Property Outline.doc

79
I. Introduction A. Ownership is a bundle of rights B. Is there a natural human instinct for property ownership? C. Goffman: Asylums 1. In spite of efforts of administration, people try to possess certain things. 2. Strongest take what they want – associated with “bad wards” 3. First come, first served – associated with “good wards” D. Pipes: Human nature and the fall of communism 1. Even animals have “ownership” – they’re possessive about things. 2. Studies of young children showed that some of the first concepts they understand, as well as their initial communications/conflicts, center around property/ownership. 3. The Bolshevik revolution led to widespread corruption and a decline in public spirit. This led to a decline in the will to live – “collective depression.” E. Lockean labor theory: you have property in your person, and so the labor of your body is yours. 1

Transcript of Property Outline.doc

Page 1: Property Outline.doc

I. IntroductionA. Ownership is a bundle of rightsB. Is there a natural human instinct for property ownership?C. Goffman: Asylums

1. In spite of efforts of administration, people try to possess certain things.2. Strongest take what they want – associated with “bad wards”3. First come, first served – associated with “good wards”

D. Pipes: Human nature and the fall of communism1. Even animals have “ownership” – they’re possessive about things.2. Studies of young children showed that some of the first concepts they understand, as

well as their initial communications/conflicts, center around property/ownership.3. The Bolshevik revolution led to widespread corruption and a decline in public spirit.

This led to a decline in the will to live – “collective depression.”E. Lockean labor theory: you have property in your person, and so the labor of your body is

yours.

1

Page 2: Property Outline.doc

II. First possessionA. Acquisition by discovery/conquest, and capture

1. Discovery/conquest and the origins of property in landa. Johnson v. M’Intosh (US 1823)

i. P purchased land from Indians; D purchased land from the government.ii. Is title by grant from a discovering nation superior to title obtained by

purchased from those that the nation conquered?iii. Yes. Discovery of land in America by a European power gives absolute title

subject only to the Indian right of occupancy. Two principles at stake: doctrine of discovery and first possessor’s rights.

iv. What are the rights of one European nation vis-à-vis other European nations?(i) The nation that discovers the land has superior ownership rights. (First in

time rule – rather than lottery, need-based, or Lockean theories)(ii) This rule creates incentives for discovery. It creates certainty of title,

promotes Lockean labor theory (you find it, you get it), and peace/order/avoiding litigation. The balance of scholarship, though, seems to be against this principle.

v. What are the first possessor’s rights vis-à-vis the native population?(i) Efficiency predominates. Usually, they should assimilate – but the Indians

are savages so that was not possible.(ii) Carol Rose: Some Indians didn’t even understand ownership; they’d run

free in the wild, from place to place.vi. Only the government can purchase the land from the Indians. So D gets the

land.vii. Discovery v. conquest:

(i) Discovery: sighting or finding of hitherto unknown territory, frequently accompanied by a landing and the symbolic taking of possession.

(ii) Conquest: taking possession of enemy territory through force, followed by formal annexation of defeated territory by the conqueror.

viii. Haslem v. Lockwood (CT 1871): P raked into heaps some manure, but let it alone until the next day. D took manure. It belongs to P, since P added value to it.

2. Capture and possession: Foxes, whales, and ducksa. Pierson v. Post (NY 1805)

i. P discovered fox and began to hunt and pursue it. D (“saucy intruder”) was aware of this but killed the fox.

ii. Does mere pursuit of a wild animal vest title in the pursuer?iii. No. Whoever occupies the animal has title to it. Spectrum of occupancy:

Sight and pursuit … close proximity to capture ... trapping the fox … killing the fox and taking possession of it. You must trap or mortally wound an animal to acquire title. D, then, has title to it.

iv. Livingston dissent: Foxes are a public nuisance, so killing them is in the public interest. We should incentivize killing foxes. Prefers standard of in reach of animal or reasonable prospect of capturing animal. This is the custom in fox hunting: If someone else is pursuing a fox, you don’t do it yourself. P should have acquired title.

Page 3: Property Outline.doc

(i) This is a “wealth-maximizing” rule.(ii) Think of how this would apply to software licensing.

b. Ghen v. Rich (MA 1881)i. P killed a whale. Custom in whaling industry was to wait a few days until it

came up to shore; the finder would get some fee after notifying the pursuer/killer. E found the whale and sold it to D.

ii. Is title to a wild animal acquired when a hunter apprehends the beast in accordance with custom?

iii. Yes. When a custom embraces an entire industry, no need for a judge-made rule. P captured whale in accordance with custom, so he acquired title.

c. Keeble v. Hickeringill (England 1707)i. P lured wildfowl to his property with decoys; this was part of his trade. D

fired a gun three times near the pond so he could scare them away. They never came back.

ii. May a landowner, in pursuit of his trade, lawfully capture wildfowl free of the malicious interference of another?

iii. Yes. Every landowner should be able to use his land as he sees fit so long as the use is lawful. The capture of wildfowl in pursuit of a trade is profitable, and creates wealth for the nation at large. D could have interfered if, say, he had put up decoys on his own land and lured them away from P’s property. But here D was malicious. Liable for damages.

iv. Through the lens of Pierson: Distinctions that can be drawn are that P is somewhere between thinking about pursuing and merely pursuing, and that this is a profession, rather than a sport.

v. What if D was interfering for sport? What if, say, Greenpeace was interfering? Some states have enacted laws preventing people from interfering with hunting on government land.

vi. Ratione soli: Wild animals belong to the persons whose land they are on (constructive possession).

d. Hardin: Tragedy of the commonsi. When there’s common property, it gets abused. Decisions reached

individually are most often not those best for society.ii. This is particularly catastrophic when populations grow.iii. Tragedy isn’t that you’re harming the people you live with, but that you’re

harming future generations.iv. Cost of pollution is lower than cost of cleaning up – so on an individual basis

there’s abuse too. v. Best way to curb the tragedy is by mutual agreements. Eliminate the

commons. Abandon the commons in breeding.e. Acheson: The lobster gangs of Maine

i. This is an instance of joint/community property (as opposed to private property or open access property). It seems the problem is less with common property and more with open access.

ii. Only way to fish in Maine is to be a member of a lobster gang. You’ll have access to a protected area that “belongs” to the gang. There is, of course, a pecking order within the gangs (usually based on seniority).

1

Page 4: Property Outline.doc

iii. Gangs will inflict revenge on others who encroach upon their territory.iv. The ocean is technically open access, but it’s de facto private property. The

gangs tend not to act too aggressively with intruders because they want to avoid identification, government regulation, and full-blown lobster wars.

v. Consider the transaction costs of these agreements.vi. So whereas Hardin would say that a communal resource gets abused, Acheson

would argue that it causes private property rights to develop.f. Demsetz: Toward a theory of property rights

i. Property rights emerge because of the relationship between transaction costs and potential benefits associated with the control of resources through property rights.

ii. Three types of ownership(i) Private: Low transaction costs, tends to reduce externalities; preferred(ii) Communal: Great externalities; negative view of this(iii) Government

iii. Note: When externalities confer a benefit, we have a “free-rider” problem.iv. Utilitarian theory is the dominant theory of property. Minimal constraints on

the transfer property are necessary to further this theory.v. How do we minimize the overutilization of resources facilitated by the rule of

capture? Private property rights, regulation, compulsory utilization for all owners, individual transferable quotas, etc.

vi. Anticommons – e.g., businesses in Moscow during communist rule, urban renewal. This happens through splintering property rights – one person has the right to sign a lease, another to receive revenue, another to occupy, etc.

g. Central point: Law is the product of human interaction and doesn’t just come from the government.

3. Property rights in natural resourcesa. Oil and gas

i. The fugitive nature of oil and gas has led courts to treat them like animals. So when an adjoining owner taps into his land and drills out the oil that’s underneath both of your properties, he owns it.

ii. Suppose A and B are adjoining landowners with a common pool of oil beneath their land. (i) If B starts draining the pool, A probably cannot do anything about it,

except maybe when it’s excessive drilling. Union Gas & Oil v. Fyffe (JY 1927). Basically, it’s a rule of capture.

(ii) If the common pool is diagonally-shaped and bottoms out on A’s property, B probably cannot drill diagonally – but can drill straight down.

(iii) If A reinjects gas that spills into B’s land, can B sue for use of property? One case that said no, because it became B’s gas under the rule of capture, was highly criticized and later overruled. Hammonds v. Central Kentucky Natural Gas Co. (KY 1934)

b. Wateri. Groundwater: Water found in underground aquifers.

(i) English rule: Can draw freely.(ii) American rule: Reasonable use. Cannot be wasteful.

2

Page 5: Property Outline.doc

(iii) WSJ, A Thirsty El Paso: Hot disputes over selling water to municipalities, options to purchase groundwater.

ii. Surface water(i) First in time rule predominates in Western US(ii) Riparian law (goes to adjacent landowners, subject to others with riparian

rights) predominates in Eastern US.iii. Legal Affairs, There’s an old saying in Colorado

(i) Politics in Colorado – centered on water compacts. Pure first-in-time rule – for beneficial use. This encompasses domestic use, generating power, and making snow.

(ii) Should water be sacrificed for kayaking parks when it would add to a local economy? Environmental concerns

(iii) Interstate compacts and other “straws” from the Colorado River. Courts hear battles over who gets water, where, etc.

B. Acquisition by creation1. Copycats and the common law

a. International News Service v. Associated Press (US 1918)i. D copied news from one of P’s postings.ii. Is there a property interest in freshly printed news that allows the created to

prevent others from copying it?iii. Yes. P has invested time and resources into the creation of news, so it can

prevent others from copying it until its commercial value as news has passed away. If copying was permitted, no news service could stay in business.

iv. This opinion seems to reflect Lockean property theory.v. Note that this is only a quasi-property right that lets you exclude others.

b. Cheney Brothers v. Doris Silk Corp. (2d Cir. 1929)i. D copied one of P’s fashion designs. Designs, of course, have a short life. P’s

designs weren’t so original that P could get a patent.ii. Is there a generic common law patent protection which lasts for the

commercial life of a creation?iii. No. It would be too difficult for courts to define the boundaries of common

law patent protection. The Court didn’t create a common law patent in INS; it was just an unusual case, and so the holding is confined to its facts. Since there’s no patent here or other recognized common law protection, P’s designs can be copied.

c. Smith v. Chanel, Inc. (9th Cir. 1968)i. D claimed in an ad that its cheap perfume was the same as Chanel No. 5. ii. Court held that this was fine; No. 5 was unpatented, and so D had a right to

copy it. Most effective way of conveying “Hey, my product is just as good as this other one, but it’s cheaper” is to actually name the other product.

iii. Copycats serve an important public interest.d. Baird, Common law intellectual property: Competition depends upon imitation.

2. Intellectual propertya. Modes of IP protection:

i. Patents: Granted for novel, useful, and nonobvious processes or products. 35 U.S.C. § 101. Last for 20 years from date of application. Non-renewable.

3

Page 6: Property Outline.doc

ii. Copyrights: Protect the expression of ideas in books, articles, music, etc. Usually last 70 years after death of the author or creator, subject to fair use.

iii. Trademarks: Words and symbols indicating the source of a product or service. These don’t expire.

b. IP, unlike normal property, is non-rival and non-excludable. Our system of protecting IP is very arbitrary – who not have the government hire people?

c. Diamond v. Chakrabarty (US 1980)i. P tried to patent a man-made bacterium that would help with oil spills. Patent

application denied because micro-organisms are products of nature and that as living things they are not patentable under § 101.

ii. Is the micro-organism a manufacture or composition of matter within § 101?iii. Burger: Yes. Things that are not patentable: laws of nature, physical

phenomena, and abstract ideas. But this micro-organism is markedly different from any one found in nature and has potential for significant utility. This is not a discovery of nature, but P. Patentable.

iv. Plants also aren’t patentable. But this case isn’t analogous because the legislative history doesn’t suggest bacteria are included in plant variety protection statutes. Also, it doesn’t matter that this is “natural” – the proper distinction according to the statute is whether it’s nature-made or man-made. Living things can also be in the scope of § 101.

v. It doesn’t matter that Congress didn’t expressly include bacteria within the scope of patent protection. The language of § 101 suggests bacteria are patentable.

vi. Brennan (dissent): Need to be careful to extend patent protection. Finds plant patent acts controlling – suggest that bacteria shouldn’t be patentable. § 101 shouldn’t include living organisms.

vii. Harvard Mouse – genetically engineered mouse developed for cancer research. Was patented. What’s good and bad about this? What happens when the mice reproduce – like a fugitive resource?

d. Article re: Open access and Lessigi. With cases like Eldred v. Ashcroft (US 2003) and laws like the Digital

Millennium Copyright Act upholding extensions to copyrights, is the US becoming less creative of a nation?

ii. “Copy Left”: It’s not so good that rights of small pieces of culture are doled out for small payments. We should have more open access.

iii. When researchers have to get permission from several patentholders to go forward with their research, isn’t something wrong going on?

iv. But what about the authors? Romantic notions of creation. Utilitarianism. Lockean theory.

3. Property rights in one’s persona/persona. Right of publicity is often recognized as a sort of property interest for celebrities.

Should/does it provide protection in cyberspace?i. This will protect your “self” – name, likeness, and other aspects of your

identity.ii. E.g., Midler v. Ford Motor Co. (9th Cir. 1988) (voice of Bette Midler); Vanna

White v. Samsung Electronics America, Inc. (9th Cir. 1992) (robot made to

4

Page 7: Property Outline.doc

look like Vanna White). Lugosi v. Universal Pictures (CA 1979) (dicta that heirs of celebrities who used personalities for commercial purposes could recover for people who used those characteristics without permission).

iii. Demsetzian story here – technology enabled copying of characteristics.b. Moore v. Regents of the University of California (CA 1990)

i. P was treated by D; some of his cells were extracted. It just so happened that the cells were very valuable for use in treating cancer. D patented these cells and developed research based on them without P’s consent. P sued for conversion.

ii. Does a doctor have a duty to disclose the extent of his research and economic interests in a patient’s body parts? Yes.

iii. Are human body parts property such that they may be converted?iv. No. Must show interference with possession or property interest. No

possession here. No property interest. Body parts are different – policy goals. CA statutes limit patient’s control over excised body parts. Also, the patent can’t be P’s property; it’s different from his organs. This isn’t as unique as likeness and the such; have same structure in every human being.

v. Conversion shouldn’t be extended. Want to protect researchers from liability. Duty to disclose protect patient’s interests. Institutional competency; leave it to the legislature. Thus, no property interest in body parts.

vi. Arabian (concurring): Human body is sacred. Difficulties would arise if we let people sell bodies for profit.

vii. Mosk (dissent): Concepts of property/ownership are very broad. Uniform Anatomical Gift Act lets competent adults make post-mortem gifts of any/all organs, but cannot receive consideration. This doesn’t prohibit sales when alive. The Act, in fact, recognizes a right to sell. Unfair to let Ds get all the profit, P none.

viii. Arabian concurrence misses the point – we can have a bundle of rights that don’t include selling for profit. Could have, e.g., enforced right to alienate.

ix. Donation rate for dead people is about 15%. Living people can sell semen, skin tissue, and blood. Kant – degrading people to objects.

x. Case of a man who committed suicide and in a note willed his sperm to his live-in girlfriend of several years. Eventually, after much litigation, the girlfriend got the sperm.

xi. What about the poor? Article on organ donations in India – 96% sold to pay off debts. Some middlemen make misrepresentations to donors. all who were in good or excellent health had severe declines after donation.

xii. Federal law prohibits organ purchases.c. Jacque v. Steenberg Homes, Inc. (WI 1997)

i. D attempted to travel across P’s land to move a trailer. D tried to get permission but P wouldn’t give it.

ii. May punitive damages be imposed when nominal damages are awarded for an intentional trespass to land?

5

Page 8: Property Outline.doc

iii. Yes. P has right to exclude people from land. Nominal damages (in this case, $1) aren’t enough to deter. (In other words, landowners have right to unreasonably exercise the right to exclude.)

iv. Blackstone would commend this decision. He viewed property as an absolute right. What about the right not to be excluded, though? More and more limitations on this notion of property. What’s wrong with absolute rights? Epstein argues nothing; it just sets up for later market transactions.(i) Local governments often prohibit aggressive panhandling, overnight

sleeping in public places.v. Spectrum: Property rule would be the rule above – interest cannot be taken

without owner’s consent. So award nominal, punitive damages for trespass. … Alternately, we could just let D enter and not impose any costs on him. … Liability rule would permit trespass for a price (a reasonable amount). Basically an option to buy a license for a judicially-determined amount. E.g., eminent domain.

d. State v. Shack (NJ 1971)i. D entered onto P’s property to provide legal advice to illegal alien. D refused

to leave when P ordered him to.ii. May a landlord use land in a manner that endangers the well-being of others?iii. No. D can enter without having to pay anything. Property rights serve public

policy and needs of others. Federal law authorizing D to give legal aid to migrant farm workers declared a public policy of aiding these people. P can’t interfere with that.

6

Page 9: Property Outline.doc

III. Subsequent possessionA. Acquisition by find

1. Armory v. Delamirie (England 1722)a. P found a jewel and took it to D’s shop to get it appraised. D wouldn’t return it to

P.b. Does the finding of lost property have title superior to all but the true owner?c. Yes. Since D isn’t the true owner, P has superior title.d. Illustrates that title is a relative concept.e. The Winkfield (England 1901): If finder recovers from jeweler, can true owner

recover from jeweler if finder is nowhere to be found? No. Burden is on true owner to recover from the finder.

f. When courts have to resolve a dispute between a wrongful prior possessor and a lawful subsequent possessor, they usually resolve the dispute in favor of the latter, despite the rule that subsequent possessors usually don’t hold better title over the prior possessor.

g. Awards of damages v. possession in cases like this.2. Hannah v. Peel (England 1945)

a. P found a brooch on property D owned but never lived on.b. If a landowner has never lived on a parcel of land, does a finder of property on

that land have superior title to the landowner?c. Yes. Precedent cases indicate that owner possesses anything attached to his land,

but not necessarily something which is on the surface of it that is not attached. This was lost property. We want to serve two objectives – return property to its owner and encourage honesty. Here, P was honest; he gave the brooch to the police immediately after finding out it may be of some value.

d. What if P was a trespasser? Authorities are split on whether trespasser can have superior title to constructive possessor (see p. 118).

e. Bridges v. Hawkesworth (England 1847ish): Bag was left in area of shop accessible to general public. Finder won because shop owner did not possess it.

3. McAvoy v. Medina (MA 1866)a. Customer of barber shop owner D left his wallet on the counter but did not

remove it. P found the wallet.b. Does the finder of mislaid property have title to it?c. No. When property is mislaid, shop owner has a duty to safeguard it until the true

owner returns. (Lost property is genuinely lost; mislaid property has been misplaced.) Finder can never gain title to it.

d. Bridges is distinguishable because property was lost in that case.e. This case requires honesty; imposes confiscatory tax on finder. Can legal

incentives to find something crowd out moral incentives to turn it in?f. If an employee/agent finds something, does he have title to it or does his superior?

Law is all over the place.g. Treasure trove: treasures hidden with the intention of return to claim them went to

the king; abandoned property went to the finder. This has persisted to a certain extent in the US.

h. Wreck: Cargo washed ashore from a ship lost at sea with no survivors went to king. Has persisted in the US. But maritime law awards salvage awards – some

7

Page 10: Property Outline.doc

percentage goes to finder – unlike other property law, where finder gets all or nothing.

i. Some states maintain the lost/mislaid/abandoned distinction (abandoned property – finder entitled to keep).

B. Acquisition by adverse possession1. Elements

a. Actual entry giving exclusive possession that isb. Open and notoriousc. Adverse under a claim of right andd. Continuous for the statutory period.

2. CA Code of Civil Procedurea. § 321 – Presumption that true owner was in possession unless it appears adversely

possessed for 5 years.b. § 322 – Claim of title, exclusive of other right, founded upon a written instrument

as a conveyance or decree or judgment by a competent court, continuous occupation/possession, for 5 years.

c. § 323 – Based on written instrument, possessed and occupied in the following cases:i. Usually cultivated or improvedii. Protected by a substantial inclosureiii. Although not inclosed, has been used for the supply of fuel, or of fencing

timber for the purposes of husbandry, of for pasturage, or for the ordinary use of the occupant

iv. Where a known farm or single lot has been partly improved, the portion that may have been left not cleared, or not inclosed according to the usual course and custom of the adjoining country, shall be deemed to have been occupied for the same amount of time as the part improved and cultivated

d. § 324 – When no claim under written instrument, only the land actually occupied can be adversely possessed

e. § 325 – Adverse possession not founded upon a written instrument is possessed / occupied only:i. Where land is protected by a substantial inclosureii. Where it has been usually cultivated or improvediii. Adverse possession not shown under any section of this code unless land has

been occupied continuously for 5 years and the party, predecessors, and grantors have paid all the taxes levied and assessed upon the land – state, local, county, etc.

3. Justificationsa. Encourage efficient use of land, clarity of title, facilitates transfers of land. b. Holmes also says that after a certain point, land becomes part of you –

psychological benefits. Seems very Lockean. c. Powell says it rests on social judgments that passage of certain time should give

security to person claiming to be owner. d. Ballantine says purpose is to quiet title. e. Ellickson claims it has quite a bit to do with cognitive psychology – value loss of

an asset in possession more than foregoing opportunity to realize equivalent gain.

8

Page 11: Property Outline.doc

4. Van Valkenburgh v. Lutz (NY 1952)a. Ds purchased land and, instead of going up a steep hill to get to their property,

walked across the land Ps later purchased. Ds cleared the land and built a 1-br shack on it. They grew vegetables on it and sold them. Some litigation occurred and Ds at least tried to claim a right of way.

b. Must possession be actual to acquire title by adverse possession? Yes. There is no actual possession here because the garden occupied only a small portion of the lots and the garage only encroached on Ps’ lot by a few inches.

c. Where a person claims title not founded upon a written instrument, must a person either protect land by a substantial enclosure or cultivate or improve land to be deemed to be in possession? Yes. The land was not enclosed. The improvements were not substantial because the shack was small, the garden was insubstantial, and placing junk on the land is not improvement.

d. Must land be possessed under a claim of title to be acquired by adverse possession? Yes. D testified he knew the land belonged to Ps.

e. Dissent: The land was substantially improved and need not be fully occupied. It only needs to be occupied to the extent necessary to put the owner on notice. Ds need not believe the property was theirs; they just need to intend to acquire and use the land as their own. (Professor favors this argument)

f. Three alternative approaches to claim of right:i. Objective (state of mind irrelevant): English/CT rule. Once true owner is

dispossessed, statute starts to run.ii. Good faith/subjective. Not commonly held in the US. But Professor

Helmholz has concluded on the basis of recent cases that even if this is not the formal rule, many courts manipulate hostility and claim-of-right to permit good-faith trespassers to get the land. Merril responded by saying we should just apply the liability rule for bad-faith adverse possessors.

iii. Aggressive trespass: Majority rule(i) What if there was a liability rule in these cases?

g. Ewing v. Burnet (US 1837): Adverse possession established when claimant under color and claim of title paid taxes on lot, occasionally dug sand and gravel from it, permitted others to do so, and brought trespass against others for doing so without his permission. Adverse possessors don’t necessarily need to live on the lot; sometimes it’s even fine if he doesn’t use the lot for a long time.i. But don’t assume that this means it’s sufficient to use the property as an

average owner would in the area. Pettis v. Lozier (NE 1984): No adverse possession of 8-acre suburban wooded lot even though the claimant occasionally used the land for a variety of purposes throughout the statutory period.

h. Claim of title – hostility/claim of right. Color of title – claim founded on written instrument or judgment/decree that is for some reason defective and invalid. Claim under color of title is not required by English law and is not required in most US. Actual possession under color of title is constructive possession of all that the writing describes.

5. Mannillo v. Gorski (NJ 1969)

9

Page 12: Property Outline.doc

a. For 20 years, D’s house (unknowingly to D) encroached upon P’s land by 15 inches.

b. Must possession be accompanied by a knowing intentional hostility for adverse possession? No. Entry and continuance of possession under mistaken belief that possessor has title to the lands satisfies hostility. (This is the majority view/Connecticut doctrine. The minority view/Maine doctrine is that knowing intentional hostility is required.)

c. Does a minor border encroachment satisfy open and notorious requirement? No. A border dispute like this one does not create a clear situation of adverse occupancy. Only way D knew he was encroaching was to have a survey of the property. Only where the true owner has actual knowledge of encroachment can it be open and notorious.

d. But equity may require that the true owner convey the land to D. Remanded.e. What does the actual knowledge to be of? Suppose P thought encroachment was

only 3 inches.f. Harrison v. Welch (CA 2004): P built a woodshed and planted some trees that

partially encroached upon neighbor D’s land. No adverse possession because P didn’t pay taxes on the area he encroached upon.

g. Accidental improvements: Common law rule was too bad – if you improve on the wrong land, no dice. Now courts can force conveyances at market price. Some statutes give landowner the option to buy the improvement.

6. Howard v. Kunto (WA 1970)a. M, D, and P had lots in a resort area. M occupied P’s land. D occupied M’s land.

D’s land was to the west. P conveyed deed to M. M conveyed deed to land that D occupied to P. M then conveyed. D obtained title from predecessor. Quiet title on land D occupies.

b. Is land that is used in a customary manner, even though it is not possessed continuously, sufficient to vest title by adverse possession? Yes.

c. Is a reasonable relationship between successive adverse possessors all that is required to tack? Yes. Privity is required; this is accomplished by the deed transferring title. This only means a reasonable relationship; designed to prevent trespassers who had no claim of right from tacking.

d. Physical tacking: If a deed intends by the parties to convey not just described land but also adversely possessed land, claimant can “tack” the strip on to land described in deed.

e. Temporal tacking: English rule – successive possessors don’t need to be in privity; American rule – yes they do.

f. The adverse possessor can only acquire the interest of the person who currently has rights to possession.

10

Page 13: Property Outline.doc

IV. Shared ownership of propertyA. Ownership divided into time periods

1. Possessory estatesa. Fee simple

i. An estate capable of being inherited by whomever turns out to be the heirs of the fee simple owner.

ii. “To A and his heirs” (though “and his heirs” is no longer required)iii. Applies only to real estate.iv. Heirs: Persons who survive decedent and are designated as intestate

successors under the state’s statute of descent. Living people have no heirs.v. Issue: If the decedent leaves issue, they take to the exclusion of all other

kindred. Issue are decedents. (i) Per stirpes: If a child of the decedent dies before the decedent and leaves

children who survive the decedent, then the child’s share goes to his or her children by right of representation.

(ii) Rule of primogeniture: Eldest son inherited land. If he died before the decedent, then his eldest son. Only if there were no sons would a daughter inherit.

(iii) Illegitimate children was considered the child of no one (filius nullius); could not inherit at all.

vi. Ancestors: Parents usually take as heirs if no issue.vii. Collaterals: Persons related by blood to decedent who are neither descendants

nor ancestors are collateral kin. If no spouse, parents, or issue, collateral kin inherit.

viii. Escheat: If a person died intestate without any heirs, real property escheats to the state. Personal property escheats to crown as goods without an owner (bona vacantia).

b. Life estatei. When A transfers his life estate to B, B has a life estate pur autre vie (it is

measured by the life of another person).ii. White v. Brown (TN 1977)

(i) L left a will that P will get home – said twice it was not to be sold. P claims fee simple interest conveyed. D claims it was merely a life estate.

(ii) Unless a contrary intention appears by the terms of the will and its context, does a will convey a testator’s entire interest?

(iii) Yes. Legislature has enacted presumption in favor of conveyance of testator’s entire interest rather than a life estate. Restraints on alienation are void as against public policy. So P has a fee simple.

(iv)Dissent: The will is unambiguous.(v) Restraints on alienation are bad – problems with marketability,

concentrating wealth, improvements, and credit.1. Disabling restraints withhold from the grantee the power of

transferring his interest.2. Forfeiture restraints provide that if the grantee attempts to transfer his

interest, it is forfeited to another person.

11

Page 14: Property Outline.doc

3. Promissory restraints provide that the grantee promises not to transfer his interest. These are rare.

4. Restatement is against absolute disabling restraints, but is fine with partial restraints if reasonable under the circumstances.

(vi)Valuation of life estate – rely heavily on life expectancy tables. See pp. 229-30.

c. Defeasible estatesi. Fee simple determinable: Automatically ends when a stated condition

happens.(i) Language in conveyance

1. “to A so long as premises are used for school purposes”2. “while used for school purposes”3. “during the continuance of said school”4. “until A no longer uses the land for a school”5. Words with a durational aspect

(ii) Future interest is the possibility of reverter.ii. Fee simple subject to condition subsequent: May be cut short or divested at

the transferor’s election when a stated condition happens.(i) Language in conveyance

1. “to A, but if the premises are not used for school purposes, O has the right to reenter and retake the premises”

2. Conveyance of fee simple, followed by language providing that it can be divested if a stated event happens.

(ii) Future interest is the right of reentry/power of termination.iii. Marenholz v. County Board of School Trustees (IL 1981)

(i) Hs conveyed land to D “to be used for school purposes only, otherwise to revert to grantors therein.” D later used the land for storage. Hs conveyed any future interest they had to P.

(ii) Did the language create a fee simple determinable?(iii) Yes. P has no interest; cannot convey these interests (per statute).

The phrase “to be used for school purposes only” used suggests Hs wanted to convey land for a particular purpose and for no longer than the purpose needed to be furthered. The phrase “otherwise to revert to grantors” suggests an automatic return to Hs. This is a fee simple determinable.

(iv)Most states permit the transfer of possibility of reverted and right of entry. But some states distinguish between the two.

(v) When does the statute of limitations begin to run? In many states, when the condition occurs. Right of reentry must be exercised within a reasonable time (usually defined as statute of limitations).

(vi)CA has no fee simple determinable. CA Civil Code § 885.020.(vii) Conditions lead to forfeiture, but violations of covenants lead to an

injunction or damages – not nearly as serious.2. Future interests

a. Interests retained by the transferori. Reversion: the interest remaining in the grantor who transfers a vested estate

of a lesser quantum than that of the vested estate which he has.

12

Page 15: Property Outline.doc

(i) E.g., “to A for life” – O has a reversion.ii. Possibility of reverter: arises when an owner carves out of his estate a

determinable estate of the same quantum.iii. Right of entry/power of termination: arises when an owner transfers an estate

subject to condition subsequent and retains the power to cut short/terminate the estate.

b. Interests created in a transfereei. Read the language from left to rightii. A transferee holding a future interest can sue the current possessor for waste.iii. A remainder is a future interest that “waits politely” until the termination of

the preceding possessory estate. But an executory interest is a future interest that can take effect only be divesting another interest.

iv. Note: A life estate can end prior to the death of the transferee. v. Note: The legal consequences of the various future interests in transferees are

minimal, if not non-existent.vi. Vested remainder

(i) A remainder given to an ascertained person that is not subject to a condition precedent (other than the termination of the preceding estate).

(ii) Indefeasibly vested remainder: remainder is certain of becoming possessory in the future and cannot be divested.1. e.g., “to A for life, then to B and her heirs.”

(iii) Of course, a remainder can be vested but not certain of becoming possessory. 1. e.g., “to A for life, then to B and her heirs, but if B does not survive A

to C and his heirs” – B has a vested remainder subject to divestment.(iv)A remainder created in a class of persons is vested if one member of the

class is ascertained and there is no condition precedent. The remainder is vested subject to open or vested subject to partial divestment of later-born children are entitled to share in the gift.1. e.g., “to A for life, then to A’s children and their heirs.”

vii. Contingent remainder(i) A remainder given to an unascertained person or is made contingent upon

some event occurring other than the natural termination of the preceding estates.1. e.g., “to A for life, then to the heirs of B” – B is alive; the heirs of B

are not ascertained.(ii) Contingent remainders cannot be possessory until they are vested.(iii) “to A for life, then to B and her heirs if B survives A, and if B does

not survive A to C and his heirs” – B and C have alternative contingent remainders.

viii. Executory interests(i) Shifting executory interests: Divest or cut short some interest in another

transferee.(ii) Springing executory interests: Divest the transferor in the future.

13

Page 16: Property Outline.doc

(iii) Fee simple subject to an executory limitation: upon the happening of a stated event, it is automatically divested by an executory interest in a transferee.1. e.g., “to A and his heirs, but if A dies without issue surviving him, to B

and her heirs” – A has a possessory fee simple subject to an executory limitation. “to A for life, then to B and her heirs, but if B dies under the age of 21, to C and her heirs” – B has a vested remainder in fee simple subject to an executory limitation.

(iv)Defeasible fees: e.g., “to Town Library Board so long as the premises are used for library purposes, then to Children’s Hospital” – TLB has a fee simple determinable. CH has an executory interest. This is because even though it would otherwise appear to be a remainder, there is a rule that a remainder cannot follow a vested fee simple. Courts err on the side of violating the definition of executory interest than that rule.

c. Trustsi. Trustee manages property for the benefit of the beneficiaries.

(i) Trustee has legal ownership and power to sell the assets and reinvest proceeds.

(ii) Net income is paid to the beneficiaries. (iii) Beneficiaries are equitable owners.(iv)Trustee is a fiduciary. Duties p. 288.(v) E.g., Blackacre conveyed “to X in trust to pay the income to A for life,

and then to pay the principal to A’s children who survive A.”ii. Swanson v. Swanson (GA 1999)

(i) S left a will that created two trusts. The Item IV trust gave his wife a life estate, which she could dispose of as she wished, with remainder to his nine children (or, if not surviving, to their children per stirpes). The Item V trust gave S’ wife a life estate, remainder divided into nine equal shares, one each for each of surviving children or the then surviving issue of the deceased child.

(ii) B died before S and left everything he had to his wife, P. He had no children.

(iii) Does the law create a preference for vested remainders over contingent remainders?

(iv)Yes. GA has two guiding principles: favor construction as conditions subsequent; and when ambiguous, favor construction as vested remainders. When there’s at least one known person, then it is a vested remainder.

(v) Item IV: Since children (all of them) were alive at the time the will was created, so each had a vested remainder interest. Two conditions subsequent – predeceasing wife and leaving children who survived wife; wife’s exercise of power of appointment. Neither occurred, so B had a vested remainder interest; passed on to P.

(vi)Item V: Provides for equal distribution among children. Just as with the Item IV, B’s share was fully vested.

14

Page 17: Property Outline.doc

(vii) Condition precedent: Condition incorporated into the language that created the interest.

(viii) Condition subsequent: Condition not incorporated into the language that creates the interest.

(ix)Indefeasibly vested remainders give you the flexibility to deal with marriages, divorces, births, and disabled or incompetent children. If everything is contingent upon you surviving your parent(s), then you can’t deal with these changing circumstances very well. 1. To avoid these problems, the grantor could give life tenant power of

appointment; or making remainder contingent upon surviving life tenant and giving remainderman a special power of appointment exercisable if the remainderman predeceases the life tenant. A special power of appointment is the power to appoint the property among a limited class of persons.

(x) Can you adopt your adult spouse to get favorable treatment in a trust? Some cases say no, since it would flout the intent of the trust.

d. Rule against perpetuitiesi. No interest is good unless it must vest, if at all, no later than 21 years after

some life in being at the creation of the interest ends.(i) Originated in Duke of Norfolk’s Case (England 1681).(ii) The validating life need not be mentioned in instrument, but must

somehow effect vesting of the interest.(iii) A child in the womb as of creation of instrument is in being.(iv)A reasonable period of gestation can be tacked on to the period.

ii. Measures what could happen.iii. Rules of construction

(i) Prefer vested to contingent(ii) Prefer early vesting to later vesting(iii) Avoid partial intestacy(iv)Prefer fee simple absolute

iv. Similar policies as adverse possession. Want to respect wishes of transferor, but don’t want to give him too much power to rule in the distant future.

v. Future interests retained in the transferor are not subject to RAP. (Although in England, the possibility of reverter and right of reentry are.)

vi. The Symphony Space, Inc. v. Pergola Properties, Inc. (NY 1996)(i) In 1978, B “sells” building to P for a very low price. B maintains

possession because P leases it back to B for $1/year. (This is a tax evasion deal.) B granted option to repurchase in 1987, 1993, 1998, or 2003. B sold its interest for almost $5m; D eventually purchased it. Value of property increased significantly and D exercised option.

(ii) Are options to purchase commercial property exempt from RAP? No. RAP applies to commercial option contracts. An exception would remove an entire class from RAP, and that’s not warranted by the language or legislative history.

(iii) Does the option contract violate RAP? Yes. It must vest by 1999, but there’s an option in 2003.

15

Page 18: Property Outline.doc

(iv)Rejects wait-and-see approach.(v) If a preemptive right (right of first refusal) can be exercised beyond the

perpetuities period, then it’s usually found void.(vi)O: “to A so long as land is used for school purposes, and when it’s no

longer used that way, O, his heirs, or his assigns can repurchase it.” This is a preemptive right that violates RAP.

vii. Modern reforms(i) Restatement 3d of Property, Servitudes, §3.3: Options not subject to RAP,

but to restraints on alienation.(ii) USRAP: RAP does not apply to options, commercial transactions.(iii) Cy pres: reformation of invalid interests so as to carry out

transferor’s intent within the perpetuities period. Mandated in a few states.

viii. Wait-and-see(i) This sacrifices the certainty provided by what-might-happen(ii) Some form of wait-and-see has been adopted by most states(iii) Wait-and-see for the common law period. Has been adopted in

about 9 states.1. Most of these states permit reformation of invalid interests

(iv)Wait-and-see for 90 years (USRAP)1. Under USRAP, if it will vest within 90 years or the common law

period, then it’s vested. If it’s unclear, wait-and-see for 90 years. Has been adopted in 26 states, incl. CA.

ix. About ¼ of the states have abolished RAP and/or permitted perpetual trusts.x. Simes, Public policy and the dead hand

(i) The purpose of RAP, to facilitate alienability, is no longer valid.(ii) Trustees have been given more powers of reinvestment.(iii) Income and estate taxes curb the concentration of wealth in

dynasties.(iv)Sometimes RAP is justified by not encouraging survival of fittest, but

guaranteeing income of some people. Well, RAP lets us do it for one generation.

(v) But there are two legitimate goals. RAP balances interests of old with those of the young. It’s also socially desirable that wealth be controlled by the living and not the dead.

xi. Dynasty trusts(i) WSJ Article – trend toward using dynasty trusts. (ii) There’s a federal estate/gift tax exemption of $1m if you put it into a

dynasty trust.(iii) Trust that endures for lives in being at creation of trust plus 21

years. In states with USRAP, goes on for 90 years or common law perpetuities period. In some states, a dynasty trust can endure forever.

B. Concurrent ownership1. Introduction

a. Tenancy in common

16

Page 19: Property Outline.doc

i. Separate but undivided interests in the property. Each is descendible and may be conveyed by deed or will. No survivorship rights.

ii. Need unity of possession.b. Joint tenancy

i. Have a right of survivorship. Together regarded as a single owner. When joint tenant dies, nothing passes to other joint tenant. It just continues. Cannot will any interest in joint tenancy.(i) So creditors can’t seize anything after a joint tenant dies, but can when

he’s alive.ii. Four unities needed:

(i) Time: Interest of each joint tenant must be acquired or vest at the same time.

(ii) Title: All joint tenants must acquire title by the same instrument or by a joint adverse possession. A joint tenancy can never arise by intestate succession or other act of law.

(iii) Interest: All must have equal undivided shares and identical interests measured by duration.

(iv)Possession: Each must have a right to possession of the whole. After it’s created, one joint tenant can voluntarily give exclusive possession to the other.

iii. If not all of the four unities are present at creation, then most states and the common law provide that it is a tenancy in common. If one of the unities severs, it’s converted into a tenancy in common.

iv. If joint tenants or tenants in common cannot come to mutual agreement, any of them can bring action for judicial partition. Court will either physically partition land or order land sold and divide proceeds among the tenants.

v. Joint tenancies help people avoid probate. But Congress got smart and subject joint tenancies to estate taxation.

vi. Courts frequently ignore the equal share unity; courts frequently divide proceeds according to intent of parties.

c. Tenancy by the entiretyi. Can be created only in husband in wife. (Although HI recently permitted

reciprocal beneficiaries – unmarried people who cannot get married – to have a tenancy by the entirety.)

ii. H and W are considered a single holder. They cannot defeat the right of survivorship of the other by a conveyance of a third party. H and W must both consent to conveyances.

iii. Exists in slightly less than ½ states.d. Presumptions

i. Tenancies in common over joint tenanciesii. Usually a presumption that if conveyed to H and W, it will be a tenancy by the

entirety, absent some clear indication otherwiseiii. Some states require specific language (by statute) to convey a joint tenancy –

e.g., “to A and B as joint tenants with the right or survivorship” (But in some states including expressly a right of survivorship will be interpreted as conveying a joint life estate with alternative contingent remainders.)

17

Page 20: Property Outline.doc

2. Severing a joint tenancya. Riddle v. Harmon (CA 1980)

i. P didn’t want her property to pass to her H when she died, so she tried to end the joint tenancy by selling the property to herself as a tenant in common.

ii. Can a joint tenant unilaterally sever a joint tenancy without the use of an intermediary by conveying her interest to herself?

iii. Yes. Since state statute governing joint tenancy permits someone to unilaterally create one by conveying property to herself and others, then it’s perfectly fine for someone to unilaterally terminate a joint tenancy. A strawman is unnecessary for the creation of a joint tenancy, it’s unnecessary for the termination.

iv. What if the wife did this almost secretly? Suppose she wrote it on a paper, told her daughter, and hid the paper.

v. Uniform Simultaneous Death Act § 3: One-half of the property is distributed as if one joint tenant survived, and one-half as if the other survived.(i) Suppose A and B, joint tenants, are in a car crash. B is decapitated –

blood gushing from his neck – and there are no signs of life from A. Who survives whom? Unclear.

vi. Uniform Probate Code § 2-803(c)(2): If one joint tenant murders another, that severs the joint tenancy. The killer loses his right of survivorship in the decedent’s share.

b. Harms v. Sprague (IL 1984)i. P and brother J own land as JTWROS. J wanted to help his boyfriend, D, buy

some property and mortgaged his interest in the land with P as a security for D’s debt. P was unaware. After J died, D’s creditors recorded the mortgage.

ii. Is a joint tenancy severed when one joint tenant mortgages his interest in the property? No. Two theories:(i) Lien theory: A mortgage on the interest is just a lien. (Majority, incl. CA)(ii) Title theory: A mortgage on the interest is a sale of it.

iii. Adopts lien theory. Liens don’t sever joint tenancies.iv. Does such a mortgage become a lien on the property after the death of the

mortgagor? No. A surviving joint tenant acquires the share of the deceased joint tenant.

3. Relations among concurrent ownersa. Partition

i. Delfino v. Vealencis (CT 1980)(i) Ps (99/144) and Ds (45/144) own property as tenants in common. D runs

a garbage removal business on her part of the land. Ps want to partition and develop the property into residential lots. D wants to keep her business (clearly a conflict between subjective and objective values).

(ii) Can a partition by sale be ordered when a physical partition is possible, and a partition by sale would protect the interests of the owner of a larger share of the property over the owner of the other share?

(iii) No. Prefer partition in kind to partition by sale. A partition by sale should be ordered only when (1) the physical attributes of the land are such that a partition in kind is impracticable or inequitable and (2) the

18

Page 21: Property Outline.doc

interests of all the owners would better be promoted by a partition by sale. PBS is essentially an extreme remedy.

(iv)Here, it’s physically possible to partition the land in kind. It’s not inequitable. Economic gain cannot justify PBS; need to consider that PBS would make D surrender her business and home. Plus, Ps’ home is on far west side of property.

(v) Professor: under this logic, each cotenant has a veto power by saying that subjective value is very high.

(vi)Antique rocking chair case (In re McDowell (NY 1973)) – A and B, heirs to their father, fight over an item they both want very much. Can’t PIK that. But perhaps you can partition in time – A gets it for 6 mos., B gets it for 6 mos. The court granted this remedy.

(vii) Courts do different things when there are many owners at stake. Some order partition by sale because it would be unduly prejudicial to the owners to PIK. But others order PIK and say the 4 cotenants can draw lots as to who gets which lot.

(viii) Modern practice is in favor of PBS, in spite of assertions that PIK is preferred.

b. Sharing benefits and burdens of co-ownershipi. Spiller v. Mackereth (AL 1976)

(i) P and D own building as tenants in common. Tenant vacates. P starts using space as a warehouse. D sent letter demanding P to pay rent or vacate. No evidence that P excluded D from the land. P put new locks on building – seemed to be because he wanted to protect merchandise.

(ii) Does P owe D rent?(iii) No. Unless there’s an agreement to pay rent or ouster, a cotenant

in possession is not liable to cotenants for the value of the use and occupation.

(iv)Ouster: Refers to (1) beginning and running of statute of limitations for adverse possession or (2) liability of an occupying cotenant for rent to other cotenants. In the second instance, is shown when occupying cotenant refuses demand of other cotenants to use property as well.

(v) There was no refusal here – P just didn’t respond to some letter D sent. D didn’t assert possessory rights. Locks weren’t ouster because not done with intent to exclude and no evidence that D asked for keys and was denied. P not liable for rent.

(vi)Minority view: Ouster is not required; there just needs to be a demand to vacate or pay rent.

(vii) This rule rewards the beneficial use of property.ii. Swartzbaugh v. Sampson (CA 1936)

(i) D/H and P/W were JTWROS. When P was ill and without P’s consent, D leased part of their land for a boxing pavilion. P didn’t want the pavilion there.

(ii) Can P cancel the leases?(iii) No. A joint tenant has the right to convey or mortgage his interest

in the property even if the other joint tenant objects.

19

Page 22: Property Outline.doc

(iv)P’s remedies: 1. If there’s no ouster, a joint tenant can only recover agreed upon price.

a. If agreed upon price is higher than FMV, then a joint tenant could just argue no ouster.

2. If there is ouster, a joint tenant can recover fair market value here.iii. Accounting for benefits

(i) Cotenant who collects rent or other payments from 3d parties must account to cotenants for amounts received.

(ii) Cotenant who pays more than his share of taxes, mortgage payments, or other necessary carrying charges usually has a right to contribution.1. An exception that is not uniformly applied is when the cotenant who

pays taxes and the such is the sole possessor and the value of the possession equals or exceeds the payments.

(iii) Necessary repairs: No affirmative right to contribution unless there’s an agreement. But can receive credit in accounting action.

(iv)Improvements: No right to contribution, no credit.C. Marital ownership of property

1. Common law systema. During marriage

i. At common law, H had complete dominion over property. Married Women’s Property Acts permitted W to have control over all of her property.

ii. Sawada v. Endo (HI 1977)(i) D and W conveyed their property to their sons without consideration one

the same day D got into an accident with Ps. Ps received judgment against D.

(ii) Is the interest of one spouse in real property held by tenancy in the entirety subject to levy and execution by his creditors?

(iii) No. 4 groups of laws on this:1. Debtor spouse = D; non-debtor spouse = H. 2 is the right of

survivorship.2. Group I: Old common law: H is the real owner of marital property

a. If D=H, then D1, D2, and X1 can be sold/levied upon.b. If D=W, then creditor is SOL.

3. Group II: W has the same rights as H under old common law (leveling up).a. D1+D2 can be levied upon. So if X dies first, creditors are very

happy. 4. Group III: H has same rights as W under old common law (leveling

down). Following Married Women’s Property Acts.a. Nothing can be levied upon.

5. Group IV: Right of survivorship for either spouse is separately alienable.a. Can only sell/levy upon D2.

(iv)Hawaii joins Group III. Since a tenant by the entirety cannot convey his interest without the consent of his spouse, it cannot be reached by only one spouse’s creditors.

20

Page 23: Property Outline.doc

(v) Dissent: Should have joined Group II – that’s what’s compelled by the Acts.

iii. United States v. 1500 Lincoln Avenue (3d Cir. 1991)(i) D/H used property he owned with D/W (completely innocent) for the

illegal distribution of drugs. Government/P tried to forfeit property. (ii) Can the action of one tenant by the entirety in subjection property to

forfeiture extinguish the property rights of the other tenant?(iii) No. Two purposes to forfeiture statute: forfeit property used for

drug offenses and protecting rights of innocent property owners. (iv)W is entitled to obtain title in fee simple if she doesn’t predecease H. Her

interest can’t be touched by a levy against her husband’s interest. Here the government will be quite happy if W predeceases H.

(v) Result may be different (i.e., in favor of wife) if H doesn’t use the property for illegal purposes. United States v. Lee (7th Cir. 2000)

b. Termination of marriage by divorcei. The common law said the following (but this has been rejected everywhere):

(i) Marital property converted to property of spouse holding title(ii) Property held as tenants in common or joint tenants remained that way(iii) Tenancy by the entirety converted to tenancy in common(iv)Wife usually entitled to lifelong alimony

ii. Common law property states have instead adopted a rule of equitable distribution. More common trend is to subject “marital property” to equitable distribution.

iii. Obligation to pay lifelong alimony abandoned. Now it’s for only a limited period of time.

iv. Movement toward equally distributing property upon divorcev. In re Marriage of Graham (CO 1978)

(i) P/W (flight attendant) supports D/H while D went to b-school and worked part-time. P’s income contributed about 70%. P did most housework. No marital property accumulated. P wanted to get future earnings.

(ii) Does education constitute property which can be divided between spouses upon divorce?

(iii) No. Degree is of personal value to holder. Terminates on death of holder. Not inheritable. Cannot be transferred, sold, assigned, etc. P’s out of luck since no marital assets acquired (in that case, her contribution would be considered).

(iv)Dissent: Most valuable asset P and D acquired during marriage was D’s earning capacity. P’s earnings were an investment. Let’s consider equity.

(v) Approach 2: Reimbursement. Professional degree is not marital property because it’s too speculative in value. Working spouse can get reimbursement alimony (covers all financial contributions toward education, including household expenses). (Most states agree with Graham or Mahoney.) Mahoney v. Mahoney (NJ 1982).

(vi)Approach 3: Full compensation. Reimbursement is not an adequate remedy. Degrees are marital property (statute provides for consideration

21

Page 24: Property Outline.doc

of contributions to career or career potential of spouse). O’Brien v. O’Brien (NY 1985)

vi. Elkus v. Elkus (NY 1991)(i) P/W was an average opera singer. D/H coached her, quit his job, and

became her manager. 10 years as voice coach. Attended and critiqued all performances. Took care of kids. Went from making 2k to 600k/year.

(ii) Does an increase in the value of one spouse’s career, when brought about by the efforts of the other spouse, constitute marital property which can be equitably divided?

(iii) Yes. Follows O’Brien – property can be tangible or intangible. Increased earning capacity just like degree. D made direct and concrete contributions to P’s career.

(iv)In most jurisdictions, professional goodwill is a divisible marital asset (even if degrees aren’t).

vii. Oldham, Putting asunder in the 1990s: NY system is double-counting because we already consider lifetime earning capacity of spouse.

c. Termination of marriage by death of one spousei. Common law

(i) Dower to W: all freehold land in which H was seised during marriage and that was inheritable by the issue of H and W. A life estate in 1/3 of each parcel of qualifying land.

(ii) Curtesy to H: life estate in each piece of W’s real property under certain conditions.

(iii) Have been abolished in all but 6 jurisdictions in the US.ii. Forced share

(i) Surviving spouse gets to choose between what is devised to him/her by will and taking 50% of decedent’s estate.

(ii) Adopted by all but one common law property state.(iii) Usually applies only to property decedent spouse owns at death. (iv)Usually does not apply to life insurance proceeds.(v) Can try to get around this through lifetime gifts, but some states permit the

surviving spouse to set aside these gifts.2. Community property

a. Fundamental idea is that earnings are owned equally. i. All assets acquired during marriage are presumed to be community property;

can rebut by preponderance of evidence. ii. Whatever is bought with earnings is community property.iii. Separate property does not become community property merely by virtue of

the passage of time.b. Nature of community property

i. In most states H and W can freely transmute nature of property via written agreement (in some states, oral).

ii. Upon divorce, some states require that community property be divided equally. Others permit courts to equitably divide.

iii. No community property state recognizes tenancy by the entirety.iv. Community property can only exist between H and W.

22

Page 25: Property Outline.doc

v. No single spouse can sell ownership interest. No single spouse has right to partition or other action.

vi. No survivorship feature. Can be passed through laws of intestacy. Some states (CA included) have developed community property with right of survivorship.

vii. At death, stepped-up tax basis – value of property at death, rather than purchase price. Internal Revenue Code § 1014.(i) This can be secured by residents of a common law stated by creating a

community property trust in AK with an AK resident as trustee.(ii) Can also be secured by a couple changing domicile to community property

state and agreeing to hold property as community property, then moving back to original state.

viii. Can devise community property.c. Management

i. Since 1960s, all community property states have passed laws giving H and W equal rights to management.

ii. Some detailed rules.iii. Manager is a sort of fiduciary. Good faith but not good judgment needed.

d. Mixing community property with separate propertyi. Three approaches

(i) Inception of right(ii) Time of vesting (i.e., when property is paid off)(iii) Pro rata apportionment depending upon relative contributions of

individual in individual capacity v. community subsequent to marriage (more common).

ii. Suppose W has business that she operates before marriage and then sells it off 5 years after marriage, with it more than doubling in value since marriage. (i) In CA, the division of proceeds depends on whether the increase in value

is primarily due to W’s personal activity and abilities or the character of the investment in the type of business.

(ii) If it’s all W’s effort, it’s all community property. If it’s entirely due to the nature of the industry, then it’s all W’s.

e. Migrating couplesi. Once the property has been characterized, ownership does not change when

the parties change their domicile unless both parties consent to the change in ownership.

ii. When someone dies, the law of his domicile at death governs the disposition of personal property. The law where land is located governs the disposition of land.

iii. Community property states usually don’t give surviving spouse a forced share.

23

Page 26: Property Outline.doc

V. Landlord/tenant lawA. The leasehold estates and the lease

1. Four types of leaseholdsa. Term of years: Lease for a single, fixed periodb. Periodic tenancy: Lease for period-to-period

i. Notice of termination by either party must be given within at least one period but not more than six months.

ii. If notice is inadequate for the next period, when does it become effective? The period after that. S.D.G. v. Inventory Control Co. (NJ 1981) – majority view

c. Tenancy at will: Lease for no fixed period that endures so long as both landlord and tenant desire.i. Unlike term of years or periodic tenancy, death of the landlord or tenant

affects the tenancy at will.ii. Modern statutes usually require notice of, say, 30 days to terminate.iii. While this necessarily can be terminated by either landlord or tenant, a

unilateral power of termination can be engrafted on to a term of years or periodic tenancy.

iv. Garner v. Gerrish (NY 1984)(i) D leased house to G. G had option of terminating lease at his choice. P

(executor of D’s estate) wants G out.(ii) If a lessee may terminate a lease when he pleases, is a determinable life

tenancy created?(iii) Yes. A life estate determinable is created when a lessee has the

option of terminating when he pleases. It ends when he dies or terminates.(iv)L leases Blackacre “to T for as many years as L desires.” 3 approaches:

1. Old common law: Tenancy at will; T also has right to terminate.2. Garner: Life estate determinable3. Restatement 2nd of Property, Landlord and Tenant: Fee simple

determinable(v) L leases Blackacre “to T for the duration of the war.” It’s not a term of

years or a periodic tenancy, so it must be a tenancy at will. But this appears to go against the intent of the parties. Perhaps it can be modified by contract. Tension between intent and certainty in property law.1. Courts will sometimes follow intent in spite of law, and sometimes

not. Some courts say that when a lease is ambiguous, there’s a rebuttable presumption that it’s at the will of both parties.

d. Tenancy at sufferance (holdover)i. Crechale & Polles, Inc. v. Smith (MS 1974)

(i) D held over after the end of his five-year lease. P rejected a term-to-term lease and treated him as a trespasser. P then accepted rent for first month, though and now wants to subject him to a full-lease term.

(ii) If a landlord elects to treat a holdover tenant as a trespasser, may he subsequently change his mind and hold him to a new term?

(iii) No. Landlord has two options when a tenant holds over: treat him as a trespasser or hold him over for a new term. Cannot change mind.

24

Page 27: Property Outline.doc

Since P initially wanted to treat D as a trespasser, cannot hold D over for a new term. By accepting rent, though, P can hold D over on a month-to-month basis.

(iv)How do you tell what the period is? Figure out on the basis of rent – not to exceed one year. Restatement.

(v) There is an array of statutes dealing with the length, form, rent amount, and the such of holdover tenants. See p. 455. Many states permit double rent. (In MS, such a statute was held to abrogate common law action.)

(vi)What if a tenant vacates but leaves stuff behind? If it doesn’t interfere with the landlord’s use of the premises, tenant is not liable as a holdover. Caserta v. Action for Bridgeport Community (CT 1976). If tenant holds over, but not voluntarily – e.g., for an illness – she’s not liable. Herter v. Mullen (NY 1899).

e. Lease v. Not-leasei. A lease is a contract and a conveyance. Historically, courts stressed the

conveyance part. But now many concepts of contract law have been incorporated into property law.

ii. The vast majority of states permits oral leases for a term less than a year. Otherwise we run into Statute of Frauds problems.

iii. Consider the roles of bargaining power, form leases, and housing shortages.B. The selection of tenants

1. Fair Housing Acta. § 3604

i. Cannot refuse to sell or rent after making an offer, or refuse to negotiate, or otherwise make unavailable on account of race, color, religion, sex, familial status, or national origin.

ii. Cannot discriminate against person in terms, conditions, or privileges of sale or rental or in provision of services or facilities in connection therewith, because of a protected characteristic.

iii. Cannot make, print, or publish, or cause to be made, printed, or published and notice, statement, or advertisement that indicates a preference, limitation, or discrimination on the basis of a protected characteristic – or the intent to discriminate, prefer, or limit.

iv. Cannot represent to any person on the basis of a protected characteristic that a dwelling is not available when it is.

v. Cannot make representations to a person that the neighborhood will have a certain composition of protected characteristics.

vi. Cannot discriminate in sale/rental or terms/privileges because of a handicap of the buyer/renter, a person who will reside in dwelling after it is rented/sold, or any person associated with the buyer/renter.(i) Discrimination includes refusal to permit reasonable modifications if they

are necessary to afford the person full enjoyment of the premises – except in case of rental may require renter to restore interior of premises to condition that existed before modification, reasonable wear and tear excepted.

25

Page 28: Property Outline.doc

(ii) Discrimination also includes a refusal to make reasonable accommodations in rules, policies, practices, or services, when necessary to afford person full enjoyment of property

(iii) Discrimination further includes failure to design and construct new dwellings so that1. Public/common areas are readily accessible to and usable by

handicapped people2. Doors designed wide enough for wheelchairs to pass through3. All premises contain features of adaptive design

a. Accessible route into and through the dwellingb. Light switches, electrical outlets, thermostats, and other

environmental controls in accessible locationsc. Reinforcements in bathroom walls to allow later installation of

grab barsd. Usable kitchens and bathrooms such that an individual in a

wheelchair can maneuver the spaceb. Exempt

i. Single-family house if owner does not own more than 3 at the same time, does not use professional services to sell or rent, and does not use advertising. (But can use attorney or escrow agents and the like). § 3603

c. Other sections of FHA prohibit discrimination in financing of housing and provision of brokerage services.

2. Civil Rights Act of 1866, § 1982: All citizens of the United States shall have the same right, in every State and Territory, as is enjoyed by white citizens thereof to inherit, purchase, lease, sell, hold, and convey real and personal property.

3. Does the regular exclusion of minorities from housing ads constitute an FHA violation? It’s a potential claim. Ragin v. New York Times Co. (2d Cir. 1991).a. What about housing set-asides for whites to guard against white flight? No. Must

give minority applicants same opportunities as whites. United States v. Starrett City Associates (2d Cir. 1988).

4. Prima facie case under FHAa. Member of protected classb. Applied for and was denied housingc. Was qualified to obtain housing

5. But note that a Civil Rights Act claim probably does require proof of intent.6. Soules v. U.S. Department of Housing & Urban Development (2d Cir. 1992)

a. P was a single mother looking for a 3BR apt for herself, her 12-year old daughter, and her mother. D posted an ad for an apt on the 2d floor of a building. D asked odd questions during a telephone interview, like “Do you have kids?” “How old are they?” “Are they noisy?” because there was this elderly couple in the apt below. P was irritated and wouldn’t answer. P eventually got to see another apt, but D lied and said there weren’t any available in P’s desired location.

b. P contacted HOME, which had a few testers call up. A tester without children got to see the apt but a tester with a 7-year old didn’t get to see. A family with children got to see it and was made an offer. The apt was eventually rented to a woman without children.

26

Page 29: Property Outline.doc

c. Administrative law judge ruled in favor of D. Became a final order of HUD.d. Can a housing provider defeat a rental applicant’s prima facie showing of

discrimination by proving a legitimate, nondiscriminatory reason for effusing to rent? Yes. P made a prima facie case. D had two legitimate reasons – P had a combative attitude and D was constantly out of town to take care of family, so it was impossible to constantly monitor the status of the apt P wanted. These aren’t pretext – substantial evidence supports them. Because the family got to see the apt, D was willing to rent to a family with children.

e. May a fact-finder inquire into a housing provider’s discriminatory intent in questioning prospective renters about familial status? Yes. Not necessarily impermissible to ask about noisy children. Here, the questions were legitimate. Local housing codes require children above 5 years old to have their own bedroom, so asking about age was OK. A housing provider is not precluded from asking about noise because noisy tenants can be deemed a nuisance and evicted. Reasons articulated not pretextual, particularly because the family got an offer.

f. Are restrictions on the number of people who can live in a house discriminatory? When business strategy is to rent below market, minimize turnover, and maintain premises, a prima facie case is rebutted. Pffaf v. HUD (9th Cir. 1996).

g. Glover v. Crestwood Lake Section 1 Holding Corps. (NY 1990): L rents 1br apts to 2 adults, 2br apts to two adults and two children, but not 1br apts to one adult and one child, or 2br apts to one adult and three children. This is discriminatory.

h. What if a landlord discriminates against a heterosexual couple because they’re unmarried? It seems that FHA gets at families with kids, so it may not be implicated. i. Suppose a state/local statute would prohibit this, but L refuses to enforce for

religious reasons. Smith v. Fair Employment & Housing Commission (CA 1996) – no excuse, religion not burdened; Swanner v. Anchorage Equal Rights Commission (AK 1994) – same.

i. L discriminates against a gay couple for fear of AIDS. Baxter v. City of Belleville (IL 1989) – violates FHA.

j. T needs a dog as a companion due to a mental disorder and L has a no-pets policy. HUD v. Riverbay (HUD 1994) – must permit her to have dog.

k. Can L discriminate against lawyers? Kramarsky v. Stahl Management (NY 1977) – yes.

l. Generally fine to mention proximity to bus lines, no drugs or drinking (but not no alcoholics), credit check required, school districts, senior discount, or presence of nursery.

C. Rights and duties in the landlord/tenant relationship1. Delivery of possession

a. Hannan v. Dusch (VA 1930)i. Former tenant failed to vacate. D didn’t do anything to get P in possession.ii. Must the landlord deliver actual possession to the tenant?iii. No. Landlord only has to deliver right to possession (legal possession)

(American rule/minority view). Rejects English rule (landlord has duty to put tenant in actual possession).

27

Page 30: Property Outline.doc

iv. Case law is pretty divided on English v. American rule. Under American rule, tenant can sue tenant wrongfully in possession. Can recover possession and damages.

v. If L leases T a landlocked parcel, L still has duty to deliver actual possession under English rule. Moore v. Cameron Parish School Bd. (LA 1987).

vi. If L leases to T and has another lease with X, but T is in possession, T must still pay rent. Campbell v. Henshey (KY 1970).

vii. Clause in contract that L is excused from liability for failure to deliver possession if building is still under construction is unconscionable. Seabrook v. Commuter Hous. Co. (NY 1972).

2. The defaulting tenanta. Berg v. Wiley (MN 1978)

i. D leased to P for term of 5 years (’twas a commercial lease). Lease provided that consent necessary for any change in building structure. P remodeled without permission and violated health code. D eventually succeeded at changing locks. Trial court found entry was forcible.

ii. May L use self-help to retake possession?iii. No. At common law, circumstances when L could use self-help:

(i) L legally entitled to possession and(ii) L’s means of entry are peaceable

iv. No determination that D was entitled to possession – L can’t determine this, courts must. As to entry: Public policy against self-help. Summary proceedings available, dude! Treble damages for forced entry! So entry was not peaceable. Only reason violence didn’t erupt was because locks were changed. Otherwise it totally would have.

v. Unless T abandons or surrenders premises, L may not use self-help. Must go to the courts.

vi. Berg reflects modern view of self-help, but not yet majority rule.vii. Every state provides some form of summary proceeding. Typically only

require a few days’ notice to T. Anything extrinsic to possession normally not addressed. Many states permit T to use self-help (e.g., withhold rent) if L doesn’t maintain premises, and so summary proceedings for nonpayment can be made. Courts have relied on availability of summary proceedings to abrogate self-help. Avg. of 114 days from request of evictions to day accomplished.

b. Sommer v. Kridel (NJ 1977)i. P failed to make efforts to re-let an apt that D abandoned (never went into

possession).ii. Is the L under a duty to mitigate damager by making reasonable efforts to re-

let an apartment wrongfully vacated by T?iii. Yes. No-mitigation rule based on property view of lease – lease is a property

interest which forecloses any control of property b landlord. But adopts contract view of lease. Landlord does have duty to mitigate damages. L has burden of showing reasonable efforts.

iv. Part of trend in landlord-tenant law to recognize contract law concepts. v. Relevant cases:

28

Page 31: Property Outline.doc

(i) Showing apt to all prospective tenants satisfies duty(ii) Advertised apt in newspaper, placed sign in window, and employed realtor

– duty satisfied(iii) L can ask for higher rent since this was merely a basis for

negotiation1. But if he asks for a ridiculously high amount, probably won’t be in

good faith(iv)D need not accept less than FMV or substantially alter obligations to

satisfy duty(v) Duty breached where newspaper ad placed in one issue of local paper by

broker(vi)Duty breached where L refused to accept suitable subtenant

vi. Since Sommer, majority rule developed that there is a duty to mitigate. NY still has a no-mitigation rule.

vii. Who has the burden of proving mitigation? It seems the majority rule is that the T must prove that the L has mitigated or failed to mitigate. A seemingly minority view is that L has burden of proving mitigation.

c. What if T fails to pay rent when due or breaches some other lease obligation? L can sue, terminate lease, and recover possession. L probably cannot have anticipatory breach recovery – i.e., difference between FMV and rent in lease – unless there’s a state statute providing for it. If it’s not a failure to pay rent but abandonment, then the remedy may be more available if the courts apply contract doctrine.

d. Security devicesi. Deposits

(i) In principle, L must return deposit less amounts necessary to compensate for defaults by T. But in reality L can easily find some problem to justify keeping deposit.

(ii) These abuses have led to some statutory reform. Some limitations include – deposit limited to 2 mos rent; deposits create trust relationship, deposits placed in trust or escrow account; L must pay interest on deposits; etc.

ii. Ls can sometimes avoid restrictions on security deposits by characterizing them not as deposits but as “bonus” or “consideration” for execution of lease. This tends to work so long as there’s no provision for return payment upon termination of the lease.

iii. Even more successful to designate it as “advance rent.” iv. Can also characterize as “liquidated damages,” but there are limitations on it

and it’s often not enforced. And if there’s a clause providing for it, T has little incentive to minimize damages once there’s been a breach.

v. Can also have rent acceleration once there’s a default. This is accepted by a majority of courts.

3. Duties, rights, and remediesa. Moral hazard – once you’re insured, less careful because you’re covered. L has

little incentive to make repairs because costs of neglect are borne by T.b. At common law, premises were “as is” and L had no duty to warrant fitness.

Sweeping reform began in the 60s.

29

Page 32: Property Outline.doc

c. Reste Realty Corp. v. Cooper (NJ 1969)i. Whenever it rained, basement D leased flooded. Became difficult for D to use

premises. D vacated premises. (D had some knowledge of the problem when he signed lease; P promised to fix.)

ii. May T vacate premises and terminate the lease if his quiet enjoyment is interfered with by L?

iii. Yes. Didn’t waive right to quiet enjoyment by knowing of problem because P promised to fix it.

iv. Was D justified in vacating? (i) Covenant of quiet enjoyment is implied in a lease.

1. It’s breached when an act or omission renders the premises unsuitable for the purpose for which it was leased. (This is called a constructive eviction.)

2. When this happens, T has right to terminate lease, and can vacate premises.

(ii) Since D couldn’t use premises for meetings, the purpose for which the basement was rented, she was justified in vacating and canceling lease.

(iii) D didn’t waive right to cancel lease because she remained in possession after learning of defect. Ample evidence that D vacated in reasonable time.

v. Note that eviction (actual or constructive) is not required to show a breach of the covenant. But instead it relates to remedies. The tenant can stay on the premises and sue for difference between value of premises without breach and with. Or the tenant can leave under the theory of constructive eviction.

vi. If a lease is illegal, it’s not enforceable. E.g., if the premises are so unsafe that they violate the health code, then L can’t require payment of rent. Brown v. Southall Realty Co. (DC 1968). (i) This doesn’t apply if the violations arise after the lease is made. Saunders

v. First Nat’l. Realty Corp. (DC 1968).(ii) Minor, technical violations don’t render a lease illegal, nor do violations

of which L didn’t have actual or constructive notice. Diamond House Corp. v. Robinson (DC 1969).

(iii) T under illegal lease is tenant at sufferance and L is entitled to reasonable rental value of premises. William J. Davis, Inc. v. Slade (DC 1970).

d. Hilder v. St. Peter (VT 1984)i. A host of problems: broken window, no key to front door, toilet broken,

bathroom light broken, water leak, plaster falling from ceiling, and broken sewage pipe. L promised to fix but never did. T repaired some things at her own expense.

ii. Is there an implied warranty of habitability in every residential lese?iii. Yes. “As is” rule historically valid, but rejected now. Old view: Lease =

estate in land. New view: Ts have changed. Ls are in much better position to repair. Warranty is non-waivable.

iv. Courts can look to municipal housing code or state court standards – not dispositive, though.

30

Page 33: Property Outline.doc

v. Once warranty is breached, T must notify L and give him time to remedy problem. If it’s not fixed, T can seek rescission, reformation, and damages. Damages shall be difference between value of apt as warranted and apt as it is. T can recover for discomfort and annoyance. T can withhold rent until damages are calculated. T can deduct expenses of repair from rent. So burden on bringing suit is on L. T can pursue punitive damages.

vi. Note that the implied warranty of habitability has exceptions in some jurisdictions – e.g., doesn’t apply to casual Ls, like a professor who goes on sabbatical; single-family residences excepted – and isn’t adopted by all states. Most jurisdictions don’t extend it to commercial properties.

vii. Standard varies, but usually the warranty is violated if a reasonable person would not find it habitable. Continued loud noise or failure of a central air conditioning system may be a violation.

viii. How are damages calculated?(i) Hilder: Value of dwelling as warranted – dwelling in defective condition.(ii) NH: Agreed rent – dwelling in defective condition.(iii) Percentage-reduction: agreed rent is reduced by percentage equal

to percentage lease-value lost by T as a result of L’s breach.ix. Ts tend to ignore specific performance even though it’s available in principle.x. Suppose maintenance staff goes on strike and city sanitation workers won’t

cross picket lines. Trash piles up. L must bear the loss – breach of IWH. Park West Management Corp. v. Mitchell (NY 1979).

xi. The implied warranty of habitability only covers the basic minimums – you can’t recover under it if, say, you pay for a luxury apt and don’t get services you expected. But you probably can recover under a contract action. Solow v. Wellner (NY 1995).

e. Most states prohibit retaliatory actions by L (within, say, 180 days of a good faith complaint). It’s usually via a rebuttable presumption if certain conditions are present. An alternative approach pursued by NY and other states is to permit L to serve an eviction notice once repairs have been made, but require L to give T a reasonable time to find other housing.

f. Note that this interacts with tort law in that some states impose a general duty of care on Ls. But most states stick to the common law.

g. Duty of T not to commit waste is breached if T makes changes to affect a vital and substantial portion of the premises, that would change its characteristic appearance, the fundamental purpose of the erection, or the uses contemplated – or a change that would affect the very realty itself, extraordinary in scope and effect, or unusual in expenditure. Pross v. Excelsior Cleaning & Dyeing Co. (NY 1919).i. Of course, not a bright-line rule. E.g., no waste when T: replaced defective

ceiling with another one that didn’t conform to code, installed light and switch, attached wooden closet to wall, and put frame around window. Rumiche Corp. v. Eisenreich (NY 1976).

ii. T’s duty to repair: Arose out of duty not to commit waste. At common law, duty was to make repairs that would keep the building windtight and

31

Page 34: Property Outline.doc

waterticht, thus preserving the property in substantially the same condition as at the commencement of the term, ordinary wear excepted.(i) But now this is disfavored – doesn’t make sense. Implied warranty of

habitability is in part based on this idea. (ii) Explicit covenants to repair usually except damage by fire or other

casualty. Current trend is that the exception applies even if T caused the harm.

(iii) Does T have a duty to pay rent when the premises have been destroyed? Historically, yes, because the building was not the primary part of the lease – it was the land. An exception was made when part of the premises had been destroyed, and T only leased part of the premises – no interest in the soil. In many jurisdictions legislation creates these results.

D. The problem of affordable housing1. Chicago Board of Realtors, Inc. v. City of Chicago (7th Cir. 1987)

a. Rent control case; ordinance reallocated rights between L and T. Concurring opinion of Judge Posner: This is reasonably related to a public goal, but we really aren’t happy about that.

b. Since this law doesn’t permit Ls to charge Ts more than $10 for late rent but permits Ts to withhold rent, it decreases incentives for Ls to improve housing.

c. Instead, Ls will try to raise rents. This will force poor Ts out. If they can’t raise rent, they will devote more resources to condos, reducing stock of housing.

d. Provision requiring deposits to be placed in IL banks transfers wealth from Ls and out-of-state banks to Ts and in-state banks.

e. This only benefits the middle class, not the poor. They’re a better risk against late rent. They’ll benefit from lower-priced, over-supplied condos.

2. Other economists have said rent control can succeed iff demand for rental units rises sharply at the same time that new construction of the units has been legally restricted in order to conserve resources.

3. Does fairness trump economics?4. In reality, rent control is on the decline.5. These arguments also apply to the implied warranty of habitability.6. We let poor people buy a host of goods that are of sub-optimal quality – what’s so

special about housing?

32

Page 35: Property Outline.doc

VI. Public and private regulation of land useA. Easements

1. Basicsa. Four types of easements

i. Affirmative: The right to use someone else’s propertyii. Negative: To prevent someone from using another’s propertyiii. Appurtenant: Right to use land that benefits owner of particular parcel of landiv. In gross: Benefits owner without regard to ownership of real estate

Appurtenant In grossAffirmative Classic Blackacre/Mauveacre

hypo – Blackacre is landlocked and the adjacent lot, Mauveacre, is next to a road.

Most common.Utility easement, sidewalk easement, billboard

Negative View easement (Aerosmith article)

Least common.Conservation easement.

2. How do you create an easement?a. Grant

i. Willard v. First Church of Christ, Scientist (CA 1972)(i) M owned some lots and let D use them for parking on Sundays. Easement

was in title when M conveyed to Petersen, but not when Petersen conveyed to P. Petersen didn’t mention the easement to P. But D used lot for parking when P was going through purchasing process.

(ii) Can a property owner, in granting her property to a second person, reserve an easement in the property for a third person?

(iii) Yes. Common law: can’t do this. But we’re not restrained by it anymore – want to follow intent of grantor. Property rights are to be treated the same as contracts. Original grantee probably paid less because of the easement. P wasn’t prejudiced – D was still using lot when he was purchasing. Interests of grantors outweigh interests grantees may have in following common law. No evidence that P relied on rule.

(iv)Authority is still divided on common law v. new rule.(v) The theory in this case is that the reservation is a regrant to the grantor

from the grantee. So, O “to A and her heirs, reserving an easement in O,” is treated as two deeds. This developed as a way to get around the common law rule.

(vi)Servient estate: Willard. Dominant estate: Church.(vii) Appurtenant easements cannot be detached from the dominant

tenement without the consent of dominant and servient owners.(viii) The law construes in favor of easements appurtenant when it’s

ambiguous.b. Estoppel

i. License(i) Revocable

33

Page 36: Property Outline.doc

1. A license is oral or written permission given by the occupant of land allowing the licensee to do some act that otherwise would be a trespass. Licenses are revocable, but easements are not.

(ii) Two exceptions: Irrevocable1. License coupled with an interest cannot be revoked – e.g., if O grants

to A the right to take timber from O’s land. A has an interest and an irrevocable license. -- Licensee has some ownership interest in chattel that is on licensor’s land.

2. License starts out as permissive and revocable and becomes irrevocable by operation of estoppel.a. Holbrook v. Taylor (KY 1976)

i. Ds let Ps use a road Ds paved on their land. Ps used the road extensively when building their house. Ps repaired the road, put in culvert, and graveled it with “red dog.” Ds then tried to cut it off.

ii. Can an easement be established by estoppel, or reliance?iii. Yes – even when person making use of property does so with

permission of owner. A license cannot be revoked after the licensee has erected improvements on the land at considerable expense while relying on the license.

iv. Shepard v. Purvine (OR 1952): An oral license is just as binding as a written one.

v. Henry v. Dalton (RI 1959): An oral license to do something on the licensor’s land can be revoked by the licensor, even if the licensee has spent money as a result of faith in the license and the license was originally intended to be a continuous one. Let’s establish a bright-line rule.

vi. Property v. liability rule: Perhaps we can conceive of this as a government subsidy of people who make efficient use of land.

vii. Restatement 3rd agrees w/Holbrook rule.viii. What if Ds’ house burned down – can Ds build a new

house and use the right of way across Ps’ land? Restatement 3rd says that expectations that create the servitude determine its scope and terms.

ix. Should courts give servient owners damages?c. Implication

i. Requirements(i) Apparent(ii) Continuous(iii) Necessity

1. Not necessarily required to show PEU – it informs the apparent nature of the use (whether it’s supposed to be continuous, for example).

2. Strict necessity required? Depends on jurisdiction. NY and TX require strict.

ii. Easement from prior existing usage: Van Sandt v. Royster (KS 1938)

34

Page 37: Property Outline.doc

(i) Shortly after city built sewer line, private sewer lines were built under B’s large lot, extending from city line. B’s lot was then divided into three lots. B sold them off. Houses were built. The house closest to the public line wasn’t so happy about the lines – his basement flooded with sewage. It wasn’t obvious that there were lines under his house – they were buried in the ground.

(ii) Can an easement be created by implication when it was used by a previous owner, yet was not readily visible to a party to the conveyance of the property?

(iii) Yes. This depends in part on the circumstances under which the conveyance of land was made, including extent to which manner of proper use may have been known by the parties. Each party assumed to know about reasonably necessary uses that are apparent upon reasonably prudent investigation. Easement may be implied for grantor or grantee on basis of necessity alone.

(iv)Quasi-easement: owner can use one part of his land to benefit another part of his land. (You can’t just give an easement to yourself.) Benefiting part of land: quasi-dominant tenement. This easement arises from the circumstances – not the language – of the conveyance.

(v) Here, P can’t claim he had no notice. P made careful inspection of property and knew the house had modern plumbing and needed to drain into a sewer. Since he had notice of the lateral sewer, the easement was apparent.

(vi)If dominant and servient tenements come under the same ownership, the easement is extinguished. If they’re redivided, another easement can arise if the circumstances at the time indicate a new easement was intended.

iii. Easement by necessity(i) Othen v. Rosier (TX 1950)

1. D had a plot next to a road. P had landlocked plot adjacent to D’s property. P used roadway on D’s property to access the road. D blocked it off. All of these lots used to be owned by H.

2. Is there an EBN here?3. No. Must show that there was unity of ownership between dominant

and servient estates, that easement is a necessity and not a convenience, and that necessity existed at time the estates were severed. Dominant estate has burden of proof.

4. There was unity of ownership here; but at the time the use of the road was a mere convenience. Other tracts of land could have been crossed. P hasn’t made adequate showing. Mere fact that parcel is landlocked does not create EBN.

5. Is there an easement by prescription? No. The use of the easement was not adverse. This was initially a permissive use.

(ii) Most courts require strict necessity. Others will grant an EBN when there’s access to the land, but it would be inadequate, difficult, or costly.

(iii) What happens if the owner of five parcels, one of which is landlocked, dies intestate and his kids fight over who has to have the

35

Page 38: Property Outline.doc

EBN? Is there an EBN? Fairness suggests there should be an EBN. But where? Perhaps we could evaluate the costs it would impose on each property – put EBN where it would cost the least. This really depends on how strict the court is about necessity and its receptiveness to basing its decision on pure fairness.

(iv)EBN endures only so long as it is necessary. EBPEU is not this way.(v) Some state statutes in the West permit landlocked parcel owners the right

to condemn an easement upon showing of necessity. Servient owner gets damages.1. Leo Sheep Co. v. United States (US 1979): US has no right to EBN to

access landlocked gov’t parcels because it has the power of eminent domain.

d. Prescriptioni. Lost grant theory: Owner of land is presumed to consent or acquiesce in use.

But if the use is made with the permission of the owner, it’s not adverse. So claimant needs to show that the owner didn’t object, but didn’t permit.

ii. The lost grant theory should have completely lost traction when US courts tied prescriptive easements to adverse possession.

iii. In a jurisdiction that doesn’t follow the lost grant theory, owner must effectively interrupt or stop adverse use to prevent a prescriptive easement.

iv. When someone acquires a prescriptive easement, should he have to pay damages to the owner? In CA, court said that legislature would have to bring any changes about, but court was very divided on merits of no-compensation rule.

v. Most courts require exclusive use for prescription, but it’s not the same as in adverse possession – Exclusivity only requires showing that claimant’s right to use land does not depend upon similar right in others.

vi. If O’s property is next to a golf course and errant golf balls frequently fly onto his property, the golf course has a prescriptive easement. MacDonald Properties, Inc. v. Bel-Air Country Club (CA 1977).

vii. Public prescriptive easement: (i) Long, continuous use by public(ii) Under a claim of right – NOT by individuals(iii) Notice to landowner of kind an extent of use(iv)Instead, some courts use theory of implied dedication. Sort of like lost

grant theory – landowner evidences intent to dedicate, and state accepts by maintaining land used by public.

viii. Beach access(i) In most states, the state holds in public trust the beach from the water to

the mean high-tide line. (ii) The dry sand portion between the mean high-tide line and the vegetation

line is subject to private ownership. (iii) Prescriptive easement doctrine has not been very successful in

providing public access, partly because the “adverse” requirement is difficult to prove – permission is presumed.

36

Page 39: Property Outline.doc

(iv)In CA, public prescriptive easements abolished by statute except on land w/in 1000 yards from the ocean. Even on this land the owner can prevent public easement by posting annually a sign (“Right to pass by permission of the owner, revocable at any time”) or recording a similar notice in the public records. Granting permission defeats “adverse.”

(v) Because permission is presumed, a few states (FL, TX, and OR) have found public access because they’ve existed for very, very long – it’s a customary right. Similarly, in HI, public right found up to vegetation line because of history.

3. Negative easementsa. Right of dominant owner to prevent servient owner from doing something on the

servient land. Prevent:i. Blocking of windowsii. Interfering with air flowing to your land in a defined channeliii. Removing the support of your buildingiv. Interfering with the flow of water in an artificial streamv. Newer ones in US

(i) View easement(ii) Conservation easement

b. Judges rather reluctant to create new types of negative easements – not as easy to discover as affirmative easements. Negative easements could arise by prescription, so adding more easements that could arise by prescription would significantly restrain the rights of the servient owner to control his land. Also, historically easements could only be created by grant.i. American courts have accepted this restriction on creating new types of

easements. Sometimes new ones are created.c. Kohl v. Legoullon (AK 1997): Two mansions, one in front of the other was

halfway through building a 5th floor – court said per a view easement, he had to convert it to an open porch/deck.

B. Covenants1. Intro

a. Real covenant: Promise about use of land that runs with the land at law.b. Vertical privity: Privity of estate between successive owners.c. Horizontal privity: Analogizing to successive relationship, it’s a grantor-grantee

relationship. Required for burden to run. Not required for benefit to run. i. Commentators hate the horizontal privity requirement. ii. Restatement 3d doesn’t require horizontal privity.

d. Can be affirmative or negativee. Cannot be enforced against an assignee who has no noticef. General requirements

i. Did original parties intend for burden/benefit to run? Will usually manifest itself in terms of covenant

ii. Does the promise touch and concern the land?iii. Notice? Only applies to burdeniv. Privity?

37

Page 40: Property Outline.doc

(i) Vertical – runs with an estate in land. Burden doesn’t extend to adverse possessor, because it’s a new title.1. Restatement 3d rejects vertical privity requirement. Instead it draws a

distinction between affirmative and negative covenants. Negative covenants are treated like easements for succession purposes – runs to all subsequent possessors and owners of the burdened and benefited land. Affirmative covenants extend to person who succeed estates of the same duration as were held by original parties to the covenant = traditional privity requirements. Burdens run to adverse possessors. Lessees must perform only covenants that are more reasonably performed by her than the L. Life tenants succeed to burdens but liability limited to value of life estate.

(ii) Horizontal – only required for burden – classic situation is where developer sells home to individual purchasers1. You can also have a straw transaction where you convey to X (say,

lawyer) and reconvey to parties to agreement with covenant in deed.g. Suppose B promises A he’ll only use his property for residential purposes. B sells

to C. A sells to D.i. A sues B when B builds a factory: This is just a contract action. Pretty

obvious.ii. A sues C when C builds a factory: A must allege that the burden runs to C,

since C is not an original party.iii. D sues B when B builds a factory: D must allege the benefit runs to D, since D

is not the original party. iv. D sues C when C builds a factory: D must allege that the burden and benefit

run.2. Covenants enforceable in equity

a. Privity not required, except for the benefit, which runs to all assignees (adverse possessors – unclear – hasn’t been litigated) – but everything else is. Enforceability at law is irrelevant.i. What about 3d parties? In some jurisdiction, 3d party beneficiaries can’t

enforce.ii. Property theory of equitable servitudes: It’s an interest in land – not an estate

in land like real covenants. Basically this is like a negative easement. Supports theory that if government condemns property, it must compensate beneficiaries for loss of covenant. Should they only be contract rights? The property theory has prevailed over the contract theory.

iii. Suppose O promises A without any consideration from A. O sells to B. B knows of the promise and violates it. A can probably enjoin B.

iv. Note that a P can always sell an injunction to D – P determines damages rather than a jury.

v. Since unification of law and equity in most states, it really doesn’t matter how it’s classified. You can get damages for equitable actions. Restatement 3d rejects equity/law distinction. Everything is a covenant running with the land.

b. Tulk v. Moxhay (England 1848)

38

Page 41: Property Outline.doc

i. P conveyed to E; title included covenant that E, his heirs, and assigns would maintain garden, without any buildings. Property eventually passed to D; title didn’t contain covenant. D conceded that he had notice of covenant. D tried to build buildings.

ii. Is a covenant enforceable against a purchaser of land when that purchaser acquired the land with knowledge of the covenant?

iii. Yes. A covenant is enforceable in equity against a person who purchases land with notice of the covenant. D had notice. He probably paid less for land because of the covenant. If he can just go and build, that’s not fair. He’d be unjustly enriched – he could resell land at a higher price.

3. Creation of covenantsa. Real covenant can only be created by a written instrument signed by the

covenantor. An equitable servitude can be implied in equity under certain limited circumstances. Cannot be obtained by prescription.

b. Sanborn v. McLean (MI 1925)i. Development which was entirely residential – all lots were residential. Ms

sold some lots with residential-only restrictions in deed. Passed on to D without the covenant contained in deed. Neighbor P tried to enjoin Ds.

ii. Is there a covenant here?iii. Yes. An equitable servitude can be implied on a lot, even when the servitude

is not created by a written instrument, if there is a scheme for development of a residential subdivision and the purchaser of the lot has notice of it.

iv. Ms included covenants for the benefit of the lots they retained. They were subject to them, too. They’re reciprocal negative easements. Can be enforced by P if Ds had notice.

v. There was intent, there was touch and concern. Was there notice? Inquiry notice is looking around to get an idea. Here, there’s been inquiry notice – it’s pretty obvious!

vi. Sufficient notice when not obvious by inquiry notice, but deeds of surrounding properties including restrictions recorded in public record. McQuade v. Wilcox (MI 1921).

vii. Actual notice is probably too tough a standard to prove.c. Neponsit Property Owners’ Association, Inc. v. Emigrant Industrial Savings Bank

(NY 1938)i. N sold to Deyers; deed contained covenant that property would be subjected

to an annual fee for infrastructure maintenance (e.g., roads, gardens, etc. in housing development), payable to P (an assignee of N). D acquired title to Deyers’ property – title mentioned covenant.

ii. Does the covenant touch and concern the land?iii. Yes. What’s determinative is the degree to which the covenant substantially

affects the legal rights of the parties to the covenant. This gave the owners some right to enjoy common property with other nearby owners.

iv. Is there privity between P and D? Yes. P was designed as a convenience to advance common interests of property owners. SO essentially a privity of estate between P and D.

39

Page 42: Property Outline.doc

v. Gradually, 3d party beneficiaries have been permitted to sue on a breach of contract. But there’s still a bit of life in the doctrine that they can’t sue. Generally you need privity. If original promisee didn’t convey land to person who wants to enforce covenant, this doctrine would prevent a suit.

vi. Touch and concern has almost always been found with negative covenants – but not so with affirmative covenants. An affirmative obligation is like a perpetual rent – feudal system. Reluctant to issue orders requiring people to do things, judicial supervision. Enforcing an affirmative covenant may impose large personal liability on a successor.

vii. Touch and concern is often found with covenants to pay money, esp. in a common interest community.

viii. Is the touch and concern requirement valuable?ix. Restatement 3d discards touch and concern. § 3.1:

(i) Servitude is valid unless it’s illegal, unconstitutional, or violates public policy

(ii) Examples of covenants that violate public policy1. Arbitrary, spiteful, or capricious2. Unreasonably burdens a fundamental constitutional right3. Imposes unreasonable restraint on alienation4. Imposes unreasonable restraint on trade or competition5. Unconscionable

(iii) § 3.5:1. An otherwise valid servitude is valid even if it indirectly restrains

alienation by limiting use that can be made of property, by reducing the amount realizable by the owner on sale or other transfer of the property, or by otherwise reducing the value of the property.

2. Servitude that lacks a rational justification is invalid.x. In CA, cannot have a covenant restricting use of home to provide day care for

nonresidents. CA Health & Safety Code § 1597.40(c).4. Scope of covenants

a. Hill v. Community of Damien of Molokai (NM 1996)i. D owned group home for people with AIDs. Unrelated individuals; limited to

4 per house. Outside nurses came to home during day. P and other neighbors noticed increase in traffic after D started using it as a group home – claimed group home violated single family home restrictive covenant. D claimed enforcing covenant, if interpreted to not include the home, would violate FHA.

ii. Does the group home fall within the single family residence covenant? Yes. “Family” isn’t defined in covenant. Ambiguous restrictive covenants interpreted in favor of free use and enjoyment of property against restrictions. The group home has many characteristics of a family – communal meals, do own shopping, provide emotional/financial/spiritual support for each other. Strong public policy of letting disabled people living in residential settings. Also, this isn’t a profit-driven organization – it’s a nonprofit charity.

iii. Do restrictive covenants violate the FHA when they have a discriminatory intent, effect, or constitute failure to make reasonable accommodations? Yes.

40

Page 43: Property Outline.doc

(i) Discriminatory intent: Not enough evidence here(ii) Disparate impact: This would definitely have a disparate impact if the

community wasn’t a single family use, above. Balance neighbor’s interest in avoiding increased traffic against community’s interest in providing housing for disabled individuals. This balance weighs in favor of the community.

(iii) Reasonable accommodations: Neighbors didn’t make reasonable accommodations. In this case, a reasonable accommodation would have been to not seek enforcement of the covenant.

iv. Other courts have interpreted “single family residence” in restrictive covenants to just mean it has to be a house of a particular size.

v. What if a restrictive covenant bars nonresidential use? Some courts have even found that a bed-and-breakfast is a residential use, so is training dogs, and home day care of 5 children. What about home offices?

b. Shelley v. Kraemer (US 1948)i. Restrictive covenant prevented blacks from moving into neighborhood.ii. Is this enforceable?iii. No. The state action here is judicial enforcement of the covenant. Equal

Protection Clause of 14th Amendment prohibits enforcement.iv. Note that since the late 60s, courts have addressed racial discrimination claims

under FHA and § 1982. But when not covered by those laws, Shelley lives. What about unreasonable restraints on alienation

v. Barrow v. Jackson (US 1953): Court cannot grant damages against a seller who breaches a covenant not to convey to a nonwhite. That’s state action.

vi. Mayers v. Ridley (DC Cir. 1972): DC recorder of deeds cannot record deeds containing racial covenants.

vii. Buchanan v. Worley (US 1917): Unconstitutional to zone on the basis of race.C. Public regulation of land use: Zoning

1. Basicsa. Village of Euclid v. Ambler Realty Co. (US 1926)

i. City enacted zoning ordinance that restricted the use and size of buildings in various districts.

ii. Is it unconstitutional to enact an ordinance which establishes a comprehensive zoning plan regulating the use of property?

iii. No. Valid exercise of police power. Sure, this wasn’t needed fifty years ago, but it’s quite necessary now given the urbanization of life. Major issue with exclusion of apartments, stores, and shops from residential zones. There are legitimate goals here – reduction of traffic, open space, quiet, etc. It’s not arbitrary, unreasonable; it’s substantially related to public health, safety, etc.

b. Standard State Zoning Enabling Acti. Empowers municipalities to regulate and restrict buildings. ii. Regulations must be made in accordance with a comprehensive plan and

designed to promote safety, health and general welfare.(i) Only half of the states require and judiciary has been traditionally relaxed,

but this may be changing.

41

Page 44: Property Outline.doc

iii. City must create a zoning (planning) commission who makes recommendations to the city council.

iv. But a few states, including CA, NJ, and PA have deviated from it in recent years. Note that there must be standards controlling the delegation.

2. Exclusionary zoninga. Village of Belle Terre v. Boraas (US 1974)

i. City zoning ordinance confined “family” to individuals related by blood, and confined entire city to singe-family use. Six college students wanted to live together.

ii. Is the ordinance constitutional?iii. Douglas: Yes, as long as it’s rationally related to legitimate objectives, such as

creating zones where family values and the blessings of quiet seclusion and clean air are preserved. No fundamental right is at stake here. This isn’t unreasonable or arbitrary. Legislature has discretion here.

iv. Marshall (dissent): The ordinance burdens rights of association and privacy under First and Fourteenth Amendments. Sure, we defer to legislatures, but not when they intrude upon fundamental rights. This is very under- and overinclusive based on the stated goals (above).

v. Moore v. City of East Cleveland (US 1977): Limited holding of Belle Terre. Court invalidated ordinance that defined “family” as not including more than one set of grandchildren. Court distinguished Belle Terre because the ordinance only applied to unrelated individuals. Here, this is a major intrusion into the family.

vi. Some states take less deferential positions than the Court did in Belle Terre. E.g., NY courts have invalidated statutes that permit any number of related people to live together but only two unrelated people to live together if they’re elderly – goals of maintaining integrity of single-family neighborhood fine, but means are too restrictive. McMinn v. Town of Oyster Bay (NY 1985).

b. City of Edmonds v. Oxford House, Inc. (US 1995)i. Zoning code limited “family” to people related by blood or a group of 5 or

fewer unrelated people. O opened a group home for 10-12 people recovering from drug or alcohol addiction in a single-family housing zone. There’s an FHA exception for reasonable restrictions on maximum number of individuals in dwelling.

ii. Does the provision fall under the exception?iii. Ginsburg: No. The primary purpose of FHA is to get fair housing for people.

So exception should be interpreted narrowly. Single-family restrictions get at character of neighborhood, but maximum-occupant restrictions get at health and safety. This is a family composition rule, not a maximum-occupant rule. This provision doesn’t answer maximum occupancy – another provision does that.

iv. Oxford House v. City of St. Louis (8th Cir. 1996): Regulation limiting occupancy to 8 has a rational basis; plus, OH didn’t apply for an exception. Don’t want federal courts to act as zoning boards.

c. Southern Burlington County NAACP v. Township of Mount Laurel (NJ 1975)

42

Page 45: Property Outline.doc

i. D’s zoning ordinance only provided for single-family residences, with only one house per lot. A new housing development would only be within financial reach of upper-income families.

ii. Rents pushed higher due to public services. Added zone for retirement community would only be accessible to wealthy retirees. City sort of agreed to low-income housing, but only on large lots and as single-family housing.

iii. Can a municipality make it physically and economically impossible to provide low and moderate income housing?

iv. No. A developing municipality must, by its land use regulations, make realistically possible the opportunity for an appropriate variety and choice of housing for all categories of people who may desire to live there, including those of low and moderate income.

v. City can’t justify its regulations by the fact that poor people who move in will use costly services and not be able to pay their own way. Relief will have to be provided from other branches of government.

vi. Mt. Laurel II (NJ 1983) - Court requires that every municipality produce low and moderate housing; much more draconian, concrete, exact about what municipalities have to do.

vii. Other means of excluding poor people(i) Minimum housing cost: Invalidated by courts(ii) Minimum floor area: Mixed judicial reaction(iii) Minimum lot size: Upheld in most cases if rational justification in

community(iv)Minimum setback: Upheld because they increase light and air, reduce fire

danger(v) Barring mobile or manufactured homes: Almost always upheld in early

cases, and still upheld today, but some exceptionsviii. Tiebout hypothesis: Consumers benefit from being able to vote with their

feet. Specialization of municipalities and competition among them enhances efficiency.(i) But contrast with Waring Blender model: Calls for all land uses and all

types of households to be represented in each neighborhood in proportion to their representation in the entire metropolitan area.

ix. Professor: Desire to pay market value for things is innate.

43

Page 46: Property Outline.doc

VII. Takings and eminent domainA. Introduction, public use, and just compensation

1. Eminent domain as a constraint on monopoly (Posner)2. This is all about the “uncompensated increment.”3. Hawaii Housing Authority v. Midkiff (US 1984)

a. Just under half of HI’s land was owned by only 72 people, and HI wanted them to break up their estates. Forced them to sell to their tenants.

b. Does this satisfy the Public Use requirement?c. O’Connor: Yes. Courts should have strong deference to legislature.

Concentration of land ownership has altered housing market. Regulating oligopoly has long been recognized as a legitimate exercise of police powers.

d. Exercise of power is legitimate, then. Statute authorizing the plans is rationally connected to the problem. Only look at the taking’s purpose, not the mechanics of it, to determine whether it’s a public use.

e. Berman v. Parker (US 1954): Redevelopment of slum areas and transfer to private interests is constitutional.

f. Public use – focus on ends or means of taking? Pressing need or mere convenience? Don’t forget additional costs to government – legislative authorization, judicial proceedings, and professional appraisals.

4. Poletown Neighborhood Council v. Detroit (MI 1981)a. D wanted to condemn some property so GM could build a plant.b. Is this a public use?c. Yes. The private benefit here is only incidental to the public benefits. D will

benefit from thousands of jobs and tax revenues. Primary objective is revitalization of local economy.

d. Dissent 1: The primary objective here is to benefit GM. It’s not blighted property.e. Dissent 2: GM dictated all the terms of the project. It just promises a greater

public benefit than the prior use.f. Was later overruled – Hathcock – in July 2004.

5. City of Oakland v. Oakland Raiders (CA 1982)a. Owners of Oakland Raiders wanted to move to LA; city tried to acquire them via

eminent domain.b. Does the taking of a professional sports franchise satisfy a legitimate public

purpose?c. Yes. Anything calculated to promote the education, recreation, or pleasure of the

public is within legitimate scope of “public use.” Cities own and operate facilities, so they can own and operate a team.

d. The public use question was remanded, and action was dismissed on other grounds. Dismissal reversed and remanded again. Court later ruled that taking would violate commerce clause.

6. Kelo v. City of New London (US 2005): Property taken for use as a Pfizer plant – CT Supreme Court said it was a public use, now before the Supreme Court. Poletown all over again.

7. Just compensationa. Generally, this just means fair market value.b. It’s an objective standard.

44

Page 47: Property Outline.doc

i. United States v. Commodities Trading Corp. (US 1950): “What compensation is ‘just’ both to an owner whose property is taken and to the public that must pay the bill?”

c. When the US takes property from city or state government, the court historically required compensation in terms of the “substitute facilities” doctrine – don’t just compensate for FMV of property, but also cost of obtaining other substitute facilities. But this was abandoned by the Court when the value of the land is ascertainable, even if the condemnee has a duty to replace condemned facility and cost of substitute exceeds compensation. United States v. 50 Acres of Land (US 1984).

B. Physical occupation and regulatory takings1. Two categorical rules

a. Loretto v. Teleprompter Manhattan CATV Corp. (US 1982)i. D installed a cable on a building under state statute. Ran along roof of

building, and was attached directly to masonry. D was given exclusive rights to provide cable in the building. P bought the building without notice of the cable.

ii. Is this a taking?iii. Marshall: Yes. A permanent physical occupation of an owner’s property

authorized by the government constitutes a taking which requires just compensation, regardless of the public interests it may serve. Property is seriously devalued as a result of this. Permanent occupation is arguably one of the most serious invasions of property rights. State can still regulate fire alarms and the such because it imposes duties on L/Ts and not third parties.

iv. Blackmun (dissent): What’s “permanent”? What about statutes requiring installation of fire alarms? The third party problem would still exist even if P owned the cable – D would still send signals through cable. Distinction between permanent occupation and temporary invasion has not basis in Takings precedent or economic logic. Takings claims should be evaluated under a multiple-factor balancing test, and not a set formula. Plus, what other use would P have for the space?

b. Hadacheck v. Sebastian (US 1915)i. P owned property that contained some very valuable clay – if it was used for

that purpose it was worth about 800k but only 60k if used for residential purpose. P already set up expensive brickyard machinery.

ii. After purchase it was annexed by City of LA, and the city said he violated an ordinance against brickyards.

iii. Can a person’s property be taken in the prohibition of a nuisance without compensation?

iv. Yes. This is an exercise of the police power and so no compensation is needed. One of the most essential powers of government, and has few limitations. Reality is that P can still use his property, just not for the brickyard. And he can operate the brickyard elsewhere.

v. Note: This decision has been heavily criticized. Seems that the rule is – if it’s a nuisance control measure, it’s not a taking. Concept is it’s regulating a public bad rather than expropriating a public good.

45

Page 48: Property Outline.doc

2. Rules based on measuring and balancinga. Pennsylvania Coal Co. v. Mahon (US 1922)

i. D owned mining rights to land, sold surface rights to P. Statute prohibited mining.

ii. Is a property regulation statute which eliminates a pre-existing property right the equivalent of a taking without compensation?

iii. Holmes: Yes. If regulation goes too far in diminishing value of property, it will be a taking. Of course, some property rights have an implied limitation and must yield to government’s police power. This eminent domain power, though, must be limited by contracts and due process clauses. Where the limits lie will depend on the facts of each case.

iv. Court suggests that a secure and average reciprocity of advantage (e.g. zoning) will be upheld.

v. Here, limited public interest in law – there’s an exception for people who mine and own surface land. This can’t be justified as a protection of personal safety because D gave P notice of intent to mine. Enforcement would eliminate D’s interest in the coal and would go against a valid contract between Ds. Making this commercially impracticable is the same as taking it.

vi. Brandeis (dissenting): Right to land is never absolute. Can’t use land in a way that threatens public welfare. Restriction is lawful if it’s an appropriate means to the public end. This is one of the only ways of keeping the surface from sinking. Mere notice can’t prevail over exercise of police power.

vii. Keystone Bituminous Coal Association v. DeBenedictis (US 1987): Basically same situation as Pennsylvania Coal. No taking because purpose not just to balance private economic interests but to promote public interest in health, environmental quality, and fiscal integrity. Coal company didn’t show sufficient diminution in value either. Rehnquist (dissenting): Majority wrongly discounted Pennsylvania Coal.

b. Pennsylvania Central Transportation Co. v. City of New York (US 1978)i. Commission D designated P1’s land a landmark. Didn’t restrict actual use, but

severely restricted any changes—needed D’s approval. P1 submitted plans to D for a lease with P2, which would have produced much income but entailed building a high rise. D rejected plans, calling one “an aesthetic joke.”

ii. Was there a taking?iii. Brennan: No. A law that is substantially related to the promotion of the

general welfare and that does not interfere with an owner’s primary expectation concerning the use of the property, and allows the owners to receive a reasonable return on his investment, does not effect a taking which demands just compensation.

iv. Look at how rights to the property as a whole are affected – not just, say, air space.

v. P1 can still get a reasonable return on the property. P1 can submit other plans that are more in line with D’s desire to maintain landmark. It’s not ideal, but P1 still has very valuable rights.

46

Page 49: Property Outline.doc

vi. Rehnquist (Dissenting): this isn’t like a typical zoning restriction where there are benefits and burdens on restricted properties. No reciprocity of advantage. Remand to see whether transferable development rights are just compensation.

vii. Transferable development rights: because of the regulation, the city gives P1

the right to violate zoning laws in other areas with buildings they own or the right to sell the TDRs. This serves to ease the burden of regulation so that the court will find that does not amount to a taking.

viii. Distinct investment-backed expectations have been very puzzling. Some courts have read them out of takings law by finding expectations frustrated only when all economically viable uses of the land are frustrated. Others have found DIBE only in instances when regulations interfered with investments that have already been made.

47