Sarah Birch - The Evolution of Electoral Integrity in New Democracies and Electoral Authoritarian...

30
1 The Evolution of Electoral Integrity in New Democracies and Electoral Authoritarian Regimes Sarah Birch University of Glasgow [email protected] ABSTRACT: Popular protests following elections in electoral authoritarian states have become more common in recent years, yet few studies have analyzed this phenomenon. This paper draws on the literatures on contentious politics and electoral integrity to provide a novel account of post-electoral protest. The main argument is that because in the wake of the ‘third wave’ of democratization, the politics of electoral reform revolves mainly around the implementation of democratic electoral principles rather than around the principles themselves, electoral authoritarian leaders tend to employ forms of electoral abuse that entail giving unfair advantage to pro-regime electoral competitors, rather than excluding either voters or competitors from the electoral arena altogether. This means that citizens have electoral rights formally accorded to them but episodically abused, a pattern which is conducive to generating grievance. When such regimes ramp up forms of manipulation that favor pro-regime political forces, the resultant deterioration in election quality can then serve as a focal point which serves to mobilize citizens to mount mass protests. In as much as protest can, under the right circumstances, lead to reforms which improve electoral integrity, one of the implications of this argument is that elections often have to get worse before they get better. Keywords: Post-electoral protest, electoral integrity, electoral misconduct, contentious politics, electoral reform THIS IS A VERY ROUGH PRELIMINARY DRAFT ONLY PLEASE DO NOT CITE Paper prepared for presentation and the University of Sydney, 12 August 2014

description

Evolución de la integridad electoral en las nuevas democracias. Análisis del Gobierno Electoral y su independencia.

Transcript of Sarah Birch - The Evolution of Electoral Integrity in New Democracies and Electoral Authoritarian...

  • 1

    The Evolution of Electoral Integrity in New Democracies and Electoral Authoritarian

    Regimes

    Sarah Birch

    University of Glasgow

    [email protected]

    ABSTRACT: Popular protests following elections in electoral authoritarian states have become

    more common in recent years, yet few studies have analyzed this phenomenon. This paper draws

    on the literatures on contentious politics and electoral integrity to provide a novel account of

    post-electoral protest. The main argument is that because in the wake of the third wave of democratization, the politics of electoral reform revolves mainly around the implementation of

    democratic electoral principles rather than around the principles themselves, electoral

    authoritarian leaders tend to employ forms of electoral abuse that entail giving unfair advantage

    to pro-regime electoral competitors, rather than excluding either voters or competitors from the

    electoral arena altogether. This means that citizens have electoral rights formally accorded to

    them but episodically abused, a pattern which is conducive to generating grievance. When such

    regimes ramp up forms of manipulation that favor pro-regime political forces, the resultant

    deterioration in election quality can then serve as a focal point which serves to mobilize citizens

    to mount mass protests. In as much as protest can, under the right circumstances, lead to reforms

    which improve electoral integrity, one of the implications of this argument is that elections often

    have to get worse before they get better.

    Keywords: Post-electoral protest, electoral integrity, electoral misconduct, contentious politics,

    electoral reform

    THIS IS A VERY ROUGH PRELIMINARY DRAFT ONLY PLEASE DO NOT CITE

    Paper prepared for presentation and the University of Sydney, 12 August 2014

  • 2

    Anyone with a television will have noticed that mass protests following the announcement of

    election results are increasingly occupying their screens. Though many have undoubtedly noted

    this fact in passing, we have as yet little understanding of what accounts for the recent rise in

    post-electoral protest. Several decades of research on contentious politics, starting with Mancur

    Olsons The Logic of Collective Action (1965) and Ted Robert Gurrs Why Men Rebel (1970),

    have provided us with considerable insight into the conditions under which popular mobilization

    and protest activity emerge. At the same time, a burgeoning literature on electoral integrity and

    manipulation sheds light on the dynamics of electoral misconduct and the impact of election-

    related mass mobilization on regime behavior. Yet we have very limited understanding of the

    circumstances in which election-related mass mobilization occurs. This paper seeks to fill this

    gap by developing a novel account of post-electoral protest.

    Previous scholarship has largely framed post-electoral protest as the result of electoral

    fraud or other forms of electoral malpractice (e.g. Norris, 2012; Svolik and Chernyk, 2012;

    Thompson and Kuntz, 2009; Tucker, 2007), but this fails argument to explain why most

    fraudulent elections are not followed by major protests. This paper proposes an answer to this

    puzzle that focuses on the specific characteristics of contemporary competitive authoritarian or

    electoral authoritarian states in creating the preconditions for mass mobilization around

    election-related grievances, together with the role of increases in electoral malpractice from one

    election to the next in triggering protest. In a nutshell, the argument put forward here is that

    because since the third wave of democratization the politics of electoral reform has revolved

    mainly around the implementation of democratic electoral principles rather than around the

    principles themselves, contemporary electoral authoritarian leaders tend to employ forms of

    electoral abuse that entail giving unfair advantage to pro-regime competitors, rather than

  • 3

    excluding either voters or competitors from the electoral arena altogether. This means that

    citizens have electoral rights formally accorded to them but episodically abused, a pattern which

    is conducive to generating grievance. When such regimes ramp up electoral misconduct, the

    resultant deterioration in election quality serves as a focal point which mobilizes mass publics to

    protest.

    There are a number of reasons why leaders might increase their use of electoral

    malpractice: they may be suffering from a decline in popularity due to poor policy delivery;

    alternatively, traditional vote-winning strategies based on clientelism may falter in the wake of

    socio-economic development or decreased state capacity to pay off target groups; or increased in

    electoral malpractice may result from internal power-struggles within the regime and the desire

    of a new leader to consolidate their grip on power (Birch, 2011; Donno, 2013b; van Ham, 2013).

    But whatever the reason why manipulation of the electoral process has increased, the result can

    be expected to be an increased propensity of citizens to mobilize against electoral abuse. Protest

    can then under the right conditions be the catalyst for lasting reforms which lead to a long-term

    improvement in electoral integrity.

    This argument unfolds as follows: the first section of the paper surveys the historical

    context that has led to the recent rise in the potential for post-electoral protests. The second

    section develops hypotheses about the relationship between changes in electoral integrity and the

    occurrence of electoral protest. The third section provides cross-national empirical evidence of

    the circumstances under which post-electoral protest takes place. A final section concludes.

    I Electoral Rights and Electoral Practice

  • 4

    Election is an ancient institution that has only in modern times been harnessed to the ends of

    representative democracy (Katz, 1997, chap. 2; Posada-Carb, 1996; Staveley, 1972). The

    increasing importance of elected assemblies as tools of governance in the 18th and 19th centuries

    was the first stage in this process. Since that time, representative democracy has evolved along

    two principal fronts: elected representatives (assemblies and executives) have gradually eclipsed

    non-elected institutions, and elections have come increasingly to embody values we associate

    with freeness, fairness and credibility.

    It is the second of these developments that is of relevance to the concerns of this paper.

    Three key phases or waves, to use Samuel Huntingtons terminology (Huntington, 1991), can

    be identified in the evolution of standards of electoral integrity. The first and second of these

    phases revolved around the increasing inclusivity of elections, and can be understood in terms of

    Dahls core democratic dimensions of participation and contestation (Dahl, 1973). In the first

    wave of electoral reform, which began in Europe and the Americas in the 18th and 19th centuries

    and was largely complete by the mid-20th century, franchises were expanded, and the entire adult

    citizenry was, with limited exceptions, gradually incorporated into electoral processes

    (Przeworski, 2008; 2011). By 1945, virtually all developed states had accepted universal

    suffrage, as had a number of non-democratic and less-developed states. There are of course

    exceptions, such as Switzerland, which only granted women the vote in 1974, the United States

    and Australia, which imposed effective restrictions on voting by blacks till the 1960s, and South

    Africa, where genuine universal suffrage was established only in 1994. There also remain a

  • 5

    handful of countries that do not currently hold direct national-level elections at all.1 However,

    franchise inclusivity was largely achieved by the end of the Second World War.

    The second major wave in the development of modern standards of electoral integrity

    took place largely in the immediate post-Cold War period and is associated with inclusivity: the

    opening of electoral systems to competition by virtually all parties and individuals who wish to

    take part in the electoral process. This development was associated with a decline in the number

    of single-party regimes and the increase in the number of competitive authoritarian or electoral

    authoritarian regimes in the post-Cold War Era (Levitsky and Way, 2010; Schedler, 2013).

    Whereas the first wave of electoral reforms effectively eliminated voter exclusion, the second

    wave dramatically reduced the number of states that formally limited the range of parties and

    candidates which were, in theory at least, allowed to compete in elections (Diamond, 2002;

    Gandhi, 2008: 40; Schedler, 2013: 3).

    For several decades commentators used the terminology of free and fair to describe

    elections. Though this language has somewhat fallen into disuse in recent years, we can say that

    the first two waves in the evolution of electoral integrity were largely about elections becoming

    freer, in the sense that electoral institutions were reformed so as to bring about greater formal

    inclusion. By contrast, the third wave of electoral reform has largely revolved around making

    elections fairer by creating a level playing field for competition. Of course, the manipulation of

    electoral procedures has for centuries been an aspect of electoral competition, and periodic

    reforms to address problems such as undue influence and vote-buying have long been debated.

    1 These include Brunei, the Peoples Republic of China, Eritrea, Qatar, Saudi Arabia, Somalia

    and the Vatican City State.

  • 6

    However, it has only been recently that the focus of efforts to improve elections has fallen

    squarely in the implementation of electoral procedures, rather than on the establishment of basic

    electoral rights.

    This third wave of electoral reform, which is ongoing, began to gain momentum in the

    wake of the third wave of democratization in the final years of the 20th century, when there was a

    growing realization that many of the states that had recently opened up their electoral processes

    to multiparty competition nevertheless carried out elections that were fundamentally flawed in

    many ways (Bjornlund, 2004; Schedler, 2002a).

    In the contemporary world, there are very few states that hold no elections to national-

    level institutions, and there are also few that impose significant suffrage restrictions. There are a

    number of what are often termed hegemonic authoritarian states (Diamond, 2002; Donno,

    2013a; Levitsky and Way, 2010) that impose substantial effective restrictions on competition,

    such that regime opponents are regularly denied ballot access. Yet in most states with problem

    elections, formal electoral rights of inclusion are guaranteed, and the principal obstacles to

    electoral integrity revolve around de facto rather than de jure inclusiveness (Birch, 2011;

    Brownlee, 2009; Donno, 2013; Schedler, 2013). It follows that the main objects of dispute in

    states that hold problematic elections tend in the contemporary period to be those pertaining to

    electoral fairness, and when reforms are introduced, they tend to involve such measures as

    guaranteeing independent electoral commissions, improving voter registers and ensuring that

    there are impartial electoral dispute resolution mechanisms available to all electoral actors.

    The result has been a gradual shift from exclusion to bias as a means of manipulating

    elections, and the argument proposed here is that this shift has had important implications for

    how mass publics react to electoral abuse. Whereas previously the terrain of contestation had

  • 7

    been largely about specific rights the right to vote and the right to stand for election now the

    grounds for grievance about elections are much more likely to revolve around how elections are

    conducted on the ground. In other words, objections to electoral conduct are more likely to focus

    on the implementation of the basic principles subtending elections than on the basic principles

    themselves. Granted, electoral laws are common objects of complaint; indeed, a recent study has

    found that the manipulation of electoral laws to be the most common form of manipulation in

    three regions of the worlds between 1995 and 2007 (Birch, 2011). Nevertheless, in only a small

    minority of these cases was the basic right to take part in an election either as a voter or as a

    candidate is at issue. In temporal terms, there is now a greater focus on what goes on

    immediately before, during and after elections. For example, elections in the Soviet Union were

    fairly low-key affairs, as the script underlying them was well-known to all those involved;

    nothing that happened during the electoral process was at all likely to affect the fundamental fact

    that there was only ever one candidate on the ballot paper. In post-Soviet Russia, by contrast, the

    right to competition is constitutionally guaranteed, and even if the results of recent electoral

    contests have been foregone conclusions, there has been far greater focus both domestically and

    internationally on how elections are carried out (McAllister and White, 2011).

    II Electoral Integrity and Post-Electoral Protest

    The behavioral implications of this shift from contestation over rights to contestation over

    processes have resulted from the fact that actors are in contemporary electoral authoritarian

    states typically included in the electoral process, but then cheated of fair treatment. In other

    words, they are given a stake in electoral institutions, and then left to watch their stake eroded by

    manipulative practices.

  • 8

    We know from the social-psychological literature that humans are generally loss-

    averse, in the sense that - contrary to traditional utilitarian expectations - the loss of existing

    assets is viewed more unfavorably than failure to gain new assets (Kahneman and Tversky,

    2000). The sense of having been cheated, of having something given and then stolen or taken

    away, thus has greater potential to lead to widespread grievance than the absence of formal

    electoral rights. Being formally included but effectively disenfranchised is also more likely to

    generate episodic disquiet and thus mobilization; hence electoral processes are the ideal

    background for contentious politics. Elections are predictably circumscribed in time, they follow

    well-defined, highly ritualized patterns, and they involve virtually the entire adult population

    (Bunce and Wolchik, 2011: 16). It is not surprising that repertoires of contentious activity should

    develop in many contexts where elections are viewed as being unfair (e.g. Blaydes, 2011; Bunce

    and Wolchik, 2010; 2011; Eisenstadt, 2004; Tarrow, 2011). As Joshua Tucker puts it, in a

    manipulated election for once, the entire country is experiencing the same act of abuse

    simultaneously (Tucker, 2007: 541).

    Thus when electoral rights are formally granted but periodically abused during the

    election contest, the circumstances are ideal for the staging of a mass protest. Moreover, this

    combination of circumstances has become more common since the rapid spread of multiparty

    elections during the third wave of democratization that kicked off in the mid-1970s and gained

    steam in the 1980s. An indicator of post-electoral protest in Susan Hyde and Nikolai Marinovs

    National Elections Across Democracies and Autocracies (NELDA) dataset allows us to chart the

    rise in electoral protests over time.2 As Figure 1 show, the 1980s is precisely the period during

    2 This is Variable 29 of the National Elections Across Democracies and Autocracies dataset (v3),

    http://hyde.research.yale.edu/gfnelda/.

  • 9

    which post-electoral protests began to increase, and they have become more common as

    competitive authoritarianism or electoral authoritarianism has reached more countries.

    - Figure 1 about here -

    It is worth noting, however, that although most elections are beset with problems of some

    kind, only a minority are followed by mass protests. A total of 417 protests in 2,974 of the

    elections in the NELDA dataset were followed by protests (14.0 percent), so mass

    demonstrations following elections are still by no means the norm. The question that arises from

    this observation is: what are the circumstances under which post-electoral protests likely to

    occur? This question has received limited attention from comparative political scientists. The

    spate of studies that followed in the wake of the colored revolutions in Central and Eastern

    Europe document how in case after case, worsening electoral irregularities led groups of citizens

    to take to the streets in protest (Beachain and Polese, 2010; Beissinger, 2007; Bunce and

    Wolchik, 2009; 2010; 2011; Kalandadze and Orenstein, 2009; White, 2010; Tucker, 2007).

    These protests were less than successful in countries such as Azerbaijan and Belarus, but in

    Serbia, Georgia and Ukraine, anti-fraud movements led to wholesale changes of power that

    improved the quality of electoral conduct (at least temporarily). This literature has identified a

    number of factors associated with the success of the colored revolutions, including incumbent

    turnover at the time of the election, well-organized and resourceful opposition coalitions and

    international assistance to grassroots organizations. But analyses of the determinants of post-

    electoral protest have yet to be extended by many scholars to the large-N setting. An important

    exception includes the work of Pippa Norris, who finds using survey data that lack of confidence

  • 10

    in electoral integrity encourages political activism at the individual level (Norris, 2012; 2014).3

    The question that concerns us here is how individual-level willingness to engage in activism

    leads to large-scale protests, which require groups of citizens to coordinate and organize in order

    to overcome the well-known collective action problems that beset attempts at popular

    mobilization (Olson, 1965).

    It thus makes sense to delve deeper into the literature on contentious politics in order to

    specify further the circumstances under which post-electoral protests will occur. Ted Robert Gurr

    recognized long ago that when repression is in steady state, people do not tend to rebel; it is

    when circumstances change that protest occurs, as peoples expectations and sense of what they

    are entitled to then deviate from their perception of what they will in fact experience

    (capabilities in Gurrs terminology), leading to relative deprivation which fuels frustration and

    the propensity toward aggression (Gurr, 1968; 1970). Gurr does not cite Kahneman and

    Tverskys (contemporary) work on loss aversion, yet he does point to the same psychological

    phenomenon as being at the root of politically rebellious action: Men [sic] are likely to be more

    intensely aggrieved when they lose what they have than when they lose hope of attaining what

    they do not yet have (Gurr, 1970: 50).

    Though it has been hugely influential, Gurrs work has also been criticized on theoretical,

    methodological and empirical grounds. It is the theoretical framework subtending his grievance-

    based approach that is of relevance here. The most damning criticism of Gurrs approach is one

    3 A formal model proposed by Milan Svolik and Svitlana Chernyk (Slovic and Chernyk, 2012)

    suggests that the occurrence of protests will be conditioned by a range of political and

    institutional factors, but these scholars do not provide empirical evidence to test their claims.

  • 11

    that applies to any explanation whose locus is primarily the individual: protests and other forms

    of contentious practice of not simply occur because large numbers of people have a propensity to

    engage in such activity; they are organized events which take place as the result of complex

    interactions between regime elites, opposition elites and ordinary citizens who are mobilized to

    take part. Only in this way is it possible to overcome collective action problems.

    Subsequent writing on contentious politics has sought to deal with this issue, while at the

    same time building on Gurrs insights. This extensive body of research identifies two broad sets

    of factors that enable collective action involving popular mobilization. The first category of

    factors is resources, which include structural aspects of a state such as overall level of socio-

    economic development and urbanization, as well as access to and developments in

    communications technology, which is key to disseminating ideas, building value-based

    communities and mobilizing potential supporters (e.g. Dalton, van Sickle and Weldon, 2010;

    McCarthy and Zald, 1977; Olson, 1965).

    The second suite of factors that is associated with successful contentious politics includes

    aspects of the social and institutional framework that facilitate and constrain collective action.

    The political opportunity structures stream in the literature on protest emphasizes the role of

    state institutions in structuring and channeling opportunities for people with grievances to come

    together to press leaders to address their concerns, as well as social and institutional obstacles to

    collective action (e.g. Kitschelt, 1986; McAdam, Tarrow and Tilly, 2001; Tarrow, 2011).

    Though our understanding of protest and contentious politics has improved immeasurably

    since Gurrs seminal book, more recent scholars have by and large retained his central insight

    that citizens rebel following a change in the relationship between what they expect and what they

    experience. Writing from a political opportunities structure perspective, Sidney Tarrow also

  • 12

    argues that popular mobilization tends to result from a change that alters the structure of

    opportunities and constraints facing actors. Summarizing a large body of work on the topic, he

    maintains that People engage in contentious politics when patterns of political opportunities and

    constraints change [] Contentious politics is produced when threats are experienced and

    opportunities are present (Tarrow, 2011; chap 1).

    The argument proposed here is that in the context of manipulated elections, the relevant

    change which generates both a threat and an opportunity is a deterioration in the quality of

    elections, which provides the necessary coordinating device that steady-state electoral

    manipulation often fails to deliver. This insight yields the hypothesis that electoral protest is

    most likely to take place where there has been a recent increase in electoral malpractice.

    At first glance this claim might seem counterintuitive. Electoral institutions are typically

    relatively technical and remote from most peoples immediate concerns. In order to explain the

    formation of coalitions for electoral reform, we thus need to explain not only how groups

    manage successfully to form, but why the select electoral irregularities as their major demand (or

    one of their major demands) rather than other grievances.

    One aspect of the answer offered here is that electoral malpractice provides an incentive

    for oppositions to come together around a common demand and to select electoral reforms as one

    of their main aims. When electoral authoritarian regimes are already weakened as they often

    are when they undertake enhanced electoral malpractice they are particularly vulnerable to

    threats such as those posed by popular uprisings (Bunce and Wolchik, 2009; McFaul, 2005).

    Moreover, mass mobilization behind protest movements can further weaken regimes internally,

    as they may exacerbate divisions and encourage defections (Schedler, 2013: 354-5). This creates

    opportunities for mobilization.

  • 13

    The demand for fair electoral institutions is a demand that transcends ideological

    positions; in this sense, it is a demand around which diverse groups can work together without

    selling out or compromising their ideological principles. As several scholars have pointed out,

    elections are frequently critical political junctures, electoral fraud can serve as a focal point,

    providing a co-ordination mechanism to opposition elites (Bunce and Wolchik, 2009; Thompson

    and Kuntz, 2006; 2009; Tucker, 2007). In Joshua Tuckers words When a regime commits

    electoral fraud, an individuals calculus regarding whether to participate in a protest against the

    regime can be changed significantly (Tucker, 2007: 353), and this helps to solve the collective

    action problem normally faced by those with grievances against an electoral authoritarian

    regime. Protest also serves to communicate information to both regime elites and members of

    the public that the regime is weak and therefore vulnerable to downfall, which can further fuel

    protests (Bunce and Wolchik, 2009; Howard and Roessler, 2006: 372; Schedler, 2013; Tucker,

    2007).

    These studies suggest that the presence of electoral abuse ought to trigger protest. Yet as

    the data presented above suggest, protests are rare, even in counties with poor-quality elections.

    High but stable levels of electoral malpractice can clearly persist for long periods without

    bringing about significant protest movements. The key to unravelling this puzzle is that although

    the above-cited accounts delineate how mobilizational opportunities are created by electoral

    malpractice, they do not adequately explain why these opportunities should be exploited

    following one manipulated election but not another. The answer proposed here is that in addition

    to the opportunity represented by electoral malpractice itself, a threat to electoral rights serves to

    galvanize groups into action by leading to a heightened sense of perceived political deprivation.

    In other words, when there is an increase in abuse, citizens are more likely to be available for

  • 14

    mobilization as they are more likely to perceive that they have lost their rights, and it is this

    concurrently-shared grievance which provides the coordinating device which enables citizens to

    overcome collective action challenges.4

    III Empirical Evidence

    The hypothesis set out above is tested on the protest indicator from the NELDA dataset together

    with a summary indicator of electoral malpractice from the Index of Electoral Malpractice (IEM)

    dataset (Birch, 2011), a dataset of 155 elections held in 61 states in four regions of the world

    between 1995 and 2007: Central Europe, the Former Soviet Union, Latin America and Sub-

    Saharan Africa.

    The measure employed for a decline in election quality is a dummy variable representing

    an increase of at least two points on the five-point IEM scale in the overall electoral quality

    variable (Q15) in this dataset. (Given that higher scores on this variable are associated with

    greater electoral malpractice, an increase represents a decline in electoral integrity.)

    In addition to changes in electoral integrity, the above discussion suggests that a number

    of other variables will be associated with the occurrence of post-electoral protests. Resource

    variables include: level of scoio-economic development (per capita GDP), level of urbanization

    4 Meirowitz and Tucker (2013) note, however, that having successfully turned an authoritarian

    leader out of office via protests, mass public may be less willing to undertake large-scale protests

    in the same context a second time, as their post-reform experience may, if negative, have altered

    their understanding of the entire population of politicians in their state.

  • 15

    and the number of telephones per 100,000 population.5 The opportunity variable designating

    institutional openness is the extent to which civil rights are guaranteed. Ethnic fractionalization is

    also included as a constraint (or negative opportunity), as it can be expected to divide groups

    that might otherwise mobilize around common concerns. Finally, an additional factor relevant to

    post-electoral protest is related to developments in the international arena which have

    undoubtedly contributed to the trend observed: the end of the Cold War led to an increase in

    pressure on states from the international community, which resulted in greater international

    attention to elections and increased the legitimacy cost of manipulating electoral procedures

    (Hyde, 2011; Kelly, 2012). Several measures of the international connectedness and dependence

    of a state were included, including trade dependence, fuel exports, and Official Development

    Assistance.6 It is expected that states which trade more and receive more aid should, all else

    being equal, be more susceptible to international pressure in the wake of large-scale protest

    against election fraud. This fact should provide an incentive for groups to mobilize protests, in

    5 In theory it would have been desirable to include also internet access and newspaper readership,

    but there was too much missing data on these variables for this to be viable. With regard to

    internet access, it should also be noted that until the widespread ownership of smartphones,

    internet usage was confined to a very small sector of the population of most of the countries

    studied here.

    6 The presence of international observers is another variable that is theoretically relevant in this

    context. Unfortunately it was not possible to test this hypothesis on the data used here, as the

    Index of Electoral Malpractice is based on the reports of international observers and thus

    includes no variance on this variable.

  • 16

    the hope of attracting international pressure that might cause their government to undertake

    reforms. The exception can be anticipated to be states that export large amounts of fuel, as global

    dependence on fossil fuel should dampen the willingness of democratic states to condemn

    elections in those from which they import oil, gas and other fuels.

    Data to construct control variables described here are taken from a variety of sources; see

    the Appendix for details of variable construction and data sources.

    Table 1 presents a logistic regression model of the probability of there being a protest

    following an election. As can be seen from this model, a decline in electoral integrity is

    associated with a higher probability of protest, even controlling for other factors.

    Table 1 about here

    In fact, few of the controls are significant, once the decline in election quality is included in the

    model. Ethnic fractionalization is, as expected, associated with a low probability of protest,

    whereas trade dependence increase the likelihood of protest, a relationship also predicted. The

    positive coefficient on the variable designating fuel exports is unexpected; the reasons for this

    are not entirely clear, but it seems that closer ties with the outside world make it more likely that

    protests will occur.

    As will be noted from the N figure at the base of Table 1, missing data has reduced the

    number of cases included in this model considerably. The next stage in the development of this

    paper is to construct a larger database of electoral integrity/malpractice, covering a wider range

    of states and a longer time period, in order to gain superior analytic leverage and to provide a

    more robust test of the hypotheses developed here.

    IV Discussion and Conclusion

  • 17

    A number of scholars have noted that protest activity has been the principal motor of electoral

    reform in many states (Beissinger, 2007; Bunce and Wolchick, 2009; 2010; 2011; Norris, 2012;

    Schedler, 2013; Thompson and Kuntz, 2004; 2006; Tucker, 2007). The way in which popular

    protests against electoral fraud play out has also been the subject of several macro-level analyses

    (Bunce and Wolchik, 2011; Case, 2006; Cox, 2009; Lehoucq, 1995; Magaloni, 2006; 2010;

    Schedler, 2002b; 2013; Thompson and Kuntz, 2006).

    Faced with large-scale protest movements, elites in weakened electoral authoritarian

    regimes have the choice of either engaging in proactive reforms in the hopes of retaining power

    democratically, or further intensifying fraud and repressive measures in the hopes of holding

    onto power through force and repression. Their decision is conditioned by a variety of factors

    including the strength and cohesiveness of the opposition (Howard and Roessler, 2006; 2009;

    Magaloni, 2010; Schedler, 2013), the strength of state and party institutions (Levitsky and Way,

    2010), and relations with democratic neighbours and influential international actors (Beaulieu

    and Hyde, 2009; Donno, 2013a; Hyde, 2011; Kelley, 2012; Levitsky and Way, 2010).

    Where formal institutions are weak and power is personalized, elections are more likely

    to be a high-stakes affairs in which losers run a considerable risk to personal security, loss of

    wealth and status and permanent exclusion from the political system. Under these conditions, it

    leaders frequently seek to retain their positions by repressing opposition elites and continuing to

    undertake electoral fraud and malpractice. In cases where large-scale electoral malpractice has

    been the norm for a considerable time and elites are not particularly weak, they are often able to

    repress calls for reform (as in Russia 2012 or Iran 2009). Under these circumstances they are

    often able to remain in power, despite widespread unrest. At this point they once again have the

    option of engaging in proactive reforms, as happened in Moldova in 2009 following the

  • 18

    Communists successful repression of an attempted electoral revolution (Pop-Eleches and

    Robertson, 2010), though they are generally unlikely to do so assuming the underlying strength

    of their institutions has not changed. If, on the other hand, key elite actors such as the military

    desert the elites, as happened in The Philippines in 1986, Serbia in 2000, Georgia 2003 or

    Ukraine 2004, then the elite will be forced to cede to popular demands and to undertake reforms.

    Following a mass protest, regime elites then have the choice of either engaging in

    proactive reforms in the hopes of retaining power democratically, or further intensifying fraud

    and repressive measures in the aim of maintaining power through force. Their decision, and the

    ultimate outcome of the regime-opposition confrontation, is conditioned by a variety of factors

    that have been examined elsewhere (Cox, 2009; Eisenstadt, 2004; Donno, 2013a; 2013b;

    Lehoucq, 1995; Levitsky and Way, 2010; Magaloni, 2006; 2010; Howard and Roessler, 2006;

    2009; Schedler, 2002b; 2013; Svolik and Chernyk, 2012; Thompson and Kuntz, 2006; 2009),

    including incumbent turnover, opposition cohesion and organisational capacity, and state

    institutional strength.

    I would not of course claim that that this process outlined here is the sole route to

    integrity-enhancing reforms, as other factors such as proximity to other democratizing or

    democratic regimes (linkage in Levitsky and Ways formulation) can also account for

    improvements in electoral quality even in the absence of protests sparked by fraud. Likewise,

    there are cases, such as Ghana, where elections exhibit gradual improvements over time without

    significant backsliding (Lindberg, 2009a: 14-15). However, the route outlined here appears to be

    becoming increasingly common. This means that elections often have to get worse before they

    get better.

  • 19

    The argument sketched in this paper cuts across the recent debates as to whether elections

    are functional or detrimental to electoral authoritarian regimes (Blaydes, 2011; Howard and

    Roessler, 2006; 2009; Lindberg, 2006; 2009a; 2009b; Lust-Okar, 2009; Pop-Eleches and

    Robertson, 2010; Schedler, 2013; Teorell and Hadenius, 2009). It could well be that elections

    and electoral manipulation in particular are for a time functional in propping up authoritarian

    regimes that would otherwise find it difficult to insulate themselves from the threats posed by

    rival elites and discontented publics, but that ultimately worsening electoral manipulation

    brought about by regime weakness sparks protest movements that undermine regime stability.

    One of the implications of this argument is that the intensification of fraud may often be a

    harbinger of impending improvement. If a deterioration in election quality is by no means a

    sufficient condition for a popular uprising to bring about democratic change, it appears to be a

    common condition. This finding is relevant for electoral assistance providers, in that it suggests

    that in contexts where electoral integrity worsens over a series of elections, the focus of electoral

    assistance may be most profitably targeted at the domestic proponents of electoral reform,

    including domestic observer groups and opposition actors.

    Further research could usefully examine in greater detail the dynamics of protest as well

    as conditions under which protests against electoral malpractice lead to lasting improvements in

    electoral quality. This is an area in which academic research can yield considerable insights that

    are of practical relevance, and it is a field in which much work remains to be done.

  • 20

    References

    Alesina, Alberto, Arnaud Devleeschauer, William Easterly, Sergio Kurlat and Romain Wacziarg

    (2003), Fractionalization, National Bureau of Economic Research: NBER Working

    Paper 9411, http://www.nber.org/papers/w9411.

    Beachain, Donnacha O. and Abel Polese (2010), Introduction, in Donnacha O. Beachain and

    Abel Polese (eds.), The Colour Revolutions in the Former Soviet Republics, New York

    and London: Routledge, pp. 1-12.

    Beaulieu, Emily and Susan D. Hyde (2009), In the Shadow of Democracy Promotion: Strategic

    Manipulation, International Observers and Election Boycotts, Comparative Political

    Studies 42:3, pp. 392-415.

    Beissinger, Mark R. (2007), Structure and Example in Modular Political Phenomena: The

    Diffusion of Bulldozer/Rose/Orange/Tulip Revolutions, Perspectives on Politics 5:2, pp.

    259-76.

    Birch, Sarah (2011), Electoral Malpractice, Oxford: Oxford University Press.

    Bjornlund, Eric C. (2004), Beyond Free and Fair: Monitoring Elections and Building

    Democracy, Baltimore and London: John Hopkins University Press.

    Blaydes, Lisa (2011), Elections and Distributive Politics in Mubaraks Egypt, Cambridge:

    Cambridge University Press.

    Brownlee, Jason (2009), Portents of Pluralism: How Hybrid Regimes Affect Democratic

    Transitions, American Journal of Political Science 53:3, pp. 515-32.

    Bunce, Valerie J. and Wolchik, Sharon L. (2009), Oppositions versus Dictators: Explaining

    Divergent Electoral Outcomes in Post-Communist Europe and Eurasia, in Staffan I.

    Lindberg (ed.), Democratization by Elections: A New Mode of Transition?, Baltimore:

    Johns Hopkins University Press, pp. 246-68.

  • 21

    --- (2010) Defeating Dictators: Electoral Change and Stability in Competitive Authoritarian

    Regimes, World Politics, 62:1, pp. 43-86.

    --- (2011) Defeating Authoritarian leaders in Post-Communist Countries, Cambridge:

    Cambridge University Press.

    Case, William (2006), Manipulative Skills: How Do Rulers Control the Electoral Arena, in

    Andreas Schedler (ed.), Electoral Authoritarianism: The Dynamics of Unfree

    Competition, London and Boulder, CO: Lynne Rienner, pp. 95-112.

    Cox, Gary (2009), Authoritarian Elections and Leadership Succession, 19752004, paper

    presented at the Annual Meeting of the American Political Science Association, Toronto.

    Dahl, Robert A. (1973), Polyarchy: Participation and Opposition, New Haven CT: Yale

    University Press.

    Dalton, Russell, Alix van Sickle and Steven Weldon (2010), The Individual and Institutional

    nexus of Political Behaviour, British Journal of Political Science 40:1, pp. 51-73.

    Diamond, Larry J. (2002), Thinking about Hybrid Regimes, Journal of Democracy 13(2), pp.

    21-35.

    Donno, Daniela (2013a), Elections and Democratization in Authoritarian Regimes, American

    Journal of Political Science 57:3, pp. 703-16.

    --- (2013b), Defending Democratic Norms: International Actors and the Politics of Electoral

    Misconduct, New York: Oxford University Press.

    Eisenstadt, Todd A. (2004), Catching the State off Guard: Electoral Courts, Campaign Finance,

    and Mexicos Separation of State and Ruling Party, Party Politics 10:6, pp. 723-45.

    Gandhi, Jennifer (2008), Political Institutions under Dictatorships, Cambridge: Cambridge

    University Press.

  • 22

    Gurr, Ted Robert (1968), A Causal Model of civil Strife; A Comparative Analysis Using New

    Indices, American Political Science Review 62.4, pp. 1104-24.

    --- (1970), Why Men Rebel, Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.

    Howard, Marc M. and Phillip G. Roessler (2006), Liberalizing Electoral Outcomes in

    Competitive Authoritarian Regimes, American Journal of Political Science 50:2.

    --- (2009), Post-Cold War Political Regimes: When Do Elections Matter?, in Staffan I.

    Lindberg (ed.), Democratization by Elections: A New Mode of Transition?, Baltimore:

    Johns Hopkins University Press, pp. 101-27.

    Huntington, Samuel P. (1991), The Third Wave: Democratization in the Late Twentieth Century,

    University of Oklahoma Press.

    Hyde, Susan (2011) The Pseudo-Democrats Dilemma: Why Election Observation Became an

    International Norm, Ithaca, NY: Cornell University Press.

    Kahneman, Daniel and Amos Tversky (2000), Prospect Theory: An Analysis of Decision under

    Risk, in Choices, Values and Frames, eds. Daniel Kahneman and Amos Tversky.

    Cambridge: Russell Sage Foundation and Cambridge University Press, 17-43.

    Kalandadze, Katya, and Mitchell A. Orenstein (2009), Electoral Protests and Democratization

    Beyond the Color Revolutions, Comparative Political Studies, 42:11, pp. 1403-1425.

    Katz, Richard (1997), Democracy and Elections, Oxford: Oxford University Press.

    Kelly, Judith G. (2012) Monitoring Democracy: When International Election Observation

    Works, and Why it Often Fails, Princeton and Oxford: Princeton University Press.

    Kitschelt, Herbert (1986), Political Opportunity Structures and Political Protest: Anti-Nuclear

    Movements in Four Democracies, British Journal of Political Science 16:1, pp. 57-83.

  • 23

    Kuntz, Philipp and Mark R. Thompson (2009), More than Just the Final Straw: Stolen Elections

    as Revolutionary Triggers, Comparative Politics 41:3, pp. 25372.

    Lehoucq, Fabrice Edouard (1995), Institutional Change and Political Conflict: Evaluating

    Alternative Explanations of Electoral Reform in Costa Rica, Electoral Studies 14:1, pp.

    23-45.

    Levitsky, Stevan and Lucan Way (2010), Competitive Authoritarianism: Hybrid Regimes after

    the Cold War, Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

    Lindberg, Staffan I. (2006), Democracy and Elections in Africa, Baltimore, MD: Johns Hopkins

    University Press.

    --- (2009a), Introduction. Democratization By Elections: A New Mode of Transition, in

    Staffan I. Lindberg (ed.), Democratization by Elections: A New Mode of Transition?,

    Baltimore: Johns Hopkins University Press, pp. 1-21.

    --- (2009b) A Theory of Elections as a Mode of Transition, in Staffan Lindberg (ed.)

    Democratization by Elections: A New Mode of Transition?, Baltimore: Johns Hopkins

    University Press, pp. 314-41.

    Lust-Okar, Ellen (2009), Competitive Clientelism in the Middle East, Journal of Democracy

    20:3, pp. 12235.

    McAdam, Douglas, Sidney Tarrow and Charles Tilly (2001), Dynamics of Contention,

    Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

    McAllister, Ian and Stephen White (2011), Public Perceptions of Electoral Fairness in Russia,

    EuropeAsia Studies 63:4, pp. 663683.

    McCarthy, John D. and Mayer N. Zald (1977), Resource Mobilization and Social Movements:

    A Partial Theory, American Journal of Sociology 82:6, pp. 1212-41.

  • 24

    McFaul, Michael (2005), Transitions from Postcommunism, Journal of Democracy 16:3, pp.

    5-19.

    Magaloni, Beatriz (2006), Voting for Autocracy: Hegemonic Party Survival and its Demise in

    Mexico, Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

    --- (2010), The Game of Electoral Fraud and the Ousting of Authoritarian Rule, American

    Journal of Political Science 54:3, pp. 751-65.

    Meirowitz, Adam and Joshua A. Tucker (2013), People Power or a One-Shot Deal? A Dynamic

    Model of Protest, American Journal of Political Science 57:2, pp. 478490.

    Norris, Pippa (2012), Why Malpractices Generate Pressures for Electoral Reform: An Agenda

    Setting Model, paper prepared for presentation at the Annual Meeting of the American

    Political Science Association, New Orleans, 30 August-2 September.

    --- (2014) Why Electoral Integrity Matters, Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

    Olson, Mancur Jr. (1965), The Logic of Collective Action: Public Goods and the Theory of

    Groups, Harvard, MA: Harvard University Press.

    Pop-Eleches, Grigore, and Graeme B. Robertson (2010), Elections, Information and Political

    Change in the Post-Cold War Era, unpublished paper.

    Posada-Carb, E. (ed.) (1996), Elections before Democracy: The History of Elections in Europe

    and Latin America, Basingstoke: Macmillan.

    Przeworski, Adam (2008), Conquered or Granted? A History of Suffrage Extensions, British

    Journal of Political Science 39, pp. 291-321.

    --- (2011), Democracy and the Limits of Self-Government, Cambridge: Cambridge University

    Press.

    Ross, Michael L. (2001), Does Oil Hinder Democracy?, World Politics 53:.3, pp. 32561.

  • 25

    Schedler, Andreas (2002a), Elections without Democracy: The Menu of Manipulation,

    Journal of Democracy 13:2.

    --- (2002b), The Nested Game of Democratization by Elections, International Political

    Science Review 23:1, pp. 103-22.

    --- (2013), The Politics of Uncertainty: Sustaining and Subverting Electoral Authoritarianism,

    Oxford: Oxford University Press.

    Staveley, E. S. (1972), Greek and Roman Voting and Elections, London: Thames and Hudson.

    Svolik, Milan W and Svitlana Chernyk (2012), Third-Party Actors and the Success of

    Democracy: How Electoral Commissions, Courts and Observers Shape Incentives for

    Election Manipulation and Post-Electoral Protest, unpublished manuscript.

    Tarrow, Sidney G. (2011), Power in Movement: Social Movements and Contentious Politics, 3rd

    ed., Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

    Teorell, Jan and Axel Hadenius (2009), Elections as Levers of Democratization: A Global

    Enquiry, in Staffan I. Lindberg (ed.), Democratization by Elections: A New Mode of

    Transition?, Baltimore: Johns Hopkins University Press, pp. 77-100.

    Thompson, Mark R., and Philipp Kuntz (2004), Stolen Elections: The Case of the Serbian

    October, Journal of Democracy 15:4, pp. 159-72.

    --- (2006), After Defeat? When Do Rulers Steal Elections?, in A. Schedler (ed.), Electoral

    Authoritarianism: The Dynamics of Unfree Competition, Boulder and London: Lynne

    Rienner, pp. 113-28.

    Tucker, Joshua A. (2007), Enough! Electoral Fraud, Collective Action Problems, and Post-

    Communist Colored Revolutions, Perspectives on Politics 5:3, pp. 535-51.

  • 26

    Van Ham, Carolien (2013), Why Do Elections Fail? Explaining Election Integrity in Third and

    Fourth Wave Regimes, paper presented at the general conference of the European

    Consortium for Political Research, Bordeaux, 4-7 September.

    White, Stephen (2010), Is There a Pattern?, in David Lane and Stephen White (eds.),

    Rethinking the Coloured Revolutions?, London and New York: Routledge, pp. 284-300.

  • 27

    Appendix: Data Sources and Variable Construction

    Civil Rights: Freedom House Political Rights and Civil Liberties scale; this is a seven-point scale

    that is inverted here such that a higher score represents greater civil rights. Source:

    www.freedomhouse. org.

    Corruption: Transparency International Corruption Perceptions Index. This index ranges from 0

    (most corrupt) to 10 (least corrupt). The data were inverted for use in the models such

    that a higher score is associated with greater corruption. Where data were missing, the

    nearest datapoint in time was used, as this is generally recognized to be a slow-changing

    variable. Source: www.transparency.org.

    Ethnic fractionalization: This measure of ethnic fractionalization varies from 0 to 1. Source:

    Alesina et al, 2003.

    Fuel exports as a proportion of merchandise exports. Following Ross (2001), fuel exports for

    Singapore and Trinidad are adjusted to take into consideration that these states are

    primarily transit states, not fuel producers. The fuel export values for these states are set

    at 0.01. Where data were missing, the nearest datapoint in time was used, as this is

    generally recognized to be a slow-changing variable. Source: World Bank Development

    Indicators at http://data.worldbank.org/indicator.

    International democracy assistance: Ofcial Development Assistance for the category of

    Government and civil society general. Figures are in millions of US dollars. Source:

    OECD Creditor Reporting System data at http://stats.oecd.org.

    Socio-economic development: UNDP Human Development Index. Source: United Nations

    Development Program, http://hdr.undp.org/en/content/human-development-index-hdi.

  • 28

    Trade dependence: The combined value of exports plus imports as a share of GDP. Where data

    were missing, the nearest datapoint in time was used, as this is generally recognized to be

    a slow-changing variable. Source: World Bank Development Indicators at

    http://data.worldbank.org/indicator.

    Telephones per capita: This indicator is taken from Bankss Cross-National Time Series Dataset:

    the measure used is phones6: all telephones including cellular per capita. Figures are per

    100,000 population. Where data were missing, figures were taken from the nearest year,

    provided that year was not more than two years before or after the year in question.

    Source: Cross-National Time Series Data Archive,

    http://www.databanksinternational.com/.

    Urbanization: Percent urban population. Source: World Bank Development Indicators at

    http://data.worldbank.org/indicator.

  • 29

    Table 1: Logistic Regression Model of Post-election Protest

    Variable Coefficient (standard error)

    Decline in election quality since previous

    election

    .2.641** (1.283)

    Resources:

    GDP per capita at ppp (logged) -.431 (934)

    Urbanization .048 (.039)

    Telephones per 100,000 .000 (.000)

    Opportunities and constraints:

    Freedom House Civil Liberties -.328 (.407)

    Ethnic fractionalization -4.701* (2.613)

    International dependence

    Trade dependence .030** (.014)

    Fuel exports (as a % of exports) .032* (.017)

    Official Development Assistance .003 (.008)

    Constant .274 (6.921)

    Nagelkerke R2 .358

    N 56

    Note: * = p < .10; ** = p < .05; *** = p < .01; **** = p < .001

  • 30

    Figure 1: Global trend in post-electoral protests 1945-2011

    Source: Calculated from Variable 29 of the National Elections Across Democracies and

    Autocracies dataset (v3), http://hyde.research.yale.edu/gfnelda/.