Prior Information and Consumer Search: Evidence from Eye ...

45
Marketing Science Institute Working Paper Series 2020 Report No. 20-141 Prior Information and Consumer Search: Evidence from Eye-tracking Qianyun Poppy Zhang, Raluca M. Ursu, and Tulin Erdem Prior Information and Consumer Search: Evidence from Eye-tracking” © 2020 Qianyun Poppy Zhang, Raluca M. Ursu, and Tulin Erdem MSI working papers are dist ributed for the bene fit of MSI corporate and academic members and the general public. Reports are not to be reproduced or published in any form or by any means, elect ronic or mechanical, without written permission. Marketing Science Institute Working Paper Series

Transcript of Prior Information and Consumer Search: Evidence from Eye ...

Marketing Science Institute Working Paper Series 2020 Report No. 20-141

Prior Information and Consumer Search: Evidence from Eye-tracking Qianyun Poppy Zhang, Raluca M. Ursu, and Tulin Erdem

Prior Information and Consumer Search: Evidence from Eye-tracking” © 2020 Qianyun Poppy Zhang, Raluca M. Ursu, and Tulin Erdem

MSI working papers are distributed for the benefit of MSI corporate and academic members and the general public. Reports are not to be reproduced or published in any form or by any means, electronic or mechanical, without written permission.

Marketing Science Institute Working Paper Series

Prior Information and Consumer Search:Evidence from Eye-tracking ∗

Qianyun Poppy Zhang† Raluca M. Ursu‡ Tulin Erdem§

Current version: September 2020

Abstract

Our objective in this paper is to quantify the impact of prior information (e.g. that obtained

from past purchases or uses of a product) on consumer search and purchase decisions. To this

end, we develop a model of sequential search where consumers with heterogeneous prior beliefs

about brand match values choose whether to search for additional information on the available

brands and their features. This additional information, though costly, allows consumers to

update their beliefs in a Bayesian fashion and to make more informed choices. We estimate

the model on a data set of consumers making smartphone search and purchase decisions. Our

data set has two novel features: (i) it contains information on consumers’ prior ownership of,

familiarity, and experience with brands; and (ii) it captures search behavior at the very granular

level of eye-movements. Preliminary evidence from our data demonstrates the importance of

prior information: consumers are more likely to search and buy brands they own and are familiar

with. Using these data and our model, we then quantify the impact of prior information, in

addition to consumer preferences and search costs, on consumer choices, as well as document

the estimation bias arising from omitting prior information from the model. Finally, through a

series of counterfactuals, we explore the managerial value of using consumers’ prior information

to construct personalized ranking-based recommendation systems.

Keywords: consumer search, search with learning, prior uncertainty, eye-tracking, recommendation

systems.∗The authors thank Paulo Albuquerque, Anocha Aribarg, Bryan Bollinger, Masakazu Ishihara, Anindya Ghose,

Pranav Jindal, Xiao Liu, Ana Martinovici, Tom Meyvis, Eitan Muller, Shervin Tehrani, Olivier Toubia, Russ Winer,as well as participants at the UT-Dallas Bass FORMS Conference 2020, Marketing Science Conference at Duke 2020,Rutgers Mentor-Mentee Symposium 2019, and NYU Marketing Department brown bag series for their comments.The authors would also like to thank Norman White, Robin Wurl, Shenglong Wang, Eugene Dzedzits and staff at bothNYU Stern Research Computing and High Performance Computing centers for their help with the computationalchallenges encountered during estimation. The usual disclaimer applies.†Stern School of Business, New York University, E-mail: [email protected].‡Stern School of Business, New York University, E-mail: [email protected].§Stern School of Business, New York University, E-mail: [email protected].

1Marketing Science Institute Working Paper Series

1 Introduction

In many markets, consumers lack perfect information about all available options or their features

before making a purchase decision. For example, when searching for a car insurance policy, con-

sumers are reported to only check 3 out of more than 20 companies available (Honka (2014)). Also,

when shopping for books, 75% of consumers only search one retailer (De los Santos et al. (2012)),

while in the digital camera category, 72% of a consumers’ search volume is concentrated at their

most visited company (Bronnenberg et al. (2016)).

To rationalize behavior in such markets, previous work has relied on consumer search models.

These models describe consumer choices as resulting from a search process whereby consumers

trade off the expected benefit of continued search against the cost to decide which products to

become informed about and which to ignore (e.g Stigler (1961); Weitzman (1979)). To quantify the

expected benefit from searching, previous work assumes either that consumers know the distribution

of the individual product rewards (e.g. price, match values) they are searching for (Hong and Shum

(2006), Moraga-Gonzalez and Wildenbeest (2008), Kim et al. (2010), De los Santos et al. (2012),

Seiler (2013), Honka (2014), Koulayev (2014), Moraga-Gonzalez et al. (2017), Chen and Yao (2017),

Honka and Chintagunta (2016), Ursu (2018), Ghose et al. (2019), Gardete and Antill (2020)) or

that consumers have common prior beliefs about these rewards that they update while searching

(Ma (2019), Ursu et al. (2020)).1 However, consumers may both lack perfect knowledge of entire

reward distributions for all products and may have different past experiences with brands (acquired

through past purchases or uses of a given product), affecting their prior beliefs. Without data on

how consumers differ in their prior knowledge of products, the study of how they search for product

information is limited.

In this paper, we develop a model of sequential search with learning that makes use of data

on consumers’ heterogeneous prior information about products. We build on Ursu et al. (2020)

and model consumer search as a learning process: consumers are uncertain about a brand’s match

value, but hold beliefs in the form of priors; by searching, they receive signals of the brand’s match

value and update their beliefs in a Bayesian manner. We extend this framework in three directions:

1Although we focus on learning about individual brands’ rewards, previous work also studies cases where consumerssearch to learn about the market distribution of rewards (Koulayev (2013),De los Santos and Koulayev (2017), De losSantos and Koulayev (2017), Hu et al. (2019)).

2Marketing Science Institute Working Paper Series

(i) we allow consumers to start searching with heterogeneous brand prior beliefs, (ii) we extend the

model to allow search not only at the brand level, but also at the brand-attribute level, and (iii)

we adapt the model to an empirical setting where consumers make very frequent search decisions

relying on partially myopic search rules.

We estimate our model on a novel data set of consumers making smartphone search and purchase

decisions among the top brands available in 2013: Apple, Samsung, Nokia, Motorola, and HTC.

These data have two features that stand out. First, they contain information on consumers’ prior

brand ownership, familiarity with each brand, and experience using different smartphone functions

(e.g. camera, wifi, texting). This feature of the data allows us model consumer prior beliefs as fully

heterogeneous. More precisely, based on preliminary evidence from our data, we model consumer

prior mean beliefs as a function of their previous ownership, their prior uncertainty as a function

of familiarity, and allow experience with product features to affect the precision of the signals

consumers obtain through search.

Second, in these data we observe consumer search decisions at the very granular level of eye-

movements using eye-tracking methods. This feature of the data has three consequences for our

analysis. First, it allows us to observe which brands and which attributes consumers choose to

become informed about, as well as the amount of information they obtained about each (i.e. the

number of eye-fixations). With these data, we can then model search at the brand-attribute level.

Second, it reveals when consumers choose to obtain brand and attribute information, and when they

look at the space around products (“white space”) that does not contain any valuable information.

We use this feature as a source of exogenous variation indicating consumers’ value of time and thus

shifting search costs. Finally, unlike in the case where consumers physically visit a store (Yavorsky

et al. (2020)) or where they need to click on product links online to obtain information (Chen and

Yao (2017); De los Santos et al. (2012); De los Santos and Koulayev (2017); Koulayev (2014); De los

Santos (2018); Ursu (2018)), searching by simply moving one’s eyes and making another fixation

involves different considerations. In particular, given the high frequency with which consumers make

search decisions in our setting, we expect the computational burden of determining the optimal

eye fixation sequence to outweigh the benefit, leading consumers to prefer partially myopic decision

rules or heuristics. Motivated by this observation, in this paper we use insights from the literature

on rational inattention and model consumers as forward-looking agents that use heuristics to make

3Marketing Science Institute Working Paper Series

decisions (Gabaix and Laibson (2000), Gabaix et al. (2006), and Hauser (2014)). Such models have

been shown to fit data patterns well (Camerer and Johnson (2004); Gabaix et al. (2006); Tehrani

and Ching (2020)), including in contexts very similar to our own (Yang et al. (2015)).

Using these data, we document that consumers vary greatly in their prior information on brands.

For example, only 79% of consumers own a smartphone. In terms of prior brand ownership, 29%

owned Apple and 24% owned Samsung previously, while 7% owned brands outside of our study.

Also, familiarity with each brand differs substantially across consumers, with the average ranging

from 2.41 (for Nokia) to 4.76 (for Apple) on a 7 point scale. In terms of experience, we find that

consumers in 2013 were most experienced with the essential communication functions of the phone

(e.g. voice-calling, texting), and least knowledgeable of the functions relating to the camera. In

addition, we find that prior information helps explain observed search and brand choices: consumers

are more likely to search the brand they own and are familiar with, and subsequently more likely

to purchase this brand.

In estimating the model, we find that prior information plays an important role in explaining

consumer search behavior. More precisely, we show that prior ownership increases consumers’

evaluation of the product before beginning search. We also show that familiarity with a brand

decreases the prior variance and that product attributes the consumer has more experience with

provide more precise signals of her match value. In addition, we document the estimation bias

arising from omitting heterogeneity in prior information from the model. We find that consumer

preferences for brands with high previous ownership or familiarity are overestimated, but find no

sizable bias for estimated search costs. More precisely, when we assume away belief heterogeneity,

the model interprets searches, that may actually be influenced by preference for a previously owned

brand or by lower uncertainty due to familiarity, as motivated by valuable brand information

obtained through search. Thus, preferences for such brands are generally inflated. Since search

costs are identified primarily from the number of options searched, they are less affected by the

omission of belief heterogeneity.

Finally, we perform a series of counterfactuals to explore the managerial value of using con-

sumers’ prior information when constructing personalized recommendation systems. In particular,

we focus on the decision to rank products for consumers and seek to measure the importance of ac-

counting for consumer prior information when personalizing such rankings. We find that, compared

4Marketing Science Institute Working Paper Series

to the default ranking observed in our data (randomized), ranking products based on our model

that accounts for heterogeneous prior beliefs benefits consumers the most, allowing them to save

on search costs (by minimizing the distance their eyes need to travel between relevant options) and

to find better matching brands. This increase in the consumer welfare in turn may increase long

term company revenues. In contrast, we find that ranking products based on a model that wrongly

assumes consumer prior beliefs are homogeneous leads to the smallest increase in welfare. Finally,

accounting for prior information by directly ordering products based on consumers’ reported prior

ownership and familiarity results in an intermediate welfare increase, almost as large as the one

based on our model. Our results emphasize the managerial importance of accounting for consumer

prior information.

The rest of the paper is organized as follows. Section 3 introduces our data and presents

preliminary reduced-form evidence for the importance of prior information. In section 5, we present

our model, followed by estimation results and counterfactual analysis. The last section concludes

and discusses limitations and future extensions of our work.

2 Literature review

This paper is related primarily to four streams of the literature: (i) prior work modeling consumer

search with learning, (ii) the literature on disentangling state dependence and heterogeneity from

consumer choices, (iii) models of rational inattention and consumer information acquisition, and

(iv) previous work using eye-tracking data to analyze consumer decisions. In what follows, we

describe our contributions to each of these streams.

Most closely related to our paper is prior work modeling consumer search with learning. Most

models of consumer search, building on the framework of Stigler (1961) or Weitzman (1979), assume

that consumers are able to resolve all the relevant uncertainty about a product with just one search.

However, these models cannot explain why consumer choose to revisit some products, a pattern

that has been established by prior work (e.g. Bronnenberg et al. (2016); Dang et al. (2020); Ursu

et al. (2020)). To rationalize this as well as other patterns, previous work relaxes the assumption of

fully revealed uncertainty through search and allows consumers to gradually learn through search,

typically by Bayesian updating (Branco et al. (2015); Branco et al. (2012); Chick and Frazier

5Marketing Science Institute Working Paper Series

(2012); Dukes and Liu (2015); Ma (2019);Ke et al. (2016), Ke and Villas-Boas (2019); Gardete and

Antill (2020); Ursu et al. (2020); Lu and Hutchinson (2020)). In parallel, when studying consumers’

repeated purchase decisions, researchers also allow consumers to learn from prior purchases and

update their beliefs in a Bayesian manner (e.g., Erdem and Keane (1996); Ackerberg (2001); Ching

et al. (2013) and Iyengar et al. (2007)). However, work estimating such search models either

assumes homogeneity in prior beliefs (e.g. Ma (2019); Lu and Hutchinson (2020); Ursu et al.

(2020)) or assumes that consumers have rational expectations and know the true utility distribution

(e.g. Gardete and Antill (2020)). We also estimate a model of search with Bayesian learning,

but we augment data on consumer search and purchase decisions with information on consumers’

prior ownership, familiarity, and experience with brands. These additional data allow us to model

consumers’ heterogeneous prior beliefs. Our results also add to previous survey and experimental

work that shows the importance of accounting for prior beliefs when considering consumer search

decisions (Johnson and Russo (1984); Moorthy et al. (1997); Jindal and Aribarg (2020)), as well as

recent theoretical work on prior ownership and search (Ning and Villas-Boas (2020)).

With data on consumers’ prior information, we can identify the effect of prior beliefs on search

and purchase decisions separately from that of preferences and search costs. As such, our work

relates to the literature on disentangling state dependence and heterogeneity from consumer choices

(e.g. Dube et al. (2010), Shin et al. (2012)). Most closely related is the work of Shin et al. (2012),

which demonstrates the value of using data on stated preferences observed before consumers make

choices (i.e. measures of liking and familiarity with products) to separate the impact of state

dependence from preferences. Our paper uses similar information on consumers’ prior choices and

familiarity with brands before engaging in the choice task in our study to capture the effect of state

dependence. We contribute to this stream of work by additionally studying the importance of state

dependence in the context of consumer search decisions.

Our paper also relates to prior work on rational inattention. This work proposes that consumers

use heuristics and rely on partially myopic rules when making choices (e.g., Gabaix and Laibson

(2000); Gabaix et al. (2006) and Hauser (2014)). Such models have been shown to fit data patterns

well (Camerer and Johnson (2004); Gabaix et al. (2006); Tehrani and Ching (2020)), including

in contexts very similar to our own (Yang et al. (2015)). Given the high frequency with which

consumers make decisions in our data, we rely on this work and model consumers as forward-

6Marketing Science Institute Working Paper Series

looking agents that use heuristics to make decisions. We provide a new application of heuristics to

models of search with learning and heterogeneous prior beliefs.

Lastly, our paper is related to prior work measuring eye-movements to inform choice mod-

els. Eye-tracking methods have gained a lot of attention from researchers studying the compu-

tational processes of decision making (e.g., Wedel and Pieters (2008); Chandon et al. (2002)).

Eye-fixations have been shown to be indicators of consumer attention (Wedel and Pieters (2000)),

utilities (Meißner et al. (2016)), and choices (Pieters et al. (2019)). Recent studies have modeled

eye-fixations as deliberate choices to search for additional information (e.g. Yang et al. (2015);

Lu and Hutchinson (2020)), approach which we will use as well. Also, previous work has found

that heuristics in decision-making can lead to distinct eye-movement patterns (Orquin and Loose

(2013)) and it has been proposed to use Bayesian methods to build models that closely examine

such eye-movements (e.g. Wedel and Pieters (2008)). Our paper develops such a model.

In the following section, we introduce our data and present summary statistics and descriptive

analysis.

3 Data

3.1 Data Description

Our data were collected in 2013 by Tobii Insight2 as part of a litigation case. Data collection re-

sulted from an experiment designed by Tulin Erdem and Rik Pieters in collaboration with Analysis

Group. The experiment mimicked a common online shopping experience for smartphones. Specif-

ically, consumers were asked to perform a product comparison task in which they evaluated five

smartphones intending to choose one to purchase. The consumers in this study were recruited from

three US cities (San Diego, Cincinnati, and Washington DC) using Tobii’s partner organizations’

database, which ensures the representativeness of the participant pool. The consumers were at

least 18 years old and were required to not have any eye problems, such as nystagmus. Also, the re-

cruited consumers could not have worked for a research company, advertising agency or technology

company. Consumers were required to own a cell phone at the time of their participation in the

study and to intend to purchase a smartphone within 9 months. There were four major segments

2https://www.tobiipro.com/insight/.

7Marketing Science Institute Working Paper Series

of consumers in the population: 1) Apple owners; 2) Samsung owners; 3) other brand owners; 4)

non-smartphone consumers. To ensure the representation of consumers in our study, we applied a

stratified sampling method to draw equal numbers of consumers from each of these four segments.

The recruited consumers were scheduled to visit the research facilities solely to complete our study

and they were offered $50 to cover the transportation costs and their time.

There were in total five smartphones under comparison: Apple iPhone 5, HTC One, Samsung

Galaxy Note II, Nokia Lumia 920, and Motorola Droid RAZR MAXX HD. For the rest of this paper,

we will refer to these smartphones solely by their brand names. Prices were as follows: $249.99 for

Apple and Samsung, $199.99 for HTC and Motorola, and $99.99 for Nokia. The determination of

the smartphones used in the experiment was guided by the top 20 Google search results for various

keywords such as ‘best top smartphone 2013’, and by mentions in consumer reports. We note that

consumers did not own any of the five products used in the study, i.e. an Apple product owner did

not own the iPhone 5, but might have owned an iPhone 3 for example.

The brand attributes displayed to consumers were chosen to be consistent with the attributes

shown on (i) the four major carrier websites (AT&T, Verizon, Sprint and T-Mobile); (ii) the

top four electronic retailers (Amazon, Bestbuy, Target mobile and Walmart); and (iii) the top

independent review websites (Verge, CNET, PCWorld and gdgt.com). Previous work suggests that

varying the number of product attributes available to consumers may increase choice complexity

(Malhotra (1982)), which in turn can affect how consumers acquire and process information (Swait

and Adamowicz (2001); Payne (1976). In our study, we used the number of attributes that were

shown to consumers to create different choice complexity levels: low (18 attributes), medium (29

attributes), and high (39 attributes). Figure 1 displays the options that consumers saw in the low

complexity condition.3 From top to bottom, attributes that consumers saw can be categorized into

seven groups as ‘Brand’ (including a photo of the product and color option), ‘Price’, ‘Technical’

(including ‘Wireless Capabilities’ and ‘Operating System’), ‘Size’ (including ‘Display’) ‘Battery’,

‘Camera’, and ‘Memory’. All three complexity conditions had these parent attribute categories.

The number of attributes that nested within these categories varied from condition to condition.

For example, while there was only 1 attribute under ‘Camera’ in the low complexity condition, there

were 3 attributes under ‘Camera’ in the high complexity condition. Also note that the information

3Figure 6 in Appendix 9.1 illustrates the options available to consumers in the high complexity condition.

8Marketing Science Institute Working Paper Series

displayed to consumers about each of these attributes was the same in each condition (for example,

Apple was shown with a price of $249.99 in all conditions). Under each of the three complexity

conditions, there were five unique combinations of attribute and brand orders, for a total of 15

unique stimuli. The order of the brands (columns) and attributes (rows) displayed on the screen

was randomized to control for the effect of order on consumer search and purchase decisions.

Consumers were asked to pick only one brand to purchase and they could take as much time as

they needed to make that decision. There was a ‘Click to buy’ button next to each of the options.

Once a consumer clicked on that button, a confirmation page appeared that asked the consumer

to confirm her choice, ending the experiment.

Figure 1: Study Design Under the Low Complexity Condition

Before engaging in the product comparison task just described, consumers were asked to fill

out a survey. We used consumers’ answers to this survey to construct three measures of their prior

brand information: prior ownership, familiarity, and experiences. The exact questions asked to

construct each measure were:

• Prior ownership

– Do you currently own a smartphone? (0 or 1; 1 means own a smartphone)

– What is the current model or brand of the smartphone you own? (choice among the five

brands in the study, or ‘None’ for consumers who do not have smartphones and ‘Others’

for consumers who owned brands that are not included in the study)

9Marketing Science Institute Working Paper Series

• Familiarity

– How familiar are you with the brands in the experiment? (measured on a scale from 1

to 7 where 1 corresponds to ‘Not at All’ and ‘7’ corresponds to ‘Extremely Well’)

• Experience

– How much do you use each of the functions of the smartphone: video taking, photo tak-

ing, internet browsing, video chatting, texting, calling, etc.? (choices included ‘Never’,

‘Less Often than Once per Month’, ‘At Least Once Per Month’, ‘At Least Once Per

Week’, ‘Nearly Every Day’, ‘Several Times Per Day’. We converted responses to a scale

ranging from 0 to 1, where 0 corresponds to ‘Never’ and ‘1’ corresponds to ‘Several

Times Per Day’)

We also gathered information on consumers’ age, income, gender (female coded as 1 and male

coded as 0) and employment status (employed coded as 1 and unemployed coded as 0). There were

four age groups (‘18-29’, ‘30-49’, ‘50-64’, and ‘65 or older’) and eight income groups measured by

annual household income (‘$14, 999 or less’, ‘$15, 000 − $24, 999’, ‘$25, 000 − $34, 999’, ‘$35, 000 −

$49, 999’, ‘$50, 000−$74, 999’, ‘$75, 000−$99, 999’, ‘$100, 000−$149, 999’, and ‘$150, 000 or more’).

There were in total 460 consumers who participated in the experiment, but we observed a

complete set of eye-movements, as well as complete demographic and survey responses, for 342

of them, who will be the focus of our study. The eye-movement data of these consumers was

described by their attention to different areas of interest (AOI) on the screen, such as the seven

main attribute categories for each brand.4 An eye fixation in the data is defined as a period of

200-400 milliseconds during which the eye is relatively fixed on an area.5 Consistent with prior

work, we interpret eye-fixations as deliberate consumer actions to search for and process additional

brand information (Shi et al. (2013); Yang et al. (2015); Lu and Hutchinson (2020)).

3.2 Summary Statistics

In our final data sample, there are 342 consumers and 78,617 observations (78,275 eye-fixations,

and 342 individual consumer brand choices). Each consumer makes on average (median) 229 (186)

4For an illustration of eye-fixations in our study, see Figure 7 in Appendix 9.1.5These data were generated using standard settings in the Tobii eye-tracking software.

10Marketing Science Institute Working Paper Series

fixations on the products and their attributes displayed on the screen. Among these consumers,

the majority of them belong to the age group 30 to 49 years old, 52% are female, 69% are white

and 71% are employed. Around 56% of the consumers have an annual income of at least $50,000.6

Approximately 79% of the consumers in our data own a smartphone.

Table 1 reports the distribution of two measures of prior information (prior ownership and

familiarity with each of the five brands), as well as consumers’ final brand choice in the study. It

can be seen that consumers are most likely to own, be familiar with, and purchase either Apple or

Samsung smartphones, with the latter being most likely to be purchased, although more consumers

own and are familiar with Apple than Samsung. Sizable fractions of consumers also own HTC,

Motorola and Nokia smartphones, with the latter being the least popular. Finally, approximately

7% of consumers own other brands than the ones presented in the task.

Table 1: Summary Statistics on Prior Ownership, Familiarity, and Brand ChoiceBrand Prior Ownership% Familiarity Brand choice%

Apple 29.53 4.76 25.73Samsung 24.27 4.20 29.24HTC 11.11 2.88 21.34Motorola 6.43 3.11 16.08Nokia 0.58 2.41 7.60

Others 7.31None 20.76

In Table 2, we summarize our third measure of prior information given by consumers’ experiences

with various smartphone functions, such as voice-calling or photo-taking. In total, there were 16

functions consumers were asked about in the survey, which we later grouped to coincide with five

of the relevant categories of attributes: Camera (e.g. photo-taking and video-taking), Battery

(e.g. voice-calling, texting, and video-chatting), Size (e.g. dimensions, weight), Technical (e.g.

OS, Wifi, warranty) and Memory (e.g. RAM). We find that consumers are most experienced with

the ‘Battery’ attribute, since it relates to the essential communication functions of the phone. In

contrast, consumers are least experienced with the ‘Technical’ and the ‘Camera’ attributes. In

2013 when we collected our data, photo-taking and video-taking with a smartphone were still new

functions to most users 7, which explains consumers’ low level of experience with these attributes.

6See Figure 8 in Appendix 9.1 for more information on consumer demographics.7https://www.nytimes.com/2014/02/06/technology/personaltech/making-the-case-for-a-more-selfie-friendly-

smartphone.html

11Marketing Science Institute Working Paper Series

Across consumers we also find that there is a large variation in their experience with each attribute.

Table 2: Consumer Experiences with Product AttributesStatistic N Mean St. Dev. Min Pctl(25) Pctl(75) Max

Battery 342 0.706 0.409 0 0.4 1 1Memory 342 0.529 0.358 0 0.1 0.8 1Size 342 0.500 0.339 0 0.2 0.8 1Technical 342 0.447 0.281 0 0.3 0.7 1Camera 342 0.446 0.309 0 0.2 0.7 1

Note: The original responses are converted to numeric values ranging from 0 to 1, where 0corresponds to ‘Never’ and ‘1’ corresponds to ‘Several Times Per Day’.

4 Reduced-Form Evidence

In this section, we present reduced-form evidence relating consumers’ prior information to their

search and purchase decisions. Our results describe these relations, as well as help motivate our

structural model, which we present in the next section.

4.1 Relation between Prior Information and Search

As mentioned, in our data we observe consumer eye fixations on the screen on various AOIs. We

interpret these fixations as search decisions. Consumers can choose to search across brands (e.g.

search Apple versus Samsung), or within brands, choosing which attributes to become informed

about (e.g. price vs. memory). To investigate the relation between prior information and con-

sumers’ search decisions, we consider two types of evidence. First, we ask whether the brands

consumers own are searched more or less than others. To answer this question, we summarize the

percentage of consumers’ fixations to each of the brands, split by whether consumers owned the

brand previously or not. Figure 4.1 reports our results. The left panel shows the share of fixations

early in the search process (first 10 fixations), while the right panel shows the share of the entire

search process.8 In each panel, the left bar shows the average percentage of fixations on brands

the consumer did not previously own, while the right displays the share for the brand they owned.

As can be seen, consumers are more likely to search the brand they previously owned, rather than

other individual brands. This pattern holds both early in the search process and throughout.

8To ensure that our results are comparable, the figure considers only consumers who own a smartphone.

12Marketing Science Institute Working Paper Series

Figure 2: Distribution of Fixations by Prior Ownership

Second, we check how search activity differs based on the identity of the brand previously owned,

as well as investigate how consumers who did not own one of the five brands in our study search.

More precisely, we split consumers based on their prior ownership and final choices into two groups:

consumers who choose to purchase the same brand as they previously owned will be referred to

as ‘loyal consumers’, while all others (including those who own a different or no smartphone) will

be referred to as ‘switchers’. Then, in Figure 3, we analyze the amount of search each group of

consumers performs. In this figure, the y-axis denotes the brands that consumers previously owned,

while the x-axis denotes the five brands available in our study. The size and color of a circle indicate

the share of searches (fixations) to the brands on the x-axis. As can be seen in the top panel, there’s

a strong trend along the diagonal, showing that loyal consumers are more likely to search the brand

they own (which evidently coincides with the one they end up choosing). The bottom panel shows

that for switchers, the distribution of their searches does not have a strong diagonal trend. Rather,

as we will show in Table 3, switchers search the brands they end up buying more often, rather than

the ones they own. For example, Apple owners who switch, search Samsung and HTC the most,

which are the brands they are most likely to choose. Among consumers who own a different or no

smartphone, the share of fixations is more even across brands, with Samsung attracting slightly

more attention.

13Marketing Science Institute Working Paper Series

Figure 3: Fixations by Prior Ownership (y-axis) and Brand Choice (x-axis)

4.2 Relation between Prior Information and Brand Choices

In Table 3, we relate prior ownership to brand choices. As can be seen from the diagonal of the

table, regardless of the brand, most consumers prefer to choose the brand they own. For example,

out all previous Apple consumers, 55.4% (56 out of 101), chose to purchase Apple again. When

prior Apple owners switch to other brands, Samsung and HTC are their top two choices. When

Samsung consumers switch to other brands, HTC and Motorola are their top two choices. It is

to be noted that among consumers who do not have a smartphone, Motorola is the most popular

choice, followed by Samsung and Apple. Among consumers who own a smartphone other than the

five displayed, HTC is the most popular choice.

14Marketing Science Institute Working Paper Series

Table 3: Prior Ownership and Brand Choice

Brand ChoicePrior Ownership Appe HTC Motorola Nokia Samsung Total

Apple 56 14 6 8 17 101HTC 3 16 6 3 10 38

Motorola 2 5 11 0 4 22Nokia 0 0 0 1 1 2

Samsung 8 18 10 2 45 83

None 14 9 20 10 18 71Others 5 11 2 2 5 25

Finally, to analyze more formally how prior information impacts consumers purchase decisions,

we run a conditional logit model at the consumer level with their brand choice as the dependent

variable. In this model, the utility of a consumer i for a brand j is given by

uij = brandj + α ∗ poij + β ∗ famij + π ∗ fixationsij + εij (1)

where utility uij is a function of brand intercepts brandj , prior ownership poij , familiarity with a

brand famij , and the number of searches/fixations accumulated for each of the five brands in our

study, fixationsij .9 Samsung is set as the reference brand.

Our results are presented in Table 4. Model (1) is the baseline model which does not include

prior information (prior ownership and familiarity) or fixations, while model (2) includes prior

information but no fixations. Finally, model (3) includes both prior information and share of fix-

ations for each brand.10 Comparing estimation results for models (1) and (2), we find that prior

ownership and familiarity both have positive and significant coefficients, suggesting that consumers

are more likely to purchase the product they own and are more familiar with, consistent with our

previous results.11 In model (3), we show that fixations also have a positive and significant coeffi-

cient, suggesting that brands consumers spend more time searching are more likely to be chosen.

After accounting for fixations and prior information, brand intercepts are no longer significant.

This suggests that the amount of attention given to each brand, summarized by the accumulated

9Note that we cannot include in the analysis our third measure of prior information, experience with productattributes, since this does not vary by brand.

10To be able to compare estimates across the three models, in the analysis we focus on consumers who own asmartphone.

11The correlation between prior ownership and familiarity is relatively small, ranging from 0.12 to 0.41 acrossbrands, showing a large variation across consumers in the two measures.

15Marketing Science Institute Working Paper Series

fixations and consumers’ prior knowledge and familiarity of the brands, capture consumers’ brand

value. Finally, our measures of model fit suggest the importance of accounting for prior information

and search decisions when studying consumer choices.

Table 4: Prior Information and Brand Choice

Brand Choice(1) (2) (3)

Brand ValueApple −0.110 −0.282 0.354

(0.166) (0.182) (0.244)HTC −0.374∗∗ 0.259 0.236

(0.178) (0.213) (0.290)Nokia −1.705∗∗∗ −0.504 0.040

(0.291) (0.329) (0.451)Motorola −0.847∗∗∗ −0.155 0.149

(0.208) (0.236) (0.320)Samsung - - -

Prior InformationPrior ownership 1.442∗∗∗ 1.624∗∗∗

(0.148) (0.207)Familiarity 0.438∗∗∗ 0.548∗∗∗

(0.082) (0.111)Search

Fixations 0.078∗∗∗

(0.007)

LL −364.928 −308.162 −165.737AIC 737.856 600.218 317.268BIC 758.315 654.907 381.071Observations 1,230 1,230 1,230

Note: ∗p<0.1; ∗∗p<0.05; ∗∗∗p<0.01

The results we presented in this section highlight the importance of calibrating consumer search

models with information on consumers’ prior brand knowledge. The next section introduces our

model relating prior information to consumer search and purchase decisions.

16Marketing Science Institute Working Paper Series

5 Model

5.1 Consumer Problem

Consider a consumer i ∈ {1, . . . , N} who seeks to purchase a brand j ∈ J , where the set of options

available is J = {Apple, HTC, Samsung, Nokia, Motorola}. The consumer faces uncertainty about

her match value with each brand j, but can (partially) resolve this uncertainty by searching j.

This search decision involves paying a search cost, but reveals information to the consumer that

may aid her choice. We build on Ursu et al. (2020) and model consumer search as a learning

process: consumers are uncertain about a brand’s match value, but hold beliefs in the form of

priors; by searching, they receive signals of the brand’s match value and update their beliefs in a

Bayesian manner.12 We extend the model to allow search not only at the brand level, but also

at the brand-attribute level. Therefore, each time period t ∈ {1, . . . , T}, the consumer decides

whether to continue searching, in which case she chooses a brand j and an attribute l ∈ L :

{Brand, Price, Technology, Size, Camera, Memory, Battery} to search, or whether to stop, in which

case she chooses which brand to purchase.

In addition, in our data, we observe three measures of consumer’ prior brand information (prior

ownership, familiarity, and experience), which allow us to model consumer prior beliefs as fully

heterogeneous. In what follows, we choose to allow these measures to affect different learning

parameters of the model, capturing the effect of state dependence.13 In particular, we expect

that prior ownership, which is a direct result of consumer prior choices, will affect the consumer

prior mean value. In other words, a brand the consumer previously owned is more likely to carry

a higher utility weight than other brands. This expectation is consistent with our reduced-form

results, showing that consumers are more likely to both search and purchase products they own.

Thus, at time t = 0, we model the consumer’s prior belief about her match value for j as

N(µij,0, δ2ij,0), (2)

12In Ursu et al. (2020), consumers obtain signals after every minute spent searching; in our paper, one signal isobtained after every eye-fixation.

13More precisely, to disentangle individual heterogeneity and state dependence, we follow Shin et al. (2012) and useour survey data on prior information from previous choice settings to capture state dependence (affecting consumerprior beliefs in our model), while choices consumers make in the current study will reveal heterogeneity in preferences.

17Marketing Science Institute Working Paper Series

where the prior mean is a function of her prior ownership of a brand, poij , as per

µij,0 = λ+ β ∗ poij . (3)

The poij is a binary variable equal to 1 for the brand the consumer previously owned and to 0

for brands she did not own. If the value of β is estimated to be positive, it would suggest that

consumers start their search with a higher utility for the brands they already own compared to

other brands. For consumers who do not have a smartphone or for brands consumers do not own,

the mean of their prior belief is given by λ.

Furthermore, we expect the consumer’s familiarity with a brand to affect her prior uncertainty.

Since familiarity reflects the amount of information a consumer has accumulated for a brand (from

prior searches, purchases or other interactions with a brand), it is likely that the consumer has

lower uncertainty for the brands she knows more about. We model this relation in exponential

form to ensure that variance is non-negative as per

δ2ij,0 =1

exp(γ ∗ famij). (4)

By searching product j and attribute l at time t, the consumer obtains noisy but unbiased

signals slij from the true distribution of match values given by

slij,t ∼ N(µij , σl2ij ), (5)

where the mean of the signal for each brand is a function of brand intercepts that may be hetero-

geneous across consumers. Note that in our data, prices do not vary within a brand. Therefore,

with brand intercepts in the model we cannot separately estimate consumer price sensitivity.

We use data on our third measure of prior uncertainty to model the signal variance. We expect

a consumer’s prior experience with a certain brand attribute to affect the precision of the signal

she receives (e.g. more experience with the phone’s camera may allow the consumer to more

easily grasp the information provided about this attribute on one search). Formally, we model the

variance of the signal as an exponential function of users’ (standardized) experiences with each of

the attributes, Eli (zero if the consumer does not have a smartphone), and constant θ0 as in

18Marketing Science Institute Working Paper Series

σl2ij =θ0

exp(θE ∗ Eli). (6)

After observing signal slij,t, the consumer uses Bayes’ rule to construct her posterior belief about

brand j, given by N(µij,t, δ2ij,t), where

µij,t+1 =

µij,tδ2ij,t

+slij,tσl2ij

1δl2ij,t

+ 1σl2ij

, (7)

δ2ij,t+1 =1

1δ2ij,t

+ 1σl2ij

. (8)

Because draws are independent, the consumer does not learn about the match value of one brand

by searching another. Therefore, after observing signal slij,t, only the posterior belief of j changes.

To obtain product information, the consumer needs to pay a search cost. We model a consumer’s

search cost for brand j as follows

cij = exp(κi + d1Distl + d2Distj + d3Ctrl + d4Ctrj + ω ∗ Complexityi+

η ∗Whitespacei + φ ∗Demoi)(9)

where the κi denotes the mean search cost, which may vary across consumers. When modeling

search costs, we also account for the distance the consumer’s eyes traveled on the current search.

Previous studies (e.g., Yang et al. (2015) and Wedel and Pieters (2008)) suggest that people are

more likely to move their eyes to contiguous cells to minimize on cognitive effort. Also, consumers’

fixations may more naturally gravitate towards the center of the screen (e.g. Wedel and Pieters

(2008) and Atalay et al. (2012)). We account for these two effects as follows. First, we include

Distl and Distj in the search cost to denote the standardized distance traveled vertically (in the

attribute space) and horizontally (in the brand space) to reach j. These range from 0 to 1, where

1 stands for the farthest possible fixation location on the screen. Second, we use Ctrj and Ctrl

to denote the location of product j and attribute l in standardized distance to the center of the

screen. These also range from 0 to 1, with 0 denoting the center of the screen.

In addition to these distance and location-based effects, search costs also account for the com-

plexity level of the task the consumer is in (low, medium or high). Based on prior work, we expect

19Marketing Science Institute Working Paper Series

higher choice complexity to decrease consumers’ processing resources and therefore increase search

costs (Malhotra (1982); Swait and Adamowicz (2001); Payne (1976)).

A unique feature of our data is that we observe not only cases where the consumer chooses to

search for information, but also cases where she chooses to be idle, that is to spend time in the

task without obtaining any valuable information. More precisely, we observe consumer fixations

to what we call “white space” or the area around the matrix with product comparisons that does

not contain any purchase relevant information. We use the ratio of the number of fixations on

this area to the overall number of fixations, variable Whitespacei, as an (exogenous) proxy for

the consumer’s value of time, which would affect her search costs. Across consumers, the average

Whitespacei is 0.305 with a minimum of 0 and a maximum of 0.69.

Finally, we also account for consumer demographics, such as age, income, gender, and employ-

ment status, when modeling search costs (similar to De los Santos (2018)). We converted the four

age groups (1 representing the ‘18-29’ years old group) and eight income groups to numeric values

(1 representing the ‘$14, 999 or less’ income group).

Figure 5.1 provides an illustration of our model. As can be seen, given information obtained

before time period t (summarized by the consumer’s prior uncertainty at that time), the consumer

decides whether to continue searching or whether to stop. If she decides to continue searching,

then she decides which brand-attribute combination to search, pays a search cost, and receives an

information signal. In this illustration, the consumer chooses to search brand 2 attribute 2, for

which she observes a signal that she then uses to update her posterior belief. With this updated

posterior, the consumer then faces the same search decision in the next period, t + 1. If instead

the consumer decides to stop searching, then she makes a purchase decision. In what follows, we

describe consumer search and purchase decisions in more detail.

20Marketing Science Institute Working Paper Series

Figure 4: How Consumers Make Search and Purchase Decisions

5.2 Search and Choice Rules

Every time period, the consumer decides whether to continue searching, in which case she chooses

a brand and an attribute l to search, or whether to stop, in which case she chooses which brand

to purchase. In this section, we describe consumer decisions that are relevant for our setting where

searching involves simply moving one’s eyes and making another fixation on the screen. This setting

differs from most other settings considered in the search literature, where consumers physically

visit a store (Yavorsky et al. (2020)) or where they need to click on product links online to obtain

information (Chen and Yao (2017); De los Santos et al. (2012); De los Santos and Koulayev (2017);

Koulayev (2014); De los Santos (2018); Ursu (2018)). More precisely, consumers in our setting

make a large number of search decisions (278 on average). Therefore, we expect the computational

burden of determining the optimal decision for each of the eye fixations consumers make to outweigh

the benefit, leading consumers to prefer partially myopic decision rules or heuristics. Motivated by

this observation, we rely on the literature on rational inattention and model consumers as forward-

looking agents that use heuristics to make decisions. Such heuristics have been shown to perform

well in explaining consumer behavior (Camerer and Johnson (2004); Gabaix et al. (2006); Tehrani

and Ching (2020)). We follow Gabaix et al. (2006) and Yang et al. (2015), and model consumers as

searching as if they have to make a purchase decision right after the immediate search (i.e. as if the

next search decision is their last). Also, to capture risk-aversion behavior, we follow Tehrani and

21Marketing Science Institute Working Paper Series

Ching (2020) and assume the consumer’s utility function has the constant absolute risk-aversion

form with risk coefficient r. This assumption also implies that utility has diminishing returns.

Let α denote a consumer’s available actions: α ∈ {Search(j, l), Purchase(j)}. Also, let Iit

indicate the information or beliefs of consumer i at time t: Iit = {µij,t, δij,t}. At t, the consumer

faces a trade-off:

• Purchase product j and receive expected utility14:

Eα [uij,t|Iit]α=purchase(j)

= −exp(−r ∗ µij,t +r2

2∗ δ2ij,t). (10)

• Search product j and attribute l, and receive the maximum utility derived from choosing

one of the alternatives at time t+ 1:

Eα [uij,t|Iit]]α=search(j,l),k 6=j

= max

{−exp(−r ∗ µij,t +

r2

2∗ δ2ij,t+1),−exp(−r ∗ µik,t +

r2

2∗ δ2ik,t)

}− cij .

(11)

In words, if at t the consumer chooses to stop and purchase product j, then she receives expected

utility as per equation (10). This utility is increasing in her posterior mean and decreasing in her

remaining uncertainty. If instead she chooses to continue searching, then she will determine what

option to search by considering the value of searching once more and then stopping to make a

purchase decision immediately after. The expression in equation (11) gives the value of searching

j and then stopping immediately after. This is given by either the value of stopping and choosing

j after an additional search, obtaining the first term in the maximum in equation (10) minus the

search costs of searching j, or stopping and choosing any other option k 6= j, given by the second

term in the maximum in equation (10) minus the search costs of searching j. Since the value of

the posterior variance evolves deterministically, we assume the consumer can compute the value

of δ2ij,t+1 obtained from an additional search of j, in order to construct the expected benefit from

choosing j after searching it again.

14Note that a higher variance decreases consumer utility, making consumers less likely to search an option, unlikein standard sequential search models (e.g. in Weitzman (1979)).

22Marketing Science Institute Working Paper Series

5.3 Likelihood Function

There are 5 brands and 7 attributes in our choice setting. Therefore, a consumer can choose among

35 different possible brand-attribute combinations, or 35 different locations on the screen, to search.

At the same time, a consumer has 5 purchase options corresponding to the 5 brands. Combining

these search and purchase options, a consumer needs to choose one out of 40 options at a given

time. Assuming utility error terms follow the type-1 extreme value distribution, the probability of

consumer i taking action αit at time t equals

p(αit|Iit) =exp(Eα [uij,t|Iit])∑αexp(Eα [ij,t|Iit])

(12)

which leads to the following likelihood function

Likelihood =∏i,t

p(αit|Iit). (13)

To integrate over the signals consumers obtain while searching, we needed to estimate our model

using simulated maximum likelihood. Given the large number of observations per consumer in our

data, we increase estimation efficiency using the following steps: (i) we compute each consumer’s

likelihood and each integration in parallel, and run our model on hundreds of computer nodes

simultaneously; (ii) we impose upper and lower bounds on the magnitude of the prior variance

and signal variance (corresponding to 100 and 0.01, respectively) based on preliminary estimation

results of our model; and (iii) to avoid calculating the Hessian corresponding to our problem, we

use the outer product of gradients estimator (OPG) to compute standard errors.15 Finally, in our

model we capture consumer heterogeneity in parameters of interest (brand match values and mean

search costs) using a latent class approach.

5.4 Identification

In this section, we discuss how the parameters of our model are identified. We seek to identify

three sets of parameters: (i) learning parameters, given by consumer prior beliefs (λ, β, γ), brand

match values (µij), and signal variance (θ0, θE); (ii) search cost parameters (κi, d1, d2, d3, d4, ω, η);

15More details about this estimator, including its asymptotic properties, are available in Berndt et al. (1974) andGreene (2003).

23Marketing Science Institute Working Paper Series

and (iii) risk coefficient (r). Our data provide information on consumers’ search decisions, i.e.

what brand and what attribute they searched every fixation, their final brand choices, as well as

survey information on consumer’s prior knowledge of the brands and their demographics. These

data together with the decision rules in equations 10 and 11 constitute the essential components of

our identification strategy.

Learning parameters are identified from the purchase probability of consumers with different

information sets (similar to Erdem and Keane (1996); Narayanan and Manchanda (2009); Ma

(2019); Ursu et al. (2020)). More precisely, consumers who search very little make purchase decisions

largely based on their prior beliefs. Observed heterogeneity in consumer’s prior brand information

(given by consumers’ prior ownership) identifies β which affects the prior mean. Consistent with

prior work (e.g. Erdem and Keane (1996)), we assume the prior mean constant λ equals the average

brand value across the five brands in the study, which can be interpreted as the average quality of

the smartphone. In contrast, when consumers search extensively, uncertainty reduces to zero and

prior beliefs converge to the true match values, which allows us to estimate brand match values

from purchase frequencies, as is typical in discrete choice models. For example, the odds of a

consumer choosing to purchase Apple over Samsung reveals her higher preference weight for this

brand. Finally, variation across consumers in their experience level with brand functions and their

search and purchase prevalence identifies the signal variance parameters.

Search costs are identified from consumers’ stopping decision. From equation (11), when the

utility of continued search decreases to such a degree that it becomes lower than the search cost,

consumers will stop search. Thus, the total number of searches a consumer performs will identify

the range of mean search costs (κi) that must have made it beneficial for the consumer to perform

that number of searches (Honka and Chintagunta (2016)). The level of mean search costs is pinned

down by the functional form and the value of product utility differences, as well as consumer prior

beliefs. In addition, differences across consumers in complexity level (randomized) and demograph-

ics identify the deviations from mean search costs. Also, consumers’ choice to focus on options that

are further or closer to the previously searched option or the center of the screen, together with

the fact that they were randomly assigned the order in which brands were displayed on the screen,

identify the distance and location parameters in the search cost.

Both high prior uncertainty and low search costs can encourage consumers to search a lot. To

24Marketing Science Institute Working Paper Series

identify these two effects separately, we rely on both distinct data patterns and functional form

identification. More precisely, the search rule in equation (11) dictates not only when consumers

should continue rather than stop searching, but also when they should search the same option again

or switch to searching a different one. Similar to the identification strategy in Ursu et al. (2020),

we note that as consumers search an option, their uncertainty decreases steadily, while the search

cost remains the same (after the first search, in our case). Thus, observing both the total number

of searches and the number of searches per option helps us separately identify these two effects.

Because all the parameters in the prior mean, prior variance, signal mean and signal variance

are estimated jointly, the risk parameter r will not be uniquely identified. Following the strategy

in Erdem et al. (2005), we normalize r to 1, which maintains the assumption that consumers are

risk averse.

5.5 Monte Carlo Simulation

To show that our model’s parameters can be recovered using our estimation strategy, we performed

the following Monte Carlo simulation exercise. To mimic our data, we generated 1000 consumers

and their prior ownership (random binary variable), familiarity with 5 brands and experiences with

7 attributes (both familiarity and experience are uniformly distributed on the interval from -5 to

5). We assigned one of the 5 brands as the reference brand with a mean match value of zero, and

assumed the same mean match value for the remaining brands. Also, to simplify estimation, we

assumed only the constant κi = κ affected search costs.

In the simulation, consumers follow the same search and choice rules we described in equations

(11) and (10). To integrate over all possible signal draws, we compute the likelihood function as

an average over 1000 draws from the signal distribution. Also, we perform the estimation exercise

50 times and report results after averaging across these estimates. We also report the standard

deviation of the mean estimate across these simulations.

Table 5 reports our results. The first column displays the true coefficients we used to generate

our data, while the second column shows our estimates. We find that our estimation strategy is

able to recover parameters in our model well.

In addition, we check the direction of the estimation bias arising when we ignore the impact of

25Marketing Science Institute Working Paper Series

heterogeneous prior information on consumer choices.16 This exercise involves estimating our model

with β, γ and θE set to zero, implying consumers have homogeneous prior beliefs and signals. We

find that parameters in the signal mean and variance are overestimated, while search cost estimates

are fairly similar. In other words, ignoring the fact that consumers have heterogeneous prior brand

information inflates brand preferences. When we assume away belief heterogeneity, the model

interprets searches, that may actually be influenced by preference for a previously owned brand

or by lower uncertainty due to familiarity, as motivated by valuable brand information obtained

through search. These results further demonstrate the need to account for prior information when

modeling consumer search and purchase decisions.

Table 5: Monte Carlo Simulation Results

Heterogeneous Prior Homogeneous Prior

True Estimate Std. Dev. Estimate Std. Dev.

Parameters (1) (2) (3) (4) (5)

Prior mean

Prior ownership 2.00 1.90 0.28 - -

Prior variance

Familiarity 1.00 1.10 0.15 - -

Signal mean

Match Value 1.00 1.19 0.22 4.01 2.08

Signal variance

Constant 1.00 0.80 0.23 1.78 1.43

Experience 1.00 0.87 0.23 - -

Search cost

Constant 0.50 0.50 0.05 0.48 0.04

LL −80600 −84788

Note: Data is simulated for 1000 consumers, 5 brands and 7 attributes and the reportedestimation results are obtained after averaging across 50 estimation results.

16This exercise is meant to illustrate a possible direction of the bias. More formal work is required to establish itsmagnitude and full range of effects.

26Marketing Science Institute Working Paper Series

6 Estimation Results

Our results from estimating the model in section 5 can be found in Table 6 and Table 7. First, in

table 6’s columns (1) and (2), we report the results from the model that accounts for consumers’

heterogeneous prior information. In columns (3) and (4), we report estimation results when we

ignore consumers’ heterogeneous prior information, by estimating our model with β, γ and θE set

to zero.

Considering first the results accounting for prior information, we find that, consistent with our

reduced-form results, prior ownership is positive and significant, indicating that consumers place

a higher value on the brand they own prior to commencing search. Also, familiarity negatively

impacts prior variance (positive effect on the inverse of prior variance; recall the expression in

equation (4)), suggesting that the more familiar the consumer is with a brand, the lower her prior

uncertainty.

Our estimates of the signal mean (functions of brand intercepts) appear in the second panel

of Table 6. We find that, compared to Samsung (the reference brand), HTC’s brand value is the

highest, followed by Motorola’s value. We also estimate that Apple has the lowest match value.

This result may seem surprising at first given the high market share of Apple among our consumers.

However, this result in part reflects consumers’ prior ownership and their switching patterns shown

in Table 3: close to half of prior Apple owners switch and choose another brand. When such a

switch occurs, prior Apple owners opt most frequently for Samsung or HTC. In contrast, when

Samsung consumers switch, most of them also switch to HTC (and Motorola), but not to Apple.

Comparing these results to those in column (3), we find that a model that ignores consumers’

heterogeneous prior information generally inflates brand preferences. For example, it estimates a

higher brand value for Apple than Samsung. More precisely, we find that when we assume away

belief heterogeneity, the model interprets searches, that may actually be influenced by preference

for a previously owned brand or by lower uncertainty due to familiarity, as motivated by valuable

brand information obtained through search. This effect is stronger for brands that have a high

share of prior ownership and high familiarity. This is an important piece of evidence that supports

accounting for consumers’ prior information in modeling search and purchase decisions. Without

such data, estimated parameters, as well as their implications for marketing strategy, may be biased.

27Marketing Science Institute Working Paper Series

The signal variance shows the effect of prior experience with different smartphone functions.

We find that such experience increases the precision of the signals (positive effect on the inverse of

the signal variance) that consumers obtain about each function. In other words, consumers who

know more about for example the ‘Battery’ function search more efficiently, obtaining more precise

information from every fixation.

Table 6: Estimation ResultsHeterogeneous Prior Homogeneous Prior

Estimates Std. Error Estimates Std. ErrorParameters (1) (2) (3) (4)

Prior MeanPrior Ownership 18.233 0.00105

Prior VarianceFamiliarity (inverse) 0.357 0.00097

Signal MeanApple -0.908 0.00106 0.627 0.00156HTC 0.747 0.00105 1.558 0.00154Motorola 0.549 0.00055 1.089 0.00157Nokia -0.588 0.00107 -0.648 0.00145Samsung - - - -

Signal VarianceConstant 20.586 0.00093 18.930 0.00147Experience (inverse) 1.165 0.00105

Search CostsConstant -1.003 0.00098 -0.996 0.00113Distance: Attribute 2.299 0.00089 2.297 0.00098Distance: Brand 1.388 0.00088 1.388 0.00094Center: Attribute 0.318 0.00089 0.317 0.00072Center: Brand 0.264 0.00090 0.264 0.00078Low Complexity - - - -Medium Complexity 0.110 0.00093 0.111 0.00083High Complexity 0.218 0.00099 0.217 0.00058Whitespace -0.146 0.00104 -0.174 0.00141Female -0.042 0.00102 -0.056 0.00151Age 0.131 0.00104 0.139 0.00134Employed 0.381 0.00103 0.430 0.00151Income -0.029 0.00086 -0.032 0.00099

LL −238520 −238606AIC 477042 477215BIC 477046 477219Observations 78617 78617

Note: The results are averaged over 50 estimations using different starting seeds. Standarderrors are calculated using the Outer Product of Gradients estimator (OPG).

28Marketing Science Institute Working Paper Series

Search cost estimates are reported in the bottom panel of Table 6.17 We find that distance

parameters increase search costs, result which confirms the findings from Yang et al. (2015): the

further away another option, the higher the search cost, which implies consumers are more likely

to search options that are close to their previously searched locations. Similarly, moving away

from the center of the screen, increases consumer search costs. Our results also suggest that

when consumers move to a new cell on the screen, they are more likely to move their eyes to a

different brand than a different attribute, given the estimated cost differences for each action. When

comparing search costs across complexity conditions, we find that the more attributes displayed

to consumers, the higher their search costs, confirming prior findings in the literature (Payne

(1976); Malhotra (1982); Swait and Adamowicz (2001)). The parameter for the white space is

negative, which suggests that consumers who spend more time on that area of the screen have a

lower valuation of their time and thus lower search cost. In other words, it is the consumers with

lower search costs who can afford to be idle. Finally, we also report the effect of demographics

on search costs. We find that male, older, and employed consumers have higher search costs,

while those with a higher income have lower search costs. These results are in contrast to those

found in some prior work that shows higher income and younger consumers have higher search

cost (De los Santos (2018)). This contrast may stem from differences in our settings. For example,

in contrast to prior work, consumers in our study do not need to browse and click through web-

pages to search, lowering the time and energy requirements of each search decision. Instead,

our study manipulates informational complexity, putting greater demand on consumers’ memory

and information-processing. This difference may explain why we observe higher search costs for

older consumers. In addition, smartphones are relatively expensive durable goods. Controlling for

consumers’ employment status, low income consumers may have stricter budget constraints and

thus may be more likely to search less. Comparing estimates with those in column (3), we find

no sizable impact on search cost estimates of omitting heterogeneous prior information from the

model. Since search costs are identified primarily from the number of options searched, they are

less affected by the omission of belief heterogeneity.

Comparing the two models in terms of log-likelihood in Table 6, AIC and BIC measures, we

17Since we cannot estimate consumers’ price sensitivity (prices do not vary within brand), we are unable to expresssearch cost estimates in dollar terms.

29Marketing Science Institute Working Paper Series

find that accounting for prior information improves fit. To further compare model fit, in Figure 5

we present aggregated market shares (obtained by averaging over 500 simulations) for each brand

under the two models, as well as in the data. It can be seen that the model with heterogeneity in

prior information performs better at predicting market shares than the one without heterogeneity.

Figure 5: Predicted Market Share from Model Estimation Results

Finally, in Table 7 we account for heterogeneity in consumer brand preferences and search

costs using a latent class approach. More precisely, we allow the signal mean and mean search

cost parameters to vary across two segments. We find that segments vary drastically in their

preferences: the larger segment (segment 1, approximately 83% of consumers) prefers Motorola,

followed by Apple, while the smaller segment strongly prefers HTC, followed by Nokia. In addition,

we observe substantial differences in the search costs: the segment 1 has much larger search costs

than the smaller segment (segment 2). This result implies that Apple is more likely to be chosen

when search is short and consumers consider few other alternatives, while other brands are favored

by additional search. Interestingly, during the time the study was conduct, Motorola’s smartphones

were being advertised and positioned as the ‘IPhone’ of Android smartphones18. It’s possible that

the larger segment consumers were more likely to be influenced by the marketing efforts given

the high search cost. During the estimation, we also observe more variations in the results across

different seeds when we estimate the effects of demographics on search cost. It’s likely that the

18https://www.pcworld.com/article/173865/verizonsdroidtargetsiphone.html

30Marketing Science Institute Working Paper Series

Table 7: Estimation Results: Latent Class Model with Heterogeneous PriorSegment 1 Segment 2

Estimates Std. Error Estimates Std. ErrorParameters (1) (2) (3) (4)

Prior MeanPrior Ownership 30.5427 0.01069

Prior VarianceFamiliarity (inverse) 0.3122 0.00641

Signal MeanApple 0.4737 0.01310 -1.1396 0.01334HTC -0.1279 0.01247 1.2576 0.01259Motorola 0.8440 0.01262 -0.1469 0.01265Nokia -0.7465 0.01034 0.4030 0.00961Samsung - - - -

Signal VarianceConstant 28.9038 0.00760Experience (inverse) 0.1439 0.00860

Search CostsConstant -0.8378 0.00659 -6.7928 0.01103Distance: Attribute 4.2055 0.00409Distance: Brand 1.7194 0.00334Center: Attribute 0.0941 0.00293Center: Brand 0.2258 0.00359Low Complexity - - - -Medium Complexity 0.0048 0.00335High Complexity 0.1185 0.00636Whitespace -0.0426 0.00687Female 0.0608 0.00864Age 0.1158 0.00822Employed -0.2451 0.00815Income -0.0142 0.00624

Segment 1 Probability: exp(π)1+exp(π)

π 1.6050 0.00440LL -226179AIC 452360BIC 452363Observations 78617 78617

Note: The results are averaged over 50 estimations using different starting seeds. Standarderrors are calculated using the Outer Product of Gradients estimator (OPG).

segment assignment correlates with the demographics, which can potentially explain the differences

in the estimation results compared to Table 6. In terms of model fit, we find that accounting for

heterogeneous consumer segments fits the data better.

In conclusion, our estimation results suggest that prior information impacts consumers’ search

31Marketing Science Institute Working Paper Series

and purchase decisions. When we do not account for prior information, model estimates and fit

may be biased.

7 Counterfactuals

In this section, we present the results of a series of counterfactual exercises that explore the man-

agerial value of accounting for consumers’ prior information. Towards this goal, we study whether

a ranking algorithm personalized based on consumers’ prior information benefits consumers and

managers. Our setting is well-suited to examine and compare different ranking algorithms because

the order in which products were shown to consumers was randomized in our study. Since in our

data we do not observe price variation across brands, which led us to estimate consumer preferences

at the brand level, we cannot compute brand or platform revenues. Thus, in what follows we will

focus on consumer welfare as a measure of consumer satisfaction and of long term revenues. The

value a consumer obtains from a ranking is defined as her expected utility from the option chosen

for purchase, net of total search costs. We obtain the change in consumer welfare from the change

in this value between two ranking algorithms considered.

In our model, a brand’s ranking influences consumer search decisions by affecting the distance

the eye is required to travel between relevant brands and attributes. Previous work in marketing

has looked at a plethora of different ranking algorithms, such as utility-based, profit-based, or

price-based rankings (e.g. Ferreira et al. (2016); Ursu (2018); Chen and Yao (2017); Ghose et al.

(2014); Choi and Mela (2019); Donnelly et al. (2020)). We contribute to this work in at least two

ways. First, we consider the impact of using prior information, in addition to product features

and consumer choices, to rank products. Second, in contrast to prior work that solely focuses on

settings where products are ordered vertically on a screen (top-down), in our setting products are

displayed horizontally (left-right), making our results more applicable to cases where consumers

use comparison websites or recommendations systems, such as Amazon’s ‘Customers who viewed

this item also viewed’ (Linden et al. (2003)), to make search and purchase decisions.

We consider five alternative ranking algorithms. Each algorithm places the highest ranked

option in the left-most position on the screen, the second highest ranked option in the second

32Marketing Science Institute Working Paper Series

position from the left, and so on.19 Algorithm (1) ranks brands based on our model that accounts for

heterogeneous prior beliefs. More precisely, it orders brands by their signal match value estimated

in column (1) in Table 6: 1. HTC, 2. Motorola, 3. Samsung, 4. Nokia and 5. Apple. Algorithm

(2) ranks brands based on the number of times a consumer searched each brand. In this case,

each consumer sees a potentially different brand ranking. Algorithm (3) ranks brands based on

consumer reported levels of familiarity and prior ownership with the brands.20 More precisely, we

placed the previously owned brand (if one existed) in the left-most position on the screen, and

ordered remaining brands based on familiarity, with ties broken randomly. In this case the ranking

also varied by consumer. Algorithm (4) ranks brands based on market share: 1. Samsung, 2. Apple,

3. HTC, 4. Motorola and 5. Nokia. Finally, algorithm (5) ranks brands based on the model that

assumes consumer prior beliefs are homogeneous, i.e. based on the signal matchs value estimated

in column (3) in Table 6: 1. HTC, 2. Motorola, 3. Apple, 4. Samsung and 5. Nokia. The brand

features and the signals consumers obtain while searching are the same across counterfactuals, with

only the order in which brands are displayed varying.

19An important distinction between ranking for vertical or horizontal lists is that in the latter case one needs tobalance both distances between products and distance from the center of the screen. To resolve this balance, wechoose to place the highest ranked product in the left-most position, ensuring that consumers’ eyes need not traveltoo far to learn about highly ranked options (for example, the 2nd and 3rd ranked options, or the 4th and 5th rankedoptions).

20Note that reported experience levels cannot be used to rank products, since these measures do not vary acrossbrands.

33Marketing Science Institute Working Paper Series

Table 8: Counterfactual Results: Effect of Ranking on Consumer Welfare and Search

Brand Value Search Share Fam and PO Market Share Brand Value

Heterog. Prior Homog. Prior

(1) (2) (3) (4) (5)

Consumer Welfare 14.22 14.01 13.89 13.77 13.14

Expected Purchased Utility 1.51 1.51 1.41 1.63 1.63

Total Search Cost -3.31 -2.87 -2.54 -3.10 -2.63

Mean Search Cost -13.34 -13.40 -13.41 -13.24 -13.15

Number of Searches 5.32 5.56 5.51 5.07 5.25

Unique Brands Searched 1.62 1.69 1.78 1.68 1.67

Unique Attributes Searched 2.23 2.18 1.99 1.83 2.27

Note: Consumer welfare is defined as the change in the difference between the expected purchase utility and totalsearch costs. We report the average percentage change across consumers. Results more than three scaled medianabsolute deviations (MAD) away from the median are excluded from aggregation.

Table 8 presents our results obtained by comparing the five ranking algorithms to the default

ranking (randomized) in our study. In comparison to the random ranking used in our study, under

the new ranking algorithms, consumers search more options, which increases their utility from

the option chosen for purchase, and pay a lower total search cost, which results in an increase in

consumer welfare of approximately 14%. Among algorithms, the one based on our model (column 1)

that accounts for consumer heterogeneous beliefs produces the largest increase in consumer welfare,

while the one based on a model that wrongly assumes consumers have homogeneous prior beliefs

(column 5) leads to the lowest increase. The difference comes mostly from a decrease in search costs.

In particular, under algorithm (5), consumers search slightly more unique brands and attributes

than under algorithm (1), which leads to a modest increase in expected purchase utility, but the

increase in search costs outweighs the benefit. Algorithm (2) that uses a brand’s search share for a

consumer to rank products leads to the second largest increase in consumer welfare, increasing the

number of brands consumers searched, while decreasing the cost per search. Given that consumers

search the brands that they are more familiar with more often (see our reduced-form results in

section 4), this ranking indirectly accounts for consumers’ prior information, showing the benefit

of such data. Also, this algorithm shows the benefit of a second type of ranking personalization: in

this algorithm, every consumer sees a different order of brands based on their own previous search

34Marketing Science Institute Working Paper Series

decisions, rather than the average brand preferences of a consumer in our data, which benefits

consumers. Algorithm (3) that directly uses consumers’ reported ownership and familiarity with

brands results in an intermediate increase in consumer welfare, almost as large as the one based on

our model, showing the importance of accounting for prior information, even in a non-structural

way, when personalising product rankings. Finally, ranking based on market shares that are the

same across consumers (Algorithm 4) encourages them to search fewer brand attributes that are

further apart, leading to one of the lowest benefits to consumers, albeit higher than one obtained

based on a model that wrongly assumes prior beliefs are homogeneous.

Table 9: Counterfactual Results: Effect of Ranking on Market Shares

Brand Value Search Share Fam and PO Market Share Brand Value

Heterog. Prior Homog. Prior

(1) (2) (3) (4) (5)

Apple -0.08 0.05 -0.13 -0.17 0.01

HTC 0.08 0.01 0.07 0.08 0.00

Motorola -0.04 -0.08 0.02 0.09 -0.02

Samsung 0.08 0.13 0.13 0.05 0.03

Nokia -0.03 -0.11 -0.08 -0.05 0.00

Note: We report average changes in market shares (measured in percentage differences)across the five brands in our study.

In Table 9, we also report how each of the brands’ market shares in our study is affected by

each algorithm. We find an asymmetric effect across brands, with Samsung and HTC benefiting

the most across all algorithms. This benefit comes largely at the expense of Apple. Although many

consumers own Apple products at the beginning of the study, these ranking algorithms induce

more searches, and hurt the brand that is more likely to be chosen when search is short (consistent

with our results in Table 7). In contrast, the more consumers search, the more likely they are to

choose Samsung and HTC. Once again, our results emphasize the importance of accounting for

prior information when predicting consumer choices.

In conclusion, in this section we have shown that, in addition to recovering more precise esti-

mates of consumer primitives, accounting for prior information also benefits managers by allowing

them to use this information to construct personalized rankings.

35Marketing Science Institute Working Paper Series

8 Discussion

In this paper, we developed a model of sequential search that explains consumers’ search and brand

purchase choices when accounting for consumers’ prior information. We estimated this model on

a data set of consumers making smartphone search and brand purchase decisions that allows us to

observe consumers’ prior ownership, familiarity and experience with available brands. We showed

that prior information impacts consumer search and purchase decisions in three ways: (1) prior

ownership of a brand increases the initial evaluation of the brand; (2) prior familiarity with the

brand decreases initial uncertainty and allows consumers to search more options; and (3) prior

experience with product attributes allows consumers to extract more precise information from

every search action. Also, we have documented the direction of the estimation bias arising if prior

information is not accounted for when modeling consumer search and purchase decisions. Finally,

using our estimation results, we performed a series of counterfactual exercises and showed the

managerial importance of modeling prior brand information when constructing product rankings.

Even in the absence of such a model, accounting for prior information by ranking products based

on consumer ownership or familiarity can benefit consumers and managers.

Our paper emphasizes the importance of prior information in understanding consumers search

and purchase decisions. In particular, it shows that preferences for brands that consumers are more

knowledgeable of are inflated and that product rankings are biased when consumer prior information

is not accounted for. As access to diverse product information sources is becoming easier than every

before, it is paramount for managers to have a framework to account for consumers’ differing level

of prior brand knowledge. We provide exactly such a framework.

Our paper can be extended in a number of directions. One direction may involve considering

different heuristics that consumers use at different stages of decision-making. It is possible that

in later stages of the search process consumers have different goals compared to initial stages (for

example wanting to confirm or compare rather than obtain new information), changing the type

of heuristics they use. It’s also possible that consumers assign a different weight to information

based on how surprising it is, and further studies can explore models that allow for such flexible

heuristics. At another extreme, one can attempt to derive the optimal search rules for our problem,

in order to compare model fit. In addition, one can further explore the role of prior information

36Marketing Science Institute Working Paper Series

in guiding managerial decisions. For example, such data may be useful in informing decisions of

whether and how to advertise to a consumer based on her prior experience with a brand (e.g. Zhang

et al. (2018)). For example, consumers with a lot of prior information on a brand may be harmed

by advertising for that brand, since it prevents them to obtaining information on other brands that

they may be less familiar with. Also, future work could investigate the role of prior information in

affecting decisions over a longer time frame when forgetting may play an additional role.

One limitation to our study is its reliance on a single data set, where consumers used a product

comparison website to make smartphone search and purchase decisions. While our focus helps

us examine the impact of prior information in a well-controlled environment, this setting may be

narrow compared to other consumer search settings. Therefore, studying the importance of prior

beliefs across a larger range of both product categories and information environments would be

recommended.

37Marketing Science Institute Working Paper Series

References

Ackerberg DA (2001) Empirically Distinguishing Informative and Prestige Effects of Advertising. RAND

Journal of Economics 32(2):316–333.

Atalay AS, Bodur HO, Rasolofoarison D (2012) Shining in the center: Central gaze cascade effect on product

choice. Journal of Consumer Research 39(4):848–866.

Berndt ER, Hall BH, Hall RE, Hausman JA (1974) Estimation and Inference in Nonlinear Structural Models.

Annals of Economic and Social Measurement, volume 3, 653–665.

Branco F, Sun M, Villas-Boas JM (2012) Optimal Search for Product Information. Management Science

58(11):2037–2056.

Branco F, Sun M, Villas-Boas JM (2015) Too Much Information? Information Provision and Search Costs.

Marketing Science 35(4):605–618.

Bronnenberg B, Kim J, Mela C (2016) Zooming In on Choice: How Do Consumers Search for Cameras

Online? Marketing Science 35(5):693–712.

Camerer CF, Johnson EJ (2004) Thinking about Attention in Games: Backward and Forward Induction.

In: The Psychology of Economic Decisions. Oxford University Press 2:111–129.

Chandon P, Hutchinson JW, Young SH (2002) Unseen is Unsold: Assessing Visual Equity with Commercial

Eye-tracking Data. Working paper.

Chen Y, Yao S (2017) Sequential Search with Refinement: Model and Application with Click-stream Data.

Management Science 63(12):4345–4365.

Chick SE, Frazier P (2012) Sequential Sampling with Economics of Selection Procedures. Management

Science 58(3):550–569.

Ching AT, Erdem T, Keane MP (2013) Learning Models: An Assessment of Progress, Challenges, and New

Developments. Marketing Science 32(6):913–938.

Choi H, Mela CF (2019) Monetizing online marketplaces. Marketing Science 38(6):948–972.

Dang CI, Ursu RM, Chintagunta PK (2020) Search revisits. Working paper.

De los Santos B (2018) Consumer Search on the Internet. International Journal of Industrial Organization

58:66–105.

De los Santos B, Hortacsu A, Wildenbeest M (2012) Testing Models of Consumer Search Using Data on

Web Browsing and Purchasing Behavior. American Economic Review 102(6):2955–80.

De los Santos B, Koulayev S (2017) Optimizing Click-through in Online Rankings with Endogenous Search

Refinement. Marketing Science 36(4):542–564.

38Marketing Science Institute Working Paper Series

Donnelly R, Kanodia A, Morozov I (2020) A unified framework for personalizing product rankings. Working

Paper .

Dube JP, Hitsch GJ, Rossi PE (2010) State Dependence and Alternative Explanations for Consumer Inertia.

The RAND Journal of Economics 41(3):417–445.

Dukes A, Liu L (2015) Online Shopping Intermediaries: The Strategic Design of Search Environments.

Management Science 62(4):1064–1077.

Erdem T, Keane MP (1996) Decision-making Under Uncertainty: Capturing Dynamic Brand Choice Pro-

cesses in Turbulent Consumer Goods Markets. Marketing Science 15(1):1–20.

Erdem T, Keane MP, Oncu TS, Strebel J (2005) Learning about Computers: An Analysis of Information

Search and Technology Choice. Quantitative Marketing and Economics 3(3):207–247.

Ferreira P, Zhang X, Belo R, Godinho de Matos M (2016) Welfare properties of recommender systems:

Theory and results from a randomized experiment. Working Paper .

Gabaix X, Laibson D, Moloche G, Weinberg S (2006) Costly Information Acquisition: Experimental Analysis

of a Boundedly Rational Model. American Economic Review 96(4):1043–1068.

Gabaix X, Laibson DI (2000) A Boundedly Rational Decision Algorithm. American Economic Review

90(2):433–438.

Gardete P, Antill M (2020) Guiding Consumers through Lemons and Peaches: A Dynamic Model of Search

over Multiple Characteristics. Working paper.

Ghose A, Ipeirotis P, Li B (2019) Modeling Consumer Footprints on Search Engines: An Interplay with

Social Media. Management Science 65(3):1363–1385.

Ghose A, Ipeirotis PG, Li B (2014) Examining the Impact of Ranking on Consumer Behavior and Search

Engine Revenue. Management Science 60(7):1632–1654.

Greene WH (2003) Econometric Analysis (Pearson Education).

Hauser JR (2014) Consideration-Set Heuristics. Journal of Business Research 67(8):1688–1699.

Hong H, Shum M (2006) Using Price Distributions to Estimate Search Costs. The RAND Journal of Eco-

nomics 37(2):257–275.

Honka E (2014) Quantifying Search and Switching Costs in the US auto insurance industry. The RAND

Journal of Economics 45(4):847–884.

Honka E, Chintagunta P (2016) Simultaneous or Sequential? Search Strategies in the US Auto Insurance

Industry. Marketing Science 36(1):21–42.

Hu M, Dang C, Chintagunta PK (2019) Search and learning at a daily deals website. Marketing Science

38(4):609–642.

39Marketing Science Institute Working Paper Series

Iyengar R, Ansari A, Gupta S (2007) A Model of Consumer Learning for Service Quality and Usage. Journal

of Marketing Research 44(4):529–544.

Jindal P, Aribarg A (2020) The Importance of Price Beliefs in Consumer Search. Working paper.

Johnson EJ, Russo JE (1984) Product familiarity and learning new information. Journal of Consumer

Research 11(1):542–550.

Ke TT, Shen ZJM, Villas-Boas JM (2016) Search for Information on Multiple Products. Management Science

62(12):3576–3603.

Ke TT, Villas-Boas JM (2019) Optimal Learning before Choice. Journal of Economic Theory 180:383–437.

Kim JB, Albuquerque P, Bronnenberg BJ (2010) Online Demand under Limited Consumer Search. Marketing

Science 29(6):1001–1023.

Koulayev S (2013) Search with Dirichlet Priors: Estimation and Implications for Consumer Demand. Journal

of Business & Economic Statistics 31(2):226–239.

Koulayev S (2014) Search for Differentiated Products: Identification and Estimation. The RAND Journal of

Economics 45(3):553–575.

Linden G, Smith B, York J (2003) Amazon. com recommendations: Item-to-item collaborative filtering.

IEEE Internet computing 7(1):76–80.

Lu J, Hutchinson J (2020) Information Search within a Webpage: Boundedly Rational Models of Eye

Movements and Clicks. Working paper.

Ma L (2019) Only the Interested Learn–A Model of Proactive Learning of Product Reviews. Working paper.

Malhotra NK (1982) Information Load and Consumer Decision Making. Journal of Consumer Research

8(4):419–430.

Meißner M, Musalem A, Huber J (2016) Eye Tracking Reveals Processes that Enable Conjoint Choices to

Become Increasingly Efficient with Practice. Journal of Marketing Research 53(1):1–17.

Moorthy S, Ratchford BT, Talukdar D (1997) Consumer Information Search Revisited: Theory and Empirical

Analysis. Journal of Consumer Research 23(4):263–277.

Moraga-Gonzalez J, Sandor Z, Wildenbeest M (2017) Consumer Search and Prices in the Automobile Market.

Working paper.

Moraga-Gonzalez JL, Wildenbeest MR (2008) Maximum Likelihood Estimation of Search Costs. European

Economic Review 52(5):820–848.

Narayanan S, Manchanda P (2009) Heterogeneous Learning and the Targeting of Marketing Communication

for New Products. Marketing Science 28(3):424–441.

40Marketing Science Institute Working Paper Series

Ning Z, Villas-Boas JM (2020) Browse or Experience. Working paper.

Orquin JL, Loose SM (2013) Attention and Choice: A Review on Eye Movements in Decision Making. Acta

psychologica 144(1):190–206.

Payne JW (1976) Task Complexity and Contingent Processing in Decision Making: An Information Search

and Protocol Analysis. Organizational behavior and human performance 16(2):366–387.

Pieters R, Erdem T, Martinovici A (2019) Attention Trajectories and Brand Choice: An Eye-Movement

Analysis. Working paper.

Seiler S (2013) The Impact of Search Costs on Consumer Behavior: A Dynamic Approach. Quantitative

Marketing and Economics 11(2):155–203.

Shi SW, Wedel M, Pieters F (2013) Information Acquisition during Online Decision Making: A Model-based

Exploration Using Eye-tracking Data. Management Science 59(5):1009–1026.

Shin S, Misra S, Horsky D (2012) Disentangling Preferences and Learning in Brand Choice Models. Marketing

Science 31(1):115–137.

Stigler GJ (1961) The Economics of Information. Journal of Political Economy 69(3):213–225.

Swait J, Adamowicz W (2001) The Influence of Task Complexity on Consumer Choice: A Latent Class

Model of Decision Strategy Switching. Journal of Consumer Research 28(1):135–148.

Tehrani SS, Ching AT (2020) A Heuristic Approach to Explore: Value of Perfect Information. Working

paper.

Ursu RM (2018) The power of rankings: Quantifying the effect of rankings on online consumer search and

purchase decisions. Marketing Science 37(4):530–552.

Ursu RM, Wang Q, Chintagunta PK (2020) Search Duration. Marketing Science (Forthcoming).

Wedel M, Pieters R (2000) Eye Fixations on Advertisements and Memory for Brands: A Model and Findings.

Marketing Science 19(4):297–312.

Wedel M, Pieters R (2008) Eye Tracking for Visual Marketing. Foundations and Trends in Marketing

1(4):231–320.

Weitzman ML (1979) Optimal Search for the Best Alternative. Econometrica: Journal of the Econometric

Society 641–654.

Yang L, Toubia O, De Jong MG (2015) A Bounded Rationality Model of Information Search and Choice In

Preference Measurement. Journal of Marketing Research 52(2):166–183.

Yavorsky D, Honka E, Chen MK (2020) Consumer Search in the US Auto Industry: The Value of Dealership

Visits. Working paper.

41Marketing Science Institute Working Paper Series

Zhang Q, Hill S, Rothschild D (2018) Post purchase search engine marketing. Companion Proceedings of the

The Web Conference 663–670.

42Marketing Science Institute Working Paper Series

9 Appendix

9.1 Further Evidence for Section 3

Figure 6: Study Design Under the High Complexity Condition

Figure 7: Illustrating Eye-Fixations

43Marketing Science Institute Working Paper Series

Figure 8: Consumer Demographics

44Marketing Science Institute Working Paper Series