar of investment. Thediscount rate consists of the after-tax real interest rateplus the depreciation rate. The latter term appearsbecause the amount of depreciation declines as theasset deteriorates.

The present values of depreciation schedules pre-scribed by the tax code can be compared with theefficient benchmark given by C. The first column oftable I gives the efficient present value under the oldand new tax laws.” The efficient present valuechanged after tax reform because the corporate taxrate fell from 46 percent to 34 percent.

The present value of actual depreciation allowancesprescribed by the tax code are presented in the sec-ond, third and fourth columns of table 1, again for theold and new tax laws.” Expected inflation plays animportant role here. Neither the old nor the new taxlaw indexes depreciation deductions for inflation. As-suming that higher expected inflation increases nomi-

“Equivalently, z’ can be derived by computing the present value ofeconomic depreciation deductions discounted at the after-tax realrate of return (1 —‘r)i. This analysis is complicated if one explicitlyconsiders the differential tax treatment of dividends and capitalgains where corporate income is distributed to shareholders. SeeAuerbach (1983) for further discussion.

“The efficient present value (z) calculations in table 1 assume a realdiscount rate of 3 percent, before taxes. The economic depreciationrates for autos and light trucks, office computing and accountingequipment, and communications equipment were estimated byGravelle (1982) as .33, .27 and .12, respectively. The averageeconomic depreciation rates for equipment and business structureswere .14 and .06 from the Washington University Macro Modelmaintained by Laurence H. Meyer and Associates, Ltd.

“See Ott (1984) and Fazzari (1987) for a discussion of how thesepresent values are computed and the details of the tax depreciationschedules. These calculations do not account for the fact that thedepreciable base for an asset eligible for the investment tax creditwas reduced by one-half of the credit, under the old tax law. Thissimplification is made to focus on the effect of changing the depreci-ation schedules alone. It is formally equivalent and conceptuallysimpler to think of the reduction in the depreciation base due to theinvestment tax credit as a reduction in the value of the credit ratherthan in the present value of depreciation deductions.

27

Page 6: Tax Reform and Investment: Blessing or Curse?

FEDERAL RESERVE SANK OF ST. LOUIS JUNEJJULY 1987

-:c? 1:iz~f~ 2k- 4~:~:t ~:

“4’\ 4, 4 4’ ,c’ $c’ ‘\, ‘/4 / ~~/ ‘C4~’N ‘4 ‘4 4’ 2 ~ ~‘ 2 44Ø$4\ ~

~a~tt~4t!!&2~4’,, ~‘ 4’ /

‘4 “4“, ‘4 N ‘4 ‘1k, ‘~4~s’4- / “ ‘4/ ~ 4’ “4‘,,

/ ‘444> ‘New’ 4,’ ,~>. ‘4’ “4CNZ’4’\ / /‘ 44

/4/44’ /44/444

~ ~ / “ / ,~ ‘4~,:~isr~~’j~’“i /// ~ ,,4’ 4’> ‘ ~4’ 1:4’4’ ~4, /4 ““4 4/ /‘ ‘ ‘4 4 ‘4’ “44,4 * ‘N

4/ 2 ~ ~ ‘4’~ ~ ‘4 “4 ‘4” “ ‘4”’~i~~~,,,, “

44’4 ~e~24~ 2 44 /‘/ ~44

”NS 44 / , 4, N

__ 4 ~‘~!~CC’/4, ‘4/4/4,4, ‘4 ,, ‘4”N /4 4>‘4” “‘,‘ 4’ :*t mflz~ir:.4’4s~x~,.~g~4c&-~4’11’~“>i”4’,.

/ 4 ,/ /4 /~‘4 ‘N s,,, “4 /

~ ‘ N, ‘,,N44’4 ‘N N4’ ‘~, ~% /4>> ‘/4

nal interest rates, the present value of a fixed, nominaldepreciation flow decreases with rising expected in-flation, as shown in table 1.”

With no expected inflation and nominal interestrates equal to real rates, the tax depreciation sched-ules generally lead to more generous present valuesthan the efficient present value. Thus, the rapid write-offs of capital goods allowed by the tax code subsidizeinvestment in the absence of inflation. Although thenew tax law reduces this subsidy somewhat, the dif-ferential still remains.

As expected inflation rises, however, the presentvalues of actual depreciation allowances decline andapproach the efficient level. The final column of table Igives the expected inflation rate at which the presentvalue of the depreciation deduction allowable for taxpurposes equals the efficient level. Under the old taxlaw, equipment deductions, on average, would have

“For the calculations in table 1, the before-tax nominal discount rateis assumed to rise by one percentage point for each percentage-point increase in the expected inflation rate. A number of econo-mists have argued that nominal interest rates must increase bymore than the rise in expected inflation to maintain real returnsconstant because of personal taxes levied on nominal interestincome. See Darby (1975) and Feldstein (1976), for example. If thisis the case, the present values of depreciation allowances willdecline more than the figures in table 1 indicate when expectedinflation rises.

been efficient with an expected inflation rate of 8.5percent. After tax reform, this declined to 7.1 percent.’6

The results for business structures are somewhatdifferent. The rapid structure depreciation allowedunder the old tax law led to a substantial subsidy atzero expected inflation. Because of its slow deprecia-tion, however, the present value of nominal deprecia-tion allowances for structures is especially sensitive toany changes in nominal interest rates caused by risingexpected inflation. Thus, under the old tax law, theaccelerated structures deduction was efficient at amoderate 3.1 percent expected inflation rate.

Tax reform sharply reduced the present value ofstructures depreciation; it increased the tax servicelife from 19 to 31.5 years and replaced an accelerateddepreciation schedule with a straight-line schedule.As table I shows, this pushes depreciation allowancesfor business structures to the efficient level at anexpected inflation rateclose to zero. Even at moderatelevels ofexpected inflation, however, the slow write-offmandated by the new tax law causes a substantial

“This result is sensitive to the assumption made about the realbefore-tax discount rate. If this rate increases from 3 percent to 5percent, the efficient expected inflation rate for the equipment aver-age rises from 7.1 percent to 12.0 percent.

28

Page 7: Tax Reform and Investment: Blessing or Curse?

FEDERAL RESERVE BANK OF ST. LOUIS JUNE/JULY 1987

disincentive for structures investment relative to theefficient level.

The Investment Tax Credit

The depreciation deductions allowed in the taxcode correspond to one aspect of the economic cost ofusing capital. In a neutral tax system, the economicvalue of these costs should be deducted from taxableincome. Inefficiency arises from depreciation deduc-

tions only to the extent that the tax depreciationschedules are more or less generous than economicdepreciation.

The investment tax credit, on the other hand, repre-sents a direct subsidy to investment. It does not cor-respond to any aspect of the economic cost of capital.By itself, the investment tax credit provides incentivesfor firms to purchase more of the eligible assets thanthe efficiency criterion would dictate. The repeal ofthe credit in the new tax law moves the tax systemcloser to neutrality.

The investment tax credit applied to only a subset ofcapital assets. Thus, the subsidy not only distorted theamount of investment, but also the composition ofinvestment. A detailed analysis of this issue lies out-side the scope of this paper, but efficiencygains fromthe repeal of the credit may result from a more effec-tive allocation of investment among different assetsand activities. Furthermore, inefficient investmentthat tookplace as a result of the subsidy competed forscarce funds and raised the interest rate. This couldhave crowded out other efficient projects that mayhave been undertaken in the absence of the subsidy.’~

Of course, given other distortions in capital taxation,some kind of subsidy may be appropriate to offset thedisincentives to investment arising from other aspects

of the tax system. As the previous analysis showed, theequipment assets eligible for the investment tax creditgenerally benefit from rapid depreciation deductionsubsidies at low inflation rates even with the changesdue to tax reform. Thus, the investment tax credit isnot needed in the current environment to offset thedistortions caused by tax depreciation schedules. Thecredit, however, may offset another distorting aspectof the tax code: firms’ inability to deduct the fullopportunity cost of funds tied up in capital invest-ment.

‘7The author thanks Milton Friedman for comments on an earlierpaper that emphasized these points.

Debt Financing and CapitalCost Deductions

In the neutral tax system represented by equation 5,the opportunity cost of capital given by the real inter-est rate Ii) is fully deductible from taxable income. Itdoes not matter whether the interest expense involvesexplicit payments to debt holders or implicit opportu-nity costs of foregone interest earnings by equity hold-ers.” The tax law, however, allows deduction of ex-plicit interest expense, but does not allow deductionof interest foregone when investment is financedthrough internal cash flow or new equity.

To the extent that new capital spending is notcompletely debt-financed, the after-tax cost of capitalrises and investment falls relative to the efficient level.This effect is reflected in equation 6 by the fact that thededuction for interest expense is multiplied by themarginal proportion of investment financed by debtIL). This introduces an important non-neutrality intothe tax system.

At a zero inflation rate, this effect alone gives firmsan incentive to employ less than the efficient level ofcapital. But inflation mitigates this distortion. Theeconomic cost of capital depends on the real interestrate. The tax code, however, allows firms to deductnominal interest expense. As expected inflation andnominal interest rates rise, therefore, the real value oftax deductions for interest expenses increases.

At a sufficiently high inflation rate, the tax benefitfrom deductions for nominal interest will offset theincrease in the after-tax cost of capital arising becauseinterest foregone on internal financing cannot be de-ducted from taxable income. One can solve for theexpected inflation rate that leads to this efficient result(ii’) by equating the deductions for interest expense inthe neutral tax system from equation 5 with the de-duction in the actual tax system from equation 6:

Ti = ‘rL(i + ‘11’)

This gives

9) ~ =

With a real interest rate of 3 percent and the debtleverage ratio 30 percent, the efficient inflation ratefrom equation 9 is 7 percent.”

“See Fazzari (1987) for a further discussion of debt and equityfinance for capital spending.

“The average corporate debt leverage ratio in the second quarter of1986 was 30.6 percent according to data from the WashingtonUniversity Macro Model.

29

Page 8: Tax Reform and Investment: Blessing or Curse?

FEDERAL RESERVE BANK OF St LOUIS JUNE/JULY 1987

Tax reform has a subtle effect on this problem. Thenew tax code, like the old law, does not allow deduc-tions for interest foregone by shareholders. But thenew law eliminates preferential personal tax rates forcapital gains income. Thus, corporations will have anincentive to pay out a greater proportion of theirincome as dividends and finance more new invest-ment with debt. This reduces the efficiency distortioncaused by the non-deductibility of foregone interestfrom internal finance at low inflation rates.”

INVESTMENT NON-NEUTRALITIESFROM PERSONAL TAXES

The discussion to this point has focused primarilyon the corporate tax system. But, ultimately, corporateprofits accrue to shareholders who are liable for per-sonal taxes as well.We shall now consider the efléct ofpersonal taxes on the firm’s incentive to invest in fixedcapital.

If personal taxes on all corporate-source incomewere uniform, they would not directly affect corporateinvestment decisions because, again, the same actionsthat maximize 100 percent ofprofits will maximize anyconstant proportion of profits.” Personal taxes on cor-porate income, however, are not uniform. In particu-lar, income from capital galns has been taxed at lowerrates than dividend and interest income.

This lower rate provides a rather subtle subsidy forinvestment. Suppose individual capital gains are taxedat a rate ~ while interest income is taxed at the regularpersonal rate;. If capital markets equate the after-taxrate of return on earnings retained by the corporationwith the after-tax interest rate on debt, then:

+ m,) = (I—-r,j(i + ‘~e~’

where i,, is the implicit real interest rate on corporateretentions?2 Thus, as long as:

i,,,, + it,, = Ii + ir,,))I —‘r~)/)I—‘r,,) < ii + it,).

“Debt finance is beneficial in the sense that it pushes the economycloser to efficiency at the microeconomic level. On the other hand,higher debt ratios can make the macroeconomic system as a wholeless stable. This issue is outside the scope of this paper. For furtherdiscussion, see Caskey and Fazzari (1986).

2~Evenuniform personal taxation could have an indirect effect oninvestment because the tax on the return from saving will reduceindividual incentives to defer current consumption. This tends toraise real interest rates and increase the opportunity cost of capital.This issue is considered later in the article.

“This approach follows Henderson (1988), p. 23. It ignores any riskpremium required by investors in corporate equity.

The favorable treatment of capital gains income leadsto a subsidized rate of interest for investment financedwith retained earnings.

Let us integrate this effect into the cost of capitalformula. As before, assume that the firm finances afraction L of marginal investments with debt and 1 — L

with retained earnings. The weighted average nominalopportunity cost of funds the firm faces is:

1—i(10) c = (1—U) )(i+ir,) + L(I—i)(i+ir,).”

I

The firm’s cost of capital is then:

(II) P0(1—k--tz)(c it, + d).

Equation 11 reduces to the right side of equation 6when the personal tax rate on capital gains equals thepersonal tax rate on regular income (t,, =

Capital Gains Taxation AfterTax Reform

Tax reform has fundamentally changed the terms ofthe capital gains subsidy by repealing the 60 percentexclusion for capital gains income. This change, how-ever, does not mean that the personal tax advantagesof capital gains income has been removed. Sharehold-ers that receive capital gains income still benefit fromthe deferral of tax until the time the asset is sold andthe capital gain is realized.

The effectivetax rate on capital gains income, there-fore, depends on the length of time an investor holdsan asset. One can compute ‘r,, as the present value ofthe tax paid at realization per dollar of capital gaindiscounted at the individual’s after-tax real interestrate:

(12) ~,, = (1— p.) i-,I[1 + (1 —‘r~)i]”,

where p. is the proportion of capital gains incomeexcluded from tax and H is the holding period.’4

“Equation 10 is based on two simplifying assumptions. First, nomarginal investment is financed with new share issues. According toHenderson (1986), new shares account for only 4.9 percent of theU.S. capital spending finance. Second, and more importantly, equa-tion 8 assumes that the earnings from marginal, internally financedinvestments are completely retained and will be taxed as capitalgains. This analysis is complicated by dividends. See Auerbach(1983) for further discussion.

‘4This equation is a simplification. In general, the accrual-equivalentcapital gains tax rate depends on the rate of growth of the asset’svalue and the holding period in a more complicated way. Furthercomplications arise because capital gains not realized before theasset holder’s death may escape taxation. Also, much capital gainsincome is realized by tax-exempt or tax-deferred funds such aspensions or individual retirement accounts. See Auerbach (1983),pp. 919—20 for further discussion and references.

30

Page 9: Tax Reform and Investment: Blessing or Curse?

FEDERAL RESERVE BANK or ST. LOUIS JUNE/JULY 1981

As we can see fi’om equation 10, the effect of thecapital gains personal tax subsidy depends on theratio 1— ;)i(i — i-a,). If the personal tax rate on interestincome equals the tax rate on capital gains income,this ratio will be unity, and equation 10 gives the sameopportunity cost of funds that was derived in theabsence of personal tax considerations.

This ratio, however, is not equal to unity. Assumingan average marginal personal tax rate on ordinaryincome of 28 percent, a 60 percent capital gains exclu-sion, a 3 percent real after-tax discount rate, and a 10-year holding period for long-term capital gains, theratio (1 —‘r~)/(i—‘r,,) was 0.78 for the old tax law. Thisfigure is based on an effective capital gains tax rate of8.3 percent from equation 12. Removing the 60 percentcapital gains exclusion and lowering the personal taxrate to 22 percent gives an effective capital gains taxrate of 16.4 percent and a ratio (1 — ‘r,,)/(i — tg) of 0.93 forthe new tax law.”

Under a completely neutral tax system, all personalincome would be taxed equivalently; so (1— ;)/(l —

would equal unity. Thus, tax reform moves the systemtoward neutrality from this perspective alone.

TAX REFORM AND EFFICIENCY: ANOVERALL ASSESSMENT

The preceding sections of this article analyzed anumber of non-neutral features of U.S. capital taxa-tion. The effect of tax reform on each of these non-neutralities was considered separately. This sectionprovides an overall assessment of whether tax reformhas brought capital taxation closer to the efficiencystandard.

Table 2 provides one perspective on the efficiencyofthe tax law, before and after tax reform. The figuresshow the ratio of the actual after-tax cost of capital tothe efficient cost ofcapital under neutral taxation. Thecalculations are based on the assumption that the realinterest rate firms face in the market reflects the socialopportunity cost of providing capital.” Thus, this ratio

“These results were not changed much by increasing the real, after-tax discount rate to 5 percent, or shortening the holding period to 5years. With the maximum marginal personal tax rates, however,greater subsidies result. The (1 —w,)/(1 -T,~) ratio was 0.59 for theold law and 0.89 for the new law.

“Thisratio is computed as the actual cost of capital from equation 11,(1 — k — Tz)(c — 7r~±d),where c is defined in equation 10, to the costof capital under neutral taxation from the right side of equation 5,(1 —i)O + d). The investment tax credit rates are adjusted to reflectthe fact that the depreciation base for an asset eligible for the creditwas reduced by one-half of the credit. Thus, k = k,(1 — 0.5 rz),where k, is the statutory investment tax credit rate.

This ratio measures the extent of the tax distortionof capital costs. If the ratio is unity, there is no distor-tion, and the tax system is neutral for that class ofasset. A ratio less than one indicates that the taxsystem encourages investment relative to the efficientrate; a ratio greater than one shows that the tax systemdiscourages investment relative to the efficient rate.

The effects of tax reform on equipment tax distor-tions are striking. Under the old tax law, the systemprovided a subsidy to equipment investment: the ra-tios are less than one. This was due primarily to theinvestment tax credit. Under the new law) the treat-ment of equipment approaches remarkably close totax neutrality. The results presented in table 2 arebased on a 3 percent real interest rate, a 4 percentexpected inflation rate and a 30 percent marginal debtleverage ratio. Qualitatively similar results for equip-ment asset classes are obtained for a wide range ofassumptions about these parameters.

For business structures, the result appears less fa-vorable. The generous depreciation allowances forstructures under the old tax law caused the after--taxcost of capital to fall below the efficient level for struc-tures as well as equipment. By sharply reducing thevalue of structures’ depreciation allowances, however,tax reform pushes the after-tax cost of structures’capital well above the efficient level.

31

provides a measure of the extent to which the capitaltaxation system alone distorts investment incentives.

Page 10: Tax Reform and Investment: Blessing or Curse?

FEDERAL RESERVE BANK OF ST. LOUIS JUNE/JULY 1987

The excessive taxation of business structures, how-ever, may not be as large as the figures in table 2suggest. The calculations assume that all investmentis financed with the average 30 percent debt leverageratio. But structure debt leverage ratios are probablyhigher than the average, because collateral value pro-vided by structures is more easily realized than thevalues of firm-specific equipment. Higher leverage ra-tios reduce the cost of capital because interest ex-pense is tax deductible. If the leverage ratio for struc-tures reaches 50 percent to 70 percent (the exact valuedepends on expected inflation), structures taxationwill be neutral, even under the new tax depreciationschedules.’~

The results presented in table 2 reflect the efficiencyof taxes on firms’ capital alone because the real marketinterest rate was assumed to reflect the social oppor-tunity cost of capital. As mentioned earlier, however,individuals pay personal taxes on interest income.Thus, the market interest rate exceeds the returnrequired by savers. Suppose that savers require anafter-tax rate of return of r. Because nominal interest istaxed, the nominal market interest rate Ii + it,) mustsatisfiy:

(13) r = (i+ir,)(i—t,) — it,

to give savers an after-tax real rate of return equal to r.”

This changes the comparison between the actualand efficient cost of capital in a fundamental way. Theefficient cost of capital is based on the social discountrate r, while firms must pay a higher real interest ratein the market to compensate savers for the personaltaxes they pay on interest income. To reach efficiencyaccording to this perspective, therefore, investmentmust receive tax subsidies that stimulate capitalspending sufficiently to offset the disincentives to sav-ing arising from taxes on personal interest income.

Table 3 presents tax ratios that incorporate thiseffect. The results are different from those in table 2 forthe capital tax system alone. The investment subsidiesfor equipment in the old tax lawled toan effectivecostof capital that still fell below the after-tax opportunity

“If the leverage ratio is higher than average for structures, it must belower than average for equipment. For example, a 50 percentstructures leverage ratio would imply about 20 percent equipmentleverage to obtain a weighted average of 30 percent becauseapproximately two-thirds of investment consists of equipment. Re-ducing the leverage ratio to 20 percent for equipment, however,does not substantially change the results presented in this article.

“This issue is discussed in detail by Darby (1975) and Feldstein(1978).

1.06

1.071111.101.35

cost of savers, although the tax ratios for the old law intable 3 are closer to unity than in table 2. ‘I’he cost ofcapital for structures that were ineligible for the in-vestment tax credit, however, was well above the ef-ficient level, even with the old law’s generous depreci-ation allowance. By removing the capital subsidies, taxreform increased the cost of capital above the efficientlevel in all cases. To the extent that investment subsi-dies are desirable to offset the disincentive to savingcaused by personal taxes on interest, tax reform doesnot improve efficiency.

One also should note that the tax distortions for thenew law become worse at higher expected inflationrates. This is because personal taxes are levied onnominal interest income. As expected inflation andnominal interest rates rise, therefore, the premiumrequired to maintain individuals’ after-tax real returnon saving rises evenfaster.

CONCLUDING REMARKS

This article has analyzed the effect of the Tax Re-form Act of 1986 on the efficiency of U.S. capital forma-tion. The results leave little doubt that the old tax lawsubsidized equipment investment. Tax reform re-moved these subsidies, especially the investment taxcredit. Now, the tax system causes the after-tax cost ofcapital to correspond closely to economic deprecia-tion and market rates of interest. Tax reform appar-ently moves equipment taxation close to neutrality, in

32

Page 11: Tax Reform and Investment: Blessing or Curse?

FEDERAL RESERVE BANK OF ST. LOUIS JUNE/JULY 1987

the sense that the after-tax cost of capital reflects realeconomic depreciation and real market interest rates.For structures, however, an apparent subsidy due togenerous depreciation allowances under the old taxlaw was more than offset by tax reform. Now the tax onstructures is substantially higher than the level con-sistent with neutrality.

From a broader perspective, however, some invest-ment subsidies were necessary to attain an efficientallocation of resources between consumption andcapital formation. Because personal interest income issubject to tax, many economists have argued that themarket interest rate overstates the social opportunitycost of investing in capital. Thus, investment subsi-dies, like those in the old tax law, can offset thedisincentive to saving arising from personal taxes.

One might argue that the distortion caused by per-sonal taxes on interest income should be dealt withdirectly rather than by subsidizing capital investment.The lower personal tax rates resulting from tax reformaccomplish this to some extent, although this effect isoffset by higher taxes on capital gains and tighterrestrictions on IRA benefits. Thus, tax reform’s impli-cations for the efficient allocation of current resourcesbetween investment and consumption remain ambig-uous.

REFERENCESAaron, Henry J. “The Impossible Dream ComesTrue: The New Tax

Reform Act,” The Arookings Review (Winter 1987), pp. 3—10.Auerbach, Alan J. “Taxation, Corporate Financial Policy and the

Cost of Capital,” Journal of Economic Uterature (September1983),pp. 905—40.

Darby, Michael R. “The Financial and Tax Effects of MonetaryPolicy on Interest Rates,” Economic lnqui,y (June 1975), pp. 266—76.

Economic Report of the President. (U. S. Government PrintingOffice, 1987).

Fazzari, Steven M. “Tax Reform and Investment: How Big anImpact?” this Review (January 1987), pp. 15—27.

Fazzari, Steven M., and Michael J. Athey. “Asymmetric Informa-tion, Financing Constraints, and Investment,” Review of Eco-nomics and Statistics (forthcoming, 1987).

Fazzari, Steven M., and John P. Caskey. ‘Macroeconomics andCredit Markets,” Joumal ofEconomic Issues (June 1986), pp. 421—29.

Feldstein, Martin. “Inflation, Income Taxes and the Rate of Interest:A Theoretical Analysis,” American Economic Review (December1976), pp. 809—20.

Gravelle, Jane 0. “Effects of the 1981 Depreciation Revisions onthe Taxation of Income from Business Capital.” National Tax Jour-nal (February 1982), pp.1—20.

Hall, Robert, and Dale Jorgenson. ‘Tax Policy and InvestmentBehavior,” American Economic Review (June 1987), pp. 391—414.

Henderson, Yolanda. “Lessons from Federal Reform of BusinessTaxes,” New England Economic Reyiew (November/December1986), pp. 9—25.

Prakken, Joel L. “The Macroeconomics ofTax Reform,” presentedat the American Council for Capital Formation conference entitled“The Consumption Tax: A Better Alternative?” September 3—5,1986, Washington, D.C.

Ott, Mack. “Depreciation, Inflation and Investment Incentives: TheEffects of the Tax Acts of 1981 and 1982,” this Review (November1984), pp. 17—30.

33