Regional Economist - April 2016

download Regional Economist - April 2016

of 24

Transcript of Regional Economist - April 2016

  • 7/25/2019 Regional Economist - April 2016

    1/24

    CommoditiesFalling Prices Hurt

    Emerging Markets

    ImmigrationWhich Populations

    Are Growing, Shrinking?

    From Backward Agrarian Societyto Industrial Powerhouse

    in Just 35 Years

    Chinas Rapid Rise

    A Quarterly Reviewof Business andEconomic Conditions

    Vol. 24, No. 2

    April 2016

    THE FEDERAL RESERVE BANK OF ST. LOUIS

    CENTRAL TO AMERICAS ECONOMY

  • 7/25/2019 Regional Economist - April 2016

    2/24

    C O N T E N T S

    Chinas Rapid Rise as an Industrial PowerhouseBy Yi Wen

    Chinas industrial revolution over the past 35 years is probably one o themost important economic and geopolitical phenomena since the originalIndustrial Revolution in the 18th century. Te rapid growth has puzzledmany, in part because China tried and ailed at this transormation beore.What was the secret this t ime?

    8

    THE REGIONAL

    ECONOMISTAPRIL 2016|VOL. 24, NO. 2

    The Regional Economistis published

    quarterly by the Research and Public Affairs

    divisions of the Federal Reserve Bank

    of St. Louis. It addresses the national, interna-

    tional and regional economic issues of

    the day, particularly as they apply to states

    in the Eighth Federal Reserve District. Views

    expressed are not necessarily those of the

    St. Louis Fed or of the Federal Reserve System.

    Director of Research

    Christopher J. Waller

    Chief of Staff to the President

    Cletus C. Coughlin

    Deputy Director of Research

    David C. Wheelock

    Director of Public Affairs

    Karen Branding

    Editor

    Subhayu Bandyopadhyay

    Managing Editor

    Al Stamborski

    Art Director

    Joni Williams

    The Eighth Federal Reserve Districtincludes

    all of Arkansas, eastern Missouri, southern

    Illinois and Indiana, western Kentucky and

    Tennessee, and northern Mississippi. The

    Eighth District offices are in Little Rock,

    Louisville, Memphis and St. Louis.

    Please direct your commentsto Subhayu Bandyopadhyay

    at 314-444-7425 or by email at

    [email protected].

    You can also write to him at the

    address below. Submission of a

    letter to the editor gives us the right

    to post it to our website and/or

    publish it in The Regional Economist

    unless the writer states otherwise.

    We reserve the right to edit letters

    for clarity and length.

    Single-copy subscriptions are free

    but available only to those with

    U.S. addresses. To subscribe, go to

    www.stlouisfed.org/publications.

    You can also write to The Regional

    Economist, Public Affairs Office,

    Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis,

    P.O. Box 442, St. Louis, MO 63166-0442.

    3 PRE S I D E N T S M E S S A G E

    4 Measuring Trends

    in Income Inequality

    By Michael . Owyang

    and Hannah G. Shell

    Beore there is discussion on what

    can and should be done about

    income inequality, interested

    parties should understand the di-

    erent methods that can be used to

    measure the gap. Knowing when

    the gap has been particularly wide

    or narrow over the past 50 or so

    years would also be helpul.

    6 Commodities Importance

    to Emerging Economies

    By Alexander Monge-Naranjo

    and Faisal Sohail

    Te ups and downs o commodityprices can have a huge impact on

    the economies o the produc-

    ing nations (emerging, as well as

    developed). Increasingly, these

    economies are susceptible to the

    needs o a single buyer: China.

    15 Interest Rate Control

    Not a Simple Process

    By Stephen Williamson

    Setting the ed unds rate is just

    one step. Te Fed also has to deal

    with the discount rate and the

    interest rate paid on reserves.

    Trow in a floor system (with a

    subfloor) and overnight reverse

    repos, and youve got a process

    that is anyt hing but simple.

    17 E C O N O M Y A T A G L A N C E

    18 D I S T R I CT O VE RV I E W

    Immigration Patterns

    Yield Some Surprises

    By Subhayu Bandyopadhyay

    and Rodrigo Guerrero

    Te percentage o oreign-born

    in the our major metro areas o

    the District is smaller than or the

    nation as a whole. However, some

    o the metro areas are showing

    aster growth in their Asian, Ari-

    can and Latin American popula-

    tions than is the nation overall.

    20 M E T RO PRO F I L E

    Cape Girardeau, Mo.:

    Ahead, Yet Behind

    By Charles S. Gascon

    and Joseph . McGillicuddy

    Tis small MSA scores well oeducational attainment, cost

    o living, employment in hea

    care services and in ot her cat

    ries. Still, output and job gro

    are relatively slow.

    23 N A T I O N A L O VE RV I E W

    GDP and Inflation

    Expected To Improve

    By Kevin L. Kliesen

    Strong job growth, consume

    spending and housing activit

    bode well or the economy th

    year.

    ComFallin

    Emer

    ImmigrationWhichPopulations

    AreGrowing,Shrinking?

    From Backward Agrarian Societyto Industrial Powerhouse

    in Just 35 Years

    Chinas Rapid Rise

    AQuarterlyReviewofBusinessandEconomicConditions

    Vol.24,No.2

    April2016

    THE FEDERAL RESERVE BANK OF ST.LOUISCENTRAL TO AMERICAS ECONOMY

    ONLINEEXTRA

    Read more at www.stlouisfed.org/publications/re.

    Tracking the U.S. Economy with NowcastsBy Kevin L. Kliesen and Michael W. McCracken

    Te Federal Open Market Committee wants its interest-rate deci-

    sions to be data-dependent. But until the past several years, much

    o the statistical inormation availablenot just to the FOMC, but

    anyonehad come rom reports that looked backward at conditions

    rom the previous month or even quarter. New models developed by

    economists allow or orecasting o conditions in the current quarter

    as reports arrive on a day-to-day basisas in now. Hence, nowcasts.

    COVER IMAGE: THINKSTOCK/ISTOCK

    7

    6

    5

    4

    3

    2

    1

    0

    Percent

    Real GDP

    1.9 2.1 2.0 2.0

    2015 (Actual) 2016

    The FOMCs March 2016 Econ

    : r i r i r i r r r r r

    r l i i r ir r r i i . l r r

    r r i r li .

    2.2

    2 The Regional Economist|April 2016

  • 7/25/2019 Regional Economist - April 2016

    3/24

    Modern economic theory says that infla-tion expectations are an importantdeterminant o actual inflation. How does

    expected inflation affect actual inflation?

    Firms and households take into account

    the expected rate o inflation when making

    economic decisions, such as wage contract

    negotiations or firms pricing decisions. All o

    these decisions, in turn, eed into the actual

    rate o increase in prices. Given that central

    banks are concerned with price stability, poli-

    cymakers pay attention to inflation expecta-

    tions in addition to actual inflation.

    Te two main ways to gauge inflation

    expectations are survey-based measures and

    market-based measures. An example o theormer is the inflation expectations rom the

    University o Michigans survey o consum-

    ers. As a predictor o inflation, this measure

    tends to overstate inflation. Over the past 10

    years, or example, expected inflation one

    year ahead averaged more than 3 percent,

    while actual inflation ended up averaging

    less than 2 percent. Te Michigan surveys

    results also tend to bounce around quite a bit

    with the price o gasoline. Because consum-

    ers usually go to the gas station, as well as

    the grocery store, on a weekly basis, changesin those prices strongly shape their inflation

    expectations. However, many other prices

    exist in the economy, perhaps making this

    particular way o looking at inflation expec-

    tations less useul.1

    Another example o a survey-based mea-

    sure comes rom the Survey o Proessional

    Forecasters (SPF), a group that tracks the

    economy extremely closely. Te SPF provides

    orecasts o inflation based on the consumer

    price index (CPI) and on the personal con-

    sumption expenditures price index (PCE).Te groups expectations o PCE inflation,

    which is the inflation measure that the Fed

    targets, are consistently around the Feds tar-

    get o 2 percent. One interpretation o these

    orecasts is that these proessional orecasters

    have confidence that the Fed will make sure

    inflation is 2 percent no matter what is going

    on in the economy. Tis could be good rom

    the central banks perspective because the

    orecasts are signaling Fed credibility with

    respect to its stated inflation target. On the

    other hand, the orecasts might not be very

    useul because they do not provide much

    guidance on what the central bank would

    have to do to steer inflation to 2 percent.

    Although many people ocus on survey-

    based measures, I tend to put more weight on

    market-based measures o inflation expecta-

    tions. Tese are tied to the market or rea-

    sury Inflation-Protected Securities (IPS)

    and are based on CPI inflation. Te basic idea

    is that a nominal security, such as a rea-

    sury note, and a real (or inflation-adjusted)

    security with the same maturity both trade

    in the market. Te price difference between

    the two could be interpreted as the marketparticipants expectation o inflation over

    the horizon o the security; this difference

    is also called the breakeven inflation rate.

    IPS-based measures o inflation expecta-

    tions are available, or instance, at five-year

    and 10-year horizons, as well as a five-year,

    five-year orward horizon, which reflects

    expectations o inflation not in the next five

    years but in the five years afer that.

    Te IPS-based measures may be viewed

    as more inormative than survey-based mea-

    sures because the ormer tend to react moreto incoming inormation about the economy

    than do the latter. In this sense, the IPS-

    based measures o inflation expectations give

    a better sense o shifing inflation expecta-

    tions than do other measures. One caveat

    to this view is that IPS spreads also reflect

    differences in the liquidity and risk charac-

    teristics o nominal and real securities, and

    that it may be premia associated with liquid-

    ity and risk that are responding to incoming

    data, as opposed to inflation expectations

    themselves.2

    I do not find those analyses verycompelling. Consequently, I think market-

    based IPS spreads provide the best measure

    o inflation expectations.3

    Ideally, all o these measures o inflation

    expectations would be close to the Feds

    target o 2 percentor 2.3 percent or those

    that reer to CPI inflation, which tends to

    run about 30 basis points higher than PCE

    inflation. However, inflation expectations in

    major inflation-targeting economies have not

    Inflation Expectations Are Important

    to Central Bankers, Too

    P R E S I D E N T S M E S S A G E

    been running close to target o late. Europe

    is a prime example where inflation expecta-

    tions ell dramatically in recent years. Te

    European Central Bank subsequently took

    extraordinary action to try to return inflation

    to target by implementing a quantitativeeasing program. In the U.S., IPS-based

    measures o inflation expectations have allen

    since the summer o 2014 and are somewhat

    below levels that would be consistent with a

    PCE inflation rate o 2 percent.4Whether the

    Feds policies will be sufficient to return these

    expectations to more normal levels remains

    to be seen.

    James Bullard,President and CEO

    Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis

    E N D N O E S

    1 The New York Feds Survey of Consumer Expecta-

    tions also provides a measure of consumers

    expectations for ination. See www.newyorkfed.org/

    microeconomics/sceindex.

    2 For instance, see Gospodi nov, Nikolay; Tkac, Paula;

    and Wei, Bin. Are Long-Term Ination Expecta-

    tions Declining? Not So Fast, Says Atlanta Fed,

    Macroblog,Jan. 15, 2016. Also see Bauer, Michael

    D.; and McCarthy, Erin. Can We Rely on Market-

    Based Ination Forecasts? FRBSF Economic Letter

    2015-30, Sept. 21, 2015.

    3 Another market-based measure of ination expecta-

    tions is so-called ination swaps. For a discussion of

    TIPS breakeven rates and ination swaps, see Lucca,

    David; and Schaumburg, Ernst. What to Make of

    Market Measures of Ination Expectations?Liberty

    Street Economics, New York Fed, Aug. 15, 2011.

    4 The drop since 2014 has been highly correlated with

    oil prices. For more on this topic, see my presentation

    on Feb. 24, 2016, More on the Changing Impera -

    tives for U.S. Monetary Policy Normalization.

    The Regional Economist | www.stlouisfed.org 3

  • 7/25/2019 Regional Economist - April 2016

    4/24

    Acentral issue in economics concerns howoutput (equivalent to income) is distrib-uted across economic agents (e.g., workers,

    entrepreneurs). A first step in addressing

    this issue is understanding how output (or

    income) is distributed in the United States

    and understanding how the distribution haschanged over time.

    Measuring income inequality, however,

    is not a trivial endeavor. Multiple sources

    o incomesalary, capital gains income,

    employer-provided health insurance and

    other non-salaried compensation, etc.make

    simply measuring income itsel problematic.

    Nonetheless, using a number o different

    definitions o income and employing various

    metrics, researchers have attempted to quan-

    tiy income inequality in the U.S.

    Economists have identified two broad peri-ods in income inequality over the post-World

    War II periodfirst in the 1970s and then,

    more recently, prior to the Great Recession.

    In the sections that ollow, we describe how

    income inequality is measured and then how

    it changed over these two periods.

    Income Inequality

    and How Its Measured

    Assessing income inequality boils down in

    effect to measuring the income gaps between

    high and low earners. Income inequality impliesthat the lower-income population receives

    disproportionately less income than the higher-

    income population: Te larger the disparity, the

    greater the degree o income inequality.

    o measure inequality, economists ofen

    sort the population by income percentiles and

    measure the difference across these percen-

    tiles. For example, the top 10 percent o earn-

    ers would be the 90th percentile. A related

    way o dividing the population is quintiles,

    which split the distribution into five even

    buckets (the bottom quintile is the 20th per-

    centile); quintiles are commonly used percen-

    tiles or studying inequality except at the top

    o the income distribution, where the income

    difference between 98th and 99th percentiles

    is large. o summarize inequality across theentire distribution, economists use the Gini

    coefficient. Te Gini coefficient measures

    income concentration at each percentile o

    the population and ranges rom 0 (perectly

    equal) to 1 (perectly unequal).

    In order to study income inequality, one

    needs income at an individual level. While

    gross domestic product is the usual aggregate

    indicator or income, there are many defini-

    tions o income and many data sources avail-

    able at the individual level. Economists ofen

    use the Internal Revenue Services Statisticso Income program (SOI) or the Census

    Bureaus Current Population Survey (CPS).

    Studies using different data sources reach

    various conclusions on income inequality,

    depending on the definition used or income.

    For example, economists Tomas Piketty

    and Emmanuel Saez compiled a dataset using

    SOI data back to 1913. Tey ocused on the

    share o income earned by the top percen-

    tiles to avoid poor data quality in the lower

    percentiles.1Te SOI definition o income is

    market income, the cash income reportedon tax orms.2Te SOI data more accurately

    measure the top o the income distribution,

    but less accurately measure low-income

    statistics because low-income households are

    not always required to file income taxes.3

    Another source o individual income

    data is the CPS. Every March, the CPSa

    monthly survey o 75,000 householdspro-

    vides the inormation used in the Annual

    Social and Economic Supplement, which is

    the primary source or census data on

    income and poverty. Te CPS data are

    reported in money incomemarket income

    plus other cash income, excluding noncash

    benefits, such as employer-provided health

    insurance. While the CPS provides quality

    low- and middle-income data, incomesabove a certain threshold are not reported to

    protect individual privacy. Tis makes it less

    ideal or high-income estimates.

    Te Congressional Budget Office (CBO)

    also constructed a dataset that merges the

    CPS and SOI and draws on each sources

    strengthsthe CPS or low income and the

    SOI or high income. Te CBO reports mar-

    ket income, both beore-tax (market income

    plus government transers) and afer-tax

    income (beore-tax income less ederal taxes)

    Most studies find that more equality is seenin afer-tax income, ollowed by beore-tax

    income and then market income.4Moreover,

    it is generally accepted that the U.S. economy

    is similar to other developed nations in

    terms o pretax and transer income inequal-

    ity. In other words, U.S. income inequality is

    not intrinsically different rom what is seen

    in other countries, and any differences are

    mainly driven by the lack o income-

    redistributing fiscal policies in the U.S.

    Trends in Income Inequality

    From the end o World War II to the early

    1970s, income inequality in the U.S. was rela-

    tively low. Te graph shows that rom 1947 to

    1970, the Gini coefficient was flat or declin-

    ing.5Piketty and Saez, using SOI data with a

    longer history, ound that income inequality

    peaked in the 1920s, then decreased afer the

    Great Depression, when top capital incomes

    ell and were unable to recover. Although

    the U.S. economy rebounded during World

    Measuring Trends

    in Income Inequality

    E C O N O M I C S

    By Michael . Owyang and Hannah G. Shell

    THIN

    4 The Regional Economist|April 2016

  • 7/25/2019 Regional Economist - April 2016

    5/24

    E N D N O E S

    1 Piketty and Saez also estimate the portion o lower

    income tax units that are excluded in the SOI data

    and add these estimated values into their measure

    o total income.2 Market income consists o beore-tax income rom

    wages and salaries; profits rom businesses; capital

    income, such as dividends, interest and rents; real-

    ized capital gains; and income rom past services.

    Other orms o income include cash and in-kind

    payments rom programs like Social Security, ood

    stamps and private benefits (e.g., health insurance).3 Te SOI data also exclude noncash benefits like

    health insurance, which a re a growing portion o

    middle-class income.4 Te differences in inequality by income concept

    are largely due to a progressive tax struct ure and

    social saet y nets, such as ood stamps, that benefit

    individuals at the bottom o the distribution.5 Family income is defined as that o two or more

    related persons living i n a household. It may

    exclude single-person households and households

    with multiple residents who are all not related.

    Family income is available in the CPS rom 1947

    to 2011, while household income was not collected

    until 1967.

    R E F E R E N C E S

    DeNavas-Walt, Carmen; and Proctor, Bernadette D.

    Income and Poverty in the United States: 2014.

    Current Population Reports.September 2015. See

    www.census.gov/content/dam/Census/library/

    publications/2015/demo/p60-252.pd.

    Te Distribution o Household Income and Federal

    axes, 2011. Congress o the United States:

    Congressional Budget Office. November 2014.

    See www.cbo.gov/sites/deault/files/113th-con-

    gress-2013-2014/reports/49440-Distribution-o-

    Income-and-axes.pd.

    Piketty, Tomas; and Saez, Emmanuel. Income

    Inequality i n the United States, 1913-1998. Te

    Quarterly Journal of Economics,Vol. 118, No. 1,

    2003, pp. 1-39. See http://eml.berkeley.edu/~saez/

    pikettyqje.pd.

    Saez, Emmanuel. Stri king It Richer: Te Evolution

    o op Incomes in the United States, updated

    with 2014 preliminary estimates. University o

    Caliornia, Berkeley. June 2015. See http://eml.

    berkeley.edu/~saez/saez-UStopincomes-2014.pd.

    Stone, Chad; risi, Danilo; Sherman, Arloc; a nd

    DeBot, Brandon. A Guide to Statistics on His-

    torical rends in I ncome Inequality. Center on

    Budget and Policy Priorities. October 2015.

    See www.cbpp.org/sites/deault/files/atoms/

    files/11-28-11pov_0.pd.

    War II, wage controls prevented growth in

    top incomes. Once the war ended, a progres-

    sive tax structure and reorms such as Social

    Security and unionization kept low- and

    middle-income growth strong.

    Starting in the 1970s, wage growth at the

    top o the income distribution outpaced the

    rest o the distribution, and inequality began

    to rise. Te Gini coefficient grew rom 0.394 in

    1970 to 0.482 in 2013. Te CBO estimates that

    between 1979 and 2011 market income grew

    56 percent in the 81st through 99th percen-

    tiles and 174 percent in the 99th percentile.

    In contrast, market income growth averaged

    16 percent in the bottom our quintiles.

    Government transers and ederal taxes

    did have a redistributive effect during this

    period, but income inequality in afer-

    tax income grew substantially. Te 1970s

    increase in inequality was different rom the

    increase during the 1920s. During the periodrom 1940 to 1970, top-income composition

    shifed rom capital income to wage income.

    In the top 0.01 percent, the total income share

    rom capital income ell rom 70 percent in

    1929 to just above 20 percent in 1998. Wage

    income rose over the same period, rom

    10 percent to about 45 percent. High growth

    in top wages is partly explained by the ax

    Reorm Act o 1986, which lowered the top

    marginal-income tax rates. Te short-term

    impact o tax reorm is circled in red on the

    graph. Longer-lasting wage growth camerom the reporting o stock options and other

    orms o income as wages on tax returns.

    Afer the increase in the 1970s, inequality

    continued to rise. In the 2001 and 2007-09

    recessions, top incomes ell sharply as stock

    market crashes decreased the value o capital

    gains and stock options. However, losses to top

    incomes were temporary. During the recovery

    period rom 2002 through 2007, or example,

    the top 1 percent captured about two-thirds

    o overall income growth, Piketty and Saez

    estimated. Further, even though top incomes

    ell 36.3 percent in the 2007-09 recession,

    the incomes o the bottom 99 percent also

    decreased 11.6 percent. Tis decrease is the

    largest two-year all in the incomes o the bot-

    tom 99 percent since the Great Depression.

    So ar, the top 1 percent has captured

    58 percent o income gains rom 2009 to

    2014. Te newest data on income show that

    growth rom 2013 to 2014 was more equal.

    Te incomes o the bottom 99 percent grew

    3.3 percent, the best rate in more than

    10 years, and the Gini coefficient on house-

    hold income decreased slightly, marking the

    first nonrecession decrease since 1998.

    Conclusion

    Economists use Gini coefficients, percen-

    tiles and detailed survey data to study trends

    in income inequality. Tey find that inequality

    has been rising in the U.S. since World War

    II, reaching its highest level in 2013 since the

    1920s. Tis result is robust or the definition o

    income and the chosen measure o inequality.

    Understanding the acts about inequal-

    ity is the first step in assessing what can and

    should be done. While there is a general

    consensus that some reallocative transers

    rom the top o the income distribution to the

    bottom are desirable, the optimal amount othese redistributions is stil l up in the air.

    Michael . Owyang is an economist , and Han-nah G. Shell is a senior research associate, bothat the Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis. Formore on Owyangs work, see https://research.stlouisfed.org/econ/owyang.

    SOURCES: Gini coefficients calculated by the Bureau of Labor

    Statistics using Current Population Survey data, accessed via

    Haver Analytics.

    NOTE: The figure to the left shows Gini coefficients calculated

    from Current Population Survey data for family and household

    income. Only family income is available from 1947 to 1967, but

    this measure is less ideal than household income because the

    census defines a family as two or more related individuals living

    in the same house. Roommates or single-person households are

    excluded. The red circles mark the temporary increase in income

    inequality from the Tax Reform Act of 1986, which lowered the

    top marginal tax rate. Gray bars indicate recessions.

    Gini Coefficient for Family and Household Income

    1947

    1949

    1951

    1953

    1955

    1957

    1959

    1961

    1963

    1965

    1967

    1969

    1971

    1973

    1975

    1977

    1979

    1981

    1983

    1985

    1987

    1989

    1991

    1993

    1995

    1997

    1999

    2001

    2003

    2005

    2007

    2009

    2011

    2013

    0.50

    0.48

    0.46

    0.44

    0.42

    0.40

    0.38

    0.36

    0.34

    0.32

    0.30

    Gini Coefficient, Family Income

    Gini Coefficient, Household Income

    The Regional Economist | www.stlouisfed.org 5

  • 7/25/2019 Regional Economist - April 2016

    6/24

    Many Countries Sink or Swimon Commodity Prices

    and on Orders from China

    T R A D E

    Many emerging economiesand alsothose o some developed countries,such as Australia, Canada and Norwayrely

    heavily on the production o commodities

    and their sale to global markets. For

    example, more than 10 percent o Canadas

    and Chiles output in 2013 could be attrib-uted to the export o commodities, as can

    be seen in Figure 1. Te equivalent share

    is much higher or Venezuela and other

    oil-producing countries. Te figure also

    Commodity Prices

    and the Business Cycle

    Figure 2 shows the deviations rom

    trend o a weighted index o commodity

    prices and log output or Argentina, Brazil,

    Canada, Colombia and Russia or all quar-

    ters between 2000 and 2016. Tis cyclicalcomponent o prices and output is obtained

    by estimating and removing the trend

    component o each variable.1Te red line

    shows the cyclical behavior o global com-

    modity prices (lef axis). Te figure shows

    that commodity prices exhibited significant

    volatility over the past 16 years. In particu-

    lar, between 2000 and 2006, commodity

    prices were trending upward (not shown in

    figure) with requent fluctuations around

    this trend. Te year leading up to the Great

    Recession saw a dramatic increase in the

    price o all commodities, led largely by

    increases in energy prices and in the prices

    or ood and beverages. Te global reces-

    sion saw a sharp decline in all prices, onlyto display an equally sharp recovery by early

    2009. Te causes o the dramatic recovery in

    commodity prices are debatable, but by 2011

    they had recovered or exceeded prerecession

    levels.2Between 2011 and 2014, commodity

    prices remained relatively stable in trend

    with small deviations.

    Since the summer o 2014, there has been

    a sustained drop in commodity prices, most

    noticeably in energy. Some o the decline in

    energy prices can be attributed to supply-

    side actors. In particular, the newound

    abundance o energy in the U.S. and result-

    ing fight or market share by the Organiza-

    tion o the Petroleum Exporting Countries

    have led to plentiul supply and alling

    prices. Tere is no such obvious supply-sideactor that can explain the drop in all other

    commodity prices, which has attracted

    much less attention.

    Te right axis o Figure 2 displays the

    deviations o output, measured as GDP,

    rom its trend or our emerging market

    economies and Canada. Te figure shows

    that the cyclical components o output and

    commodity prices are highly correlated

    with each other.3Indeed, the dramatic,

    ast and sustained recovery in commodity

    prices must be credited as a major source othe relatively stronger, aster and sustained

    recovery o emerging markets ollowing

    the recession, relative to the recoveries in

    the U.S., Europe, Japan and other major

    economies.4Both Figures 1 and 2 make

    a compelling case or the interlinkages

    between emerging markets and the prices

    o commodities: One or two years afer the

    collapse in 2009, a tidal wave in rising com-

    modities prices pushed emerging economies

    to quickly recover and grow. Nowadays, the

    tidal wave has receded, and many emergingmarkets are in danger o capsizing.

    The Impact of China

    From colonial times a ew centuries ago,

    commodity prices have been driving fluctu-

    ations o commodity-exporting economies.

    What is interesting in this last cycle is the

    emerging role o China, an emerging economy

    itsel. Strikingly, Chinaand to a lesser extent

    Indiahas surged as an importer o commo-

    THINKSTOCK/

    By Alexander Monge-Naranjo and Faisal Sohail

    Some of the rise of China as the top importer of commodities

    is due to a global shift in manufacturing, which also has

    manifested in a decline in energy imports into the U.S. and

    slow growth in Japan.

    shows the diversity in the mix o commodi-

    ties produced and exported, as well as

    some diversity in the ratio o commodities

    exported as a percentage o gross domestic

    product (GDP) across these countries.

    In this art icle, we examine the extent to

    which the business cycles in emerging coun-

    tries are highly dependent on fluctuations in

    the global prices o commodities. As a corol-

    lary, we show that the prospects o expan-

    sions and contractions or emerging countries

    are closely linked with the outlook or thecountries importing commodities. Addition-

    ally, we show how the changing composition

    o buyers o commodities has made emerg-

    ing markets increasingly susceptible to the

    whims o a single buyer: China. Indeed, the

    recent decline in commodity prices and the

    slowdown o growth in China go a long way

    in explaining the recent recessions in Brazil

    and Canada and may portend urther turmoil

    in many emerging markets.

    6 The Regional Economist|April 2016

  • 7/25/2019 Regional Economist - April 2016

    7/24

    E N D N O E S

    1 Tese deviations are computed using the Hodrick-

    Prescott filter, the most common method to separate

    business cycle components rom long-run trends. 2 See Fawley and Juvenal. 3 Te values or the coefficient o correlat ion o

    output and prices or all the emerging economies

    are positive and above 0.50, ranging rom 0.51 or

    Argentina to 0.80 or Brazil. 4 See Helbling.

    R E F E R E N C E S

    Fawley, Brett; and Juvenal, Luciana. Commodity

    Price Gains: Speculation vs. Fundamentals. Te

    Federal Reserve Bank o St. Louis Te Regional

    Economist,July 2011, Vol. 19, No. 3, pp. 4 -9.

    Helbling, Tomas. Commodities in Boom. Interna-

    tional Monetary Funds Finance and Development

    June 2012, Vol. 49, No. 2, pp. 30-31.

    dities over the past two decades. In 1990,

    China accounted or only 2 percent o all

    commodities traded, while the U.S. and Japanaccounted or about 15 percent each. By 2013,

    China was the leading commodity importer, at

    15 percent o global trade, while the U.S. and

    Japan had allen to 10 percent each. A similar

    trend holds i we consider only the market or

    energy commodities, e.g., oil, natural gas and

    coal. (India displays similar trends, although

    starting much later: In 2005, India accounted

    or 1 percent o all global imports o commod-

    ities; in 2013, it accounted or 5 percent.)

    Some o the rise o China as the top

    importer o commodities is due to a globalshif in manuacturing, which also has

    maniested in a decline in energy imports

    into the U.S. and slow growth in Japan.

    Moreover, since the early 2000s, the U.S.

    has increasingly relied on domestic energy

    sources, lowering its need or energy imports,

    while Japans lost decade led to a decline in

    trade. However, Chinas annual GDP growth

    rate averaged about 10 percent between 1990

    and 2013, and this high growth rate was

    accompanied by an ever-growing demand or

    industrial inputs. Indeed, Chinas growth wasshared by many emerging economies as they

    provided the exports to sustain Chinas surge.

    But these same economies must also share

    in Chinas slow-growth periods. Recently,

    Chinas growth rate has allen to about 6 or 7

    percent (still high compared with that o the

    U.S. and other developed countries today),

    and the uncertainty around Chinese growth

    has increased. All o these actors are behind

    the recent collapse in commodities prices.

    FIGURE 1

    Agriculture Food and Beverage Agriculture Raw Material Metals Energy

    Argentina

    Brazil

    Canada

    Chile

    Colombia

    Indonesia

    Mexico

    Russia

    South Africa

    Venezuela

    As a Percentage of GDP

    Commodity Exports as a Percentage of GDP in 2013

    SOURCES: Massachusetts Institute of Technology Observatory of Economic Complexity, Haver Analytics.

    NOTE: The figure shows the share of export in commodities as a percentage of real GDP as of 2013.

    Commodities are grouped following the Standard International Trade Classification, rev. 3.

    0 2 4 6 8 10 12 14 16 18 20

    FIGURE 2

    All Commodities (left axis)

    Quarter

    Argentina Brazil

    Canada Colombia Russia

    Cyclical Component of Prices and Output

    SOURCES: International Monetary Fund, Haver Analytics.

    NOTE: The figure plots the cyclical component of commodity prices (left axis) and output (right axis). The underlying commodity price data are

    normalized to 1 in the first quarter of 2000. The Hodrick-Prescott (HP) filter with smoothing parameter of 1600 was applied to quarterly data on

    prices and the natural logarithm of output (measured as real GDP) to obtain the cyclical component. The final data point is 2015:Q4 for prices

    data and is 2015:Q2 for output data.

    2000:Q

    1

    2001:Q

    1

    2002:Q

    1

    2003:Q

    1

    2004:Q

    1

    2005:Q

    1

    2006:Q

    1

    2007:Q

    1

    2008:Q

    1

    2009:Q

    1

    2010:Q

    1

    2011:Q

    1

    2012:Q

    1

    2013:Q

    1

    2014:Q

    1

    2015:Q

    1

    1.0

    0.8

    0.6

    0.4

    0.2

    0.0

    0.2

    0.4

    0.6

    0.8

    1.0

    CyclicalComponentofPrices

    0.02

    0.01

    0.00

    0.01

    0.02

    C

    yclicalComponentofOutput

    Conclusion

    It is striking how strongly commodities

    prices drive the overall economic fluctua-

    tions o emerging countries despite remark-

    able differences in their composition o

    commodities or export and their total

    export shares as a percentage o their GDP.

    Yet, or these countries a salient common

    actor emerges: the importance o China

    and its growth prospects.

    Alexander Monge-Naranjo is an economist andFaisal Sohail is a technical research associate,both at the Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis.For more on Monge-Naranjos work, see https://research.stlouisfed.org/econ/monge-naranjo.

    The Regional Economist | www.stlouisfed.org 7

  • 7/25/2019 Regional Economist - April 2016

    8/24

    By Yi Wen

    Chinas Rapid RiseFrom Backward Agrarian Society

    to Industrial Powerhousein Just 35 Years

    Chinas industrial revolution, which started 35 years ago, is perhapsone o the most important economic and geopolitical phenomenasince the original Industrial Revolution 250 years ago. Te reason is sim-

    ple: Less than 10 percent o the worlds population is ully industrialized;

    i China can successully finish its industrialization, an additional 20 per-

    cent o the worlds population will be entering modern times. Along the

    way, China is igniting new growth across Asia, Latin America, Arica andeven the industrial West, thanks to the countrys colossal demand or raw

    materials, energy, trade and capital flows.

    Chinas rapid growth has puzzled many people, including economists.

    THINKSTOC

    I N T E R N A T I O N A L

    8 The Regional Economist|April 2016

  • 7/25/2019 Regional Economist - April 2016

    9/24

    The Regional Economist|www.stlouisfed.org 9

    How could a nation with 1.4 billion

    people transorm itsel relatively suddenly

    rom a vastly impoverished agricultural

    land into a ormidable industrial power-

    house when so many tiny nations have been

    unable to do so despite their more avorable

    social-economic conditions? Among the

    many conflicting views that have emerged tointerpret Chinas rise, two stand out as the

    most popular and provocative. Te first sees

    Chinas hypergrowth as a gigantic govern-

    ment-engineered bubble. It is not sustain-

    able and will collapse because China has no

    democracy, no human rights, no reedom

    o speech, no rule o law, no Western-style

    legal system, no well-unctioning markets,

    no private banking sector, no protection

    o intellectual properties, no ability to

    innovate (other than copying and stealing

    Western technologies and business secrets),nor a host o many other things that the

    West has possessed or centuries and have

    proved essential or Western prosperity and

    technological dominance.1According to this

    view, the bubble will burst at the expense o

    Chinas people and environment.

    Te second view sees Chinas dramatic rise

    simply as destiny. It is returning to its histori-

    cal position: China had been one o the richest

    nations and greatest civilizations (alongside

    India) rom at least 200 B.C. to 1800, the dawn

    o the Industrial Revolution in England. (SeeFigure 1.) It was only a matter o time or

    China to reclaim its historical glory and domi-

    nate the world once again. (As Napoleon once

    said, Let China sleep, or when the dragon

    awakes, she will shake the world. 2)

    But neither view is backed by serious

    economic analysis, instead being based either

    on prejudice or nave extrapolation o human

    history. How could a nation with all those

    adverse elements or business and innovation

    be able to grow at a double-digit annual rate

    or several decades and transorm itsel in

    such a short time rom an impoverished agri-

    cultural economy into a ormidable manu-

    acturing powerhouse? I culture or ancient

    civilization is the explanation, then why

    arent Egyptian, Greek or Ottoman empires

    bursting onto the world stage?

    Tis article provides a different view o

    Chinas rise, one based on undamental

    economic analysis. It hopeully will lead to

    a better understanding o Chinas miracle

    growth but also will shed light on the ail-

    ures and successes o many other nations

    attempts at industrialization, including the

    original Industrial Revolution itsel.

    Admittedly, many people think Chinas

    economic miracle has come to an end. Te

    growth o its economy has declined sharplyrom the double digits to 7 percent or lower.

    Its stock market is in turmoil, and its cur-

    rency is under attack. But keep in mind that

    the United States experienced 15 financial

    crises and a our-year civil war as it rose to

    global prominence. It was on the verge o

    collapse in 1907 afer taking on the mantle

    o the worlds superpower rom the United

    Kingdom. Te U.S. also weathered the Great

    Depression in the 1930s and the global

    financial crisis in 2007. Does all o this mean

    it is no longer an economic star?

    Some Facts about Chinas Rise

    Tirty-five years ago, Chinas per capita

    income was only one-third o that o sub-

    Sahara Arica. oday, China is the worlds

    largest manuacturing powerhouse: It

    produces nearly 50 percent o the worlds

    major industrial goods, including crude steel

    (800 percent o the U.S. level and 50 percent

    o global supply), cement (60 percent o the

    worlds production), coal (50 percent o the

    worlds production), vehicles (more than25 percent o global supply) and industrial

    patent applications (about 150 percent o the

    U.S. level). China is also the worlds largest

    producer o ships, high-speed trains, robots,

    tunnels, bridges, highways, chemical fibers,

    machine tools, computers, cellphones, etc.

    Figure 2 shows the manuacturing out-

    put o the top five countries in the world

    between 1970 and 2013. In the early 1970s,

    when President Richard Nixon visited

    China, it produced very ew manuactured

    goodsa tiny raction o the U.S. level.

    About 1980, Chinas manuacturing started

    to take off, surpassing the industrial powers

    one by one, overtaking the U.S. in 2010 to

    become the No. 1 industrial powerhouse.

    The Secret Recipe

    How did China achieve this in 35 years?

    Te short answer is that China has redis-

    covered the secret recipe o the Industrial

    Among the many conflicting

    views that have emerged to

    interpret Chinas rise, two

    stand out as the most popu-

    lar and provocative. The first

    sees Chinas hypergrowth

    as a gigantic government-

    engineered bubble. The

    second view sees Chinas

    dramatic rise simply as

    destiny. But neither

    view is backed by serious

    economic analysis, instead

    being based either on preju-

    dice or nave extrapolation

    of human history.

  • 7/25/2019 Regional Economist - April 2016

    10/24

    Revolution. But what is the secret recipe,

    and why didnt China find it sooner?Te British Industrial Revolution was one

    o the most important socioeconomic events

    in human historyperhaps as significant as

    the discovery o fire and agriculture. Beore

    this revolution, humanity across all conti-

    nents had lived essentially at a subsistence

    level, stagnating in the so-called Malthusian

    trap.3But the Industrial Revolution changed

    it all: Starting about 1760, the living standard

    in the United Kingdom began to increase

    dramatically, leading to an era o permanent

    growth in per capita income. Because o thealmost magical increases in living standards

    and national income, among other things,

    almost every nation has tried to emulate the

    British Industrial Revolution.

    Unortunately, only a ew places have suc-

    ceeded: Northern and Western Europe, the

    United States, Japan and the Asian igers,

    among others. Although the Asian igers

    (South Korea, aiwan, Hong Kong and Sin-

    gapore) industrialized rather quickly afer

    WWII, some o them (such as aiwan) so

    ar have reached a per capita income o only

    about hal the U.S. level.

    Why have only a ew nations succeeded?

    Political institutions are the key, according

    to the institutional theory. Inclusive institu-

    tions (e.g., democracy) put restrictions on

    the elite class, allowing the ree market, ree

    trade, private property rights and the rule o

    law to flourish. Tis implies private incen-

    tives or wealth accumulation, innovation

    and growth. On the other hand, extractive

    institutions (such as dictatorship) imply the

    lack o not only reedom o choice but o

    protection o private-property rights and

    the rule o law, all o which leads to the lack

    o private incentives to work hard, accumu-

    late capital and innovate. Te end result is

    poverty. Tereore, the solution or endingpoverty is simple: democracy.4

    Or is it?

    Such theories are difficult to square with

    the acts. First, there are ample democracies

    with pervasive economic stagnation and

    continuous political turmoil: Aghanistan,

    Egypt, Iraq, Libya, Pakistan, Tailand,

    unisia and Ukraine, to name a ew. Second

    there are ample extractive institutions that

    have been economically strong, such as

    Germany (1850-WWII) and Russia (1860-

    WWII). Te institutional theory also cantexplain the dismal ailure o todays Russia

    at economic reorm under democracy and

    shock therapy, Japans rapid industrializa-

    tion during the Meiji Restoration, South

    Koreas economic takeoff in the 1960s-1980s

    under dictatorship or Singapores post-inde-

    pendence economic miracle. Nor can the

    theory explain why under identical political

    institutions, property rights and the rule o

    law, there exist pockets o both extreme pov-

    erty and extreme wealth, as well as o violent

    crime and obedience to law. Such dichoto-mies exist in many U.S. cities, or example.

    Italy is another example, with its poverty in

    the south and wealth in the north.

    Chinas Past Failures

    What is happening in China is not its first

    attempt at industrialization but the ourth

    over the past 120 years.

    Te first attempt was made between 1861

    and 1911. It came on the heels o Chinas deeat

    in 1860 by the British in the Second Opium

    War. Deeply humiliated by unequal trea-

    ties imposed by Western industrial powers,

    the Qing monarchy that was then in control

    in China embarked on a series o ambitious

    programs to modernize its backward agrarian

    economy, including establishing a modern

    navy and industrial system. Tis attempt

    started eight years earlier than the Meiji

    Restoration that triggered Japans successul

    industrialization. Fify years later, the effort in

    Economic History of China and Other Major Powers

    Non-Asian Ancient Civilizations

    (Greece, Egypt, Turkey, Iran)

    China

    Germany

    United States

    100%

    90%

    80%

    70%

    60%

    50%

    40%

    30%

    20%

    10%

    0%

    ShareofCu

    mulativeGDP

    India

    Japan

    Russia

    Italy

    Spain

    United Kingdom

    France

    1

    1000

    1500

    1600

    1700

    1820

    1850

    1870

    1900

    1913

    1940

    1950

    1960

    1970

    1980

    1990

    2000

    2010

    2014

    SOURCE: The Maddison-Project, http://

    www.ggdc.net/maddison/maddison-

    project/home.htm, 2013 version.

    NOTE: The cumulative gross domestic

    product is for all the countries listed and

    represents at least 70 percent of the total

    for the world at any given time, with the

    rest provided by smaller countries.

    FIGURE 1

    10 The Regional Economist|April 2016

  • 7/25/2019 Regional Economist - April 2016

    11/24

    China turned out to be a gigantic ailure: Te

    government was deep in debt, and the hoped-

    or industrial base was nowhere in sight.

    A nationwide demand or political

    reorms, ollowed by social turmoil, ulti-

    mately led to the 1911 Xinhai Revolution. It

    overthrew the extractive Qing monarchy

    and established the Republic o China,the first inclusive government in China

    based on Western-style constitutions. Te

    new republic tried to industrialize China

    by a wholesale mimicking o U.S. political

    institutions, including democracy and the

    separation o powers (legislative, executive

    and judicial branches o government).

    At that time, a amous slogan among the

    Chinese was Only science and democracy

    can save China. Te revolutionaries o the

    educated elite believed that the monarchys

    ailure to industrialize and Chinas overallbackwardness were due to its lack o democ-

    racy, political inclusiveness and pluralism

    (exactly as the modern institutionalism theory

    has argued). But 40 years passed, and China

    remained one o the poorest nations on earth.

    In 1949, the republic was deeated by

    the Communist peasant army. Te new

    government initiated the third ambitious

    attempt to industrialize Chinathis time by

    mimicking the Soviet Unions central plan-

    ning model. Tirty years passed, and the

    effort ailed again: In 1978, China remainedessentially in the same Malthusian poverty

    trap, with per capita income not signifi-

    cantly different rom what it was around the

    Second Opium War.

    Hence, the reason or Chinas three

    ailures was clearly not the lack o ree

    market and private-property rightsthe

    Qing dynasty had probably a better market

    system and better private-property rights

    than did England and the rest o Europe in

    the 17th and 18th centuries. Nor was it the

    lack o democracythe government o the

    Republic o China was so inclusive that even

    members o the Communist Party were

    allowed in the government.

    What Was Different This Time?

    Chinas ourth attempt started in 1978 under

    leader Deng Xiaoping. Te country reused to

    take advice rom Western economists (unlike

    what Russia did in the 1990s) and instead

    took a very humble, gradualist, experimental

    approach with its economic reorms. Te keys

    to this approach have been to:

    1. maintain political stability at all costs;

    2. ocus on the grassroots, bottom-up

    reorms (starting in agriculture instead oin the financial sector);

    3. promote rural industries despite their

    primitive technologies;

    4. use manuactured goods (instead o

    only natural resources) to exchange or

    machinery;

    5. provide enormous government support

    or inrastructure buildup;

    6. ollow a dual-track system o government/

    private ownership instead o wholesale

    privatization; and

    7. move up the industrial ladder, rom lightto heavy industries, rom labor- to capital-

    intensive production, rom manuactur-

    ing to financial capitalism, and rom

    a high-saving state to a consumeristic

    welare state.

    Chinas ourth attempt mimics the

    historical sequence o the British Industrial

    Revolution, despite dramatic differences in

    political institutions. (Afer all, China is still

    an authoritarian state.) Te British Indus-

    trial Revolution ollowed five key stages:

    1. the proto-industrialization stage, which

    developed rural industries or long-

    distance trade;

    2. the first industrial revolution, which ea-

    tured labor-intensive mass production or

    the mass market;

    3. the industrial trinity boom, which

    involved the mass supply o energy,

    locomotive power and inrastructure to

    acilitate mass distribution;5

    1970 1975 1980 1985 1990 1995 2000 2005 2010

    3,500

    3,000

    2,500

    2,000

    1,500

    1,000

    500

    0

    U.

    S.d

    ollars,

    billions

    Manufacturing Output for Top Five Countries in 2013

    SOURCE: United Nations.

    China

    United States

    Japan

    Germany

    Russia

    FIGURE 2

    The Regional Economist| www.stlouisfed.org11

  • 7/25/2019 Regional Economist - April 2016

    12/24

    4. the second industrial revolution, eaturing

    the mass production o the means o mass

    production, such as steel and machine

    tools (including agricultural machinery),

    as well as the creation o a large credit

    system; and

    5. the welare state stage, which incorporates

    economic welare (such as the modernservice economy, unemployment insurance,

    equal access to health care and education,

    and a ull-fledged social saety net) and

    political welare (such as democracy, human

    rights, the end o the death penalty, legaliza-

    tion o gay marriage).

    Along such a development path, democ-

    racy is the consequence instead o the cause

    o industrialization. Democracy reinorces

    stability only in industrialized societies.

    Almost all successully industrialized econ-

    omies have gone through these key stages inhistory, as the ollowing examples show:

    U.K. path to industrialization: 6

    1. 1600-1760: Proto-industria lization in

    rural areas, organized and financed by

    rich merchants (e.g., via the putting-out

    system7);

    2. 1760-1830: first industrial revolution

    in textile industries, relying on wood-

    ramed and water-powered textile

    machines or mass production;

    3. 1830-1850: boom in industrial trinity:energy (such as coal), transportation

    (such as railroad) and locomotive (such

    as steam engine);

    4. 1850-1900: second industrial revolution,

    involving the mass production o the

    means o mass production, such as iron,

    steel, chemicals and machinery; and

    5. Afer 1900: entering the welare state

    (e.g., universal suffrage in 1928).

    U.S. path to industrialization:

    1. Beore 1820: rural industries mushroom-

    ing in the countryside;

    2. 1820-1860: first industrial revolution

    mass production o textiles, based on

    imported or stolen British technologies;

    3. 1830-1870: boom in industrial trinity,

    such as the 1828-1873 railroad mania;

    4. 1870-1940: second industrial revolution,

    eaturing mass production o steel, automo-

    biles, telecommunications, chemicals and

    mechanized agriculture in the 1940s; and

    5. 1940s-present: entering the welare state

    afer WWII with such key steps as the

    civil rights movement in the 1960s, uni-

    versal suffrage in 1965, Violence Against

    Women Act o 1994 and legalization o

    same-sex marriage in 2015.

    Japans path to industrialization:

    1. 1603-1868 (the Edo period): commercial

    agriculture and rural artisan manuactur

    ing flourished amid political stability;

    2. 1868-1890 (early Meiji): ull-fledged

    proto-industrialization;

    3. 1890-1920 (including late Meiji): first

    industrial revolution, based on mass pro-

    duction o textiles, relying on imported

    machinery and exports o labor-intensive

    textile products;

    4. 1900-1930: boom in industrial trinity(e.g., railroads);

    5. 1920-1941: beginning o second industrial

    revolution; and

    6. 1945-1980: continuation o second indus-

    trial revolution, democratic reorm under

    U.S. occupation, entering welare state.

    Chinas Path

    China compressed the several centuries

    o Western (and Japanese) development into

    three decades. Its path to industrialization

    has gone through three major phases:1. 1978-1988: proto-industrialization. Tis

    phase eatured the sprouting o millions

    o rural enterprises (collectively instead o

    privately owned by armers) across Chinas

    vast countryside and small towns; these

    enterprises acted as the engine o national

    economic growth during the first 10 years

    o economic reorm. Te number o village

    firms increased more than 12-old (rom

    1.5 million to 18.9 million), village industrial

    gross output increased more than 13.5-old

    (rom 14 percent o gross domestic prod-

    uct, or GDP, to 46 percent o GDP), village

    peasant-workers grew to nearly 100

    million by 1988, and armers aggregate

    wage income increased 12-old. Because

    o such phenomenal growth in the supply

    o basic consumer goods, China ended its

    shortage economy (a typical eature o all

    centrally planned economies, character-

    ized by the rationing o meat, other ood,

    Along such a development

    path, democracy is the conse-

    quence instead of the cause

    of industrialization. Democracy

    reinforces stability only in

    industrialized societies. Almostall successfully industrialized

    economies have gone through

    these key stages in history. ...

    12 The Regional Economist|April 2016

  • 7/25/2019 Regional Economist - April 2016

    13/24

    clothes and other basic consumer goods) in

    the mid-1980s and simultaneously solved

    its ood security problem. Te 800 million

    armers were the biggest beneficiaries o

    the economic reorm in this period.

    2. 1988-1998: first industrial revolution. Tis

    phase eatured mass production o labor-

    intensive light consumer goods acrossChinas rural and urban areas, relying

    first mainly on imported machinery. Dur-

    ing this period, China became the worlds

    largest producer and exporter o textiles,

    the largest producer and importer o cot-

    ton, and the largest producer and exporter

    o urniture and toys. Rural enterprises

    continued their hypergrowth, and their

    workers reached 30 percent o Chinas

    entire rural labor orce (not including

    migrant workers). Village industrial out-

    put grew by 28 percent per year, doublingevery three years (an astronomical 66-old

    increase) between 1978 and 2000.

    3. 1998-present: second industrial revo-

    lution. Tis phase eatured the mass

    production o the means o mass pro-

    duction. Because o the rapidly and

    enormously expanding domestic market

    or intermediate goods, machinery and

    transportation, there was a big surge in

    the consumption and production o coal,

    steel, cement, chemical fibers, machine

    tools, highways, bridges, tunnels, ships,etc. In all, 2.6 million miles o public

    roads were built, including more than

    70,000 miles o express highways (46 per-

    cent more than in the U.S.). wenty-eight

    provinces (out o 30) have high-speed

    trains (with total length exceeding 10,000

    miles, 50 percent more than the total or

    the rest o the world).

    The Triumph of Marketism?

    Is Chinas achievement the triumph o

    marketism? Yes and no. Yes or obvious

    reasons: Markets impose economic incen-

    tives to compete, impose discipline on

    management and on technology adoption,

    and create Darwinian creative destruction

    to eliminate losers.

    But no or overlooked reasons: Its

    extremely costly or independent, anarchic,

    uneducated peasants to orm cooperatives

    unless social trust and markets exist; its also

    extremely costly to create a unified national

    mass market and a global market to support

    the division o labor and mass production;

    and it is especially costly to create market

    regulatory institutions to prevent cheating

    and raud. Tese costs prevented the prior

    ormation o industries and, thus, explain the

    ailures o the Qing dynasty and the Repub-lic o China to kick-start Chinas industrial

    revolution in the 19th and early part o the

    20th centuries, despite their having private-

    property rights and even democracy.

    Te poverty o nations is caused by their

    inability to mass-produce consumption goods.

    But mass production requires mass markets

    and mass distribution to render it profitable.

    Where does the mass (world) market

    come rom? Early European powers relied

    on a mercantilist state government and

    militarized merchants to create monopo-listic global markets through colonialism,

    imperialism and slave trade. In particu-

    lar, generations o British monarchs and

    merchants (e.g., the British East India Co.)

    helped create or England the worlds largest

    textile market, cotton supply chains and

    trading networks that kick-started the origi-

    nal Industrial Revolution.

    oday, developing nations no longer have

    such privilege or the time to nurture such

    a powerul merchant class to create markets.

    Hence, governments play a bigger role inmarket creation.

    Tereore, the ongoing industrial revolu-

    tion in China has been driven not by

    technology adoption per se, but instead by

    continuous market creation led by a capable

    mercantilist government; the market cre-

    ation is based on mutually beneficial trade

    instead o the gunboat diplomacy methods

    o earlier Western powers.8

    The Secret Is Sequencing

    Democracy and laissez-aire do not

    automatically create a global market. Mar-

    ket creation requires state power, correct

    developmental strategies and correct indus-

    trial policies. Te ree market is actually

    extremely costly to create.9

    As weve already seen, the development

    o an industrial market is a sequential

    process (rom the agricultural and artisan

    stage to the proto-industrial market and so

    THINKSTOCK/TOP

    The Regional Economist|www.stlouisfed.org13

  • 7/25/2019 Regional Economist - April 2016

    14/24

    E N D N O E S

    1See Chang. 2 See Jacques or http://wander ingchina.blogspot.

    com/2008/08/napoleon-and-his-view-on-china.

    html. 3 Te Malthusian trap, named afer the 19th cen-

    tury British political economist Tomas Robert

    Malthus, suggests that or most o human history,

    income was largely stagnant because technological

    advances and discoveries only resulted in more

    people, rather than improvements in the standardo living. It is argued that many countries in tropical

    Arica still find themselves in the Malthusian trap. 4 See Acemoglu and Robinson.5 Te specific components o the industrial trinity

    evolve over time. In terms o energy, it was coal in

    the 19th century, oil in the 20th century and solar

    power in the 21st century. In terms o communi-

    cation, it was the telegraph in the 19th century,

    the telephone in the 20th century and electronic

    mail in the 21st century. 6 Te demarcations o the stages are approxima-

    tions and can never be exact, and they ofen tend

    to overlap with each other or a substantial period

    o time. But a higher stage always appears later

    than a lower stage in history or the successul ly

    industrialized nations, whereas the unsuccessullyindustrialized nations tend to directly jump i nto

    higher stages by skipping earlier stages. 7 Te putting-out system was a system o ami ly-

    based domestic manuacturing that was prevalent

    in rural a reas o western Europe during the 17th

    and 18th centuries. Domestic workers involved in

    this system typically owned their own primitive

    tools (such as looms and spinning wheels) but

    depended on merchant capitalists to provide them

    with the raw materials to ashion products, which

    were deemed the property o the merchants. Semi

    finished products would be passed on by the mer-

    chant to another workplace or urther processing

    while finished products would be taken direct ly to

    market by the merchants. 8 In this regard, China contributed to and also ben-

    efited rom the postwar peaceul world order cre-ated by the joint efforts o developing countries,

    their independence movements and the industrial

    world powers, especially the United States.9 See Wen or more detail ed analysis.

    10 A theoretical ramework or why successul in-

    dustrialization must go through stages is provided

    in my orthcoming book, titled Te Making of an

    Economic Superpower: Unlocking Chinas Secret

    of Rapid Industrialization. See https://research.

    stlouised.org/econ/wen/sel.

    R E F E R E N C E S

    Acemoglu, Daron; and Robinson, James A. Why

    Nations Fail.New York: Crown Publishers, 2012.

    Chang, Gordon G. Te Coming Collapse of China.

    New York: Random House, 2001.

    Jacques, Martin. When China Rules the World: Te

    End of the Western World and the Birth of a New

    Global Order.Second Edition. London: Penguin

    Press, 2012, 2nd edition.

    Wen, Yi. Te Making of an Economic Superpower:

    Unlocking Chinas Secret of Rapid Industrializa-

    tion.St. Louis Fed Working Paper 2015-006B,

    2015. See https://research.stlouised.org/wp/

    more/2015-006.

    on). No matter how late a nation starts its

    development, it must repeat earlier stages to

    succeed.10It is like learning mathematics.

    Trough thousands o years o development,

    the human race discovered math knowledge

    sequentially: rom numbers to arithmetic to

    algebra to calculus, etc. Although calculus

    is in todays first-year college textbooks,every generation o children must still

    repeat humanitys evolutionary process to

    learn math. Tey do not jump to calculus

    at age 6; instead they start with learning

    numbers (with the help o their fingers, just

    like our ancestors did) and gradually move

    up the ladder.

    In contrast, modern economic theories

    teach poor countries to leap orward, to

    start industrialization by building advanced

    capital-intensive industries (such as chemical,

    steel and automobile industries), by settingup modern financial systems (such as a float-

    ing exchange rate, ree international capital

    flows, and ully fledged privatization o state-

    owned properties and natural resources)

    or by erecting modern political institutions

    (such as democracy and universal suffrage).

    But such top-down approaches violate the

    historical sequence o the Industrial Revolu-

    tion and have led to political chaos, develop-

    mental disorders and deormed capitalism

    in Arica, Latin America, Southeast Asia and

    the Middle East.

    Challenges Ahead

    As China has industrialized, it has

    picked up not only the posit ives o Western

    development but the negatives, including

    rampant corruption and organized crime,

    unprecedented pollution and environmental

    destruction, rising divorce and suicide rates,

    widespread business raud and scandals,

    markets ull o lemons and low-quality

    goods, pervasive asset bubbles, rising

    income inequality and class discrimina-

    tion, requent industrial accidents, etc. And

    there are other challenges, including build-

    ing social saety nets, finishing social and

    economic reorms in the health care and

    education sectors, finishing rural urbaniza-

    tion and agricultural modernization, estab-

    lishing modern financial inrastructure and

    regulatory institutions as in the U.K. and

    U.S., and establishing a modern legal system

    as in Hong Kong and Singapore.

    However, as long as China ollows the

    right sequence o economic development,

    these problems should be merely growing

    pains and not the same daunting structural

    obstacles like the Malthusian poverty trap

    or the middle-income trap aced by many

    developing nations in Arica, Latin Amer-ica, the Middle East and Southeast Asia.

    Conclusion

    Ever since the 15th century, the spirit o

    capitalism has been shake hands and do

    business, regardless o ideology, religion,

    culture and national boundary. It is pre-

    cisely such a spirit that has created modern

    industrial civilization and will continue to

    change the world.

    For a hal-century afer World War II, the

    U.S. pursued one o historys most success-ul nation-building win-win strategies: It

    nurtured the rebuilding o Europe and Japan

    and the development o other poor coun-

    tries and bonded them economically. China

    today seems to be carrying the U.S. banner

    orward: China is pursuing win-win develop-

    ment strategies, too, that are ocused on eco-

    nomics. It is doing so through global business

    engagement and international inrastructure

    buildup regardless o religion, culture, politi-

    cal system and national boundary.

    Chinas rise provides a golden opportunity

    or developing nations to ride or ree on the

    China train. But how much each individual

    nation can benefit rom Chinas rise depends

    entirely on its own worldview, development

    strategies and industrial policies.

    Meanwhile, the 21st century appears to be

    shaping up as Chinas century.

    Yi Wen, a native of China, is an economistat the Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis. Tis

    article is based on a lecture of his in November(see www.stlouisfed.org/dialogue-with-the-fed/chinas-industrial-revolution-past-present-future), which drew heavily from his forthcom-ing book, titled Te Making o an EconomicSuperpower: Unlocking Chinas Secret oRapid Industrialization.For the working paperversion of the book, see his website at https://research.stlouisfed.org/econ/wen. Wen wouldlike to thank William R. Emmons, also aneconomist at the St. Louis Fed, for commentsand Maria A. Arias, a senior research associateat the Bank, for research assistance.

    14 The Regional Economist | April 2016

  • 7/25/2019 Regional Economist - April 2016

    15/24

    Most people are aware that decisionsby the Federal Reserve (Fed) affectmarket interest rates. Tese decisions have

    consequences or the interest rates that con-

    sumers pay on mortgage loans, credit cards

    and auto loans, and or the interest rates

    aced by businesses on bank loans, corpo-rate bonds and commercial paper.

    But there is more than one interest rate

    that the Fed sets, either as a target or by

    administrative fiat. Many people are aware

    o the target or the ederal unds rate, or ed

    unds rate, that the Federal Open Market

    Committee (FOMC) o the Fed sets at its

    eight regular meetings a year. Te ed unds

    rate is an interest rate on overnight credit

    arrangements among financial institu-

    tionsthat is, a very short-term interest

    rate. Te Fed also sets the discount rate, orthe interest rate on primary credit, which

    is an interest rate at which the Fed lends

    to commercial banks in its role as a lender

    o last resort. Still another rate is that on

    interest paid by the Fed on reserves. Banks

    hold reserve accounts with the Fed; these

    accounts essentially play the role o checking

    accounts or financial institutions. (A reserve

    account is useul when a bank needs to make

    large payments to other financial institu-

    tions.) Tus, a reserve account is a loan to the

    Fed rom a bank. Beore late 2008, reserveaccounts paid zero interest, as dictated by

    Congress in the Federal Reserve Act.

    Prior to the financial crisis (late 2007

    through 2008), the Fed conducted monetary

    policy within what economists call a chan-

    nel system. Te Fed targeted the overnight

    ed unds rate within a channel, with the

    discount rate as the upper bound on the

    channel and the interest rate on reserves

    as the lower bound on the channel. For

    Interest Rate ControlIs More Complicated

    Than You Thought

    F E D E R A L R E S E R V E S Y S T E M

    By Stephen Williamson

    FEDERAL RESERVE BOARD

    example, in January 2007, the discount rate

    was set at 6.25 percent, the ed unds rate was

    targeted at 5.25 percent and the interest rate

    on reserves was 0 percent. Te ed unds rate

    could not, in principle, go above the discount

    rate because no bank would choose to borrow

    rom another bank at an interest rate higher

    than the rate at which it could borrow romthe Fed (the discount rate). Similarly, no bank

    would lend to another bank at an interest rate

    lower than the interest rate it could receive

    rom the Fed (the interest rate on reserves).

    In 2007, the New York Fed would intervene

    every day in financial marketsthrough open

    market operations, which are the purchase

    and sale o assets by the Fedto try to bring

    the ed unds rate as close as possible

    to the target set by the FOMC.

    But between 2007 and now, the details

    o how the Fed conducts monetary policy

    have changed in important ways. First, since

    late 2008, the reserves held at the Fed by

    financial institutions have earned interest;

    such interest payments are allowed under

    an amendment to the Federal Reserve Actpassed by Congress. Further, and more

    importantly, the interest rate on excess

    reserves, or IOER, is set by the Fed and

    can be changed over time.

    Second, during the Great Recession (late

    2007 to mid-2009) and its afermath, the Fed

    engaged in some unconventional monetary

    policy actions. For our purposes, the most

    important o these was a program o large-

    scale asset purchases, sometimes known as

    quantitative easing. Tis program led to a

    large increase in the stock o reserves at theFedeffectively, the Fed purchased a large

    quantity o assets (U.S. reasury securities

    and agency mortgage-backed securities) by

    issuing more reserves.

    For the Fed, the large stock o reserves

    outstanding implies that monetary policy

    works differently nowwithin afloor

    system rather than a channel system. In a

    floor system, the IOER plays a key role. In

    principle, what should happen in a floor

    system is that, with plenty o reserves in the

    system, the Fed can achieve its target or theed unds rate by simply setting the IOER.

    Why? I the ed unds rate were lower than

    the IOER, then banks would be able to make

    a profit rom borrowing on the ed unds

    market and lending to the Fed at the IOER,

    thus orcing up the ed unds rate. I the ed

    unds rate were higher than the IOER, then

    a bank wanting to lend would earn more

    interest on the ed unds market than by

    lending to the Fed at the IOER. Te large

    Also by Stephen Williamson

    The St. Louis Fed has just released its annual report.

    The main essay, written by Williamson, is about the

    Feds return to normal monetary policy after seven

    years of abnormally low interest rates. St. Louis Fed

    President and CEO James Bullard also addresses this

    topic. Elsewhere in the annual report, the St. Louis

    Feds work, people, mission and results are featured.

    To read the report online, go to www.stlouisfed.org/

    annual-report.

    The Regional Economist |www.stlouisfed.org 15

  • 7/25/2019 Regional Economist - April 2016

    16/24

    demand or ed unds would then orce the

    ed unds rate down.

    According to this logic, controlling the

    ed unds rate should be easy or the Fed

    under a floor system. But theory and reality

    sometimes do not agree. From late 2008 to

    December 2015, the IOER was set at 0.25 per-

    cent. However, contrary to what many people

    might think, since early 2009 the ed unds

    rate has generally been 5 to 20 basis points

    (one basis point is equal to 0.01 percentage

    points) lower than the IOER. Tis difference

    between the IOER and the ed unds rate is

    typically ascribed to costs or commercial

    banks associated with borrowing on the ed

    unds market.1

    Te persistent difference between the

    IOER and the ed unds rate was a concern

    or the Fed as it anticipated the time when

    lifoff would occur, where lifoff reers

    to the date at which the Fed would departrom its long period (since late 2008) o

    zero interest rate policy, or ZIRP. Could the

    Fed expect that the ed unds rate would

    increase along with the IOER i the Fed

    attempted to control the ed unds rate only

    through increases in the IOER?

    Te solution adopted by the Fed is unique

    in central bankinga floor system with a

    subfloor. Te New York Fed, in intervening

    in overnight financial markets, is now mak-

    ing use o an overnight reverse repurchase

    agreement (ON-RRP) acility. ON-RRPs areessentially reserves by another name. In ON-

    RRP transactions, financial institutions lend

    to the Fed, just as they do when they hold

    reserve accounts with the Fed. Te difference

    between reserves and ON-RRPs is that, in an

    ON-RRP arrangement, the Fed posts securi-

    ties in its portolio as collateral, just as in any

    private repurchase agreement transaction.

    A repurchase agreement is simply a special

    kind o financial market loan that is secured

    by collateral just as, or example, your mort-

    gage is secured by your house, which can beseized i you deault on the mortgage.

    Without getting into all the details,2the

    idea behind the floor-with-subfloor system

    is that the Fed sets, along with the discount

    rate and IOER, an ON-RRP rate, which is

    the rate at which financial institutions can

    lend to the Fed in the market or repurchase

    agreements. Te ON-RRP rate is set below

    the IOER, and then policy is announced as a

    target range or the ed unds rate, with the

    top o the range given by the IOER and the

    bottom o the range determined by the ON-

    RRP rate. Tus, the IOER sets the floor, and

    the ON-RRP rate sets the subfloor.

    But could this system work? On Dec. 16,

    2015, the FOMC decided to increase the

    target range or the ederal unds rate rom

    0-0.25 percent to 0.25-0.50 percent,3

    withthe discount rate at 1.0 percent, the IOER

    at 0.50 percent and the ON-RRP rate set at

    0.25 percent.

    As shown in Figure 1, the value o

    ON-RRPs outstanding increased rom

    $105 bill ion on Dec. 17, 2015, to $475 bil lion

    on Dec. 31, ollowing which the quantity

    dropped back to the neighborhood o

    $100 billion. In the ed unds market, as

    shown in Figure 2, the average daily ed

    FIGURE 1

    FIGURE 2

    12/17/15

    12/19/15

    12/21/15

    12/23/15

    12/25/15

    12/27/15

    12/29/15

    12/31/15

    01/02/16

    01/04/16

    01/06/16

    01/08/16

    01/10/16

    01/12/16

    01/14/16

    01/16/16

    01/18/16

    0 1 / 2 0 / 1 6

    0.6

    0.5

    0.4

    0.3

    0.2

    0.1

    0.0

    PercentPerAnnum

    A Floor and a Subfloor for the Federal Funds Rate

    SOURCES: Federal Reserve Board/Haver Analytics.

    IOER Federal Funds Rate ON-RRP Rate

    NOTE: In principle, the large stock of reserves outstanding should result in the fed funds rate equaling the interest on excess

    reserves (IOER), but economic factors have resulted in the former rate running below the latter. The rate for overnight reverserepurchase agreements (ON-RRP) should serve as a secondary floor for the fed funds rate, and it largely has. The only time

    the fed funds rate has fallen below the ON-RRP rate since liftoff was Dec. 31, 2015, and this is likely explained, in part, by

    the fact that financial reporting took place on that day and the fact that there are differences in the time frames of f ed funds

    and ON-RRP transactions.

    Dec. 31

    12/17/15

    12/20/15

    12/23/15

    12/26/15

    12/29/15

    01/01/16

    01/04/16

    01/07/16

    01/10/16

    01/13/16

    01/16/16

    01/19/16

    01/22/16

    500

    400

    300

    200

    100

    0

    Billi

    ons

    ofDollars

    Value of ON-RRPs Outstanding

    SOURCES: Federal Reserve Board/Haver Analytics. NOTE: ON-RRP stands for overnight reverse repurchase agreement.

    Dec. 31

    unds rate has typically been within a tight

    range o 0.35-0.37 percent, except on Dec. 31,

    2015, when the average rate was 0.20 per-

    cent. Tus, in terms o results, the Fed has

    been successul in controlling the ed unds

    rate within the 0.25-0.50 percent range.

    But why was the average ed unds rate

    so low and the ON-RRP quantity so highon Dec. 31, 2015? Tis date was both the

    quarter-end and year-end, which is impor-

    tant because at this time financial reporting

    takes place and financial institutions want to

    have their balance sheets appear as avorable

    as possible to their shareholders and regula-

    tors. Lending on the ed unds market can be

    a risky activity, as lending is unsecured, while

    lending to the Fed in the orm o ON-RRPs

    is essentially riskless. Tereore, we might

    16 The Regional Economist | April 2016

  • 7/25/2019 Regional Economist - April 2016

    17/24

    On the web version of this issue, 11 more charts are available, with much of those charts data specific to the Eighth District.

    Among the areas they cover are agriculture, commercial banking, housing permits, income and jobs. To see those charts, go to

    www.stlouisfed.org/economyataglance.

    U . S . A G R I C U L T U R A L T R A D E AVERAGE LAND VALUES ACROSS THE EIGHTH DISTRICT

    15 1611 12 13 14

    90

    75

    60

    45

    30

    15

    0

    NOTE: Data are aggregated over the past 12 months.

    Exports

    Imports

    FebruaryTrade Balance

    BILLIONS

    OFD

    OLLARS

    2014:Q4 2015:Q1 2015:Q2 2015:Q3 2015:Q4

    6

    4

    2

    0

    2

    4

    6

    YEAR-

    OVER-

    YEAR

    PER

    CENT

    CHANGE

    Quality Farmland

    Ranchland or Pastureland

    SOURCE: Agricultural Finance Monitor.

    C I V I L I A N U N E M P L O Y M E N T R A T E I N T E R E S T R A T E S

    11 12 13 14 15 16

    10

    9

    8

    7

    6

    5

    4

    3

    PERCENT

    March

    11 12 13 14 15 16

    4

    3

    2

    1

    0

    10-Year Treasury

    Fed Funds TargetFebruary

    1-Year Treasury

    PERCENT

    NOTE: On Dec. 16, 2015, the FOMC set a target range for the

    federal funds rate of 0.25 to 0.5 percent. The observations

    plotted since then are the midpoint of the range (0.375 percent).

    I N F L A T I O N - I N D E X E D T R E A S U R Y Y I E L D S P R E A D S R AT ES ON FE DE RA L F UN DS FU TU RE S O N S EL EC TE D D AT ES

    3.00

    2.75

    2.50

    2.25

    2.00

    1.75

    1.50

    1.25

    1.00

    NOTE: Weekly data.

    5-Year

    10-Year

    20-Year

    PERCENT

    April 8, 2016

    12 13 14 15 161st-Expiring

    Contract3-Month 6-Month 12-Month

    0.8

    0.7

    0.6

    0.5

    0.4

    0.3

    0.2

    0.1

    0.0

    CONTRACT SETTLEMENT MONTH

    PERCENT

    10/28/15

    12 /1 6/ 15 3 /1 6/ 16

    1/27/16

    R E A L G D P G R O W T H C O N S U M E R P R I C E I N D E X ( C P I )

    10 11 12 13 14 15

    6

    4

    2

    0

    2

    NOTE: Each bar is a one-quarter growth rate (annualized);

    the red line is the 10-year growth rate.

    PERCENT

    Q4

    11 12 13 14 15 16

    4

    2

    0

    2PERCENT

    CHANGE

    FROM

    A

    YEAR

    EARLIER

    March

    CPIAll Items

    All Items, Less Food and Energy

    E C O N O M Y A T A G L A N C E

    expect that, on Dec. 31, lenders in the over-

    night market would shif their activity rom

    the ed unds market to the ON-RRP market,

    as this would reduce risk on their balance

    sheets. Sure enough, we saw a large increase

    in ON-RRP activity on Dec. 31.

    Still, why were ed unds market lenders

    accepting an average interest rate o 0.20

    percent on Dec. 31, 2015, which is lower

    than the ON-RRP rate on that date, and why

    were some participants accepting interest

    rates as low as 0.08 percent? A potential

    explanation or this is that ed unds market

    trades and ON-RRP trades are very differ-

    ent in terms o the time o the day lending

    occurs and when the loan is paid back the

    next day. In particular, ON-RRP borrow-

    ing by the Fed occurs between 12:45 and

    1:15 p.m. E, and loans are paid back the

    next day between 3:30 and 5:15 p.m. E.

    However, a ed unds transaction can occuras late as 6:30 p.m., with unds potentially

    returned early the next day.4So, while a ed

    unds market transaction may be riskier

    because lending is unsecured, it is also more

    liquid, as lending can occur later in the day

    and unds can be returned more quickly the

    next day. Tus, lenders may be willing to pay

    or liquidity with a lower overnight interest

    rate, and this would have a larger effect at

    the quarter-end, when trading on the ed

    unds market is thin.

    Stephen Williamson is an economist at theFederal Reserve Bank of St. Louis. For more onhis work, see https://research.stlouisfed.org/econ/williamson. Research assistance was providedby Jonas Crews, a research analyst at the Bank.

    E N D N O E S

    1See Williamson.2 See Williamson or more inormation.3 See Board o Governors.4 See Bartolini, Hilton and McAndrews or more

    inormation on the timing o transactions.

    R E F E R E N C E S

    Bartolini, Leonardo; Hilton, Spence; and McAndrews,James. Settlement Delays in the Money Market.New York Federal Reserve Bank Staff Reports,2008,No. 319. See www.newyorked.org/medialibrary/media/research/staff_reports/sr319.pd.

    Board o Governors o the Federal Reserve System. PressRelease,Dec. 16, 2015. See www.ederalreserve.gov/newsevents/press/monetary/20151216a.htm.

    Williamson, Stephen D. Monetary Policy Normali-zation in the United States. Federal Reserve Banko St. Louis Review, 2015, Vol. 97, No. 2, pp. 87-108.See https://research.stlouised.org/publications/

    review/2015/q2/Williamson.pd.

    The Regional Economist |www.stlouisfed.org 17

  • 7/25/2019 Regional Economist - April 2016

    18/24

    D I S T R I C T O V E R V I E W

    Immigration Patterns in the District

    Differ in Some Ways from the NationsThe Eighth Federal Reserve Districtis composed of four zones, each of

    which is centered around one of

    the four main cities: Little Rock,

    Louisville, Memphis and St. Louis.

    By Subhayu Bandyopadhyay and Rodrigo Guerrero

    Immigration has a variety o economiceffects on a nation. For example, immi-grants may provide employers with cheaper

    or more-skilled labor than what the native

    population provides, which makes the

    host nation more competitive in its export

    markets. Domestic consumers may benefitrom lower prices due to greater production

    efficiencies. On the negative side, immigra