Privatisation in Ireland: The Divestiture of Bord Gáis Energy

53
1 Title Page Name: Adam Burke ID Number: 10112545 Project Title: Privatisation in Ireland: The Divestiture of Bord Gáis Energy Internal Supervisor: Dr. Donal Palcic Degree Title: Bachelor of Arts in Economics and Sociology Date: 20 February 2014 Word Count: 12,983

description

University of Limerick Final Year Project

Transcript of Privatisation in Ireland: The Divestiture of Bord Gáis Energy

  • 1

    Title Page

    Name: Adam Burke

    ID Number: 10112545

    Project Title: Privatisation in Ireland: The Divestiture of Bord Gis Energy

    Internal Supervisor: Dr. Donal Palcic

    Degree Title: Bachelor of Arts in Economics and Sociology

    Date: 20 February 2014

    Word Count: 12,983

  • 2

    Abstract

    A new round of divestiture in the Irish public enterprise portfolio appears imminent.

    Government is pursuing privatisation as a means of raising revenue to service the countrys

    debt and part-finance its NewERA economic stimulus package in the wake of Irelands

    financial crisis. This paper contends that this privatisation policy is a manifestation of lead

    coalition government member Fine Gaels neo-liberal economic agenda that seeks to reduce

    the role of the state in the provision of goods and services previously provided by state owned

    enterprises (SOEs). The theoretical and empirical case for privatisation as a means of

    improving enterprise performance is demonstrated to be ambiguous. A case study of the

    ongoing divestiture of Bord Gis Energy (BGE) is undertaken which finds that BGE is being

    solid amidst significant regulatory and governance shortcomings and via a method of sale

    widely criticised in the failed divestiture of Telecom ireann. In conclusion, a

    recommendation is made that calls for the immediate postponement of any future

    privatisation of Irelands SOEs.

  • 3

    Contents

    Acknowledgements 5

    Declaration 6

    List of Abbreviations 7

    List of Figures and Tables 8

    Introduction 9

    Chapter 1 Literature Review 11

    1.0 Introduction 11

    1.1 Defining Economic Efficiency 11

    1.2 Theoretical Literature Review 11

    1.3 Methodological Issues 13

    1.4 Empirical Literature Review 13

    1.5 Conclusion 16

    Chapter 2 Public Enterprise and Privatisation in Ireland 17

    2.0 The History of Irelands Public Enterprise Formation 17

    2.0.1 Introduction 17

    2.0.2 Public Enterprise Formation in Ireland: 1927-1957 17

    2.0.3 Public Enterprise Formation in Ireland: 1957- 1989 19

    2.1 Privatisation in Ireland 19

    2.1.1 Introduction 19

    2.1.2 Privatisation in Ireland: 1991-1996 20

    2.1.3 The Privatisation of Telecom ireann 21

    2.1.4 Privatisation in Ireland: 2001-2006 22

    Chapter 3 A New Round of Divestitures 24

    3.0 Introduction 24

    3.1 The Economic Crisis in Ireland 24

    3.2 Fine Gaels New Economy Recovery Authority 26

    3.3 Memoranda of Understandings 28

    3.4 Report of the Review Group on State Assets and Liabilities 29

    Chapter 4 The Privatisation of Bord Gis Energy 31

    4.0 Introduction 31

  • 4

    4.1 The Economics of Natural Gas 32

    4.2 The European Gas Market 33

    4.3 Bord Gis ireann 34

    4.3.1 The Development of Bord Gis ireann 34

    4.3.2 The Structure of Bord Gis ireann 35

    4.4 Bord Gis Energy 36

    4.4.1 Introduction 36

    4.4.2 Market Share: Electricity 37

    4.4.3 Market Share: Natural Gas 37

    4.4.4 Price Regulation in the Residential Supply Sector 38

    4.4.5 Business Performance 40

    4.5 The Sale Process to Date 42

    Chapter 5 Future of Privatisation Policy in Ireland 45

    5.0 Introduction 45

    5.1 A Critique of the Imminent Privatisation of Bord Gis Energy 45

    5.2 Recommendations in Conclusion 47

    Bibliography 48

  • 5

    Acknowledgements

    Firstly, I would like to thank my supervisor Dr. Donal Palcic whose guidance and expertise

    were invaluable throughout the development of this project.

    I would also would like to thank Shelby, for being a beautiful distraction and infinitely

    patient throughout.

    Finally, I would like to thank my parents Ger and David. Your sacrifice, love and

    encouragement have enabled me to thrive during my four years at the University of Limerick.

    One day I will be able to repay the debt I owe you.

  • 6

    Declaration

    I hereby declare that this project is entirely my own work, in my own words, and that all

    sources used in researching it are fully acknowledged and all quotations properly identified. It

    has not been submitted, in whole or in part, by me or another person, for the purpose of

    obtaining any other credit / grade. I understand the ethical implications of my research, and

    this work meets the requirements of the Faculty of Arts, Humanities and Social Sciences

    Research Ethics Committee.

    _____________________

    Adam Burke

    20/02/2014

  • 7

    List of Abbreviations

    UK United Kingdom

    SOE State Owned Enterprise

    BGE Bord Gis Energy

    NewERA Ltd. New Economy Recovery Authority Limited

    EC European Council

    EU European Union

    IMF International Monetary Fund

    ECB European Central Banl

    TFP Total Factor Productivity

    ROCE Return on Capital Employed

    VA Value Added

    DEA Data Envelopment Analysis

    ACC Agricultural Credit Corporation

    ICC Industrial Credit Corporation

    TSB Trustee Savings Bank

    ESOP Employee Share Ownership Plan

    MoU Memoranda of Understanding

    GDP Gross Domestic Product

    GJ Gigajoule

    US United States

    VAT Value Added Tax

    USSR Union of Soviet Socialist Republics

    NAM Nederlandse Aardolie Maatschappij

    OPEC Organisation of the Petroleum Exporting Countries

    KM Kilometre

    CER Commission for Energy Regulation

    NDM Non-daily metered

    IC Industrial and Commercial

    FVT Fuel Variation Tariff

    RTF Regulated Tariff Formula

    TD Teachta Dla

    RBC Royal Bank of Canada

    OECD Organisation for Economic Co-Operation and Development

    ICTU Irish Congress of Trade Unions

  • 8

    List of Figures and Tables

    Table 1 Commercial State-Owned Enterprises in Ireland

    by the 1980s

    18

    Table 2 Privatised SOEs in Ireland and Exchequer

    Proceeds

    20

    Fig. 1 The Structure of Bord Gis ireann and its

    Subsidiaries

    35

    Table 3 Table 3: Market Share of Electricity Suppliers as a

    Percentage of Customer Numbers Across Market

    Segments

    37

    Table 4 Table 4: Market Share of Natural Gas Suppliers as

    a Percentage of Customer Numbers across Market

    Segments

    38

    Fig. 2 Market Share of Residential Natural Gas Supply 39

    Table 5 Irish Residential Gas Prices to Residential

    Consumers at Purchasing Power Parity (all

    taxes included) (1st Semester 2013) EU Comparison

    40

    Fig. 3 Fig. 3 BGE Operating Profit before Depreciation

    and Amortisation (EBITDA) 2009-2012

    41

  • 9

    Introduction

    Since being brought into vogue by Margaret Thatchers UK conservative government in the

    late 1970s, privatisation has prevailed as the most popular means of improving public sector

    performance. This prevalence is largely due to a global swing towards a hegemonic neo-

    liberal economic ideology which seeks to minimise government control of the economy by

    establishing a liberal and competitive private sector market economy. Privatisation has thus

    become a divisive issue in a wider ideological debate about the role of government in the

    economy. It is often presented by proponents as the common sense approach to modern

    economics, while those in opposition tout it as a malicious method of undermining public

    welfare in the pursuit of maximised profits (Palcic and Reeves 2011).

    The term privatisation has been used loosely to describe a variety of public sector reforms

    including liberalisation, deregulation and contraction out of public sector activities. Thus,

    Starr (1988) defines privatisation as any transfer in the production of goods and services from

    the public to the private sector. Starr (1988: 16-17) refines this definition in the following

    sub-categorisation:

    Governments ending public programmes and disengaging from specific

    responsibilities.

    The sale or lease of public assets (public land, infrastructure or state owned

    enterprises) by the state to transfer ownership to the private sector.

    Government withdrawal from the production of services while remaining financier.

    For example, this can occur by contracting out or through some forms of public

    private partnerships.

    The deregulation of entry into former state monopolistic markets.

    For the purpose of this study, privatisation will hereafter refer exclusively to the transfer of

    state owned enterprises (SOEs) to the private sector by sale. SOEs are to be understood as per

    Palcic and Reeves (2011) explanation as commercial enterprises owned by the state, who

    earn the majority of their income in selling goods and services.

  • 10

    As the pioneers of privatisation policies in Europe, empirical research of the European

    privatisation experience has typically focused on the experience of the UK. There exists a

    small but growing trend of country specific studies which seek to illuminate the motivations,

    rationale, methods and outcomes of the privatisation of state owned companies (Palcic and

    Reeves 2011). This study seeks to contribute to the existing literature on the Irish

    privatisation experience by providing an analysis of the ongoing divestiture of Bord

    Gis Energy (BGE), the retail arm of Irelands state-owned utilities company Bord

    Gis ireann.

    This study is structured as follows; a review of the theoretical and empirical literature of

    privatisation to date is undertaken. This theory is then applied to an analysis of Irish SOE

    formation and privatisation activity to date. Irelands current economic crisis is then

    identified and explained as a driving force and rationale for a renewed interest in privatisation

    in the context of a structured bailout programme. A number of documents are then analysed;

    the governments NewERA economic stimulus plan, the various Memoranda of

    Understanding agreed in return for Irelands bailout between the Irish government and the

    EC/IMF/ECB and a Report of the Review Group on State Assets and Liabilities. This

    analysis will identify the trajectory of recent privatisation policy formation and demonstrate

    the key role played by the Troika in the decision making process. A case study of the ongoing

    divestiture of Bord Gis Energy follows.

  • 11

    Chapter 1: Literature Review

    1.0 Introduction

    A thorough review of the theoretical and empirical literature of privatisation policy is

    essential in moving beyond a discourse all too often hijacked by vested interests. This

    literature largely developed in parallel with the implementation of privatisation policies in the

    UK in the early 1980s and has advanced substantially since. A period of stagflation with

    sustained unemployment, decreasing growth and rising inflation in the 1970s undermined

    Keynsian economic theory and paved the way for neo-liberal reforms in the British economy.

    Deregulation, liberalisation and privatisation were the order of the day as the British

    government sought to emerge from economic crisis (Palcic and Reeves 2011).

    1.1 Defining Economic Efficiency

    The economic argument for the sale of SOEs to the private sector is generally premised on

    the supposition that enterprises under private ownership will achieve superior efficiency. It is

    imperative to distinguish between different concepts of efficiency. Parker (2000: xv) offers

    this distinction; Technical efficiency, a supply side concept, occurs when firms minimise

    costs by maximising output at a given level of resources. Allocative efficiency, on the other

    hand, is conceptualised from the demand side. Firms are allocatively efficient when they

    when they set prices equal to the marginal economic cost of supply. In doing so, societal

    economic well being is maximised through an optimal distribution of resources.

    1.2 Theoretical Literature Review

    The initial theoretical rationale for employing privatisation as a means of improving

    economic efficiency came from theories of government failure; public choice perspectives

    and property rights. Principal-agent theory was subsequently developed as a contractual

    approach to the theoretical analysis of privatisation, and has influenced much of the

    theoretical developments in the area thereafter (Palcic and Reeves 2011).

    Public choice theory as developed by Buchanan and Tullock (1962) focuses on the motives of

    elected representatives and bureaucrats as a source of inefficiency. Chicagoan public choice

    theory asserts that decision making will always be based on individuals financial self-

    interest. Thus, public sector workers and politicians will always forsake maximised profits

  • 12

    and efficiency in pursuit of personal financial gain. It is argued that privatisation can put in

    place an incentive structure that allows for the alignment of financial self-interests and

    corporate goals. Virginian public choice theory on the other hand, identifies non-economic,

    political motivations for privatisation such as a reduction in state power. This leads Boycko et

    al (1996) to claim that democratic elections, rather than ownership per se, are the primary

    source of inefficiencies in state owned enterprises.

    Parker and Willner (2007) have developed a considerable rebuttal to public choice theory in

    which they question the very assumption on which the literature is built, that of the individual

    as homo economicus. They assert that the concept of an economically rational, financially

    driven individual is not useful in all situations, pointing to the examples of non-commercial

    activity and social institutions. Furthermore, they argue there to be a bias in the preposition

    that public sector managers are inherently more disposed to being self-serving and wasteful.

    They go on to question whether state owned enterprises operate more efficiently in a

    dictatorship as implied by Boyckos (1996) rationale and find the opposite to be empirically

    true.

    De Alesi (1987) concedes that state intervention in the provision of goods and services is

    useful in so far as it allows for the correction of allocative and distributive market failures.

    However, he employs a property rights argument to justify privatisation. He sees public

    servants as pursuing their own self-interest and those of lobbying groups. They do not

    maximise profit or efficiency, nor do they operate in the publics best interest. Thus public

    ownership is easily corrupted, bent to political will and unaccountable. However, it can be

    argued that the incentive to maximise efficiency for governments is large, as state owned

    enterprises directly influence government finances and that the democratic process is such

    that the pressure of future elections makes governments accountable for the performance of

    those enterprises under their control (TASC 2012).

    Principal-agent theory examines the relationship between a principal who delegates work to

    an agent. Objective and information asymmetries characterise this relationship under public

    ownership; the principal and agents objectives can become misaligned, and the principal

    strains to see what the agent is doing through a thick layer of organizational bureaucracy. Bs

    (1991: 92) argues that privatisation alters the context of this relationship. The layer of

    bureaucracy is reduced, and ownership is diversified amongst a multitude of parties, such as

    financial organizations, individual shareholders and employees. It is argued that these

  • 13

    organizational and ownership changes induce an environment where incentives can be re-

    aligned, monitoring increased and information can flow more freely. The struggle to design

    appropriate incentive structures and contracts is overcome, thereby leading to greater

    efficiency.

    1.3 Methodological Issues

    Prior to a review of empirical studies of privatisation, it is important to highlight the key

    methodological issues that inevitably compromise any comparative study of public versus

    private enterprises. As mentioned previously, state owned enterprises often operate with

    motives beyond profit. These enterprises can become vehicles of government policy. Thus,

    standard performance indicators used to measure performance in the private sector such as

    financial, productivity and cost measures may not be appropriate for publicly owned

    companies thereby undermining comparative studies. Furthermore, price as a basis of most

    indicators may not be appropriate as many state owned enterprises operate in non-competitive

    markets (Palcic and Reeves 2011).

    The effect of ownership change is but one of a host of factors such as the regulatory

    environment, size, market and incentive structures that affect performance. This is further

    complicated when looking at performance over time, where one must also control for

    technological variation and sector trends. The task of controlling for such a vast set of

    interdependent and non-mutually exclusive variables so as to isolate the effect of ownership

    on performance is a daunting one, and something that a lot of studies fail to achieve. The

    following will review the empirical literature of privatisation in light of these methodological

    challenges (Palcic and Reeves 2011).

    1.4 Empirical Literature Review

    A nominal division of the numerous empirical studies of the effect of privatisation on

    financial and operating performance can be made along the lines of broad based international

    studies and in-depth country specific studies. The methods, limitations and conclusions of a

    selection of prominent studies from both categories are discussed and their collective results

    demonstrated to be ambiguous.

    Much of the early empirical research on privatisation was conducted in the UK, as academics

    clamored to understand the effects of its governments pioneering public sector reforms.

  • 14

    Yarrow (1986) used financial performance indicators to study productive efficiency. It was

    found that private ownership was preferential over public ownership in competitive markets.

    However, where there existed a market failure, no evidence of improved performance could

    be observed following divestiture

    Bishop and Kay (1989) used similar performance indicators to assess the productive

    efficiency of a sample of UK public and privately owned enterprises in a comparative study.

    A total factor productivity analysis was also undertaken. This study found that growth and

    profitability can cause privatisation, and that the very threat of privatisation can improve

    performance through increasing commercialisation. Bishop and Thompson (1992) studied the

    performance of British utilities between 1970-1980 and 1980-90. Labour productivity gains

    were found, as privatisations took hold at the end of the 1970s. Productivity gains measured

    with a total factor productivity analysis were identified to be higher in the 1980s than the

    1970s but the researchers suggest that changes in the regulatory environment were more

    influential than ownership changes in bringing about these gains.

    These studies are not without methodological problems. Both studies by Yarrow (1986) and

    Bishop and Thompson (1992) were undertaken immediately after privatisation thus

    precluding the longer term effects of these divestitures from their analysis. Bishop and Kays

    1989 study failed to control for national productivity which may have had a significant

    bearing on their findings. Furthermore, the time periods analysed in Bishop and Thomsons

    1992 study did not coincide with the times of privatisations occurring thereby rendering it

    very difficult to identify the effect of privatisation on the observed productivity gains. In

    general, such studies fail to account for the effect of organisational and management changes

    that tend to arise with an ownership change. If the effect of these changes has a significant

    bearing on performance gains, a case might be made for corporate restructuring over

    privatisation as a means of achieving economic efficiency (Palcic and Reeves 2011).

    Three broad based empirical studies conducted by Meggison et al (1994), Boubakri and

    Cosset (1998) and DSouza and Meggison (1999) collectively analysed the effect of

    privatisation on the performance of 211 firms, across 42 countries and 56 industries. Using

    largely the same methodology, the studies tested whether privatisation led to increased

    profitability, operating efficiency, capital investment spending output, dividend payments,

    decreased employment and leverage. These performance indicators were measured for the

    three years prior to and following divestiture.

  • 15

    Meggison et al (1994) found performance to be superior following privatisation. Profitability,

    dividend payments and capital investment increased while employment remained constant.

    These performance indicators were not market adjusted; however they concluded that their

    results were not influenced by the macroeconomic environment by computing the average

    Gross National Product growth rate, inflation rate and change in countries industrial

    production index. Boubakri and Cosset (1998) found similar gains in performance while

    exclusively studying privatisation in developing countries. They sought to isolate the effect of

    privatisation from economy wide factors by calculating performance indicators with both raw

    and market adjusted data. DSouza and Meggison (1999) made no such allowance for the

    business cycle. However, their findings correspond with those of the two aforementioned

    studies, as well as measuring an increase in post-divestiture employment.

    These studies do not overcome the methodological issues as outlined previous. The

    performance measures employed cannot accommodate the non-profit motive of state owned

    enterprises, nor can the effect of divestiture be isolated from the wide array of determinants

    of performance. Further problems arise when one analyses the composition of the companies

    studied in these broad based studies. Boubakri and Cosset (1998) dealt exclusively with

    divestitures in developing countries. The relevance of their experience could be questioned

    for a study of a small open economy such as Irelands. Furthermore, DSouza and Meggison

    (1999) used a sample with a high proportion of electricity and telecom companies. Such

    companies experiences have been unique, with a global policy preference towards

    privatisation as a means of funding the capital investment needed for a rapid technological

    advancement in the sector. Thus, their findings are limited in their application to other sectors

    at different stages of development (Palcic and reeves 2011).

    While the methodological difficulties in studying privatisation are such that the academic

    literature is unavoidably imperfect, Martin and Parkers (1997) study of 11 privatised

    companies in the UK represents one of the most comprehensive to date. Throughout, national

    productivity trends were accounted for and averages figures used for periods before and after

    divestiture. The researchers employed several methods to establish the impact of privatisation

    on performance:

    Martin and Parker (1997) began by studying the effect of the change from public to private

    ownership had on labour productivity, finding it increased in most cases. However, a Total

    Factor Productivity (TFP) analysis saw TFP increase in only 2 cases. The researchers

  • 16

    concluded that overstaffing occurred in public enterprises through managerial slackness and

    inefficiencies arising from political intervention. Repeating the study using the accountancy

    ratios Return on Capital Employed (ROCE) and Value-Added (VA), the researchers could

    not support the hypothesis that private enterprises performed better than their public

    counterparts on efficiency grounds.

    In looking at the affect of privatization on technical efficiency, Martin and Parker (1997)

    employed a Data Envelopment Analysis (DEA). This linear programming method derives the

    relative efficiencies of decision making units. Using 3 different models, no systemic evidence

    of technical efficiency gains following divestiture were found, despite 3 of the 11 privatised

    companies demonstrating technical efficiency gains. Finally, the effect of business

    restructuring on performance was analysed in the context of privatisaion and a change in the

    competitive environment. This highlighted the importance of internal factors on performance,

    as privatisation and a more competitive market were found to bring about several positive

    changes internally, such as an increased focus on profits and consumer needs, flexible

    working practices, a flattening of organisational structures and an increase in disposals and

    acquisitions.

    1.5 Conclusion

    The theoretical literature of privatisation is inconclusive. Even if we agree that in theory,

    privatisation can lead to improved efficiency and profitability, the effect of privatisation on

    wider society must be considered. One must acknowledge that economic efficiency is not

    always the primary motive of a state owned enterprise. The deliverance of a good quality

    product or service at an affordable price, with universal access may not be a technically

    efficient strategy, but is equitable and beneficial to the wider society. Nobel Prize laureate

    Joseph Stiglitz (1994) describes privatisation as a trade off between Technical and Allocative

    efficiency, the result of which is ambiguous at best:

    We cannot, in general, be assured that private production is necessarily "better" than

    public production. Privatization involves costs and benefits, which, as always, must

    be weighed against each other.

    (Stiglitz 1994: 194)

  • 17

    Chapter 2: Public Enterprise and Privatisation in Ireland

    2.0 The History of Irelands Public Enterprise Formation

    2.0.1 Introduction

    An analysis of the rationale for the formation of SOEs in Ireland is necessary to contextualise

    subsequent privatisation policies, and understand the key role SOEs continue to play in

    important sectors of the Irish economy. The following explores the history of Irelands public

    enterprise formation up until the 1980s, as underpinned by factors both common to SOE

    formation in Europe and unique to Irelands experience.

    Parris et al (1987: 14-21) explains why Post-World War Two European governments sought

    the establishments of a strong public enterprise sector. A socialist political ideology

    prevailed, which advocated for public ownership. Countries saw SOEs as necessary to

    developing national wealth in the absence of private sector initiative. Such SOEs could be

    used as a vehicle for regional development. Sectors characterised by duplication were being

    rationalised with the establishment of state mandated monopolies. Although many of these

    factors which underpinned European SOE formation are relevant to Ireland at particular

    points in time, the chronology of Irelands SOE formation is somewhat different. Having

    gained independence in 1922 and exercised neutrality throughout World War One and Two,

    Ireland did not develop its SOEs in accordance with wide European trends (see Table 1 for

    chronology).

    2.0.2 Public Enterprise Formation in Ireland: 1927-1957

    Protectionist policies were pursued in Ireland following independence from British rule in

    1922. The state sought to break neo-colonial ties with Britain by vying for self-sufficiency

    with an extensive import-substitution program. The successful establishment of the

    Electricity Supply Board in 1927 set a precedent for public enterprise as a means of achieving

    economic development (Palcic and Reeves 2011). Sweeney (1990) explains that SOEs were

    subsequently established to meet the extraordinary needs of the fledging state. The

    Agricultural Credit Corporation was also established in 1927, and the Industrial Credit

    Corporation in 1933, to provide much needed funding to Irelands agricultural and industrial

    sectors respectively. The Irish Sugar company was established in 1933 as a prototype of a

    commercial SOE. As government continued to strive towards self-sufficiency, Ceimici Teo

  • 18

    was established in 1939, initially as a producer of industrial alcohol, but then extending to

    produce a multitude of chemicals. In 1936 Ireland established Aer Lingus as the state airline,

    while Aer Rianta took control of Dublin Airport.

    Table 1: Commercial State-Owned Enterprises in Ireland by the 1980s

    Company Established Sector

    Agricultural Credit Corporation 1927 Banking & Finance

    Electricity Supply Board 1927 Electricity

    Industrial Credit Corporation 1933 Banking & Finance

    Irish Sugar 1933 Sugar Production

    Aer LIngus 1936 Air Transport

    Aer Rianta 1937 Airports

    Ceimici Teo 1939 Chemicals

    Irish Life 1939 Insurance

    Irish Shipping 1941 Sea Transport

    Cras Iompair ireann 1944 Rail & Road

    Transport

    Bord na Mna 1946 Peat Production

    Irish Steel 1946 Steel Production

    Arramara Teo 1949 Seaweed Processing

    Voluntary Health Insurance 1957 Health Insurance

    Raidi Teilifs ireann 1960 Broadcasting

    Ntrigin ireann Teo- IFI 1961 Fertiliser Production

    B&I Line 1965 Sea Transport

    Foir Teo 1972 Banking

    Bord Gis ireann 1976 Gas Distribution

    Irish National Petroleum Corporation 1979 Oil Refining & Supply

    Telecom ireann 1984 Telecommunications

    An Post 1984 Postal Services

    Coillte Teo 1989 Forestry

    Source: Palcic and Reeves 2011

    The outbreak of World War Two in 1939 provided an additional impetus for Ireland to

    operate self-sufficiently. Irish Shipping was founded in 1941 to secure service between

    Ireland and Britain during the war. The transport company Cras Iompair ireann, Irish Steel

    and a seaweed processing company Arramara Teo were established throughout the 1940s

    following nationalisations and mergers (see Table 1). The state established itself in the

    financial services sector with the formation of Irish Life Assurance Company in 1939

    following the nationalisation of 5 British companies the state had invested in, and formed the

    Voluntary Health Insurance company in 1957 to insure those not covered by the Health Acts

    (Palcic and Reeves 2011).

  • 19

    2.0.3 Public Enterprise Formation in Ireland: 1957-1989

    SOEs now existed across many sectors, and were essential in implementing broad

    government policies as Ireland began to embark upon an era of outward looking economic

    planning from 1958. Governments emphasis shifted from self sufficiency to establishing an

    export orientated economy which was attractive to foreign direct investment. Agencies such

    as Cras Trchtl and the Irish Export Board were formed to service the needs of this private

    capital by offering advice and information (OMalley 1989:86). Other agencies were

    established such as Gaeltarra ireann in 1959 to develop Irish speaking areas and Bord

    Iascaigh Mhara in 1952 to develop Irelands fishing industry. Commercial SOEs continued

    to be established; the state broadcasting agency Raidi Teilifs ireann in 1960, the fertiliser

    company Ntrigin ireann Teo in 1961 and B&I Line, a ferry company formed in 1965

    following the nationalisation of a failing British company (Palcic and Reeves 2011).

    SOE formation continued into the 1970s, with the establishment of the state rescue bank Foir

    Teo in 1972. Of particular interest to this study is the establishment of Bord Gis ireann in

    1976 as the monopoly distributor of natural gas in Ireland. Telecom ireann and An Post

    (1984) and the state forestrys company Coillte Teo in 1989 were corporatized from the civil

    service to become commercial SOEs. At the beginning of the 1980s, 23 SOEs were

    categorized as commercial entities engaging in the production of goods and services (Palcic

    and Reeves 2011).

    In sum, the rationale for establishing SOEs in Ireland was largely due to the need for the

    creation of national wealth in a newly independent state without basic industries or the means

    of attracting private enterprise. The formation of SOEs provided state autonomy and the

    means to pursue state goals (Palcic and Reeves 2011).

    2.1 Privatisation in Ireland

    2.1.1 Introduction

    The Irish state has to date raised 8.36 billion in privatisation revenues, significantly

    changing the structure and composition in several key sectors of the Irish economy (Palcic

    and Reeves 2011). This section explores these divestitures by applying the aforementioned

    theoretical rationales of principal agent and public choice theories. Furthermore, it is

    explained that European integration influenced government to privatise SOEs; the Single

    Common Market necessitating liberalisation incompatible with certain public monopolies, the

  • 20

    Maastricht Treaty asserting a pressure to quickly reduce government debt and deficits to meet

    its criteria and the issuing of EU directives banning state aid to failing SOEs (Palcic and

    Reeves 2011). In conclusion, it will be demonstrated that decisions to privatise in the Irish

    case have been made pragmatically, and not based on any single rationale.

    Table 2: Privatised SOEs in Ireland and Exchequer Proceeds

    Company Year of sale Exchequer proceeds

    (000s)

    Irish Sugar Apr. 1991 210,650.8

    Irish Life Jul. 1991 601,930.8

    B&I Line Jan. 1992 10,792.8

    Irish Steel Apr. 1996 0

    Telecom ireann Jul. 1999 6,399,907.9

    Industrial Credit Corporation Feb. 2001 322,274.8

    Trustee Savings Bank Apr. 2001 408,350.3

    Irish National Petroleum Corporation Jul. 2001 20,000.0

    Agricultural Credit Corporation Feb. 2002 154,603.0

    Aer Lingus Oct. 2006 240,902.3

    Total 8,369,412.7

    Source: Palcic and Reeves 2011

    2.1.2 Privatisation in Ireland: 1991-1996

    Throughout the 1980s, Ireland opted to commercialise its SOEs rather than follow a growing

    trend of privatisation in the UK and Europe, despite facing a severe financial crisis.

    Government promises to trade unionists to avoid privatisations were eventually broken

    however, as the pro-privatisation Progressive Democrats came into power as a minority

    coalition member in 1989. The dual divestiture of Irish Sugar Company and Irish Life

    Assurance in 1991 set a precedent for further divestitures in Ireland. These privatisations can

    largely be explained with Chicagoan public choice theory, which demonstrates internal

    actors ability to lobby relevant government ministries and officials. The privatisation of Irish

    Sugar Company and Irish Life Assurance was driven by decision makers within the

    companies, who pushed their privatisation agendas through to IPOs in 1991 (Palcic and

    Reeves 2011).

    Government continued to proceed cautiously and pragmatically following these divestitures.

    Increasing the commercial performance of SOEs took priority over changing ownership.

    Government took a hard line on loss makers, as evidenced by the liquidation of Irish

    Shipping and Ceimici Teo in 1984 and 1986 respectively. It can be noted that the hard line

  • 21

    taken at this time was partly due to increasing European integration, with the conditions of

    the Maastricht Treaty necessitating stricter fiscal discipline. By 1991, shipping company B&I

    Line had accumulated losses of 170.71 million, relying on exchequer funding to service its

    debt. Irish steels performance was similarly weak. Between 1980 and 1993, the steel

    company received 234.9 million funding from government, but remained unprofitable, with

    a net loss of 16.48 million in 1993. Rather than opt for liquidation, government choose to

    sell the companies as going concerns. B&I Line was sold in 1992 to Irish Continental Group

    for 10.79 million, with government agreeing to pay 44.4 million of its debt. Irish Steel was

    sold in 1996 to ISPAT International (Palcic and Reeves 2011).

    2.1.3 The Privatisation of Telecom ireann

    By far the most significant divestiture in the history of the Irish state is that of Telecom

    ireann (T); the national telecommunications operator. From its establishment in 1984, T

    operated as a monopoly in the Irish telecommunications market. EU legislation saw T

    facing full market liberalisation in 1998. To adapt to this impending competitive market,

    internal management sought large capital investment. It was argued that such an investment

    could only come from private sources thus management instigated a partial strategic

    privatisation, eventually leading to full privatisation. In 1996 Comsource consortium

    purchased a 20% stake in T, with an option to increase this holding to 35%. The

    Communications Workers Union, the final hurdle in the full divestiture, agreed on the basis

    of a generous 5% employee share ownership plan, with a further 9.9% stake bought at a fair

    price (Palcic and Reeves 2011: 155-177).

    T, rebranded as Eircom, was fully privatised in 1999 with the remaining 50.1% stock

    flotation generating sales revenue of approximately 6.4 Billion. To put this in the context,

    this represents 76.47% of total exchequer proceeds from privatised SOEs in Ireland.

    Government promoted Ts flotation as a means promoting popular capitalism. Its goal of

    widening share ownership seemed successful initially, with 575,000 people purchasing stock.

    However as stock prices deteriorated, many thousands of these small shareholders were

    burned, curbing the publics appetite for future privatisations (Palcic and Reeves 2011: 155-

    177).

    The privatisation of T has become known to be an example of failure in privatisation. The

    lessons learned from this should be applied in future privatisations. Central to this failure was

    governments decision to sell T as a vertically integrated business, not keeping the network

  • 22

    element of the business in state control. Also, selling T in one go as opposed to gradually

    reducing ownership and keeping a golden share, which would have allowed the state to

    prevent undesirable changes in ownership has been a source of much criticism (Palcic and

    Reeves 2011: 155-177).

    Eircom, was split up, with its fixed line business sold to private equity consortium Valentia.

    In 2006, Australian investment firm Babcock and Brown bought Eircom in a leveraged

    buyout and subsequently sold it to Singapore Technologies Telemedia in 2010. Eircom now

    holds over 4 billion in debt, which has hampered its ability to invest in capital infrastructure

    and contributed significantly to the slow roll out of broadband services in Ireland. This

    infrastructural deficit persists in Ireland today, and has necessitated government intervention

    (Palcic and Reeves 2011: 155-177).

    2.1.4 Privatisation in Ireland: 2001-2006

    Between 2001 and 2002, the 3 state owned commercial banks were privatised; the

    Agricultural Credit Corporation (ACC), Industrial Credit Corporation (ICC) and Trustee

    Savings Bank (TSB). Government policy sought to foster competition in Irelands banking

    sector and considered a number of options for the 3 publicly owned banks including a

    merger of the three or the sale of TSB to recapitalise a merged ACC and ICC. With

    privatisations initially mooted in 1992, it was 2001 before the ICC was sold to Bank of

    Scotland (Ireland) for 349 million. TSB was sold later that year to Irish Life and Permanent

    for 430 million to form Permanent TSB. In 2002, the ACC was sold to Rabobank for 165

    million. In all three cases, ESOPs of 14.9 % were agreed which ensured worker cooperation.

    Successive governments were in agreement that government should exit the banking sector,

    selling 3 small players to aid competition. This rationale guided the privatisations through a

    protracted period of practical difficulties in finding an appropriate buyer for each (Palcic and

    Reeves 2011).

    In July 2001, the Irish National Petroleum Company was sold to Tosco Corporation for 116

    million. The cost of capital investment necessary to upgrade its refinery facilities was deemed

    too high to be paid from the exchequer and the sale proceeded with a number of conditions;

    Tosco agreed to commercially operate the refinery and terminal operations for 15 years while

    maintaining existing jobs and employment conditions. Also, they agreed to undertake any

    capital investment necessary to adhere to future EU regulations (Palcic and Reeves 2011).

  • 23

    The state-owned airline Aer Lingus had struggled to remain commercially viable through a

    volatile 25 year period which included the Gulf War of 1990-91, the outbreak of foot and

    mouth disease in 2000 and the terrorist attacks on New York and Washington in September

    2001. 2 rationalisation plans saw injections of state capital, sale of non-core assets, a pay

    freeze, redundancies and a granting of a 14.9% ESOP. As the state made it clear it would not

    provide any further capital injections, management sought to mobilise private capital to meet

    the cost of funding necessary fleet renewal. Government opted to retain a 25% stake in the

    company, and floated the remainder on the stock exchange in 2006. The decision to privatise

    was initially made in 1999; however a lack of political impetus for privatisation following the

    failed privatisation of T among other political considerations protracted the process (Palcic

    and Reeves 2011).

  • 24

    Chapter 3: A New Round of Divestitures

    3.0 Introduction

    A new round of divestitures in the Irish public enterprise portfolio is imminent. The historical

    context of Irelands public enterprise development has been explained. This chapter will go

    on to locate Irelands return to privatisation in its economic and political context. The Irish

    government is making privatisation decisions in a situation unprecedented in an Irish context;

    public finances have been decimated and economic sovereignty surrendered. The potential

    for an economically ill-advised fire sale of state assets is large. Bord Gis Energy, the retail

    arm of the state owned utilities company and network operator Bord Gis ireann, has been

    identified by government as a non-strategic asset and a suitable candidate for privatisation.

    To evaluate the economic case for this planned privatisation, this chapter analyses the

    evolution of this policy through a number of influential documents; Fine Gaels New

    Economy Recovery Authority (NewERA) plan, Memoranda of Understandings (MoUs)

    between the Irish government and the Troika of global institutions over seeing their bailout

    program and a Fianna Fil requested Report of the Review Group on State Assets and

    Liabilities published in 2011. These documents have shaped recent Irish privatisation policy.

    3.1 The Economic Crisis in Ireland

    It can be noted that since 2002, there had been a general lack of appetite for privatisation. The

    state had withdrawn from several key sectors of the economy, and those commercial SOEs

    that remained were large utility companies or companies not appropriate for private

    ownership because they held considerable market power (Palcic and Reeves 2011). The

    following section explains the national economic crisis that has emerged since 2008 which

    has seen the state re-enter the banking sector and return to privatisation as a means of raising

    revenue for the exchequer.

    Between 1994 and 2007, the Irish economy experienced an unprecedented period of

    sustained real economic growth. During the period, the Irish economy expanded at an

    average rate of 9%, had average unemployment of just 3.6%, and experienced low inflation at

    1.4%. Commentators dubbed it The Celtic Tiger economy. Donovan and Murphy (2013)

    argue that up until 2002 this growth was sustainable. Ireland was established as a springboard

    to Europe for investors. Boasting favourable corporate tax rates of 12% and as the only

    English speaking country in the Euro currency zone, Ireland was well positioned to take

  • 25

    advantage of a global technological boom. Good macro-economic policies underpinned this

    growth, as evidenced by an ability to reduce its debt to GDP ratio to 25% (Central Statistics

    Office 2012).

    Donovan and Murphy (2013) note the global economy began to contract in 2002. Equity

    markets in the US and Europe fell due to unrealistic profit expectations largely in the

    technology sector. Terrorist attacks in the US on September 11th 2001, and the foot and

    mouth crisis of the same year saw a downturn in the US and European economies. They

    suggest that Ireland resisted this contraction by pursuing policies to grow its construction

    sector. Where in the 1990s increasing property prices were arguably justifiable by real

    economic growth, an artificial property bubble was created. This second phase of economic

    activity was fuelled by cheap access to European wholesale credit from an Irish financial

    sector under light regulation from government, the financial regulator and the central bank.

    The Irish government received windfall revenue through stamp duty, capital gains tax and

    construction sector related VAT. Government pursued pro-cyclical policies by increasing

    budget expenditure and balancing it against unsustainable property related tax revenue. By

    2007, the property bubble had developed to the extent that residential property prices had

    quadrupled since 1996 (Palcic and Reeves 2013).

    This property bubble inevitably burst after 2007. Prices of residential properties in Ireland in

    September 2013 have fallen 62.2% from their peak in August 2007 (Central Statistics Office

    2014a). This collapse in construction activity saw a sharp rise in unemployment, from 4.5%

    in 2007 to 12% in 2009 (Central Statistics Office 2014b) which squeezed public finances

    already reeling from the loss of property related revenue such as stamp duty, on which the

    exchequer had become overly reliant on. As the economy contracted, it became apparent that

    the Irish banking sector was overly exposed to the property sector. At the end of 2007, bank

    loans and advances to customers were over twice the size of the countrys GDP, at almost

    400 billion (Nyberg 2011).

    By late September 2009, the Irish banking sector was on the brink of collapse. The Irish

    government took the decision to guarantee the deposits and most liabilities of all Irish banks,

    a gross liability guarantee of 375 billion, 33% of which was senior unsecured debt.

    Government decided that it would prevent any Irish bank from defaulting on its maturing

    obligations, thereby avoiding a crisis of confidence in the Irish banking sector and preventing

    a run on Irish banks. This decision has proven to be an extremely costly one. Government did

  • 26

    not foresee the extent of Irish banks bad debts, largely arising from property related loans.

    To date, the recapitalisation of Irish banks has cost the state 64 billion (Nyberg 2011).

    Ireland faced a dual dilemma; the true cost of recapitalising its banks was becoming apparent

    and a massive structural deficit was developing. International financial markets were in a

    liquidity crisis, and the global economy had begun to slip into recession. International money

    markets became increasingly reluctant to lend to Ireland. By late 2010, Ireland was unable to

    access credit and government was forced to enter into an EC/IMF/ECB bailout program on

    29 November 2010. Ireland secured 85 billion in funding composed of 45 billion in

    bilateral loans and funding from the European Stability Fund, 22.5 billion from the

    International Monetary Fund and 17.5 Billion from Irish contributions via the National

    Pension Reserve Fund (Donovan and Murphy 2013).

    The effects of Irelands economic collapse are made stark by key indicators; Unemployment

    rose from a low of 3.7% in the first 5 months of 2011, and peaked at 15.1% in February 2012.

    This figure has improved somewhat to 12.3% in January 2014, although economic emigration

    accounts for some of this reduction (Central Statistics 2014b). Real GDP for the second

    quarter of 2013 was 9.8% lower than its peak in the fourth quarter of 2007. Irelands Debt to

    GDP ratio averaged 71.3% between 1980 and 2012, and fell to a low of 24.8% in December

    2006 (Central Statistics Office 2014c). At year end 2013, Irelands Debt to GDP was 124.1%

    (Irish Fiscal Advisory Council 2013). Government policy in response to this crisis, and the

    stipulations of the bailout program with the EC/IMF/ECB has significantly altered the

    composition and function of Irelands public sector; with a raft of nationalisations, new SOE

    formations and planned privatisations occurring (Palcic and Reeves 2011). Although Ireland

    left this structured bailout program in December 2013, the decision making process around

    public enterprise appears to have been altered indefinitely.

    3.2 Fine Gaels New Economy Recovery Authority

    In November 2009, Fine Gael was the opposition political party in the Irish government when

    they released the New Economy Recovery Authority (NewERA) plan; an economic stimulus

    plan that sought to create 105,000 new jobs with a 18.2 Billion investment in Irish

    infrastructure over a four year period. Fine Gaels NewERA plan aimed to increase long term

    competitiveness, increase energy security, eliminate the digital divide that has developed

  • 27

    between Ireland and Europe and create a new governance structure for the public sector (Fine

    Gael 2009).

    This stimulus was to be financed from a number of sources; The European Investment Bank,

    The National Pension Reserve Fund, commercial borrowings of SOEs, a NewERA recovery

    bond to be offered to the Irish people and, of primary interest to this study, from revenues

    accruing from the sale of non-strategic state assets. The non-network elements of both major

    state utilities companies, Bord Gis ireann and the Electricity Supply Board, were

    earmarked for sale (Fine Gael 2009).

    The governance of the state sector would be restructured with the establishment of NewERA

    Ltd. as the states holding company. 100 professionals would be employed at NewERA to

    commercially manage 5 new SOEs in a consolidated public portfolio. Smart Grid and

    Gaslink would become owners and operators of Irelands electricity and gas networks

    respectively. Furthermore, a National Recovery Wholesale Bank would be established to

    facilitate commercial borrowings of SOEs (Fine Gael 2009).

    Fine Gael came into power as the majority party in a coalition government with Labour in

    September 2011 on the back of an economic mandate largely represented by NewERA. It

    must be noted that Fine Gaels neo-liberal economic policies, which seek to minimise the

    states role in the provision of services, is at odds with Labours policies. In their pre-election

    manifesto in 2011, Labour stated its commitment to public enterprise:

    Labour is committed to the concept of public enterprise, and is determined to ensure

    that semi-state companies play a full role in the recovery of the Irish economy.

    Labour is opposed to short-termist privatisation of key state assets, such as Coillte or

    the energy networks.

    (Labour 2011)

    As Taft (2012) observes, Labour failed to protect this commitment in negotiations for the

    program for government, which when published contained Fine Gaels commitment to

    raising 2 Billion in revenue from the sale of state assets (Fine Gael and Labour 2011).

    At the time of writing, much of this program has not been implemented. The NewERA Ltd.

    holding company to manage public enterprise has not been established. NewERA has instead

    developed as a non-statutory body within the National Treasury Management Agency tasked

    with overseeing the financial performance, corporate strategy, capital and investment plans of

    the five commercial semi-state companies within its remit; ESB, Bord Gis ireann, EirGrid,

    Bord na Mna and Coillte (NTMA 2013). Planned divestitures of ESB and Coillte have been

  • 28

    rowed back on due to union resistance and popular protest respectively. To date, the

    establishment of Irish Water as a subsidiary of Bord Gis ireann, a new SOE to take over

    the operation of the Irish water infrastructure, has been the only full implementation of the

    plan.

    3.3 Memoranda of Understandings

    Upon receiving bailout funding from the Troika of global institutions, Ireland signed a bailout

    agreement renouncing its economic sovereignty. Both the political decision making process

    and economic landscape were altered from that in which NewERA was developed.

    Government now had to operate within the parameters of a Troika specified program for

    government which was to be communicated in a series of Memoranda of Understandings

    (MoUs) between the government and the Troika. Of interest to this paper is the

    conditionality for the sale of sale assets prescribed (Palcic and Reeves 2013).

    Privatisation as a condition of financial support has been a staple of IMF/World Bank

    bailouts since the 1980s (Bennell 1997, Martin 1993). Where NewERA sought revenue from

    the sale of non-strategic assets for investment in a stimulus plan aimed to restore growth and

    finance national investment programs, Troika bailout agreements have prioritised the paying

    down of national debt. However, Ireland has received somewhat favourable terms in

    comparison to bailouts in Greece and Portugal (Palcic and Reeves 2013). Indeed, the first

    MoU signed in November 2010 contained no specifics regarding privatisation. Updated six

    times since, targets for revenue from divestments have emerged. Although there is significant

    pressure being exerted from the Troika outside of these MoUs, the Irish government has

    been afforded independence in deciding which SOEs are to be privatised and some

    flexibility in the spending of revenues accrued as a result (Palcic and Reeves 2013).

    Fine Fil ordered a report from the Review Group on State Assets and Liabilities. 5 billion

    in revenues from recommended divestitures were identified in this report which was endorsed

    in an IMF country report in September 2011 (IMF 2011a). However, upon coming into power

    as the majority party in a coalition government with Labour in September 2011, Fine Gael

    indicated it would seek only 2 billion in privatisation revenues. By January 2012, the

    Troikas Quarterly Review sought specifics from government who scaled this target up to 3

    billion (IMF 2011b).

    This revenue would come from a sale of a minority stake in ESB, a full divestment of the

    state forestry company Coillte, sale of the states majority stake in the semi-state owned

  • 29

    airline Aerlingus and the privatisation of the non-network elements of Bord Gis ireann.

    However, mass public protests saw a reversal of the planned divestment of Coillte.

    Furthermore, government reversed its decision to sell a minority stake in ESB. The sale of

    Aerlingus will be delayed until market conditions become favourable. Thus, the only planned

    privatisation to date is that of Bord Gis Energy, the retail arm of Bord Gis ireann. The use

    of the proceeds of any privatisation is much debated, and again the Troika have been flexible

    in this regard. The latest indication resulting from negotiations in March 2011 is that 50% of

    revenues will be used to pay down government debt with the remainder available for state

    investment as per NewEra (IMF 2012).

    3.4 Report of the Review Group on State Assets and Liabilities

    A report by The Review Group on State Assets and Liabilities as requested by Fine Gael

    exists as the principle document directing privatisation policy in Ireland. In it, McCarthy et al

    (2011) recommend 5 billion of revenues to be garnered from the sale of non-strategic state

    assets. Unfortunately, this report does not contextualise its recommendations in Irelands

    bailout program and the subsequent changes to the decision making landscape that resulted. It

    was undertaken amidst a dynamic situation of bargaining between the Irish government and

    the Troika, who had not yet set specific revenue targets. However, the flexibility afforded to

    the Irish government as discussed previously means that this does not completely undermine

    its recommendations. The Review Group recommends sales revenues from privatisation be

    used to pay down government debt and decrease the burden of necessary spending cuts. They

    do not advocate for the reinvestment of revenues in infrastructure development as per

    NewERA (McCarthy et al 2011).

    As a prelude, the Review Group stresses that there should not be an accelerated sale process,

    and that sales should only be undertaken after state companies have been restructured and the

    regulatory environment strengthened. Recommendation 4 calls for a comprehensive review

    of legislation governing economic regulatory agencies, and necessary legislative amendments

    made prior to any disposals (McCarthy et al 2011). However, in light of Irelands bailout

    program, the time needed to undertake this may not be available and the sale process could be

    inevitably accelerated.

    The report warns that without significant regulation, there may be a subsequent under

    investment in infrastructure as occurred in Irish telecoms networks following the sale of T

    to a private equity fund with little interest in investment (Palcic and Reeves 2011: 155-177).

  • 30

    As revenues are recommended to be diverted from infrastructural investment to offset

    spending cuts, such a situation could undo any short term gains to the exchequer made

    through revenue realisation.

    Bord Gis Energy is dominant across all market sectors in the supply of natural gas,

    especially in the residential sector. Thus, regulation must be stringent to protect competition

    and avoid a situation whereby a privately owned BGE could influence market price.

    Acknowledging this, McCarthy calls for a full review of the system of energy regulation in

    Ireland prior to any divestiture; which has not been done. The Review Group does ultimately

    recommend the privatisation of all Bord Gis ireanns operations except its transmission

    and interconnector assets (McCarthy et al 2011). Government has acted on this

    recommendation, but this paper contends they have done so while ignoring concerns and

    recommendations regarding the adequacy of Irelands energy regulatory regime.

  • 31

    Chapter 4: The Privatisation of Bord Gis Energy

    4.0 Introduction

    Despite a near blanket failure to implement their public enterprise policy, Fine Gael-Labour

    government has persisted with the planned divestiture of the non-network elements of Bord

    Gis ireann. In July 2013, the government brought before the Dil the Gas Regulation Bill,

    which creates the legal basis for the divestiture of Bord Gis ireann (Gas Regulation Bill

    2013). This followed a press release by BGEs Financial Director, Michael G OSullivan in

    May 2013 which stated that the sale process had commenced and that the sale was expected

    to be concluded by the end of that year (Bord Gis ireann 2012a). This bill faced significant

    legal challenges for government as they worked to comply with the full ownership

    unbundling requirements of the EU Gas Directive 2009 (Council Directive 2009/73/EC). In

    consequence, both the Minister for Communications, Energy and Natural Resources and the

    Minister for Public Expenditure may not retain any decision making role in the new Bord

    Gis Network business as they are shareholders in other state energy companies.

    Despite regulatory reform being a staple prerequisite of divestiture in the NewEra document,

    The Report of The Review Group on State Assets and Liabilities and Fine Gaels program for

    government, none such reform has been delivered. Despite this, the sale of BGE has

    commenced. Fine Gaels 2011 election manifesto offered the only clear indication from

    government of the potential composition of this reform. In it, it committed to establishing the

    Competition, Consumer, Utilities Commission as one supra-regulator of the Irish economy.

    This commission has not been established. The Commission for Energy Regulation regulates

    the Irish electricity and natural gas sectors largely unchanged from its establishment in 1999

    (Fine Gael 2011). Thus, BGE is being sold amid significant regulatory shortcomings that this

    paper contends could lead to an economically harmful situation post-divestiture.

    This chapter undertakes a case study of the ongoing divestiture of Bord Gis Energy. The

    study begins by outlining the economic theory of natural gas supply, both as a network and a

    natural resource industry. The development of Bord Gis ireann in the context of the

    European gas market is then described. An overview of Bord Gis ireann follows, which

    distinguishes the network and non-network elements of the business. An overview of Bord

    Gis Energy is then provided, describing BGEs place in the Irish retail gas market. A

    summary of the sale process will explain that a consortium led by a British multinational

    utility company, Centrica, is poised to purchase BGE. In conclusion, recommendations are

  • 32

    made that call for reform of Irelands system of energy regulation and SOE governance

    structure prior to any future privatisations, and that these privatisations are undertaken in a

    series of tranches.

    4.1 The Economics of Natural Gas

    The market for natural gas combines a network industry and a natural resource industry. With

    network industries, economies of scale are essesntial. The domestic transport and distribution

    system services of natural gas in Ireland are made up of a high pressure long distance

    pipeline, with a low pressure distribution grid connecting it and end-consumers. There is a

    high fixed cost associated with the construction of such a network, with a relatively low

    marginal cost of extending it. In Ireland, it is not feasible or efficient for different natural gas

    suppliers to operate via duplicated parallel pipelines thus the countrys gas network is a

    natural monopoly (CPB 2006).

    In Monopoly and the Rate of Extraction of Exhaustible Resources (1976), Stiglitz explains

    that in exhaustible resource markets such as that of natural gas, the total stock of resource is

    fixed. Total production for a monopolist or a firm in a competitive market cannot change.

    However, a monopolist does have the power to change the pattern of production over time to

    influence price. Assuming constant elasticity of demand and zero extraction costs, Stiglitz

    demonstrates that the rate of extraction for a monopolist and a firm in competition will be the

    same. However, in reality price and elasticity of demand are positively linked, thus

    monopolists tend to produce less than a competitive firm and welfare is not optimized.

    Resource rents occur when there is a difference between market price and marginal cost of

    extraction.

    Both characteristics have regulatory implications. The Irish government has seemingly

    learned from the failure arising from the privatisation of Ts network, and has committed to

    keeping the network element of Bord Gis ireann in state control. Government can thereby

    guard against rent seeking and ensure the integrity and safety of the system if regulation is

    adequate. Of strategic importance to the state is security of supply. By controlling the gas

    network and the interconnectors to the UK, from which Ireland imports 93% of its natural

    gas, government can effectively manage our energy security, an issue particularly important

    to Ireland as a small island country with a high reliance on imported gas (TASC 2012). The

    EU mandated that European gas markets be liberalised in 2003 and forced ownership

    unbundling in 2009 (Council Directive 2003/55/EC, Council Directive 2009/73/EC). These

  • 33

    policies are an endorsement of neo-classical economic theory which advocates for the welfare

    optimality of competitive equilibrium, however as will be demonstrated, such perfect

    competition does not exist across all sectors of Irelands natural gas supply market which

    remains price regulated in one sector.

    4.2 The European Gas Market

    The strategic importance of SOEs in post-war Europe, as explained, is particularly relevant

    to the utilities sectors. Governments undertook extensive reconstruction efforts and faced

    very real threats to energy supply (Palcic and Reeves 2011). The oil and gas sector was

    therefore tightly controlled. In 1959 the European natural gas business was mainly confined

    to Northern Italy and South West France, with additional imports from parts of the USSR. At

    the time, energy multinational ExxonMobil had acquired a 50% share in NAM as a balancing

    item in a global asset swap. NAM, operated by Royal Dutch Shell, was the exploration

    company working at Groningen, in the northeast of the Netherlands. This exploration

    established the European gas business proper. The joint venture uncovered a giant natural gas

    field, 2.8 trillion cubic meters in size with 2,800 BCM of recoverable gas. NV Nederlandse

    Gasunie was established as the monopoly producer and transmitter of Groningen gas for 30

    years, 50% owned by the Dutch government and a 25% stake owned by Shell and Exxon

    respectively (Heren 1999).

    Exxon insisted on the controlled supply of this gas, pegging its value to that of other fuels,

    and guarding against an over-supply of cheap natural gas. Further discoveries followed;

    onshore in Germany, offshore in the UK and Norway, with supply further supplemented with

    imports from Algeria and Russia. ). Ireland was no exception. In 1971, natural gas was

    discovered off the coast of Kinsale, in southern Ireland. Deemed commercially viable, Bord

    Gis ireann was established by the Gas Act 1976 as the state gas development agency (Bord

    Gis ireann 2013a).

    OPEC had traditionally been the primary supplier of oil to Europe. However, having suffered

    an OPEC induced oil price shock in the 1970s that rattled the European economy,

    governments sought to move away from an over-reliance on OPEC oil. Suppliers pushed out

    by OPEC began to find an outlet in these new reservoirs (Heren 1999).

    Governments generally opted for a hands on approach in managing their nations new found

    natural wealth. With the exception of a liberalised British market in the late 1980s, the

    European gas market is traditionally characterised by an absence of rights to transmission and

  • 34

    distribution pipes, the prevalence of state monopolies, and prices pegged to those of

    competing fuels (Heren 1999). EU directives have sought to correct this by creating a single

    internal market for natural gas. In doing so, they liberalised European gas markets in 2003

    and forced ownership unbundling in 2009. The EUs objectives are to increase service

    quality, achieve universal service, increase consumer protection and achieve security of

    supply with a competitive internal market with appropriate regulation. It seeks to achieve this

    by removing government from the European gas market and relying on competition between

    profit maximising private enterprises to achieve their objectives (Council Directive

    2009/73/EC, Council Directive 2003/55/EC). However as we have seen, privatisation

    literature does not definitively support this approach.

    4.3 Bord Gis ireann

    4.3.1 The Development of Bord Gis ireann

    In 1971, natural gas discovered off the coast of Kinsale, Co. Cork was confirmed as

    commercially viable. With the approval of the Gas Act by the Oireachtas in 1976, Bord Gis

    ireann was established as the State Gas Development Agency. The beginning of natural gas

    production in Ireland was marked by the first delivery of natural gas, received on-shore by

    then Taoiseach Jack Lynch, in 1978. Throughout the 1980s pipelines were built, first in the

    Cork area, then to Dublin with a series of spurs ever broadening the availability of natural gas

    in Ireland. By 1995, 35% of Irelands dwellings were connected to the network. In 1985 Bord

    Gis ireann was ordered to acquire Cork Gas, who found themselves in a perilous financial

    position. In 1987 Bord Gis ireann took over the assets of Dublin Gas Company, whom

    government had placed in receivership (Bord Gis ireann 2012).

    In 1994 an inter-connector came into operation, completed with 35% funding from the EU,

    which connected Irelands gas network with the UK and the European Gas networks,

    securing a supply of gas beyond the exhaustion of gas in the Kinsale field. 1999 saw the

    beginning of the opening up of 80% Irelands natural gas market. By 2002, any consumer

    consuming 500,000 standard cubic meters of natural gas was free to choose from any

    supplier. In 2001, Bord Gis ireann began to diversify its portfolio by entering the Irish

    electricity supply market. This diversification has proven successful, evidenced by BGEs

    ability to construct a gas-fired power plant at White-Gate, Co. Cork which became

    operational in 2008 and acquire a 30 megawatt wind farm development in the West of Ireland

    in the same year. BGE now operates as an all-island natural gas supplier with its subsidiary

  • 35

    Firmus in Northern Ireland, having entered the Northern Irish market in 2003 via network

    connections from Belfast to Dublin and Carrickfergus (Co. Antrim) to Derry city (Bord

    Gis ireann 2012).

    4.3.2 The Structure of Bord Gis ireann

    Today, Bord Gis ireann operates as a commercial enterprise owned by the Irish state. Bord

    Gis ireann has evolved from a gas transmission company to become a major energy

    provider. Recently, government has created a subsidiary, Irish Water, which is being

    established as Irelands new public water utility (Bord Gis ireann 2013b). The firms

    business structure is illustrated in Fig. 1. This study focuses solely on the divestiture of Bord

    Gis ireanns retail arm, Bord Gis Energy. As such, an understanding of the parent

    companys structure is essential.

    Fig 1. The Structure of Bord Gis ireann and its Subsidiaries

    Source: Bord Gis irean Annual Report and Financial Statements 2012

    Gaslink is the independent gas system operator, created as per the unbundling requirements

    of the EU. Gaslink is responsible for the maintenance and operation of the gas distribution

    and transmission networks. Bord Gis ireann owns the networks, and in practice Gaslink

    uses Bord Gis Networks as a service provider to carry out the majority of this work. It is

    thought in the future much of Bord Gis Networks work will be transferred to Gaslink (Bord

    Gis ireann 2013b).

    Bord Gis ireann

    Bord Gis Networks

    Bord Gis Energy

    Firmus

    Irish Water Gaslink

  • 36

    Bord Gis Networks work on behalf of Gaslink to develop and maintain Irelands natural gas

    transmission and distribution network, as well as providing gas transportation services to

    suppliers and shippers. This network now consists of over 14,000 km of pipes and 2 sub-sea

    interconnectors to the UK (Bord Gis ireann 2013b).

    Irish Water has been established as per NewERA to take over the public water services from

    34 local authorities. Irish Water will deliver services to public water uses and are responsible

    for the installation and of water meters and subsequent billing of water users. As a subsidiary

    of Bord Gis ireann it is thought they will better be able to raise finance on international

    markets to fund capital investment projects necessary to maintain and upgrade Irelands

    public water infrastructure, and will benefit from the groups experience in network

    operations (Bord Gis ireann 2013b).

    Firmus is Bord Gis Energys subsidiary in Northern Ireland, where it is licensed to supply

    natural gas and electricity in 10 towns and cities including the greater Belfast area, Derry,

    Newry and Ballymena. It is also responsible for developing and connecting the gas network

    in licensed areas to that of the Republic of Ireland. As Bord Gis Energys subsidiary, Firmus

    will also be privatised (Bord Gis ireann 2013b).

    4.4 Bord Gis Energy

    4.4.1 Introduction

    Bord Gis Energy is the retail arm of Bord Gis ireann. It is a dual-fuel, all island supplier

    of electricity and natural gas to residential, commercial and industrial customers in the

    Republic of Ireland and Northern Ireland (via Firmus). BGEs trading arm procures natural

    gas, electricity and carbon on international wholesale markets and works to optimise its

    portfolio with hedging and trading strategies, risk management and market modelling. Its

    assets arm manages BGEs existing assets, develops new assets to meet the companys needs

    and invests in emerging energy technologies. In 2012, the latest year for which full market

    data is available, BGE supplied electricity to 327,000 residential customers and 21,000

    businesses. BGE supplied natural gas to 416,000 residential customers and 11,096

    businesses. Residential natural gas supply persists as the only market in which BGE is price

    regulated by the Commission for Energy Regulation (CER), Irelands independent energy

    regulator (Bord Gis ireann 2013b).

  • 37

    At the end of 2012, BGE employed 453 people in the Republic of Ireland. The following

    outlines BGEs position across all market segments in the electricity and natural gas supply

    markets as per the data of the Commission for Energy Regulations annual report 2012 (CER

    2013). An overview of BGEs financial performance is then given.

    4.4.2 Market Share: Electricity

    All market segments in Irelands electricity supply market have been deregulated, however

    Irelands state owned electricity company the Electrical Supply Boards retail arm Electric

    Ireland remains dominant across all market segments. In 2012, BGE saw a decline in its

    market share in electricity supply. Table 3 details BGEs market share across the 4 market

    segments as per year end 2012. Total customer numbers for all suppliers for the year were

    2,237,203. BGE supplied 328,617 of these in the domestic market, and 19,030 in the business

    and large energy users segments (CER 2013).

    Table 3: Market Share of Electricity Suppliers as a Percentage of Customer Numbers across Market

    Segments

    Domestic Small Business Medium

    Business

    Large Energy

    User

    Electric Ireland 64.55% 45.88% 55.97% 42.13%

    Airtricity 18.06% 21.29% 15.98% 26.20%

    Bord Gis

    Energy

    16.26% 9.33% 4.85% 9.38%

    Vayu - - - 4.51%

    Energia - 23.41% 22.49% 15.63%

    Others 1.14% 0.09% 0.72% 2.16%

    Total 100% 100% 100% 100%

    Source: CER Electricity and Gas Retail Markets Annual Report 2012

    4.4.3 Market Share: Natural Gas

    BGE remains dominant across all market segments in the supply of natural gas, however

    competition is driving their market share down year on year. The CER (2013) divides the

    natural gas market into segments as per the following:

    Domestic: non-daily metered (NDM) residential customers.

    Industrial and Commercial (IC): businesses with a supply point capacity of below

    3,750kWh and consumption level below 73,000kWh.

  • 38

    Fuel Variation Tariff (FVT) : NDM gas customers with a supply point capacity of

    above 3,750kWh and consumption level above 73,000kWh.

    Regulated tariff formula (RTF): annual consumption of between 5.5GWhs and 264

    GWhs.

    8 suppliers compete across 4 market segments in the supply of natural gas in Ireland. In

    the domestic market in 2012, BGE had a very large market share. This share is falling in

    line with CER targets however, and was significantly lower at year end 2013 as discussed

    in detail below. In the IC market of 22,949 customers, BGE supplied 10,677. In the FVT

    market BGE supplied 589 of 1,750. Although Vayu and Energia hold a larger market

    share in the RTF market as a percentage of the 246 customers, BGE supplied the largest

    volume of natural gas (1,194 GWhs or 21.09% of total volume). Across all deregulated

    market segments BGE faces ever increasing competition and declining market share

    however it remains dominant as the markets largest supplier (CER 2013).

    Table 4: Market Share of Natural Gas Suppliers as a Percentage of Customer Numbers across Market

    Segments

    Domestic IC FVT RTF

    Bord Gis

    Energy 65.65% 46.52% 33.66% 19.51%

    Airtricity 17.14% 5.29% 2.63% 9.76%

    Electric Ireland 12.38% 2.92% - 4.07%

    Flogas 4.83% 25.65% 22.34% -

    Energia - 17.14% 19.77% 21.54%

    Vayu - 2.46% 21.20% 31.71%

    Phoenix - - - 7.72%

    Gazprom - - - 5.69%

    Others - 0.01% 0.40% -

    Total 100% 100% 100% 100%

    Source: CER Electricity and Gas Retail Markets Annual Report 2012

    4.4.4 Price Regulation in the Residential Supply Sector

    Policies which have liberalised and deregulated areas of Irelands market for natural gas aim

    to maximise social welfare through competition. These policies are premised on the

    assumption that the firms operate within a perfectly competitive market. The following

    section analyses the residential market for the supply of natural gas in Ireland, detailing the

    suppliers in operation, their market share as of December 2013 and the switching rate

  • 39

    between them to assess if there exists an appropriate level of competition for the successful

    divestiture of Bord Gis Energy into a deregulated market (CER 2014).

    The Irish natural gas market was fully liberalised in 2007, however new entrants had existed

    since 2004. All areas of the market are now deregulated except residential supply. The

    Commission for Energy Regulation (2014) has outlined three criteria that must be met before

    it ceases to regulate prices set by BGE in this market:

    BGE must hold less than 55% of the market share of residential gas supply.

    There must be 3 (2 non-BGE) suppliers in the market with more than 10% of the

    market share of residential gas supply.

    Consumer switching rates between natural gas suppliers should be greater than 10%

    per year.

    Source: CER Review of the Regulatory Framework for the Domestic NDM Retail Gas Market Competition

    Review December 2013

    As illustrated in Fig. 2, 2 of the CERs criteria for full deregulation of the natural gas sector

    in Ireland have been met. There are 3 suppliers, BGE, Electric Ireland and Airtricity, with a

    market share in excess of 10%. Furthermore, the consumer switching rate for the year 2013

    was 17.33%. However, BGE hold a market share of 57.23% at year end 2013, in excess of

    the 55% threshold for deregulation. As such, BGEs decisions of supply and price setting are

    57.23%

    20.32%

    17.33%

    5.12%

    Fig. 2 Market Share of Residential Natural Gas Supply

    BGE

    Electric Ireland

    Airtricty

    Flogas

  • 40

    non-negligible. It holds market power in an imperfectly competitive market for residential

    supply.

    Table 5: Irish Residential Gas Prices to Residential Consumers at Purchasing Power Parity (all taxes

    included) (1st Semester 2013) EU Comparison

    Residential Consumption Bands Price /kWh Relative to EU average

    2013 Semester 1

    Consumption < 20 GJ 6.58 75%

    20 GJ < Consumption < 200 GJ 6.04 93%

    Consumption > 200 GJ 5.77 93%

    Source: Eurostat 2014

    Currently, BGEs residential gas prices are competitive relative to the EU average as

    evidenced in Table 5. Privatising BGE in such a scenario will require stringent regulation to

    guard against BGE abusing this market power (CER 2014) and increasing prices across the

    market. However, the effectiveness of Irelands current regulatory agencies has been

    questioned, notably in the Report of the Review Group on State Assets and Liabilities;

    The Review Group recommends that a comprehensive review of the legislation

    governing economic regulatory agencies be undertaken and that necessary legislative

    amendments be enacted prior to any state disposals.

    (McCarthy et al 2011)

    4.4.5 Business Performance

    Bord Gis Energy is a profitable, commercially viable SOE. Fig. 3 graphs BGEs EBITDA

    growth from 2009-2012. BGE have performed strongly throughout Irelands economic

    downturn, despite facing volatile markets for wholesale gas and electricity and decreasing

    consumer demand. BGE successfully entered the electricity supply market in 2009 (Bord

    Gis ireann 2010), pioneering the dual-fuel supply model in Ireland. Although they have

    faced significant competition in both markets, BGE has consolidated its market share in

    electricity supply and remain dominant in the supply of gas as discussed previously. BGE

    experienced a large increase in EBITDA in 2012, up to 79.4 million from 44.3 million in

    2011. This increase is largely attributed to increased retail performance as a result of a

    reduction in costs, a lowering of discounts having established themselves in the electricity

    supply market and an increase in residential gas tariffs of 8.5%. BGEs strong financial

    performance has made a significant contribution to Bord Gis ireanns ability to pay a

    dividend of 23.8 million to the exchequer in 2012, bringing the total dividends paid since its

  • 41

    inception in 1976 to 854 million. BGE employed 453 individuals in 2012 (Bord Gis

    ireann 2013b).

    Fig. 3 BGE Operating Profit before Depreciation and Amortisation (EBITDA) 2009-2012

    Source: Bord Gis ireann Annual Reports (2009-2012)

    Beyond being a source of dividend and employment for the exchequer and economy

    respectively, BGE fulfils wider social aims. Throughout the economic downturn, BGE has

    worked closely with government agencies and non-profits such as Saint Vincent de Paul,

    ALONE and MABS to ensure energy is supplied to vulnerable customers who struggle to

    meet their payments. It has facilitated flexible payment plans and deems cessation of supply a

    very last resort, only to be undertaken when all other avenues have been exhausted (Bord

    Gis ireann 2010, 2011). Also, BGE plays an important role in the development of new

    energy technologies. It has committed capital and resources to the Irish Energy Research

    Centre and the Irish Maritime and Energy Resource Centre, contributing 1.5 million to the

    latter for the construction of new premises (Bord Gis ireann 2013b).

    In the absence of a full cost-benefit analysis of the divestiture, this paper can only observe

    that BGE will cease to contribute to Bord Gis ireanns dividend to the state and that no

    commitment has been made to retain BGEs staff. These employees however, will benefit in

    the short-run from the sale of their employee share ownership plan which sees them hold a

    stake of 3.27% of the company (Bord Gis ireann 2013b). Uncertainty prevails over a

    20

    30

    40

    50

    60

    70

    80

    90

    2009 2010 2011 2012

    EB

    ITD

    A

    'mil

    lion

    Year

  • 42

    privately owned BGEs policy regarding universal access, consumer debts and BGEs

    commitment to the research and development of new technologies.

    4.5 The Sale Process to Date

    Labours pre-election opposition to privatization has waned, and two Labour Party TDs now

    preside over the sale; Minster for Public Expenditure and Reform Brendan Howlin and

    Minister for Communications, Energy and Natural Resources Pat Rabitte. Management of

    Bord Gis ireann have co-operated with the sale of BGE, as acknowledged in Chairperson

    Rose Hynes statements in Bord Gis ireanns annual reports in 2011 and 2012 Bord Gis

    ireann 2012b, 2013b). However, it does not appear that the sale was advocated for by

    management as it was, for example, in the case of T and Aer Lingus.

    The timeline of the sale process to date is as follows:

    22 Febraury 2012: Government initially announces its plans to sell BGE, indicating

    that the sale would only take place