Risk/arbitrage strategies - International Actuarial Association

46
Risk/Arbitrage Strategies: A New Concept for Asset/Liability Management, Optimal Fund Design and Optimal Portfolio Selection in a Dynamic, Continuous-Time Framework Part V: A Guide to Efficient Numerical Implementations Hans-Fredo List Swiss Reinsurance Company Mythenquai 50/60, CH-8022 Zurich Telephone: +41 1 285 2351 Facsimile: +41 1 285 4179 Mark H.A. Davis Tokyo-Mitsubishi International plc 6 Broadgate, London EC2M 2AA Telephone: +44 171 577 2714 Facsimile: +44 171 577 2888 Abstract. Asset/Liability management, optimal fund design and optimal portfolio selection have been key issues of interest to the (re)insurance and investment banking communities, respectively, for some years - especially in the design of advanced risk- transfer solutions for clients in the Fortune 500 group of companies. The new concept of limited risk arbitrage investment management in a diffusion type securities and derivatives market introduced in our papers Risk/Arbitrage Strategies: A New Concept for Asset/Liability Management, Optimal Fund Design and Optimal Portfolio Selection in a Dynamic, Continuous-Time Framework Part I: Securities Markets and Part II: Securities and Derivatives Markets, AFIR 1997, Vol. II, p. 543, is immediately applicable to ALM, optimal fund design and portfolio selection problems in the investment banking and life insurance areas. The main quantities of practical interest (i.e., the optimal LRA asset allocation, etc.) can be derived by essentially solving a (quasi-) linear partial differential equation of the second order (e.g., by using a finite difference approximation with locally uniform convergence properties). Similarly, in our more sophisticated impluse control approach to modelling the RCLL risk portfolio dynamics of a large, internationally operating (re)insurer with considerable (“catastrophic”) non-life exposures, the optimal portfolio strategies can be determined numerically by using an efficient Markov chain approximation scheme, i.e., essentially the same (formal) finite difference techniques (with weak convergence properties), see Part III: A Risk/Arbitrage Pricing Theory and Part IV: An Impulse Control Approach to Limited Risk Arbitrage and also the paper Baseline for Exchange Rate - Risks of an International Reinsurer, AFIR 1996, Vol. I, p. 395. However, in many practical applications there are even simpler numerical solution techniques. We present here such an alternative lattice-based methodology that can be used as a general guide to simple and efficient numerical implementations of LRA investment 367

Transcript of Risk/arbitrage strategies - International Actuarial Association

Page 1: Risk/arbitrage strategies - International Actuarial Association

Risk/Arbitrage Strategies: A New Concept for Asset/Liability Management, Optimal Fund Design and Optimal Portfolio Selection

in a Dynamic, Continuous-Time Framework Part V: A Guide to Efficient Numerical Implementations

Hans-Fredo List Swiss Reinsurance Company

Mythenquai 50/60, CH-8022 Zurich Telephone: +41 1 285 2351 Facsimile: +41 1 285 4179

Mark H.A. Davis Tokyo-Mitsubishi International plc 6 Broadgate, London EC2M 2AA

Telephone: +44 171 577 2714 Facsimile: +44 171 577 2888

Abstract. Asset/Liability management, optimal fund design and optimal portfolio selection have been key issues of interest to the (re)insurance and investment banking communities, respectively, for some years - especially in the design of advanced risk- transfer solutions for clients in the Fortune 500 group of companies. The new concept of limited risk arbitrage investment management in a diffusion type securities and derivatives market introduced in our papers Risk/Arbitrage Strategies: A New Concept for Asset/Liability Management, Optimal Fund Design and Optimal Portfolio Selection in a Dynamic, Continuous-Time Framework Part I: Securities Markets and Part II: Securities and Derivatives Markets, AFIR 1997, Vol. II, p. 543, is immediately applicable to ALM, optimal fund design and portfolio selection problems in the investment banking and life insurance areas. The main quantities of practical interest (i.e., the optimal LRA asset allocation, etc.) can be derived by essentially solving a (quasi-) linear partial differential equation of the second order (e.g., by using a finite difference approximation with locally uniform convergence properties). Similarly, in our more sophisticated impluse control approach to modelling the RCLL risk portfolio dynamics of a large, internationally operating (re)insurer with considerable (“catastrophic”) non-life exposures, the optimal portfolio strategies can be determined numerically by using an efficient Markov chain approximation scheme, i.e., essentially the same (formal) finite difference techniques (with weak convergence properties), see Part III: A Risk/Arbitrage Pricing Theory and Part IV: An Impulse Control Approach to Limited Risk Arbitrage and also the paper Baseline for Exchange Rate - Risks of an International Reinsurer, AFIR 1996, Vol. I, p. 395. However, in many practical applications there are even simpler numerical solution techniques. We present here such an alternative lattice-based methodology that can be used as a general guide to simple and efficient numerical implementations of LRA investment

367

Richard Kwan
8th AFIR Colloquium, 1998: 367-412
Page 2: Risk/arbitrage strategies - International Actuarial Association

management together with a corresponding concrete example that plays an important role in the securitization of large non-life portfolio exposures in the capital markets.

Key Words and Phrases. Markovian weak approximation, implied trees, adaptive filtering, Milstein approximation, “Beta”, alternative risk transfer process, securitization structure.

Contents (all five parts of the publication series).

Part I: Securities Markets (separate paper) 1. Introduction 2. Securities Markets, Trading and Portfolio Management

- Complete Securities Markets - Bond Markets - Stock Markets - Trading Strategies - Arrow-Debreu Prices - Admissibility - Utility Functions - Liability Funding - Asset Allocation - General Investment Management - Incomplete Securities Markets - Securities Market Completions - Maximum Principle - Convex Duality - Markovian Characterization

3. Contingent Claims and Hedging Strategies - Hedging Strategies - Mean Self-Financing Replication - Partial Replication - American Options - Market Completion With Options

Appendix: References

Part II: Securities and Derivatives Markets (separate paper) 4. Derivatives Risk Exposure Assessment and Control

- Market Completion With Options - Limited Risk Arbitrage - Complete Securities Markets - Options Portfolio Characteristics - Hedging With Options

5. Risk/Arbitrage Strategies - Limited Risk Arbitrage Investment Management - Strategy Space Transformation

368

Page 3: Risk/arbitrage strategies - International Actuarial Association

- Market Parametrization - Unconstrained Solutions - Maximum Principle - Convex Duality - Markovian Characterization - Risk/Arbitrage Strategies - Dynamic Programming - Drawdown Control - Partial Observation

Appendix: References

Part III: A Risk/Arbitrage Pricing Theory (separate paper) 1. Introduction 2. Arbitrage Pricing Theory (APT)

- Dynamically Complete Market - Incomplete Market

3. Risk/Arbitrage Pricing Theory (R/APT) - General Contingent Claims - Optimal Financial Instruments - LRA Market Indices - Utility-Based Hedging - Contingent Claim Replication - Partial Replication Strategies - Viscosity Solutions - Finite Difference Approximation

Appendix: References

Part IV: An Impulse Control Approach to Limited Risk Arbitrage (separate paper) 1. Introduction 2. Dynamic Programming

- Risk/Arbitrage Controls - Viscosity Solutions - Finite Difference Approximation

3. Impulse Control Approach - Jump Diffusion State Variables - Singular Controls - Markov Chain Approximation

Appendix: References

Part V: A Guide to Efficient Numerical Implementations

1. Introduction

2. Markovian Weak Approximation

3. Implied Trees

4. Diffusion Parameter Estimation

5. Securitization

Appendix: References

4 12

17

21

26

42

369

Page 4: Risk/arbitrage strategies - International Actuarial Association

1. Introduction

Risk/Arbitrage strategies [see Part I: Securities Markets and Part II: Securities and Derivatives Markets] are trading or portfolio management strategies in the securities and derivatives markets that guarantee (with probability one) a limited risk exposure over the entire investment horizon and at the same time achieve a maximum (with guaranteed floor) rate of portfolio value appreciation over each individual trading period. They ensure an efficient allocation of investment risk in these integrated financial markets and are the solutions of the general investment management and asset allocation problem

(1.1)

with drawdown control

(1.2)

limited risk arbitrage objectives

(instantaneous investment risk) (1.3a)

(future portfolio risk dynamics) (1.3b)

(portfolio time decay dynamics) (1.3c)

(portfolio value appreciation dynamics) (1.3d)

[θ (t) = Ix (t)v(t)] and additional inequality and equality constraints (1.4a)

(1.4b) (e.g., market frictions, etc.) in a securities and derivatives market

(1.5)

with associated [expressed in terms of an underlying Markov risk exposure assessment and control model (t,S(t))] instantaneous investment risk, future derivatives risk dynamics, options time decay dynamics and asset value appreciation dynamics

(1.6)

[where the gamma

(N x N-matrix), etc. of traded asset Xi(t,S(t)) in the market, 1≤ i ≤ L, and the market

370

is the delta (N-vector),

Page 5: Risk/arbitrage strategies - International Actuarial Association

prices of risk associated with the exogenous sources W(t) of market uncertainty are

with the asset price covariance matrix

If this financial economy is dynamically complete, then (in a Markovian framework) the value function

(1.7)

of the limited risk arbitrage investment management and asset allocation portfolio satisfies the linear partial differential equation

(1.8)

with boundary conditions V(0,X,Z) = v and V(H,X,Z) = Iv(Z) where

(1.9)

[and and

holds]. The optimal trading strategy is

(1.10)

In the incomplete case we have the quasi-linear partial differential equation

(1.11)

for the portfolio value function

(1.12)

with boundary conditions V(0,X,Y,Z) = v and V(H,X,Y,Z) = Iv(Z) where

[and and

holds and moreover

(1.13)

371

Page 6: Risk/arbitrage strategies - International Actuarial Association

(1.14)

for the completion premium associated with the

market prices of risk The optimal asset allocation is

(1.15)

During the construction process that led to these optimal solutions of the above stochastic control problem for strictly limited risk investments in (highly geared) derivative financial products several assumptions about an investor’s utility functions

Uc(t,c) and Uv(V) had to be made, especially

(1.16)

for the associated coefficients of relative risk aversion. In a general dynamic programming framework [see Part III: A Risk/Arbitrage Pricing Theory and Part IV: An Impulse Control Approach to Limited Risk Arbitrage] all these restrictions (beyond the standard differentiability and boundedness assumptions) on the investor’s overall risk management objectives can be removed and furthermore efficient alternative numerical solution methods obtained: We consider a discrete-time Markov chain approximation xh(t) (derived with the explicit finite difference method in a viscosity solution setting) of the controlled continuous-time state dynamics

(1.17)

[where are the controls and the coefficients

and satisfy the usual conditions that guarantee a unique strong solution of the associated evolution equation with bounded absolute moments] with one step transition probabilities

(1.18a)

372

and

Page 7: Risk/arbitrage strategies - International Actuarial Association

(1.18b)

(1.18c)

[where is the diffusion process covariance matrix,

e0,..,eL is the standard basis in RL+1 and for all other grid points y on

the associated lattice structure . The discrete-time HJB dynamic programming equation is then

(1.19)

with boundary condition Vh(H, x) = ψ (x) [where

(1.20)

are the investor’s overall risk management objectives and is the set of all feasible controls u(s) on the time interval [t,H] when the time t state is x] and an associated

optimal Markov control policy ?h(t,x) maximizes the expression

(1.21)

in [backwards in time from H-h to 0]. Furthermore, we have the uniform convergence

[where

(1.23)

is the corresponding continuous-time expected utility maximization criterion] of the discrete-time Markov chain control problem to the continuous-time diffusion process control problem. If we now however instead of requiring the securities and derivatives investment management strategies θ (t) to be of the risk/arbitrage (without drawdown control) type, i.e.,

(1.24)

for an arbitrarily given trading strategy θ (t) consider the stochastic evolution of the corresponding portfolio value and sensitivities

(1.25)

373

Page 8: Risk/arbitrage strategies - International Actuarial Association

over the investment horizon [0,H], then the limited risk arbitrage objectives can periodically be enforced at a certain cost by using impulsive controls that keep the portfolio value and sensitivities within a specified tolerance band

(1.26) [see Part IV: An Impulse control Approach to Limited Risk Arbitrage]: With a discrete-time Markov chain approximation

(1.27)

[that is locally consistent with the controlled continuous-time reflected jump diffusion state dynamics

(1.28)

where X(t) is the price process of the traded assets - bonds, stocks and options -

spanning the securities and derivatives market] an approximation Vh(t, x) of the value

function

(1.29)

[where the continuous reflection part of the bounded and continuous total risk exposure

control costs (L,M,N) satisfies on ?G and the infimum is taken over all admissible (relaxed/singular) control systems] of such a singular (or impulse) control approach

(1.30a)

(1.30b)

(1.30c)

[which is based on a Lipschitz continuous solution mapping in the Skorokhod problem for (G,R) and under standard conditions on the diffusion coefficients and the usual

374

(1.30d)

Page 9: Risk/arbitrage strategies - International Actuarial Association

compact control space has a unique strong solution

x ε G ] to limited risk arbitrage investment management satisfies the discrete-time HJB dynamic programming equation

(1.31)

By solving this equation backwards in time from to 0 we can

determine an optimal Markov control policy [which we denote by (du) in relaxed control notation], the corresponding (optimal) intertemporal singular control

impulses and the necessary reflection impulses at the boundary

∂ Gh (where is a corresponding discretization of the given risk/arbitrage tolerance

band i.e., an optimal discrete-time impulsive risk exposure control strategy

and the associated state evolution A weak

convergence argument [with an embedded time scale adjustment to ensure tightness of the singular control and boundary reflection parts of the approximating discrete-time state dynamics xh(t)] then also establishes an optimal solution of the initially given continuous-time impulsive limited risk arbitrage investment management problem, i.e.,

a continuous-time optimal impulsive risk exposure control strategy and the

associated state evolution . The above outlined HJB dynamic programming framework (based on the Markov chain approximation technique) also turns out to be a very convenient setting for a full extension of the concept of limited risk arbitrage investment management to a financial market with discontinuous securities and derivatives price processes. Such a generalization and extension then implements an optimal combination of continuous risk/arbitrage control (i.e., expected utility maximization under given risk exposure constraints) and impulsive risk exposure control (i.e., minimization of the exposure control costs associated with a given risky trading or portfolio management strategy). Consider for example the general asset/liability management problem of a large, internationally operating (re)insurance company with significant ("catastrophic”) non-life exposures (see the paper Baseline for Exchange Rate - Risks of an International Reinsurer, AFIR 1996,

Vol. I, p. 395): Which portfolio strategies are suitable candidates for effectively

375

for every

Page 10: Risk/arbitrage strategies - International Actuarial Association

managing a multi-currency portfolio of assets (e.g., cash, bonds, stocks, futures and options) and liabilities (e.g., life and non-life (re-)insurance contracts) over some extended period [0,H] of time? We call H the associated ALM horizon. For 1 ≤ i ≤ m, let E i (t) denote the exchange rate at time t of foreign currency i (i = 0 is

the index of the domestic or accounting currency). Furthermore, for and

respectively, let A i j (t) denote the market value at time t of asset j

available in currency i and, similarly, let L i j (t) denote the cost at time t associated

with liability j in currency i . If now

and (1.32)

are the currency i asset and liability portfolio positions at time t , respectively, and

and (1.33)

the corresponding total foreign currency asset and liability positions, then the value at time t , denominated in the domestic currency, of the entire multi-currency asset/liability portfolio is

(1.34)

[where the initial value is is the total

asset/liability portfolio at time t and

and (1.35)

holds for the components of the two vectors 0 l of assets

and of liabilities, respectively]. At this stage of the ALM modeling process, we introduce a general Markov jump diffusion state variable

(1.36)

in which the component represents the multi-currency

asset/liability market [and Applying the impulse control techniques outlined above, we now consider the controlled state variable

(1.37)

which would at least have the following additional components: (t) (instantaneous investment risk) (1.38a)

(t) (future portfolio risk dynamics) 1.38b)

(t) (portfolio time decay dynamics) (1.38c)

(t) (portfolio value appreciation dynamics) (1.38d) (on the liability side exposure constraints in the form of jump size restrictions or solvency capital restrictions are possible). Denoting the controls with u(t) = (v(t),...)

and with the region in state space (ALM tolerance band)

376

Page 11: Risk/arbitrage strategies - International Actuarial Association

defined by corresponding inequality constraints we want to

make sure that with optimal stochastic control holds, 0 ≤ t ≤ H : Started at an admissible point x ∈ G the state variable x(t) evolves in time until it comes close to the boundary ∂ G of the ALM tolerance band. At each boundary point y ∈∂ G, a set R(y) of admissible reflection directions is assumed to be given [e.g., the interior normals n(y) ⊥ ∂ G on the hyperplanes at all points y ∈ ∂ G where they exist] and the state evolution is then reflected back into G in one of these admissible directions. We also allow (relaxed) intertemporal control of the state variable while it meets the ALM constraints, i.e., resides in G, and therefore consider the general singular (reflected jump diffusion) control model

(1.39)

which is based on a Lipschitz continuous solution mapping in the Skorokhod problem for (G,R) and under our above assumptions [and the usual compact control space

has a unique strong solution for every x ∈ G. Note that any (conventional) progressively measurable control process has

a relaxed control representation (du) [by an adapted random measure on the Borel sets B(U) ] such that

(1.40)

holds. The control-theoretical value function associated with general impulsive asset/liability management is then

377

Page 12: Risk/arbitrage strategies - International Actuarial Association

(1.41)

where (V(H)) is the utility of final wealth [the utility (t,c(t)) of intertemporal fund consumption would be included in the term L(t, x(t), u(t)) ] and the continuous reflection part of the bounded and continuous total risk exposure control costs (L,M,N) satisfies on ∂ G. The infimum is taken over all admissible (relaxed/singular) control systems and the corresponding (formal) HJB dynamic programming equation is of the form

(1.42)

where the parabolic integro-differential operator (in relaxed control notation) is defined with the controlled jump diffusion parameters, i.e. ,

(1.43)

Efficient numerical solutions can now be determined with the above outlined Markov chain approximation approach. The discrete-time state dynamics are

378

Page 13: Risk/arbitrage strategies - International Actuarial Association

(1.44)

2. Markovian Weak Approximation

Alternatively to the very powerful numerical techniques considered so far, in the complete financial markets case [characterized by (1.7) to (1.10) above] which is applicable in most practical ALM problems (from a pragmatic point of view), the following simple (lattice-based) discrete-time securities market approximation can be used (Harrison and Kreps [1], Harrison and Pliska [2, 3], Taqqu and Willinger [4], Duffie [5], Willinger and Taqqu [6], Eberlein [7], He [8], Dalang, Morton and Willinger [9], He [10], Willinger and Taqqu [11], Cutland, Kopp and Willinger [12], Duffie and Protter [13], Eberlein [14], Cutland, Kopp and Willinger [15, 16] and Schachermayer [17]): (1) With a time discretization

(2.1)

a weak (order 1.0) Euler approximation of the continuous-time securities and derivatives market dynamics

(2.2a)

[LRA investment management, see Part I: Securities Markets and

Part II: Securities and Derivatives Markets] and

(2.2b)

[LRA contingent claim analysis, see Part III: A Risk/Arbitrage Pricing Theory] is

(2.3a)

and

379

Page 14: Risk/arbitrage strategies - International Actuarial Association

(2.3b)

where

is a sequence of N -dimensional i.i.d. random vectors on the filtered probability space

(2.5)

with

(2.6)

[general N -variate and N + 1 -nomial lattice evolving on the time grid

If and are corresponding piecewise constant interpolations (RCLL processes), then we have weak convergence

(2.7)

under the usual differentiability and boundedness assumptions on the model parameters (note that numerically more accurate and efficient discretization schemes can be obtained by using higher order Ito-Taylor expansions, see also Boyle [18], Omberg [19], Nelson and Ramaswamy [20], Breen [21], Trigeorgis [22], Amin [23] and Sandmann [24]). (2) Similarly, with a piecewise constant interpolation β n (t) of the Euler approximation

(2.8)

we have weak convergence

(2.9)

Furthermore,

(2.10) defines a unique equivalent martingale measure for the securities and derivatives

market discretization on (3) Introducing conditional one

period Arrow-Debreu state prices on the lattice structure by the equation system

380

and

(2.4)

Page 15: Risk/arbitrage strategies - International Actuarial Association

(2.11)

then immediately leads to the explicit representation

(2.12)

(4) With the above general securities and derivatives market discretization (and the corresponding mode of convergence to the continuous-time limit) in place we first turn our attention to the LRA bond, stock and options portfolio management problem: The discrete-time (LRA) investment management and asset allocation problem

(2.13)

can be solved with standard Lagrangian methods. Defining the associated Lagrange multiplier as the solution of the non-linear equation

(2.14)

and the corresponding optimal fund withdrawal rate and final wealth by

we obtain [in a Markovian framework - with the investor’s marginal utility of wealth ς as additional state variable] the recursive equation for the portfolio value

function

(2.16)

with boundary conditions and The optimal discrete-time (LRA) asset allocation [in ν (t) - strategy space] can then be determined by solving the linear equation system

(2.17)

381

(2.15)

Page 16: Risk/arbitrage strategies - International Actuarial Association

[in which is the amount of cash held at time and

the corresponding amount of bonds, stocks and options]. (5) Let

and be piecewise constant RCLL interpolations of and

) and similarly and be piecewise constant LCRL

interpolations of and furthermore be the Lagrange multiplier associated with the continuous-time LRA investment management and asset allocation problem

(2.18)

and denote weak convergence of (xn) to x [where or denotes the corresponding usual mode of convergence]. Under appropriate

differentiability, growth and Lipschitz conditions on the model coefficients (2.19)

and the investor’s utility functions

(2.20) (see He [8, 10]) we then have the convergence results

(2.21a)

(2.21b)

2.21c

(2.21d)

which confirm that indeed the securities and derivatives market discretization

is a structure preserving approximation of the continuous-time financial

economy relevant in an LRA investment management

context. (6) Recalling that (in a Markovian framework)

(2.22)

382

Let

Page 17: Risk/arbitrage strategies - International Actuarial Association

is the value function of the given R/A-attainable contingent claim we consider the recursive equation

(2.23)

with boundary condition The corresponding discrete-time (LRA) replication strategy [in ν (t) - strategy space] can then be determined by solving the linear equation system

(2.24)

[in which is again the amount of cash held at time and

the corresponding amount of bonds, stocks and options]. (7) Let as

above be a piecewise constant RCLL interpolation of and

similarly and be piecewise constant LCRL interpolations of and Under appropriate differentiability, growth and Lipschitz conditions on the model coefficients

and the boundary condition

(2.25)

(see He [8]) we then have the convergence results (2.26)

(2.27a)

(2.27b)

which demonstrate that the securities and derivatives market discretization

is again a suitable approximation of the continuous-time financial

economy relevant in an LRA contingent claim analysis

context.

3. Implied Trees

As a concrete (very simple) example of the above general lattice-based techniques, we mention the standard binomial option pricing model

383

Page 18: Risk/arbitrage strategies - International Actuarial Association

(3.1)

(Black & Scholes lattice model for stock, stock indices and foreign currencies) where

(3.2)

This simple but important model can immediately be extended to have the following properties (Dupire [25,26], Derman and Kani [27], Heynen [28] and Rubinstein [29]): (1) The market variable follows a general diffusion process

(3.3)

which evolves in discrete-time on a recombining binomial lattice structure with parameters

3.4a such that

(3.4b)

(risk-averse state evolution) and parameters

(3.5a) such that

384

Page 19: Risk/arbitrage strategies - International Actuarial Association

(3.5b)

[risk-neutral state evolution, see Part I: Securities Markets]. (2) Denoting with n(t,x) the number of paths ending in node (t,x) and with (t,x) and (t,x) the associated risk-averse and risk-neutral time/state probabilities we have

(risk-averse state evolution) and

(risk-neutral state evolution). Note that

holds and therefore the one step transition probabilities (risk-averse state evolution)

(risk-neutral state evolution) and the time/state probabilities

(risk-averse state evolution)

(3.7)

(3.8)

(risk-neutral state evolution) (3.9)

can be determined from a corresponding terminal probability distribution (risk - averse state evolution)

(risk - neutral state evolution) (3.10)

by solving equations (3.6a) and (3.6b) backwards in time from i = m- 1 to i = 0. Simultaneously solving equations (3.4b) and (3.5b) at each node also leads to the remaining lattice parameters

(risk - averse state evolution)

(risk- neutral state evolution). (3.11)

Specifically, we have

(3.6a)

(3.6b)

385

Page 20: Risk/arbitrage strategies - International Actuarial Association

(3.12a)

(3.12b)

(3.14)

(risk-averse state evolution) and

(risk-neutral state evolution). (3) If U(R) = log(R) is the representative utility of the return R of a risky investment in equilibrium, then the myopic optimization program

(3.13)

allows us [KKT first order conditions, see Part II: Securities and Derivatives Markets] to relate risk-neutral and risk-averse one step transition probabilities, i:e., we have

(4) The risk-neutral pricing formula¹ is in this context

(3.15)

[see Part III: A Risk/Arbitrage Pricing Theory; note that for standard American options

(3.16)

is the corresponding intrinsic value] and the contingent claim sensitivities (derivatives risk parameters) are

(3.17a)

¹ X (intertemporal cashflows) and F (terminal condition) characterize the contingent claim. L ≤ v ≤ U are boundary conditions for its price process.

386

Page 21: Risk/arbitrage strategies - International Actuarial Association

(3.17b)

(3.17c)

(3.24)

(conditionally expected rates of change) and

(3.18)

(finite difference method) where

in general]. (5) A risk-neutral terminal probability distribution can be determined by solving the quadratic program

(3.19) holds. Theta can be defined via the relationship

(3.20)

and the approximation

(3.21)

(3.22)

where

(3.23) is a simple (standard) approximation of the market variable dynamics

and and are the bid and ask prices at time t of European call options with T exercise values X

k . The market variable itself is also assumed to be

the price of a traded asset (with x b and x a the bid and ask prices, respectively, at time t).

387

maturity and

Page 22: Risk/arbitrage strategies - International Actuarial Association

4. Diffusion Parameter Estimation

Given general (diffusion type) securities market dynamics (4.1)

simple estimates of the associated drift and diffusion coefficients (4.2)

can be obtained by (strong, order 1.0) numerical approximation with the Milstein scheme (Andrews [30], Rogers and Satchell [31], Hansen [32], Aggoun and Elliott [33], Chesney, Elliott, Madan and Yang [34] and Elliott and Rishel [35]). We first consider the problem of estimating the diffusion coefficient σ (t,x(t)) of the market

variable x(t). (1) Writing y(t) = e x(t) and applying Ito's formula we have

(4.3)

and furthermore

(4.4)

for any function f(y) of class C². (2) With Milstein's approximation formula we then obtain

(4.5a)

(4.5b)

and therefore

(4.6)

from which it can be seen that

(4.7)

is an unbiased estimate of σ (t)². (3) With f(y) = y 1+α this reduces to

388

and

Page 23: Risk/arbitrage strategies - International Actuarial Association

(4.8)

and we have the corresponding conditional moments

(4.9a)

(4.9b)

from which the optimal (variance minimization) exponent

(4.10)

can be determined. (4) In two dimensions we obtain similarly

(4.11)

[where for the variances and with the variables

(4.12)

(and corresponding exponents and also

(4.13)

for the associated covariances. The drift coefficient µ (t,x(t)) of the market variable

(4.14) can now be estimated by using an adaptive filtering technique and the above Milstein approximation scheme. (1) The dynamics of the observation process

389

and

Page 24: Risk/arbitrage strategies - International Actuarial Association

(4.15) are given by

(4.16)

where is a constant vector and X(t) is a Markov chain on the set

of orthonormal basis vectors in R N with

(4.17)

(4.18)

with the associated innovations process

[A is a constant N × N -matrix] and the semimartingale representation

[M(t) is a square-integrable {F t } -martingale]. (2) A filtered coefficient is then

(4.19)

estimate of the drift

(4.20)

[which is a {Y t } - Brownian motion]. (3) With the Girsanov transformation

(4.21)

[K(t) is an {Ft} -martingale] of probability measure and the {Ft} -martingale

(4.22)

[ K(t) Λ (t) = 1 ] the Zakai form of a corresponding smooth estimate is

(4.23)

[note also that

390

Page 25: Risk/arbitrage strategies - International Actuarial Association

(4.24)

holds by the Bayes formula]. (4) Denoting with the number of jumps of the

Markov chain X(s) from state e i

to state e j in the time interval [0, t] and with the

time spent by X(s) in state e i during the time period [0, t] and setting

(4.27c)

(4.25)

adaptive (improving) estimates of the model coefficients are

(4.26)

where

(4.27a)

(4.27b)

(5) Writing

(4.28) a corresponding Milstein approximation is then

(4.29a)

(4.29b)

(4.29c)

391

and

and

Page 26: Risk/arbitrage strategies - International Actuarial Association

(4.29d)

and the adaptive updates for the model parameters based on observations in the time period [0, t] consequently

(4.30)

392

and

Page 27: Risk/arbitrage strategies - International Actuarial Association

5. Securitization

In the final part of our paper we should like to briefly indicate a potentially interesting area of application for limited risk arbitrage techniques: the securitization of “catastrophic” non-life (re)insurance exposures in the capital markets. One important reason why LRA techniques are very well suited for this kind of application lies in the fact that they achieve an overall allocation of the asset/liability risks involved that meets set targets at a reasonable price whereas the otherwise commonly applied hedging techniques (for the finance part of a securitization program) often unnecessarily avoid financial risks at an unacceptably high price while the (potentially dominating) risk exposure on the liability side remains high. Starting point of our considerations is Swiss Re’s recently launched “Beta” program for Oil & Petrochemicals industry high-excess property and casualty layers as an example for “catastrophic” non-life (re)insurance exposures:

“Beta” provides multi-year, high-excess, broad form property and comprehensive general liability coverage with meaningful total limits for Fortune 500 clients in the Oil & Petrochemicals industry (“Beta” is also available in other Fortune 500 segments, its program parameters are industry-specific, however).

Coverage is provided at optimal layers within prescribed minimum and maximum per occurrence attachment points and per occurrence (i.e., each and every loss: E.E.L., see Fig. 1 below) and aggregate (AGG.) limits, split appropriately between property and casualty. These attachment points and limits are derived from the risk profiles and the needs of the insureds (Swiss Re’s Value Proposition for the Oil & Petrochemicals industry).

The aggregate limits provide “Beta” base coverage for one year and over three years. Simply stated, if the base coverage is not pierced by a loss, then its full, substantial limits (USD 200M property and 100M casualty) stay in force over the entire three year “Beta” policy term.

Insureds might be concerned they would have no (or only a reduced) coverage if losses were to pierce the base coverage. Therefore, “Beta” includes a provision to reinstate all or a portion of the base coverage that is exhausted.

Lastly, the “Beta” design includes an option at the inception of the base coverage to extend its initial three year high-excess insurance coverage (i.e., the property and casualty base coverage and the provision for a single reinstatement of the base coverage) for an additional three year policy term at a predetermined price.

393

Page 28: Risk/arbitrage strategies - International Actuarial Association

Fig. 1: The “Beta” Insurance Coverage for the Oil & Petrochemicals Industry

From Swiss Re’s risk management point of view, optimal layers for “Beta” property and casualty excess coverages are defined as follows:

No annual loss should pierce the chosen property or casualty excess layer more frequently than once every four years (based both on the historical and scenario annual aggregate loss distributions). This translates into a 75% confidence that annual aggregate losses for a given layer of “Beta” coverage will equal zero.2

The risk quantification process leading to the above optimal “Beta” layers for multi- year (i.e., three years) high-excess property and casualty Oil & Petrochemicals industry insurance coverage in principle follows standard actuarial tradition - however with some new elements:

The ‘Beta” implementation team (consisting of Swiss Re and ETH Zurich3 personnel) has developed and implemented a consistent and stable (with respect to small perturbations in the input data) actuarial modelling approach for “Beta” high-excess property and casualty layers (see Fig. 2 below). This new methodology is based on

2 This optimality criterion is mainly derived from Swiss Re’s perception (based upon an extensive Oil & Petrochemicals industry analysis) of a “Beta” or “catastrophic” event. In the case of “Beta” programs with combined single limits / deductibles, lower percentiles and thus shorter contract maturities may be preferable from a marketing point of view. 3 The ETH Zurich “Beta” implementation team was lead by Prof. Dr. Hans Bühlmann, Prof. Dr. Paul Embrechts (Extreme Value Theory) and Prof. Dr. Freddy Delbaen (“Beta” Options).

394

Page 29: Risk/arbitrage strategies - International Actuarial Association

Extreme Value Theory (Peaks-Over-Thresholds Model4) and fits a generalized Pareto distribution 5 to the exceedances of a data-specific threshold.

Once the frequency and severity distribution parameters are determined, per claim loss layers are selected and aggregate distributions both within the selected layers and excess of those layers up to the maximum potential individual loss (MPL) in the Oil & Petrochemicals industry (e.g., USD 3 billion for property and USD 4 billion for casualty) calculated.

This procedure is repeated for sequential layers (usually chosen at the discretion of the underwriter to approximate the anticipated “Beta” program structures reflecting the needs of the insureds or the entire Oil & Petrochemicals industry), thus mapping out the "Beta" risk potential.

4 It has to be noted that claims histories are usually incomplete, i.e., only losses in excess of a so-called

displacement δ are reported. Let therefore be an i.i.d. sequence of ground-up losses, be

the associated loss amounts in the “Beta” layer and the corresponding

aggregate loss. Similarly, let , be the losses greater than the displacement δ and

, the corresponding “Beta” aggregate loss amount. Some elementary

considerations then show that holds for the aggregate loss distributions, provided that δ < D. The Peaks-Over-Thresholds Model (Pickands-Balkema-de Haan Theorem) on the other hand says that the exceedances of a high threshold t < D are approximately distributed,

where is the generalized Pareto distribution with shape ξ , location t ≡ µ and scale

σ > 0. The threshold t < D is chosen in such a way that in a neighbourhood of t the MLE-estimate

of ξ (and therefore the “Beta” premium) remains reasonably stable (see Fig. 2). 5 The generalized Pareto distribution (GPD) is defined by

where . Compare this with the ordinary Pareto

distribution (PD):

395

and for

Page 30: Risk/arbitrage strategies - International Actuarial Association

The resulting probabilistic (excess-of-loss) profiles (“Beta” risk landscapes or risk maps, see Fig. 3 below) can also be used for the securitization 6 of “Beta” portfolio components.

Sample Mean Excess Plot

6 From an actuarial standpoint, securitization is a modern capital markets alternative for traditional retrocession agreements.

396

Page 31: Risk/arbitrage strategies - International Actuarial Association

QQPlot

397

Page 32: Risk/arbitrage strategies - International Actuarial Association

Data : Shape by Threshold

398

Page 33: Risk/arbitrage strategies - International Actuarial Association

Data : GPD Fit to 98 exceedances

Fig. 2a: Oil & Petrochemicals Industry Severity Parameters (Property) Solid Line: GPD, Dotted Line: PD

399

Page 34: Risk/arbitrage strategies - International Actuarial Association

Sample Mean Excess Plot

400

Page 35: Risk/arbitrage strategies - International Actuarial Association

QQPlot

401

Page 36: Risk/arbitrage strategies - International Actuarial Association

Data : Shape by Threshold

402

Page 37: Risk/arbitrage strategies - International Actuarial Association

Data : GPD Fit to 51 exceedances

Fig. 2b: Oil & Petrochemicals Industry Severity Parameters (Casualty)Solid Line: GPD, Dotted Line: PD

403

Page 38: Risk/arbitrage strategies - International Actuarial Association

404

Fig. 3a: Oil & Petrochemicals Industry Risk Landscape (Property)

Page 39: Risk/arbitrage strategies - International Actuarial Association

405

Fig. 3b: Oil & Petrochemicals Industry Risk Landscape (Casualty)

Page 40: Risk/arbitrage strategies - International Actuarial Association

Based upon a risk management target for "Beta” portfolio excess-of-loss probabilities, a corresponding securitization structure might then look as follows (in simple terms that could be made more precise with some financial engineering):

1.

2.

3.

4.

5.

etc.).

AAA Swiss Re bond with coupon a. r fixed = best financial markets conditions b. + x variable = linked to performance of underlying risk portfolio and a maturity schedule that is adapted to the coverage structure of the underlying risk portfolio, i.e., in the case of “Beta” a maturity of at least 3 years. For tax reasons, (the fixed part r of) the coupon would (at the investor’s discretion) not actually be paid out, i.e., the bond would be of the deep-discount type. In the case of a catastrophic loss in the underlying risk portfolio, the notional principal of the bond would be transformed into a long-term loan (i.e., the investor would not loose any money). With some financial engineering, interest rates at best financial market conditions could be guaranteed to both sides at the outset. In the case where an existing Swiss Re share-holder participates in such a structure, the notional principal of the bond could alternatively be transformed into Swiss Re shares at a fixed price (i.e., Swiss Re would not actually have to pay it back). The limited risk arbitrage techniques outlined in this publication series could be used to effectively exploit any opportunities for arbitrage profits offered by the global financial markets (disparity in interest rate regimes, exchange rates,

Note that such a securitization program can also be designed according to specific risk management requirements (w.r.t. exposures, capital, cashflows, etc.) of a particular client. Usually, however, securitization (the “back-end” of an alternative risk transfer process) is completely transparent to "Beta" clients, i.e., Swiss Re takes complete care of the allocation of (re)insurance risks in the capital markets.

Returning to LRA techniques now, we note that the above mentioned financial engineering critically depends upon an efficient model for interest-rates, stocks and foreign currency which is also reflective of the “Beta” excess-of-loss probabilities. The main idea is to start with an interest rate model (as interest rates are the most significant factor in the above securitization scheme) and to combine this in a consistent way with a model for stocks /stock indices / currencies (on the same lattice):

A. Processes.

406

Page 41: Risk/arbitrage strategies - International Actuarial Association

(I) for stocks, stock indices and currencies

Reference: J.C. Hull, Options, Futures and Other Derivative Securities, Prentice-Hall 1993

Generalization: M. Rubinstein, Implied Binomial Trees, Journal of Finance 49, 771 - 818 (1994)

(II) for interest rates (volatilities)

Reference: J.C. Hull and A. White, One-Factor Interest-Rate Models and the Valuation of Interest-Rate Derivative Securities, Journal of Financial and Quantitative Analysis 28, 235 - 254 (1993)

B. Rubinstein Implied Tree (consistent with Hull & White interest rates).

Stock / Stock Index / Currency Dynamics (as in 3. Implied Trees above):

(5.1)

Interest Rates and Dividend Yields (Ito formula):

(5.2a)

(5.2b)

Hull & White Interest Rates (comparison of respective drift and diffusion terms):

407

Page 42: Risk/arbitrage strategies - International Actuarial Association

(5.3)

Simplification r(t, x) = a + bt + cx + dx² :

(5.4a)

(5.4b)

This defines the stock / stock index / currency evolution (consistent with interest rates). The simplification y( t, x) = e + ft + gx then leads to the parameters (initial conditions)

(5.5a)

(5.5b)

(5.5c)

(5.5d)

with the remaining model specifications

for r(t, x) :

for y( t, x) :

408

(5.6a)

(5.6b)

Page 43: Risk/arbitrage strategies - International Actuarial Association

Using this model, the LRA techniques presented in this paper can be implemented on a notebook computer with reasonable response times for both lattice construction and contingent claim (portfolio) evaluation.

409

Page 44: Risk/arbitrage strategies - International Actuarial Association

Appendix: References

[1] J. M. Harrison and D. M. Kreps, Martingales and Arbitrage in Multiperiod Securities Markers, Journal of Economic Theory 20, 381-408 (1979) [2] J. M. Harrison and S. R. Pliska, Martingales and Stochastic Integrals in the Theory of Continuous Trading, Stochastic Processes and their Applications 11, 215- 260 (1981) [3] J. M. Harrison and S. R. Pliska, A Stochastic Calculus Model of Continuous Trading: Complete Markets, Stochastic Processes and their Applications 15, 313-316 (1983) [4] M. S. Taqqu and W. Willinger, The Analysis of Finite Security Markets Using Martingales, Advanced Applied Probability 19, 1-25 (1987) [5] D. Duffie. An Extension of the Black-Scholes Model of Security Valuation, Journal of Economic Theory 46, 194-204 (1988) [6] W. Willinger and M. S. Taqqu, Pathwise Stochastic Integration and Applications to the Theory of Continuous Trading, Stochastic Processes and their Applications 32, 253-280 (1989) [7] E. Eberlein, Strong Approximations of Continuous Time Stochastic Processes, Journal of Multivariate Analysis 31, 220-235 (1989) [8] H. He, Convergence from Discrete- to Continuous-Time Contingent Claims Prices, Review of Financial Studies 3, 523-546 (1990) [9] R. C. Dalang, A. Morton and W. Willinger, Equivalent Martingale Measures and No-Arbitrage in Stochastic Securities Market Models, Stochastics and Stochastics Reports 29, 185-201 (1990) [10] H. He, Optimal Consumption-Portfolio Policies: A Convergence from Discrete to Continuous Time Models, Journal of Economic Theory 55, 340-363 (1991) [11] W. Willinger and M. S. Taqqu, Toward a Convergence Theory for Continuous Stochastic Securities Market Models, Mathematical Finance, Vol. 1, No. 1, 55-99 (1991) [12] N. Cutland, E. Kopp and W. Willinger, A Nonstandard Approach to Option Pricing, Mathematical Finance, Vol. 1, No. 4, 1-38 (1991) [13] D. Duffie and P. Protter, From Discrete- to Continuous-Time Finance: Weak Convergence of the Financial Gain Process, Mathematical Finance. Vol. 2, No. 1, 1- 15 (1992) [14] E. Eberlein, On Modeling Questions in Security Valuation, Mathematical Finance, Vol. 2, No. 1, 17-32 (1992) [15] N. J. Cutland and E. Kopp, From Discrete to Continuous Financial Models: New Convergence Results for Option Pricing, Mathematical Finance, Vol. 3, No. 2, 101-123 (1993) [16] N. J. Cutland, E. Kopp and W. Willinger, A Nonstandard Treatment of Options Driven by Poisson Processes, Stochastics and Stochastics Reports 42. 115-133 (1993) [17] W. Schachermayer, Martingale Measures for Discrete-Time Processes with Infinite Horizon, Mathematical Finance, Vol. 4, No. 1, 25-55 (1994)

410

Page 45: Risk/arbitrage strategies - International Actuarial Association

[18] P. P. Boyle, A Lattice Framework for Option Pricing with Two State Variables, Journal of Financial and Quantitative Analysis 23, 1-12 (1988) [19] E. Omberg, Efficient Discrete Time Jump Process Models in Option Pricing, Journal of Financial and Quantitative Analysis 23, 161-174 (1988) [20] D. B. Nelson and K. Ramaswamy, Simple Binomial Processes as Diffusion Approximations in Financial Models, Review of Financial Studies 3, 393-430 (1990) [21] R. Breen, The Accelerated Binomial Option Pricing Model, Journal of Financial and Quantitative Analysis 26, 153-164 (1991) [22] L. Trigeorgis, A Log-Transformed Binomial Numerical Analysis Method for Valuing Complex Multi-Option Investments, Journal of Financial and Quantitative Analysis 26, 309-326 (1991) [23] K. I. Amin, On the Computation of Continuous Time Option Prices Using Discrete Approximations, Journal of Financial and Quantitative Analysis 26, 477-494 (1991) [24] K. Sandmann, The Pricing of Options with an Uncertain Interest Rate: A Discrete-Time Approach, Mathematical Finance, Vol. 3, No. 2, 201-216 (1993) [25] B. Dupire, Model Art, Risk, September 1993 [26] B. Dupire, Pricing with a Smile, Risk, January 1994 [27] E. Derman and I. Kani, Riding on a Smile, Risk, February 1994 [28] R. Heynen, An Empirical Investigation of Observed Smile Patterns, Tinbergen Institute, Erasmus University, Rotterdam, 1994 [29] M. Rubinstein, Implied Binomial Trees, Journal of Finance 49, 771-818 (1994) [30] D. W. K. Andrews, Heteroskedasticity and Autocorrelation Consistent Covariance Matrix Estimation, Econometrica 59, 817-858 (1991) [31] L. C. G. Rogers and S. E. Satchell, Estimating Variance from High, Low and Closing Prices, Annals of Applied Probability 1, 504-512 (1991) [32] B. E. Hansen, Consistent Covariance Matrix Estimation for Dependent Heterogeneous Processes, Econometrica 60, 967-972 (1992) [33] L. A. Aggoun and R. J. Elliott, Finite Dimensional Predictors for Hidden Markov Chains, Systems & Control Letters 19, 335-340 (1992) [34] M. Chesney, R. J. Elliott, D. Madan and H. Yang, Diffusion Coefficient Estimation and Asset Pricing when Risk Premia and Sensitivities are Time Varying, Mathematical Finance, Vol. 3, No. 2, 85-99 (1993) [35] R. J. Elliott and R W. Rishel, Estimating the Implicit Interest Rate of a Risky Asset, Stochastic Processes and their Applications 49, 199-206 (1994) [36] J. C. Hull and A. White, One-Factor Interest-Rate Models and the Valuation of Interest-Rate Derivative Securities, Journal of Financial and Quantitative Analysis 28, 235 - 254 (1993) [37] J. C. Hull, Options, Futures, and Other Derivative Securities, Prentice-Hall 1993 [38] I. Karatzas and S. E. Shreve, Brownian Motion and Stochastic Calculus, Graduate Texts in Mathematics, Springer 1991

411

Page 46: Risk/arbitrage strategies - International Actuarial Association

[39] P. Protter, Stochastic Integration and Differential Equations: A New Approach, Applications of Mathematics, Springer 1990 [40] R. S. Liptser and A. N. Shiryayev, Statistics of Random Processes I: General Theory, Applications of Mathematics, Springer 1977 [41] R. S. Liptser and A. N. Shiryayev, Statistics of Random Processes II: Applications, Applications of Mathematics, Springer 1978 [42] A. N. Shiryayev, Probability, Graduate Texts in Mathematics, Springer 1984 [43] J. Jacod and A. N. Shiryayev, Limit Theorems for Stochastic Processes, Grundlehren der Mathematischen Wissenschaften, Springer 1987 [44] R. J. Elliott, Stochastic Calculus and Applications, Applications of Mathematics, Springer 1982 [45] S. N. Ethier and T. G. Kurtz, Markov Processes: Characterization and Convergence, Wiley 1986 [46] P. E. Kloeden and E. Platen, Numerical Solution of Stochastic Differential Equations, Application of Mathematics, Springer 1992 [47] M. S. Bazaraa, J. J. Jarvis and H. D. Sherali, Linear Programming and Network Flows, Wiley 1990 [48] M. S. Bazaraa, H. D. Sherali and C. M. Shetty, Nonlinear Programming: Theory and Algorithms, Wiley 1993

412