Prices and Production (1931) - F. A. Hayek

174

Transcript of Prices and Production (1931) - F. A. Hayek

Page 1: Prices and Production (1931) - F. A. Hayek
Page 2: Prices and Production (1931) - F. A. Hayek

First published September 1931Reprinted January 1932

Second edition (revised and enlarged) 1935Reprinted 1941, 1946, 1949, 1951, 1957, 1960 and 1967

Published in the U.S.A. by Augustus M. Kelly, PublishersNew York

Library of Congress Catalogue Number67-19586

Printed in Great Britain

Page 3: Prices and Production (1931) - F. A. Hayek

CONTENTSPAGE

PREFACE TO THE SECOND EDITION . . . . vii

LECTURE I : THEORIES OF THE INFLUENCE OF

MONEY ON PRICES . . . . i

I I : THE CONDITIONS OF EQUILIBRIUM

BETWEEN THE PRODUCTION OF

CONSUMERS' GOODS AND THE

PRODUCTION OF PRODUCERS'

GOODS 32

„ I I I : THE WORKING OF THE PRICE

MECHANISM IN THE COURSE OF

THE CREDIT CYCLE . . . . 69

IV: THE CASE FOR AND AGAINST AN

" ELASTIC " CURRENCY . . 105

APPENDIX : CAPITAL AND INDUSTRIAL FLUCTUA-

TIONS. A Reply to a Criticism 132

Page 4: Prices and Production (1931) - F. A. Hayek
Page 5: Prices and Production (1931) - F. A. Hayek

PREFACE TO THE SECOND EDITION

THIS book owes its existence to an invitation by theUniversity of London to deliver during the sessionI93°-3I four lectures to advanced students in economics,and in the form in which it was first published it literallyreproduced these lectures. This invitation offered tome what might easily have been a unique opportunityto lay before an English audience what contribution Ithought I had then to make to current discussions oftheoretical economics ; and it came at a time when Ihad arrived at a clear view of the outlines of a theory ofindustrial fluctuations but before I had elaborated it infull detail or even realised all the difficulties which suchan elaboration presented. The exposition, moreover,was limited to what I could say in four lectures, whichinevitably led to even greater oversimplification than Iwould probably have been guilty of in any other case.But although I am now conscious of many more defectsof this exposition than I was even at the time of itsfirst publication, I can only feel profoundly grateful tothe circumstances which were such an irresistible temp-tation to publish these ideas at an earlier date than Ishould otherwise have done. From the criticisms anddiscussions that publication has caused I hope to haveprofited more for a later more complete exposition thanI could possibly have done if I had simply continued to

vii

Page 6: Prices and Production (1931) - F. A. Hayek

viii PREFACE TO THE SECOND EDITION

work on these problems for myself. But the timefor that more exhaustive treatment of these problemshas not yet come. It is perhaps the main gain whichI derived from the early publication that it made itclear to me that before I could hope to get muchfurther with the elucidation of the main problemsdiscussed in this book it would be necessary considerablyto elaborate the foundations on which I have tried tobuild. Contact with scientific circles which were lessinclined than I was to take for granted the main pro-positions of the " Austrian " theory of capital on whichI have drawn so freely in this book has shown—notthat these propositions were wrong or that they were lessimportant than I had thought for the task for which Ihad used them—but that they would have to be devel-oped in far greater detail and have to be adapted muchmore closely to the complicated conditions of real lifebefore they could provide a completely satisfactoryinstrument for the explanation of the particularly com-plicated phenomena to which I have applied them.This is a task which has to be undertaken before thetheses expounded in the present book can be developedfurther with advantage.

Under these circumstances, when a new edition ofthis book was called for, I felt neither prepared to rewriteand enlarge it to the extent that a completely adequatetreatment of the problems taken up would make neces-sary, nor to see it reappear in an altogether unchangedform. The compression of the original exposition hasgiven rise to so many unnecessary misunderstandings

Page 7: Prices and Production (1931) - F. A. Hayek

PREFACE TO THE SECOND EDITION ix

which a somewhat fuller treatment would have pre-vented that certain additions seemed urgently neces-sary. I have accordingly chosen the middle course ofinserting into the, on the whole unchanged, originaltext further elucidations and elaborations where theyseemed most necessary. Many of these additions werealready included in the German edition which appeareda few months after the first English edition. Othersare taken over from a number of articles in which in thecourse of the last three years I have tried to develop orto defend the main thesis of this book. It has, however,been by no means possible to incorporate all the furtherelaborations attempted in these articles in the presentvolume and the reader who may wish to refer to themwill find them listed in the footnote below.1

By these modifications I hope to have removed atleast some of the difficulties which the book seems tohave presented in its original form. Others were dueto the fact that the book was in some ways a continua-tion of an argument which I had begun in other pub-lications that at the time of its first appearance wereavailable only in German. In the meantime English

1 " The Pure Theory of Money, A Rejoinder to Mr. Keynes",Econotnica, November, 1931 ; " Money and Capital, A Reply toMr. Sraffa ", Economic Journal, June, 1932 ; " Kapitalaufzehrung ",Weltwirtschaftliches Archiv, July, 1932 ; " A Note on the Develop-ment of the Doctrine of ' Forced Saving'," Quarterly Journal ofEconomics, November, 1932 ; Der Stand und dei ndchste Zukunftder Konjunkturforschung, Festschrift fur Arthur Spiethoff, Miinchen,1933 ; " Ueber neutrales Geld ", Zeitschrift fur Nationalokonomie,vol. IV, October, 1933 ; " Capital and Industrial Fluctuations ",Econometrica, vol. II, April, 1934 » " On the Relationship betweenInvestment and Output ", Economic Journal, June, 1934.

Page 8: Prices and Production (1931) - F. A. Hayek

x PREFACE TO THE SECOND EDITION

translations have, however, been published1 and in thosethe reader will find explained some of the assumptionswhich are implicit rather than explicitly stated in thefollowing discussion.

Some of the real difficulties which I fully realisethis book must present to most readers will, however,not be removed by either of these changes becausethey are inherent in the mode of exposition adopted.All I can do in this respect short of replacing this bookby an entirely new one is to draw the attention of thereader in advance to this particular difficulty and toexplain why the mode of exposition which causes ithad to be adopted. This is all the more necessary sincethis irremediable defect of the exposition has causedmore misunderstandings than any other single problem.

The point in question is shortly this. Considerationsof time made it necessary for me in these lectures totreat at one and the same time the real changes of thestructure of production which accompany changes in theajnount of capital and the monetary mechanism whichbrings this change about. This was possible only underhighly simplified assumptions which made any changein the monetary demand for capital goods proportionalto the change in the total demand for capital goods whichit brought about. Now "demand" for capital goods,in the sense in which it can be said that demand deter-mines their value, of course does not consist exclusivelyor even primarily in a demand exercised on any market,

x Monetary Theory and the Trade Cycle, London, 1933 ; " TheParadox of Saving ", Economica, May, 1931.

Page 9: Prices and Production (1931) - F. A. Hayek

PREFACE TO THE SECOND EDITION xi

but to a perhaps even greater degree in a demand orwillingness to continue to hold capital goods for afurther period of time. On the relationship betweenthis total demand and the monetary demand for capitalgoods which manifests itself on the markets during anyperiod of time, no general statements can be made;nor is it particularly relevant for my problems whatthis quantitative relationship actually is. What was,however, of prime importance for my purpose was toemphasise that any change in the monetary demand forcapital goods could not be treated as something whichmade itself felt only on some isolated market for newcapital goods, but that it could be only understood as achange affecting the general demand for capital goodswhich is an essential aspect of the process of maintaininga given structure of production. The simplest assump-tion of this kind which I could make was to assume afixed relationship between the monetary and the totaldemand for capital goods so as to make the amountof money spent on capital goods during a unit periodof time equal to the value of the stock of capital goodsin existence.

This assumption, which I still think is very usefulfor my main purpose, proved however to be somewhatmisleading in two other, not unimportant, respects. Inthe first instance it made it impossible to treat adequatelythe case of durable goods. It is impossible to assumethat the potential services, embodied in a durable goodand waiting for the moment when they will be utilised,change hands at regular intervals of time. This meant

Page 10: Prices and Production (1931) - F. A. Hayek

xii PREFACE TO THE SECOND EDITION

that so far as that particular illustration of the monetarymechanism was concerned I had to leave durable goodssimply out of account. I did not feel that this was tooserious a defect, particularly as I was under the—Ithink not unjustified—impression that the role whichcirculating capital played was rather neglected and accor-dingly wanted to stress it as compared with that of fixedcapital. But I realise now that I should have givenproper warning of the exact reason why I introducedthis assumption and what function it performed, andI am afraid that the footnote which I inserted in thefirst edition (page 37, note 2) at the last moment, whenmy attention was drawn to the difficulty which myargument might present, has served rather to confusethan to clear up the point.

The second effect of this assumption of separate" stages " of production of equal length was that itimposed upon me a somewhat one-sided treatment ofthe problem of the velocity of circulation of money.It implied more or less that money passed through thesuccessive stages at a constant rate which correspondedto the rate at which the goods advanced through theprocess of production, and in any case excluded con-siderations of changes in the velocity of circulation orthe cash balances held in the different stages. Theimpossibility of dealing expressly with changes in thevelocity of circulation so long as this assumption wasmaintained served to strengthen the misleading impres-sion that the phenomena I was discussing would be causedonly by actual changes in the quality of money and not

Page 11: Prices and Production (1931) - F. A. Hayek

PREFACE TO THE SECOND EDITION xiii

by every change in the money stream, which in the realworld are probably caused at least as frequently, ifnot more frequently, by changes in the velocity of cir-culation than by changes in the actual quantity. It hasbeen put to me that any treatment of monetary problemswhich neglected in this way the phenomenon of changesin the desire to hold money balances could not possiblysay anything worthwhile. While in my opinion this isa somewhat exaggerated view, I should like to emphasisein this connection how small a section of the whole fieldof monetary theory is actually treated in this book.All that I claim for it is that it deals with an aspectwhich has been more neglected and misunderstood thanperhaps any other and the insufficient understandingof which has led to particularly serious mistakes. Toincorporate this argument into the body of monetarytheory is a task which has yet to be undertaken andwhich I could not and did not try to undertake here.But I may perhaps add that so far as the general theoryof money (as distinguished from the pure theory of capi-tal) is concerned, it is th«s work of Professor Mises1

much more than that of Knut Wicksell which providesthe framework inside which I have tried to elaborate aspecial point.

1 See particularly his Theorie des Geldes und der Utnlaufsmittel,first published in 1912 and now fortunately available in an Englishtranslation : L. Mises, The Theory of Money, London (JonathanCape), 1934. Cf- a l s o m Y Monetary Theory and the Trade Cycle,London 1933, which is concerned more with the monetary factorswhich cause the trade cycle than the present book which is mainlydevoted to the real phenomena which constitute it.

Page 12: Prices and Production (1931) - F. A. Hayek

xiv PREFACE TO THE SECOND EDITION

In addition to this acknowledgment of a greatintellectual obligation I should like to repeat from thePreface to the first edition not only the acknowledgmentof what I owe to the great tradition in the field ofthe theory of capital which is connected with the namesof W. S. Jevons, E. v. B6hm-Bawerk and K. Wicksell,but also of the more specific debt to those who havehelped me in the preparation of these lectures: toMr. Albert G. Hart, now of the University of Chicago,who gave me the benefit of his advice when I wasdrafting the original English manuscript of these lec-tures and particularly to Professor Lionel Robbins,who, when the first edition was published, undertookthe considerable labour of putting the manuscriptinto a form fit for publication and seeing it through thepress, and who ever since has most generously givenme his help with all my English publications, includingthe present second edition of this book.

F. A. v. HAYEK.

The London School of Economicsand Political Science.

August, 1934.

Page 13: Prices and Production (1931) - F. A. Hayek

LECTURE I

THEORIES OF THE INFLUENCE OF MONEYON PRICES

" He realised well that the abundance of money makeseverything dear, but he did not analyse how that takes place.The great difficulty of this analysis consists in discovering bywhat path and in what proportion the increase of moneyraises the price of things."

RICHARD CANTILLON (died 1734),Essai sur la nature du commerce en g&niral, II, 6.

(1) THAT monetary influences play a dominant role indetermining both the volume and direction of produc-tion is a truth which is probably more familiar to thepresent generation than to any which have gone before.The experiences of the war- and post-war-inflation,and of the return to the gold standard, particularlywhere, as in Great Britain, it was accomplished by acontraction of the circulation, have given abundantevidence of the dependence on money of every produc-tive activity. The widespread discussions of recentyears concerning the desirability and practicability ofstabilising the value of money, are due mainly to ageneral recognition of this fact. At the present momentmany of the best minds believe the cause of theexisting world-wide depression to be a scarcity of goldand seek accordingly for monetary means to over-come it.

Page 14: Prices and Production (1931) - F. A. Hayek

2 PRICES AND PRODUCTION

And yet, if it were asked whether understandingof the connection between money and prices has madegreat progress during these years, at any rate untilvery recently, or whether the generally accepted doc-trines on this point have progressed far beyond what wasgenerally known a hundred years ago, I should beinclined to answer in the negative. This may seemparadoxical, but I think anyone who has studied themonetary literature of the first half of the nineteenthcentury will agree that there is hardly any idea incontemporary monetary theory which was not knownto one or more writers of that period. Probably themajority of present-day economists would contendthat the reason why progress has been so slight is thatmonetary theory has already reached such a state ofperfection that further progress must of necessity beslow. But I confess that to me it still seems that someof the most fundamental problems in this field remainunsolved, that some of the accepted doctrines are ofa very doubtful validity, and that we have even failedto develop the suggestions for improvement which canbe found in the works of these early writers.

If that be true, and I hope to convince you that it is,it is surely somewhat astonishing that the experiencesof the last fifteen years have not proved more fruitful.In the past, periods of monetary disturbance havealways been periods of great progress in this branchof Economics. The Italy of the sixteenth century hasbeen called the country of the worst money and thebest monetary theory. If recently that has not been

Page 15: Prices and Production (1931) - F. A. Hayek

INFLUENCE OF MONEY ON PRICES 3

true to the same extent, the reason seems to me to liein a certain change of attitude on the part of mosteconomists in regard to the appropriate methodologyof economics, a change which in many quarters is hailedas a great progress : I mean the attempt to substitutequantitative for qualitative methods of investigation.In the field of monetary theory, this change has beenmade even by economists who in general reject the" new " point of view, and indeed several had madeit some years before the quantitative method hadbecome fashionable elsewhere.

(2) The best known instance, and the most relevantcase in point, is the resuscitation by Irving Fisher sometwenty years ago of the more mechanistic forms of thequantity theory of the value of money in his well-known " equation of exchange". That this theory,with its apparatus of mathematical formulae con-structed to admit of statistical verification, is a typicalinstance of " quantitative" economics, and that itindeed probably contributed a good deal to influencethe methodology of the present representatives of thisschool, are propositions which are not likely to bedenied. I do not propose to quarrel with the positivecontent of this theory: I am even ready to concedethat so far as it goes it is true, and that, from a practicalpoint of view, it would be one of the worst thingswhich would befall us if the general public should everagain cease to believe in the elementary propositionsof the quantity theory. What I complain of is notonly that this theory in its various forms has unduly

Page 16: Prices and Production (1931) - F. A. Hayek

4 PRICES AND PRODUCTION

usurped the central place in monetary theory, but thatthe point of view from which it springs is a positivehindrance to further progress. Not the least harmfuleffect of this particular theory is the present isolationof the theory of money from the main body of generaleconomic theory.

For so long as we use different methods for theexplanation of values as they are supposed to existirrespective of any influence of money, and for theexplanation of that influence of money on prices, itcan never be otherwise. Yet we are doing nothing lessthan this if we try to establish direct causal connectionsbetween the total quantity of money, the general levelof all prices and, perhaps, also the total amount ofproduction. For none of these magnitudes as such everexerts an influence on the decisions of individuals ;yet it is on the assumption of a knowledge of thedecisions of individuals that the main propositions ofnon-monetary economic theory are based. It is to this" individualistic " method that we owe whatever under-standing of economic phenomena we possess ; that themodern " subjective " theory has advanced beyondthe classical school in its consistent use is probablyits main advantage over their teaching.

If, therefore, monetary theory still attempts toestablish causal relations between aggregates or generalaverages, this means that monetary theory lags behindthe development of economics in general. In fact,neither aggregates nor averages do act upon one another,and it will never be possible to establish necessary

Page 17: Prices and Production (1931) - F. A. Hayek

INFLUENCE OF MONEY ON PRICES 5

connections of cause and effect between them as we canbetween individual phenomena, individual prices, etc.I would even go so far as to assert that, from the verynature of economic theory, averages can never form alink in its reasoning ; but to prove this contentionwould go far beyond the subject of these lectures.I shall here confine myself to an attempt to show in aspecial field the differences between explanationswhich do and explanations which do not have recourseto such concepts.

(3) As I have said already, I do not want to criticisethe doctrines of these theories so far as they go ; Iindicate their characteristics only in order to be ableto show later on how much more another type oftheory may accomplish. The central preoccupation ofthese theories is changes in the general price level.Now everybody agrees that a change of prices wouldbe of no consequence whatever if all prices in the widestsense of the term were affected equally and simultane-ously. But the main concern of this type of theory isavowedly, with certain suppositions " tendencies,which affect all prices equally, or at any rate imparti-ally, at the same time and in the same direction".1

And it is only after the alleged causal relation betweenchanges in the quantity of money and average prices hasthus been established that effects on relative prices areconsidered. But as the assumption generally is thatchanges in the quantity of money affect only the general

1 This is the formulation of R. G. Havvtrey. Cf. his lecture on" Money and Index Numbers " in the Journal of the Royal Statis-tical Society, Vol. XCIII, Part I, 1930, p. 65.

Page 18: Prices and Production (1931) - F. A. Hayek

6 PRICES AND PRODUCTION

price level, and that changes of relative prices are dueto "disturbing factors" or "frictions", changes inrelative prices are not part of this explanation of thechanges in the price level. They are mere accompany-ing circumstances which experience has taught us tobe regularly connected with changes of the price level,not, as might be thought, necessary consequences ofthe same causes. This is very clear from the form ofexposition and the concepts it employs. Certain" lags " are found to exist between the changes ofdifferent prices. The prices of different goods are saidgenerally to be affected in a definite sequence, and it isalways implied that all this would never take place ifthe general price level did not change.

When we come to the way in which the influenceof prices on production is conceived by this theory,the same general characteristics are to be discovered.It is the price level, the changes of which are supposedto influence production; and the effect considered isnot the effect upon particular branches of production,but the effect upon the volume of production in general.In most cases, no attempt is made to show why thismust be so; we are referred to statistics which showthat in the past a high correlation of general prices andthe total volume of production has been present. Ifan explanation of this correlation is attempted, it isgenerally simply to the effect that the expectationof selling at higher prices than present costs will induceeverybody to expand production, while in the oppositecase the fear of being compelled to sell below costs will

Page 19: Prices and Production (1931) - F. A. Hayek

INFLUENCE OF MONEY ON PRICES 7

prove a strong deterrent. That is to say, it is only thegeneral or average movement of prices which counts.

Now this idea that changes of relative prices andchanges in the volume of production are consequentupon changes in the price level, and that money affectsindividual prices only by means of its influence on thegeneral price level, seems to me to be at the root of atleast three very erroneous opinions: Firstly, thatmoney acts upon prices and production only if thegeneral price level changes, and, therefore, that pricesand production are always unaffected by money,—thatthey are at their " natural " level,—if the price levelremains stable. Secondly, that a rising price leveltends always to cause an increase of production, and afalling price level always a decrease of production ;and thirdly, that " monetary theory might even bedescribed as nothing more than the theory of how thevalue of money is determined ".* It is such delusions,as we shall see, which make it possible to assume thatwe can neglect the influence of money so long as thevalue of money is assumed to be stable, and apply with-out further qualification the reasonings of a generaleconomic theory which pays attention to " real causes "only, and that we have only to add to this theory aseparate theory of the value of money and of the con-sequences of its changes in order to get a completeexplanation of the modern economic process.

Further details are unnecessary. You are allsufficiently familiar with this type of theory to supply

1 R. G. Hawtrey, I.e., p. 64.

Page 20: Prices and Production (1931) - F. A. Hayek

8 PRICES AND PRODUCTION

these for yourselves and to correct any exaggerationswhich I may have committed in my endeavour tomake the contrast with the other types of theory asstrong as possible. Any further strengthening of thecontrast can best be carried out by my proceedingforthwith to the second of the major stages in thedevelopment of monetary theory. I wish only toemphasise, before I pass on to that, that hence-forward when I speak of stages of development, I donot mean that each of these stages has in turn takenthe place of the foregoing as the recognised doctrine.Quite on the contrary, each of these stages is stillrepresented among contemporary monetary theoristsand indeed in all probability the first has still the greatestnumber of adherents.

(4) As might be expected, the second stage arises byway of dissatisfaction with the first. This dissatis-faction makes its appearance quite early. Locke andMontanari, at the end of the seventeenth century, hadstated quite clearly the theory I have been discussing.Richard Cantillon, whose criticism of Locke I have takenas the motto of this lecture, realised its inadequacy, andin his famous Essai sur le Commerce (published 1755),he provides the first attempt known to me to trace theactual chain of cause and effect between the amountof money and prices. In a brilliant chapter, whichW. S. Jevons called " one of the most marvellousthings in the book ", he attempts to show " by whatpath and in what proportion the increase of money raisesthe price of things". Starting from the assumption

Page 21: Prices and Production (1931) - F. A. Hayek

INFLUENCE OF MONEY ON PRICES 9

of the discovery of new gold or silver mines, heproceeds to show how this additional supply of theprecious metals first increases the incomes of allpersons connected with their production, how theincrease of the expenditure of these persons nextincreases the prices of things which they buy inincreased quantities, how the rise in the prices of thesegoods increases the incomes of the sellers of thesegoods, how they, in their turn, increase their expendi-ture, and so on. He concludes that only those personsare benefited by the increase of money whoseincomes rise early, while to persons whose incomes riselater the increase of the quantity of money is harmful.

Better known is the somewhat shorter expositionof the same idea which David Hume gave a little laterin a famous passage of his Political Discourses,1 whichso closely resembles the words of Cantillon that it ishard to believe that he had not seen one of thosemanuscripts of the Essai which are known to have beenin private circulation at the time when the Discourseswere written. Hume, however, makes it clear that,in his opinion, " it is only in this interval or intermedi-ate situation, between the acquisition of money andthe rise of prices, that the increasing quantity of goldand silver is favourable to industry ".

To the Classics, this line of reasoning did not seemsusceptible of improvement. While Hume is often

1 Published 1752, republished as part of his Essays Moral,Political and Literary (Pt. II, Essay IV, Of Money) which originallyappeared in 1742, and therefore are often wrongly quoted with thatdate.

Page 22: Prices and Production (1931) - F. A. Hayek

io PRICES AND PRODUCTION

quoted, his method of approach was not amplified formore than a century. It was not until the increase ofthe supply of gold consequent upon the Californian andAustralian discoveries that there was any new impetusto this type of analysis. J. E. Cairnes' Essay on theAustralian Gold Discoveries1 contains probably themost noteworthy refinement of the argument of Cantil-lon and Hume before it was finally incorporated intomore modern explanations based upon the subjectivetheories of value.

It was inevitable that modern theory should besympathetic towards a point of view which traces theeffects of an increase of money to its influence on indi-vidual decisions. But a generation passed before seriousattempts were made to base the explanation of thevalue of money and the effects of changes in the amountof money upon the fundamental concepts of marginalutility theory. I shall not dwell here at any length onthe variety of forms this assumes in the different moderntheories which base the explanation of the value ofmoney on the subjective elements determining thedemand for money on the part of the individual. In theform this theory has received at the hands of Professor

1 Essays towards a Solution of the Gold Question, in Essays inPolitical Economy, Theoretical and Applied, London, 1873, partic-ularly Essay II : " The Course of Depreciation." These Essayswere originally published in 1855-60 in Frazers Magazine and theEdinburgh Review. It may be of interest to mention here thatCarl Menger who has decisively influenced modern developmentin this field, was well acquainted with Cairnes' exposition. Cf. onthis point my Introduction to Vol. I of the Collected Works of CarlMenger in the Series of Reprints of Scarce Tracts in Economics,edited by the London School of Economics.

Page 23: Prices and Production (1931) - F. A. Hayek

INFLUENCE OF MONEY ON PRICES n

Mises, it belongs already to the third and fourth of ourmain stages of development, and I shall have occasionto refer to it later. It is worth noticing, however,that, in so far as these theories are confined to anexplanation of the manner in which the effects ofincrease in the amount of money are distributed throughthe various channels of trade, they still suffer froma not unimportant defect. While they succeed inproviding a general scheme for the deduction of thesuccessive effects of an increase or decrease of theamount of money, provided that we know where theadditional money enters into circulation, they donot help us to make any general statements about theeffects which any change in the amount of money musthave. For, as I shall show later, everything dependson the point where the additional money is injectedinto circulation (or where money is withdrawn fromcirculation), and the effects may be quite oppositeaccording as the additional money comes first intothe hands of traders and manufacturers or directlyinto the hands of salaried people employed by theStajte.

(5) Very early, and, in the beginning, with onlylittle relation to the problem of the value of money,there had, however, sprung up a doctrine, or rathera number of closely related doctrines, the importance ofwhich was not appreciated at the time, although in theend they were to be combined to fill the gap I have beendiscussing. I refer to the doctrines of the influence ofthe quantity of money on the rate of interest, and

Page 24: Prices and Production (1931) - F. A. Hayek

12 PRICES AND PRODUCTION

through it on the relative demand for consumers'goods on the one hand and producers' or capital goodson the other. These form the third stage in the develop-ment of monetary theory. These doctrines have hadto surmount unusual obstacles and prejudices, anduntil recently they received very little attention.It almost seems as if economists had for so long a timestruggled against the popular confusions between thevalue of money proper and the price for a money loanthat in the end they had become almost incapable ofseeing that there was any relation at all between therate of interest and the value of money. It is thereforeworth while attempting to trace their developmentin rather greater detail.

While the existence of some relation between thequantity of money and the rate of interest was clearlyrecognised very early—traces of an understandingcould certainly be found in the writings of Locke andDutot—the first author known to me to enunciate aclear doctrine on this point was Henry Thornton.In his Paper Credit of Great Britain, published in 1802at the beginning of the discussion on Bank Restriction—a really remarkable performance, the true importanceof which is only now beginning to be recognised—hestruck for the first time one of the leading notes of thenew doctrine. The occasion for his statement was aninquiry into the question whether there existed a naturaltendency to keep the circulation of the Bank of Englandwithin the limits which would prevent a dangerousdepreciation. Thornton denied that such a natural

Page 25: Prices and Production (1931) - F. A. Hayek

INFLUENCE OF MONEY ON PRICES 13

tendency existed and held that, on the contrary, thecirculation might expand beyond all assignable limitsif the Bank would only keep its rate of interest lowenough. He based his opinion on considerations soweighty that I cannot resist quoting them at somelength :

" In order to ascertain how far the desire of obtainingloans at the Bank may be expected at any time to be carried,we must enquire into the subject of the quantum of profitlikely to be derived from borrowing there under the existingcircumstances. This is to be judged of by considering twopoints : the amount, first, of interest to be paid on the sumborrowed ; and, secondly, of the mercantile or other gainto be obtained by the employment of the borrowed capital.The gain which can be acquired by the means of commerce iscommonly the highest which can be had ; and it also regulates,in a great measure, the rate in all other cases. "We may,therefore, consider this question as turning principally on acomparison of the rate of interest taken at the bank with thecurrent rate of mercantile profit"1 (p. 287).

Thornton restated these doctrines in the first of histwo speeches on the Bullion Report, which were alsopublished as a booklet2 and would deserve beingrecovered from oblivion. In this speech he attemptsto call the attention of the House to the subject of therate of interest as " a very great and turning point",and, after restating his theory in a shorter form, adds

1 In order to appreciate the importance of this statement, anotherpassage occurring a little earlier in the same chapter (p. 261) shouldbe consulted. In the course of this passage, Thornton writes :" As soon, however, as the circulating medium ceases to increase,the extra profit is at an end." (Italics mine.)

2 Substance of two speeches by Henry Thornton, Esq., in thedebate in the House of Commons on the report of the BullionCommittee on the 7th and 14th May, 1811, London, 1811. Cf.particularly p. 19 et seq.

Page 26: Prices and Production (1931) - F. A. Hayek

14 PRICES AND PRODUCTION

a new and different theory on the relations betweenprices and interest (which must on no account be con-fused with his other theory) namely a theory of theinfluence of an expectation of a rise of prices on themoney rate of interest, a theory which later on was tobe re-discovered by A. Marshall and Irving Fisher.This theory, however, does not concern us here.1

Thornton's theory seems to have been generallyaccepted among the " bullionists ", though it appears tohave been forgotten by the time that the doctrine of thisschool became the target of those attacks of the BankingSchool to which it would have been a sufficient answer.Within the next two years it had been restated by LordKing3 and J. L. Foster,3 and, what is much moreimportant, it was accepted by David Ricardo, in hispamphlet of 1809, who gave it a still more modern ringby speaking of the rate of interest falling below itsnatural level in the interval between the issues of theBank and their effects on prices.4 He repeated thisalso in his Principles,5 which should have been suffi-cient to make it generally known. The doctrine

1 Cf. T. E. Gregory, Introduction to Tooke and Newmarch'sHistory of Prices and of the State of the Circulation, p. 23. ProfessorGregory does not, however, clearly distinguish between the twotheories.

2 Thoughts on the Effects of the Bank Restriction, London, 1803,p. 20.

3 An Essay on the Principles of Commercial Exchanges, 1804,p. 113.

4 The high price of bullion a proof of the depreciation of Bank Notes.Third edit., 1810, p. 47. Essays, ed. E. K. C. Gonner, p. 35.

5 Principles of Political Economy and Taxation, Works, ed.McCulloch, p. 220.

Page 27: Prices and Production (1931) - F. A. Hayek

INFLUENCE OF MONEY ON PRICES 15

makes its appearance in the Bullion Report,1 and itremained familiar to economists for some time afterthe restriction period.

In 1823, Thomas Joplin, the inventor of thecurrency doctrine, enunciates the same principle whicha few years later he elaborated into a peculiar but veryinteresting theory of the " pressure and anti-pressureof capital upon currency " and propounds it as a newdiscovery.2 Though his theory is interwoven withsome quite erroneous opinions, which probably pre-vented his contemporaries from recognising the real con-tributions contained in his writings, yet, nevertheless, hesucceeds in providing the clearest explanation of therelations between the rate of interest and the fluctuationsof the note circulation which had been given up to thattime. The principle which, in Joplin's opinion, neitherThornton nor those who adopted his opinions discovered,and which probably was responsible for " every greatfluctuation in prices that has occurred since the firstestablishment of our banking system ", is that when thesupply of capital exceeds the demand, it has the effect of

1 Bullion Report, etc., octavo edit., 1810, p. 56 ; ed. Cannan,P. 51-

2 In a work entitled Outlines of a system of Political Economy ;written with a view to prove to Government and the Country thatthe cause of the present agricultural distress is entirly artificial,and to suggest a plan for the management of currency by which itmay be remedied now and any recurrence of similar evils be preventedin the future, London, 1^23, pp. 62 and 19S et seq. This work prob-ably contains also the first exposition of the programme lateradvocated and put into practice by the members of the " Cur-rency School " Joplin's second work referred to in the Text isAn Analysis and History of the Currency Question, London, 1832.

Page 28: Prices and Production (1931) - F. A. Hayek

16 PRICES AND PRODUCTION

compressing the country circulation : when the demandis greater than the supply, it has the effect of expandingit again.1 He devotes some pages to an expositionof how the rate of interest operates to equalisethe demand for and the supply of capital, and how anychange of that rate affects productive activity, and thenproceeds: " But, with our currency, or rather thecurrency of the country banks . . . the effects aredifferent. The interest of money, when it is abundant,is not reduced, but the circulation . . . is dim-inished ; and on the contrary, when money is scarce,an enlargement of issues takes place, instead of a risein the rate of interest. The Country Bankers nevervary the interest they charge. . . . He must, ofnecessity, have one fixed charge, whatever it may be :for he never can know what the true rate is. Witha metallic currency, on the contrary, the Banker wouldalways know the state of the market. In the first place,he could not lend money until it had been saved andplaced in his hands, and he would have a particularamount to lend. On the other hand, he would havemore or fewer persons wanting to borrow, and inproportion as the demand would exceed or fall shortof the amount he had to lend, he would raise or lowerhis terms: . . . But, in consequence of theCountry Banks being not only dealers in incipientcapital, but issuers of currency, the demand forcurrency and the demand for capital are so mingled

1 Analysis and History, p. 101.

Page 29: Prices and Production (1931) - F. A. Hayek

INFLUENCE OF MONEY ON PRICES 17

together that all knowledge of either is totally con-founded."1

For the next seventy-five years there was hardlyany progress in this connection. Three years afterJoplin, in 1826, Thomas Tooke (who eighteen years laterwas to enlarge upon the erroneousness of what he thencould already call the commonly received doctrine thata low rate of interest is calculated to raise prices anda high rate to depress them)2 accepted Thornton'sdoctrine, and developed it in some minor points.3 In1832 J. Horlsey Palmer reproduced it before the par-liamentary committee on the Renewal of the BankCharter,4 and as late as 1840 the doctrine that the" demand for loans and discounts at a rate below theusual rate is insatiable " was treated almost as a matterof course by N. W. Senior,5 and it even entered, thoughin a somewhat emasculated form, into J. S. Mills' Prin-ciples of Political Economy.6

1 Analysis and History, pp. 108-9. Cf. also pp. 111-13.a T. Tooke, An Inquiry into the Currency Principle, London,

1844, p. 77.3 Tooke, Considerations on the State of the Currency, London,

1826, p. 22, footnote. As late as 1840 he still reprinted this notein the appendix to the first volume of his History of Prices thoughnot without omitting some important sentences. Cf. Gregory,Introduction, p. 25.

4 Report on the Committee of Secrecy on the Bank of England Charter,London, 1833, p. 18. Q. 191-7.

5 In an anonymous article entitled " Lord King " in the EdinburghReview, October, 1846, later reprinted in N. W. Senior's BiographicalSketches, London, 1863. The relevant parts of this article are nowal reproduced in N. W. Senior's Industrial Efficiency and SocialEconomy, ed. by S. Leon Levy. New York, 1928. Vol. II. pp. 117-18.

6 Book III. Chap. XXIII, para. 4, ed. Ashley, p. 646 et seq.

Page 30: Prices and Production (1931) - F. A. Hayek

18 PRICES AND PRODUCTION

(6) Before following the more modern developmentof this theory, I must, however, trace the origins ofthe second strand of thought which in the end becameinterwoven with the one just considered to constitutemodern doctrine in this matter. While the line ofthought we have already considered pays attentiononly to the relation between the rate of interest, theamount of money in circulation and, as a necessaryconsequence of the latter, the general price level, thesecond pays attention to the influence which an increasein the amount of money exercises upon the productionof capital, either directly or through the rate of interest.The theory that an increase of money brings aboutan increase of capital, which has recently becomevery popular under the name of " forced saving ", iseven older than the one we have just been considering.

The first author clearly to state this doctrine and theone who elaborated it in greater detail than any of hissuccessors up to very recent times was J. Bentham.In a passage of his Manual of Political Economy writtenin 1804 but not published until 1843, he deals in somedetail with the phenomenon which he calls " ForcedFrugality". By this he means the increased " additionto the mass of future wealth " which a government canbring about by applying funds raised by taxation or thecreation of paper money to the production of capitalgoods. But interesting and important as this discussionby Bentham is, and although it is more than probablethat it was known to some of the economists of thiscircle, the fact that it appeared in print only so many

Page 31: Prices and Production (1931) - F. A. Hayek

INFLUENCE OF MONEY ON PRICES 19

years later reduces its importance for the developmentof the doctrine very much.1

The honour of first having discussed the problemin some detail in print is apparently due toT. R. Malthus,who, in 1811, in an unsigned review2 of Ricardo's firstpamphlet, introduces his remarks with the complaintthat no writer he is acquainted with " has ever seemedsufficiently aware of the influence which a differentdistribution of the circulating medium of the countrymust have on those accumulations which are destinedto facilitate future production". He then demon-strates on an assumed " strong case '* that a changeof the proportion between capital and revenue to theadvantage of capital so "as to throw the produce ofthe country chiefly in the hands of the productiveclasses " would have the effect that " in a short time, theproduce of the country would be greatly augmented ".The next paragraph must be quoted in full. He writes :

" Whenever, in the actual state of things, a fresh issue ofnotes comes into the hands of those who mean to employ themin the prosecution and extension of profitable business, adifference in the distribution of the circulating medium takesplace, similar in kind to that which has been last supposed;and produces similar, though of course comparatively incon-siderable effects, in altering the proportion between capital

1 Bentham's contribution to this problem is discussed insomewhat greater detail in a note by the present author on " Thedevelopment of the doctrine of Forced Saving " (Quarterly Journalof Economics, November, 1932) where also an even earlier referenceto the problem by H. Thornton and a number of later contributionsto the discussion on it are mentioned, which are omitted in thepresent sketch.

* Edinburgh Review, Vol. XVII. No. XXXIV, February, 1811,p. 363 et seq. Cf. also the reply of Ricardo in appendix to thefourth edition of his pamphlet on the High Price of Bullion.

Page 32: Prices and Production (1931) - F. A. Hayek

20 PRICES AND PRODUCTION

and revenue in favour of the former. The new notes go intothe market as so much additional capital, to purchase whatis necessary for the conduct of the concern. But, before theproduce of the country has been increased, it is impossiblefor one person to have more of it, without diminishing theshares of some others. This diminution is affected by the riseof prices, occasioned by the competition of the new notes,which puts it out of the power of those who are only buyers,and not sellers, to purchase as much of the annual produceas before : While all the industrious classes,—all those whosell as well as buy,—are, during the progressive rise of prices,making unusual profits; and, even when this progressionstops, are left with the command of a greater portion of theannual produce than they possessed previous to the newissues."

The recognition of this tendency of an increasedissue of notes to increase the national capital does notblind Malthus to the dangers and manifest injusticeconnected with it. He simply offers it, he says, as arational explanation of the fact that a rise of prices isgenerally found conjoined with public prosperity.

With a single exception this suggestion of Malthusdoes not seem to have been appreciated at the time—though the mere fact that Ricardo replied to it;atlength should have made it familiar to economists.The exception is a series of memoranda on the BullionReport which Dugald Stewart prepared in 1811 for LordLauderdale and which were later reprinted as an appen-dix to his lectures on Political Economy.1 Objectingto the oversimplified version of the quantity theory

1 Cf. the Collected Works of Dugald Stewart, edited by SirWilliam Hamilton, London, 1855, vol. VIII, pp. 440-9. A fullerdiscussion of D. Stewart's views on the subject will be found in thenote on "The Development of the Doctrine of Forced Saving",quoted before.

Page 33: Prices and Production (1931) - F. A. Hayek

INFLUENCE OF MONEY ON PRICES 21

employed in the reasoning of the Bullion Report heattempts to explain the more " indirect connectionbetween the high prices and an increased circulatingmedium ". In the course of this discussion he comesvery near to the argument employed by Malthus andin one of the later memoranda actually refers to thearticle which in the meantime had come to his notice,and reproduces the paragraph quoted above.

There are further allusions to the problem by otherauthors of the early nineteenth century, notably byT. Joplin and R. Torrens, and John Stuart Mill inthe fourth of his Essays on Some Unsettled Questions ofPolitical Economy—" On profits and Interest "—(written in 1829 or 1830) goes at least so far as to men-tion that, as the result of the activity of bankers," revenue " maybe " converted into capital; and thus,strange as it may appear, the depreciation of the cur-rency, when effected in this way, operates to a certainextent as a forced accumulation."1

But he believed then that this phenomenon belongedto the " further anomalies of the rate of interest whichhave not, so far as we are aware, been hitherto broughtwithin the pale of exact science ". The first editionof his Principles seems to contain nothing on this point.But in 1865, in the sixth edition, he added to his chapteron " Credit as a Substitute for Money " a footnotewhich so closely resembles the statement by Malthusthat it seems very probable that something—perhaps

x Essays on Some Unsettled Questions of Political Economy,London, 1844, p. 118.

Page 34: Prices and Production (1931) - F. A. Hayek

22 PRICES AND PRODUCTION

the publications of D. Stewart's Collected Works—haddirected his attention to the earlier discussion of thepoint.1

(7) In the period after the publication of J. S. Mill'sPrinciples for a long time attention was paid only to thefirst of the two related ideas we have been analysing.For many years there was very little progress at all.Occasional restatements of the views of the earlierauthors occurred, but added nothing and receivedlittle attention.2 The doctrine of the " indirect chain ofeffects connecting money and prices ", as developed bySidgwick, Giffen, Nicholson, and even Marshall,3 addshardly anything to what had been evolved from Thorn-ton to Tooke. More significant is the further develop-ment and perhaps independent re-discovery of theforced saving doctrine by Leon Walras in 1879.4

Although his contribution had been practically forgottenand has only recently been recovered from oblivion byProfessor Marget, it is of special interest because it isprobably through Walras that this doctrine reachedKnut Wicksell. And it was only this great Swedisheconomist who at the end of the century finally succeededin definitely welding the two, up to then, separate

1 J. S. Mill. Principles of Political Economy, ed. Ashley, p. 512.2 An instance of such restatement of earlier doctrine which is

somewhat surprising in view of the later opinions of this author,occurs in Adolf Wagner's early BeitrSLge zur Lehre von den Ban ken,Leipzig, 1857, pp. 236-9.

3 Cf. J. W. Angell, The Theory of International Prices, Cam-bridge, 1926, p. 117 et seq.

4 Leon Walras, Theorie Mathdmatique du Billet de Banque, 1879,reprinted in Etudes d'Bconomie Politique Appliqui, Lausanne andParis, 1898.

Page 35: Prices and Production (1931) - F. A. Hayek

INFLUENCE OF MONEY ON PRICES 23

strands of thoughts into one. His success in thisregard is explained by the fact that his attempt wasbased on a modern and highly developed theory ofinterest, that of Bohm-Bawerk. But by a curiousirony of fate, Wicksell1 has become famous, not for hisreal improvements on the old doctiine, but for the onepoint in his exposition in which he definitely erred:namely, for his attempt to establish a rigid connectionbetween the rate of interest and the changes in thegeneral price level.

Put concisely, Wicksell's theory is as follows : Ifit were not for monetary disturbances, the rate of inter-est would be determined so as to equalise the demandfor and the supply of savings. This equilibriumrate, as I prefer to call it, he christens the natural2

rate of interest. In a money economy, the actualor money rate of interest (" Geldzins ") may differfrom the equilibrium or natural rate, because thedemand for and the supply of capital do not meetin their natural form but in the form of money, thequantity of which available for capital purposes may bearbitrarily changed by the banks.

1 Wicksell's first and most important exposition of this doctrineis in his Geldzins und Giiterpreise (published in German Jena, 1898)which should be consulted together with Wicksell's later restatementin the second volume of his Vorlesungen iiber Nationalokonomie,Jena, 1922.

2 Sometimes also the "normal" (p. m ) or " r e a l " rate ofinterest. This latter form of expression has given rise to a confusionwith a different theory concerning the influence of an expectationof price changes on the rate, which is commonly associated with thename of Fisher, but which, as mentioned before, was already knownto Thornton, Ricardo and,Marshall.

Page 36: Prices and Production (1931) - F. A. Hayek

24 PRICES AND PRODUCTION

Now, so long as the money rate of interest coincideswith the equilibrium rate, the rate of interest remains" neutral " in its effects on the prices of goods, tendingneither to raise nor to lower them. When the banks,however, lower the money rate of interest below theequilibrium rate, which they can do by lending morethan has been entrusted to them, i.e., by adding tothe circulation, this must tend to raise prices ; if theyraise the money rate above the equilibrium rate—acase of less practical importance—they exert a depress-ing influence on prices. From this correct statement,however, which does not imply that the price levelwould remain unchanged if the money rate correspondsto the equilibrium rate, but only that, in such condi-tions, there are no monetary causes tending to produce achange in the price level, Wicksell jumps to the con-clusion that, so long as the two rates agree, the pricelevel must always remain steady. There will be moreto say about this later. For the moment, it is worthobserving a further development of the theory. Therise of the price level which is supposed to be the neces-sary effect of the money rate remaining below theequilibrium rate, is in the first instance brought aboutby the entrepreneurs spending on production theincreased amount of money loaned by the banks. Thisprocess, as Malthus had already shown, involves whatWicksell now called enforced or compulsory saving.1

1 Geldzins und Giiterpreise, pp. 102, 143.

Page 37: Prices and Production (1931) - F. A. Hayek

INFLUENCE OF MONEY ON PRICES 25

That is all I need to say here in explanation of theWicksellian theory. Nor shall I here discuss the impor-tant development of this theory added by the Austrianeconomist, Professor Mises.1 An exposition of thepresent form of this theory will form the main subjectof my next two lectures. Here it is only necessaryto point out that Professor Mises has improved theWicksellian theory by an analysis of the differentinfluences which a money rate of interest differentfrom the equilibrium rate exercises on the prices ofconsumers' goods on the one hand, and the pricesof producers' goods on the other. In this way, hehas succeeded in transforming the Wicksellian theory

1 Theorie des Geldes und der Umlaufsmittel, 1912. Simultaneouslywith Professor Mises a distinguished Italian economist, ProfessorMarco Fanno, made in an exceedingly interesting and now very rarebook on Le Bane he e il Mercato Monetario, an independent attemptto develop Wicksell's theory further. A revised shorter Germanversion of the views of this author is now available in his contributionto the Beitrdge zur Geldtheorie, Vienna, 1933.

Considerable elements of Professor Mises' theory and particularlythe doctrine of " Forced Saving " seem to have been introduced intoAmerica through Professor Schumpeter's Theorie der WirtschaftlichenEntwicklung and Dr. B. M. Anderson's Value of Money and gainedconsiderable vogue since. In any case since the publication of thisbook in 1917 " Forced Saving" has been discussed by ProfessorsF. W. Taussig {Principles of Economics, 3rd edit., pp. 351, 359),F. Knight (Risk, Uncertainty and Profit, p. 166 note and Index),D. Friday (Profit, Wages and Prices, pp. 216-17), and A. H. Hansen(Cycles of Prosperity and Depression, 1921, pp. 104-6). Whether theAmerican author whose views on these problems comes nearest tothose expressed in the present book, Mr. M. W. Watkins, whoseexceedingly interesting article on " Commercial Banking and theFormation of Capital" (Journal of Political Economy, vol. xxvii.,1919), I have only recently become acquainted with, is indebtedto the same source I do not know.

In England similar ideas seem to have been developed independ-ently, first by Professor Pigou (in Is Unemployment Inevitable ?r925. PP- 100-11) and then in much greater detail by Mr. D. H,Robertson (Banking Policy and the Price Level, 1926, passim).

Page 38: Prices and Production (1931) - F. A. Hayek

26 PRICES AND PRODUCTION

into an explanation of the credit cycle which is logicallysatisfactory.

(8) But this brings me to the next part of mydiscussion. For it is partly upon the foundationslaid by Wicksell and partly upon criticism of his doc-trine that what seems to me the fourth of the greatstages of the progress of monetary theory is beingbuilt. (I ought, perhaps, expressly to warn you thatwhile up to this point of our survey I have been describ-ing developments which have already taken place,what I am about to say about the fourth stageconcerns rather what I think it should be than whathas already taken definite shape.)

It would take too much time to trace chronologic-ally the steps by which, by degrees, the Wickselliantheory has been transformed into something new.You will be better able to appreciate this change ifI turn immediately to the discussion of those deficienciesof his doctrine which eventually made it necessarydefinitely to break away from certain of the funda-mental concepts in the theory which had been takenover by him from his predecessors.

I have mentioned already that, according to Wicksellthe equilibrium rate of interest was a rate whichsimultaneously restricted the demand for real capitalto the amount of savings available and secured stabilityof the price level. His idea was obviously one which isvery generally held even at the present time, namely,that as, at an equilibrium rate of interest, moneywould remain neutral towards prices, therefore in such

Page 39: Prices and Production (1931) - F. A. Hayek

INFLUENCE OF MONEY ON PRICES 27

circumstances there could be no reason at all for achange of the price level.

Nevertheless, it is perfectly clear that, in orderthat the supply and demand for real capital should beequalised, the banks must not lend more or less thanhas been deposited with them as savings (and suchadditional amounts as may have been saved andhoarded). And this means naturally that (alwaysexcepting the case just mentioned) they must neverallow the effective amount of money in circulation tochange.1 At the same time, it is no less clear that, inorder that the price level may remain unchanged, theamount of money in circulation must change as thevolume of production increases or decreases. Thebanks could either keep the demand for real capitalwithin the limits set by the supply of savings, or keep theprice level steady; but they cannot perform bothfunctions at once. Save in a society in which therewere no additions to the supply of savings, i.e., a station-ary society, to keep the money rate of interest at thelevel of the equilibrium rate would mean that in timesof expansion of production the price level would fall.To keep the general price level steady would mean, insimilar circumstances, that the loan rate of interestwould have to be lowered below the equilibrium rate.

1 From now onward the term " amount of money in circulation "or even shortly " the quantity of money " will be used for what shouldmore exactly be described as the effective money stream or theamount of money payments made during a unit period of time.The problems arising out of possible divergences between these twomagnitudes will only be taken up in Lecture IV. v

Page 40: Prices and Production (1931) - F. A. Hayek

28 PRICES AND PRODUCTION

The consequences would be what they always are whenthe rate of investment exceeds the rate of saving.

It would be possible to cite other cases where theinfluence of money on prices and production is quiteindependent of the effects on the general price level.But it seems obvious as soon as one once begins tothink about it that almost any change in the amountof money, whether it does influence the price level ornot, must always influence relative prices. And, asthere can be no doubt that it is relative "prices whichdetermine the amount and the direction of production,almost any change in the amount of money mustnecessarily also influence production.

But if we have to recognise that, on the one hand,under a stable price level, relative prices may be changedby monetary influences, and, on the other that relativeprices may remain undisturbed only when the pricelevel changes, we have to give up the generally receivedopinion that if the general price level remains the same,the tendencies towards economic equilibrium are notdisturbed by monetary influences, and that disturbinginfluences from the side of money cannot make them-selves felt otherwise than by causing a change of thegeneral price levei.

This doctrine, which has been accepted dogmatic-ally by almost all monetary theorists, seems to me tolie at the root of most of the shortcomings of present-day monetary theory and to be a bar to almost allfurther progress. Its bearing on various proposalsfor stabilisation is obvious. In these lectures, however,

Page 41: Prices and Production (1931) - F. A. Hayek

INFLUENCE OF MONEY ON PRICES 29

it is in the theoretical foundations of these schemesrather than in the formulation of alternative practicalproposals that we are interested. And here, it may besuggested, it is possible very greatly to underestimatethe changes in economic theory which are implied ifonce we drop these unjustified assumptions. Forwhen we investigate into all the influences of moneyon individual prices, quite irrespective of whetherthey are or are not accompanied by a change of theprice level, it is not long before we begin to realise thesuperfluity of the concept of a general value of money,conceived as the reverse of some price level. And,indeed, I am of the opinion that, in the near future,monetary theory will not only reject the explanationin terms of a direct relation between money and theprice level, but will even throw overboard the conceptof a general price level and substitute for it investiga-tions into the causes of the changes of relative pricesand their effects on production. Such a theory ofmoney, which will be no longer a theory of the valueof money in general, but a theory of the influence ofmoney on the different ratios of exchange betweengoods of all kinds, seems to me the probable fourthstage in the development of monetary theory.

This view of the probable future of the theory ofmoney becomes less startling if we consider that theconcept of relative prices includes the prices of goodsof the same kind at different moments, and that here,as in the case of interspatial price relationships, onlyone relation between the two prices can correspond

Page 42: Prices and Production (1931) - F. A. Hayek

30 PRICES AND PRODUCTION

to a condition of " intertemporal" equilibrium, andthat this need not, a priori, be a relation of identityor the one which would exist under a stable price level.(This has a particular bearing on the problem of moneyas a standard of deferred payments, because in thisfunction money is to be conceived simply as the mediumwhich effects an intertemporal exchange.) If thisview is correct, the question ,which in my opinion willtake the place of the question whether the value ofmoney has increased or decreased will be the questionwhether the state of equilibrium of the rates of inter-temporal exchange is disturbed by monetary influencesin favour of future or in favour of present goods.1

(9) It will be the object of the following lecturesto show how it is possible to solve at least some of themost important problems of monetary theory withoutrecourse to the concept of a value of money in general.It will then remain for you to make up your mindwhether we can conceivably entirely dispense with it.For the moment, I wish only to remind you of one fur-ther reason why it seems that, in the case of money, incontrast to any other good, the question of its value ingeneral is of no consequence.

We are interested in the prices of individual goodsbecause these prices show us how far the demand forany particular good can be satisfied. To discoverthe causes why certain needs, and the needs of certain

1 I have dealt more fully with the difficult question of the con-ditions of intertemporal equilibrium of exchange in an article " Dasintertemporale Gleichgewichtsystem der Preise und die Bewegungendes ' Geldwertes ' " in the Weltwirtschaftliches Archiv., vol. 28, 1928.

Page 43: Prices and Production (1931) - F. A. Hayek

INFLUENCE OF MONEY ON PRICES 31

persons, can be satisfied to a greater degree thanothers is the ultimate- object of economics. There is,however, no need for money in this sense,—the absoluteamount of money in existence is of no consequence tothe well-being of mankind—and there is, therefore,no objective value of money in the sense in which wespeak of the objective value of goods. What we areinterested in is only how the relative values of goods assources of income or as means of satisfaction of wantsare affected by money.

The problem is never to explain any " generalvalue " of money but only how and when moneyinfluences the relative values of goods and under whatconditions it leaves these relative values undisturbed,or, to use a happy phrase of Wicksell, when moneyremains neutral relatively to goods.1 -Not a moneywhich is stable in value but a neutral money musttherefore form the starting point for the theoreticalanalysis of monetary influences on production, andthe first object of monetary theory should be to clear upthe conditions under which money might be consideredto be neutral in this sense. We stand as yet at the verybeginning of this kind of investigation. And, thoughI hope that what I say in the next lectures may help alittle, I am fully conscious that all results we obtainat this stage should only be regarded as tentative.So far as I am concerned, it is the method of approachmore than the details of the results which is of impor-tance in what follows.

1 Cf. the Appendix to Lecture IV.

Page 44: Prices and Production (1931) - F. A. Hayek

LECTURE II

THE CONDITIONS OF EQUILIBRIUM BETWEENTHE PRODUCTION OF CONSUMERS' GOODS

AND THE PRODUCTION OF PRODUCERS'GOODS

" The question of how far, and in what manner, an increaseof currency tends to increase capital appears to us so veryimportant, as fully to warrant our attempt to explain it. . . .I t is not the quantity of the circulating medium which producesthe effects here described, but the different distribution of it. . . on every fresh issue of notes . . . a largerproportion falls into the hands of those who consume andproduce, and a smaller proportion into the hands of those whoonly consume."

T. R. MALTHUS,Edinburgh Review, vol. XVII (1811),

p. 363 et seq.

(1) Before we can attempt to understand theinfluence of prices on the amount of goods produced,we must know the nature of the immediate causesof a variation of industrial output. Simple as thisquestion may at first appear, contemporary theoryoffers at least three explanations.

(2) First of these, we may take the view that themain causes of variations of industrial output are tobe found in changes of the willingness of individualsto expand effort. I mention this first, because it isprobably the theory which has at present the greatest

3*

Page 45: Prices and Production (1931) - F. A. Hayek

CONSUMERS' AND PRODUCERS' GOODS 33

number of adherents in this country. That this pointof view is so widely accepted in England is probablydue to the fact that a comparatively great number ofeconomists here are still under the influence of "real cost"theories of value which make this type of explanation ofany change in the total value of output the natural one.Mr. D. H. Robertson's stimulating book on BankingPolicy and the Price Level provides, perhaps, the bestexample of reasoning based on this assumption. YetI do not think that this assumption is at all justifiedby our common experience ; it is a highly artificialassumption to which I would only be willing to resortwhen all other explanations had failed. But itscorrectness is a question of fact, and I shall make noattempt to refute it directly. I shall only try to showthat there are other ways of accounting for changesin industrial-output which seem less artificial.

(3) The second type of explanation is the onewhich " explains" variations of production simplyby the changes of the amount of factors of productionused. In my opinion this is no explanation at all.It depends essentially upon a specious appeal to facts.Starting from the existence of unused resources of allkinds, kilown to us in daily experience, it regards anyincrease of output simply as the consequence ofbringing more unused factors into use, and any diminu-tion of output as the consequence of more resourcesbecoming idle. Now, that any such change in theamount of resources employed implies a correspondingchange in output is, of course, beyond question. But

Page 46: Prices and Production (1931) - F. A. Hayek

34 PRICES AND PRODUCTION

it is not true that the existence of unused resourcesis a necessary condition for an increase of output, norare we entitled to take such a situation as a startingpoint for theoretical analysis. If we want to explainfluctuations of production, we have to give a completeexplanation. Of course this does not mean that wehave to start for that purpose ab ovo with an explanationof the whole economic process. But it does mean thatwe have to start where general economic theory stops ;that is to say at a condition of equilibrium when nounused resources exist. The existence of such unusedresources is itself a fact which needs- explanation.It is not explained by static analysis and, accordingly,we are not entitled to take it for granted. For thisreason I cannot agree that Professor Wesley Mitchellis justified when he states that he considers it no partof his task " to determine how the fact of cyclicaloscillations in economic activity can be reconciledwith the general theory of equilibrium, or how thattheory can be reconciled with facts ".* On the con-trary, it is my conviction that if we want to explaineconomic phenomena at all, we have no means avail-able but to build on the foundations given by theconcept of a tendency towards an equilibrium. Forit is this concept alone which permits us to explainfundamental phenomena like the determination ofprices or incomes, an understanding of which is essentialto any explanation of fluctuation of production. If

1 Business Cycles, The Problem and its Setting, New York, 1927,p. 462.

Page 47: Prices and Production (1931) - F. A. Hayek

CONSUMERS' AND PRODUCERS' GOODS 35

we are to proceed systematically, therefore, we muststart with a situation which is already sufficientlyexplained by the general body of economic theory.And the only situation which satisfies this criterionis the situation in which all available resources areemployed. The existence of unused resources mustbe one of the main objects of our explanation.1

(4) To start from the assumption of equilibrium hasa further advantage. For in this way we are compelledto pay more attention to causes of changes in theindustrial output whose importance might otherwisebe underestimated. I refer to changes in the methodsof using the existing resources. Changes in the direc-tion given to the existing productive forces are notonly the main cause of fluctuations of the outputof individual industries ; the output of industry as awhole may also be increased or decreased to an enor-mous extent by changes in the use made of existingresources. Here we have the third of the contemporaryexplanations of fluctuations which I referred to atthe beginning of the lecture. What I have here inmind are not changes in the methods of productionmade possible by the progress of technical knowledge,but the increase of output made possible by a transi-tion to more capitalistic methods of production, or,what is the same thing, by organising production sothat, at any given, moment, the available resources

1 I have dealt more fully with the relation between pure economictheory and the explanation of business fluctuations in my book,Monetary Theory and the Trade Cycle (London, 1933), Chaps. I and II.

Page 48: Prices and Production (1931) - F. A. Hayek

36 PRICES AND PRODUCTION

are employed for the satisfaction of the needs of afuture more distant than before. It is to this effectof a transition to more or less " roundabout " methodsof production that I wish particularly to direct yourattention. For, in my opinion, it is only by an analysisof this phenomenon that in the end we can show howa situation can be created in which it is temporarilyimpossible to employ all available resources.

The processes involved in any such transition froma less to a more capitalistic form of production are ofsuch a complicated nature that it is only possible tovisualise them clearly if we start from highly simpli-fied assumptions and work through gradually to asituation more like reality. For the purpose of theselectures, I shall divide this investigation into twoparts. Today I shall confine myself to a considerationof the conditions under which an equilibrium betweenthe production of producers' goods and the productionof consumers' goods is established, and the relation ofthis equilibrium to the flow of money; I reserve forthe next lecture a more detailed explanation of theworking of the price mechanism during the period oftransition, and of the relations between changes inthe price system and the rate of interest.

(5) My first task is to define the precise meaningof certain terms. The term production I shall alwaysuse in its widest possible sense, that is to say, allprocesses necessary to bring goods into the hands ofthe consumer. When I mean land and labour, I shallspeak of original means of production. When I

Page 49: Prices and Production (1931) - F. A. Hayek

CONSUMERS' AND PRODUCERS' GOODS 37use the phrase factors of production without furtherqualification this will cover capital also, that is to saythis term will include all factors from which we deriveincome in the form of wages, rent, and interest. WhenI use the expression producers' goods, I shall be designat-ing all goods existing at any moment which are notconsumers' goods, that is to say, all goods which aredirectly or indirectly used in the production of con-sumers' goods, including therefore the original means ofproduction, as well as instrumental goods and allkinds of unfinished goods. Producers' goods whichare not original means of production, but which comebetween the original means of production and con-sumers' goods, I shall call intermediate products. Noneof these distinctions coincides with the customarydistinction between durable and non-durable goods,which I do not need for my present purpose. I shall,however, have to use this distinction and to add a newone, which stands in some relation to it, in my nextlecture.

(6) I have already pointed out that it is anessential feature of our modern, " capitalistic",system of production that at any moment a far largerproportion of the available original means of productionis employed to provide consumers' goods for somemore or less distant future than is used for the satis-faction of immediate needs. The raison d'etre of thisway of organising production is, of course, that bylengthening the production process we are able toobtain a greater quantity of consumers' goods out of

Page 50: Prices and Production (1931) - F. A. Hayek

38 PRICES AND PRODUCTION

a given quantity of original means of production.It is not necessary for my present purpose to enterat any length into an explanation of this increase ofproductivity by roundabout methods of production.It is enough to state that within practical limits we mayincrease the output of consumers' goods from a givenquantity of original means of production indefinitely,provided we are willing to wait long enough for the pro-duct. The thing which is of main interest for us is thatany such change from a method of production of anygiven duration to a method which takes more or lesstime implies quite definite changes in the organisationof production, or, as I shall call this particular aspectof organisation, to distinguish it from other morefamiliar aspects, changes in the structure of production.

In order to get a clear view of what is actuallyimplied by these changes in the structure of productionit is useful to employ a schematic representation.1

For this purpose, I find it convenient to representthe successive applications of the original means ofproduction which are needed to bring forth the outputof consumers' goods accruing at any moment of time,

1 The following diagrams were originally the result of an attemptto replace the somewhat clumsy tables of figures, used for the samepurpose in my Paradox of Saving (Economica, May, 1931), by a moreeasily grasped form of representation. Later I noticed that similartriangular figures had been used as representations of the capitalisticprocess of production not only by W. S. Jevons (Theory of PoliticalEconomy, 4th edit., 1911, pp. 230-7), but particularly also byK. "Wicksell (Lectures on Political Economy, vol. I, p, 152 et seq.)and, following him, G. Ackerman (Realkapital und Kapitalzins,Part I. Stockholm, 1923). Dr. Marschak has recently made thevery appropriate suggestion to designate these triangular figuresas the " Jevonian Investment Figures".

Page 51: Prices and Production (1931) - F. A. Hayek

CONSUMERS* AND PRODUCERS' GOODS 39

by the hypotenuse of a right-angled triangle, such asthe triangle in Fig. I. The value of these original

ORIGINAL MEANS OF PRODUCTION

OUTPUT OF CONSUMERS GOODSFIG. 1.

means of production is expressed by the horizontalprojection of the hypotenuse, while the verticaldimension, measured in arbitrary periods from thetop to the bottom, expresses the progress of time, so

Page 52: Prices and Production (1931) - F. A. Hayek

40 PRICES AND PRODUCTION

that the inclination of the line representing the amountof original means of production used means that theseoriginal means of production are expended continuouslyduring the whole process of production. The bottomof the triangle represents the value of the currentoutput of consumers' goods. The area of the trianglethus shows the totality of the successive stages throughwhich the several units of original means of productionpass before they become ripe for consumption. Italso shows the total amount of intermediate productswhich must exist at any moment of time in order tosecure a continuous output of consumers' goods.For this reason we may conceive of this diagram notonly as representing the successive stages of the pro-duction of the output of any given moment of time,but also as representing the processes of productiongoing on simultaneously in a stationary society.To use a happy phrase of J. B. Clark's, it gives a pictureof the " synchronised process of production ".I>3

1 The methodological bearing of the concept of a synchronisedproduction is particularly well brought out by Hans Mayer in hisarticle," Produktion",in the Handwdrterbuch der Staatswissenschafteti,fourth edit., vol. VI, Jena, 1925, p. 1115 et seq.

2 So long as we confine ourselves to the real aspects of the capitalstructure the triangular figures may be taken to represent not onlythe stock of goods in process but also the stock of durable instrumentsexisting at any moment of time. The different instalments of futureservices which such goods are expected to render will in that casehave to be imagined to belong to different " stages " of productioncorresponding to the time interval which will elapse before theseservices mature. (For a more detailed discussion of the problemsarising out of the two different aspects, of actual duration of pro-duction and the durability of goods, in which time enters in theproductive process, cf. my article " On the Relationship betweenInvestment and Output", Economic Journal, June, I934-) But as

Page 53: Prices and Production (1931) - F. A. Hayek

CONSUMERS' AND PRODUCERS' GOODS 41

Now it should be clear without further explanationthat the proportion between the amount of intermediateproducts (represented by the area of the triangle) whichis necessary at any moment of time to secure acontinuous output of a given quantity of consumers'goods, and the amount of that output,1 must grow with

soon as it is tried to use the diagrammatic representations to showthe successive transfers of the intermediate products from stage tostage in exchange for money it becomes evidently impossible to treatdurable goods in the same way as goods in process since it is impossibleto assume that the individual services embodied in any durablegoods will regularly change hands as they approach a stage nearerto the moment when they will actually be consumed. For thisreason it has been necessary, as has been pointed out in the preface,to abstract from the existence of durable goods so long as the assump-tion is made that the total stock of intermediate products as itgradually proceeds towards the end of the process of productionis exchanged against money at regular intervals.

1 It would be more exact to compare the stock of intermediateproducts existing at a moment of time not with the output ofconsumers' goods during a period of time, but rather with the rateat which consumers' goods mature at the same moment of time.Since, however, this output at a moment of time would be infinitelysmall, that proportion could only be expressed as a differentialquotient of a function which represents the flow of intermediateproducts at the point where this flow ends, i.e., where the inter-mediate products become consumers' goods. This relationship isessentially the same as that between the total quantity of waterin a stream and the rate at which this water passes the mouth ofthis stream. (This simile seems to be more appropriate than themore familiar one which considers capital as a " stock " and onlyincome as a " flow ". Cf. on this point N. J. Polak, Grundziige derFinanzierung, Berlin, 1926, p. 13.) It is convenient to treat thequantity of intermediate products at any point of this stream as afunction of time f(t) and accordingly the total quantity of inter-mediate products in the stream, as an integral of this function overa period r equal to the total length of the process of production.If we apply this to any process of production beginning at themoment x, the total quantity of intermediate products in the stream

will be expressed by / / (t). dt, and the output of consumers' goods

at a moment of time by f(x + r). In the diagrams used in the textthe function f{t) is represented by the hypotenuse, its concrete

Page 54: Prices and Production (1931) - F. A. Hayek

42 PRICES AND PRODUCTION

the length of the roundabout process of production.As the average time interval between the applicationof the original means of production and the completionof the consumers' goods increases, production becomesmore capitalistic, and vice versa. In the case we arecontemplating in which the original means of produc-tion are applied at a constant rate throughout thewhole process of production, this average time is exactlyhalf as long as the time which elapses between theapplication of the first unit of original means of pro-duction and the completion of the process. Accord-ingly, the total amount of intermediate products mayalso be represented by a rectangle half as high as thetriangle, as indicated by the dotted line in the diagram.The areas of the two figures are necessarily equal, andit sometimes assists the eye to have a rectangle insteadof a triangle when we have to judge the relative magni-tude represented by the area of the figure. Further-more, it should be noticed that, as the figure representsvalues and not physical production, the surplus returnobtained by the roundabout methods of production isnot represented in the diagram. In this lecture Ihave intentionally neglected interest. We shall haveto take that into consideration next time; Until thenwe may assume that the intermediate products remain

value f{* + r) by the horizontal side and the integral by the area ofthe triangle. There is of course no reason.to assume that thefunction /(/) will be linear, i.e., that the amount of original factorsapplied during successive stages of the process is constant, as isassumed in the diagrams. On these and some connected pointssee the article on " Investment and Output", quoted in the precedingfootnote.

Page 55: Prices and Production (1931) - F. A. Hayek

CONSUMERS' AND PRODUCERS' GOODS 43

the property of the owners of the original means ofproduction until they have matured into consumers'goods and are sold to consumers. Interest is thenreceived by the owners of the original means ofproduction together with wages and rent.

(7) A perfectly continuous process of this sort issomewhat unwieldy for theoretical purposes: more-over such an assumption is not perhaps sufficientlyrealistic. It would be open to us to deal with thedifficulties by the aid of higher mathematics. ButI, personally, prefer to make it amenable to a simplermethod by dividing the continuous process intodistinct periods, and by substituting for the conceptof a continuous flow the assumption that goods moveintermittently in equal intervals from one stage of pro-duction to the next. In this way, in my view, the lossin precision is more than compensated by the gain inlucidity.

Probably the simplest method of transformingthe picture of the continuous process into a pictureof what happens in a given period is to make crosssections through our first figure at intervals correspon-ding to the periods chosen, and to imagine observersbeing posted at each of these cross cuts who watchand note down the amount of goods flowing by. Ifwe put these cross sections, as indicated by the brokenlines in Fig. 1, at the end of each period, and representthe amount of goods passing these lines of division in aperiod by a rectangle of corresponding size, we get thenew illustration of the same process given in Fig. 2.

Page 56: Prices and Production (1931) - F. A. Hayek

44 PRICES AND PRODUCTION

It is convenient for the purposes of exposition tocount only that part of the total process of production

ORIGINAL MEANS OF PRODUCTION

18=

WE

%

NTER

I 1 11

1

== 2U =

11

— 1

- - 1

kO

OUTPUT OF CONSUMERSFIG. 2.

GOODS

which is completed during one of these periods, as aseparate stage of production. Each of the successive

Page 57: Prices and Production (1931) - F. A. Hayek

CONSUMERS' AND PRODUCERS' GOODS 45

shaded blocks in the diagram will then represent theproduct of the corresponding stage of production as it ispassed on to the next while the differences in the lengthof the successive blocks correspond to the amount oforiginal means of production used in the succeedingstage. The white block at the bottom representsthe output of consumers' goods during the period. Ina stationary state, which is still the only state I amconsidering, this output of consumers' goods is neces-sarily equal to the total income from the factors ofproduction used, and is exchanged for this income.The proportion of the white area to the shaded area,in this diagram 40:80 or 1:2, expresses the proportionbetween the output of consumers' goods and the outputof intermediate products (or between the amount ofconsumption and the amount of new and renewedinvestment during any period of time).

So far, I have used this schematic illustration ofthe process of production only to represent the move-ments of goods. It is just as legitimate to use it as anillustration of the movement of money. While goodsmove downwards from the top to the bottom of ourdiagram, we have to conceive of money moving in theopposite direction, being paid first for consumers' goodsand thence moving upwards until, after a varyingnumber of intermediary movements, it is paid out asincome to the owners of the factors of production,who in turn use it to buy consumers' goods. But inorder to trace the relation between actual money pay-ments, or the proportional quantities of money used

Page 58: Prices and Production (1931) - F. A. Hayek

46 PRICES AND PRODUCTION

in the different stages of production, and the movementsof goods, we need a definite assumption in regard to thedivision of the total process among different firms,which alone makes an exchange of goods against moneynecessary. For this does not by any means necessarilycoincide with our division into separate stages of pro-duction of equal length. I shall begin with the simplestassumption, that these two divisions do coincide, thatis to say that goods moving towards consumption dochange hands against money in equal intervals whichcorrespond to our unit production periods.

In such a case, the proportion of money spent forconsumers' goods and money spent for intermediateproducts is equal to the proportion between the totaldemand for consumers' goods and the total demandfor the intermediate products necessary for theircontinuous production ; and this, in turn, must corre-spond, in a state of equilibrium, to the proportionbetween the output of consumers' goods during a periodof time and the output of intermediate products of allearlier stages during the same period. Given theassumptions we are making, all these proportions areaccordingly equally expressed by the proportionbetween the area of the white rectangle and the totalshaded area. It will be noticed that the same deviceof the dotted line as was used in the earlier figureis employed to facilitate the comparison of the twoareas. The dotted rectangle shows that, in the kindof production represented by Fig. 2, which actuallytakes four successive stages, the average length of the

Page 59: Prices and Production (1931) - F. A. Hayek

CONSUMERS' AND PRODUCERS' GOODS 47

roundabout process is only two stages, and the amountof intermediate products is therefore twice as great asthe output of customers' goods.

(8) Now if we adopt this method of approach,certain fundamental facts at once become clear. Thefirst fact which emerges is that the amount of moneyspent on producers' goods during any period of timemay be far greater than the amount spent forconsumers' goods during the same period. Ii has beencomputed, indeed, that in the United States, pay-ments for consumers' goods amount only to aboutone-twelfth of the payments made for producers' goodsof all kinds.1 Nevertheless, this fact has not onlyvery often been overlooked, it was even expresslydenied by no less an authority than Adam Smith.According to Smith2: " The value of goods circulatedbetween the different dealers never can exceed the valueof those circulated between dealers and consumers;whatever is bought by the dealer being ultimatelydestined to be sold to the consumers." This proposi-tion- clearly rests upon a mistaken inference from thefact that the total expenditure made in productionmust be covered by the return from the sale of theultimate products; but it remained unrefuted, and

x Cf. M. W. Holtrop, De Omloopssnelheid van het Geld, Amsterdam,1928, p. 181.

2 Wealth of Nations, Book II, Chap. I, ed. Caiman, p. 305. Itis interesting to note that this statement of Adam Smith is referredto by Thomas Tooke as a justification of the erroneous doctrines ofthe Banking School. {Cf. An Inquiry into the Currency Principle,London, 1844, p. 71.)

Page 60: Prices and Production (1931) - F. A. Hayek

48 PRICES AND PRODUCTION

quite recently in our own day it has formed the founda-tion of some very erroneous doctrines.1 * The solutionof the difficulty is, of course, that most goods areexchanged several times against money before they aresold to the consumer, and on the average exactly asmany times as often as the total amount spent forproducers' goods is larger than the amount spent forconsumers' goods.

Another point which is of great importance for whatfollows, and which, while often overlooked in currentdiscussion,2 is quite obvious if we look at our diagram,is the fact that what is generally called the capitalequipment of society—the total of intermediateproducts in our diagram—is not a magnitude which,once it is brought into existence, will necessarily lastfor ever independently of human decisions. Quitethe contrary: whether the structure of productionremains the same depends entirely upon whetherentrepreneurs find it profitable to re-invest the usual

1 Cf. W. T. Foster and W. Catchings, Profits, Publications of thePollak Foundation for Economic Research, No. 8, Boston and NewYork, 1925, and a number of other books by the same authors andpublished in the same series. For a detailed criticism of theirdoctrines, cf. my article, " The ' Paradox ' of Saving," Economica,May, 1931.

2 J. S. Mill's emphasis on the " perpetual consumption andreproduction of capital ", like most of his other penetrating, butoften somewhat obscurely expressed observations on capital, hasnot had the deserved effect, although it directs attention to theessential quality of capital which distinguishes it from other factorsof its production. More recently the misplaced emphasis whichsome authors, particularly Professors J. B. Clark, J. Schumpeterand F. H. Knight, have put on the tautological statement that solong as stationary conditions prevail capital is ex definitionepermanent, has further contributed to obscure the problem.

Page 61: Prices and Production (1931) - F. A. Hayek

CONSUMERS' AND PRODUCERS' GOODS 49

proportion of the return from the sale of the productof their respective stages of production in turning outintermediate goods of the same sort. Whether this isprofitable, again, depends upon the prices obtained forthe product of this particular stage of productionon the one hand and on the prices paid for the originalmeans of production and for the intermediate productstaken from the preceding stage of production on theother. The continuance of the existing degree ofcapitalistic organisation depends, accordingly, on theprices paid and obtained for the product of each stageof production and these prices are, therefore, a veryreal and important factor in determining the directionof production.

The same fundamental fact may be described in aslightly different way. The money stream which theentrepreneur representing any stage of productionreceives at any given moment is always composed ofnet income which he may use for consumption withoutdisturbing the existing method of production, and ofparts which he must continuously re-invest. But itdepends entirely upon him whether he re-distributeshis total money receipts in the same proportions asbefore. And the main factor influencing his decisions willbe the magnitude of the profits he hopes to derive fromthe production of his particular intermediate product.

(9) And now at last we are ready to commence todiscuss the main problem of this lecture, the problemof how a transition from less to more capitalistic methodsof production, or vice versa, is actually brought about,

Page 62: Prices and Production (1931) - F. A. Hayek

50 PRICES AND PRODUCTION

and what conditions must be fulfilled in order that anew equilibrium may be reached. The first questioncan be answered immediately: a transition to more(or less) capitalistic methods of production will takeplace if the total demand for producers' goods (expressedin money) increases (or decreases) relatively to thedemand for consumers' goods. This may come aboutin one of two ways : either as a result of changes in thevolume of voluntary saving (or its opposite), or as aresult of a change in the quantity of money whichalters the funds at the disposal of the entrepreneursfor the purchase of producers' goods. Let us firstconsider the case of changes in voluntary saving, thatis, simple shifts of demand between consumers' goodsand producers' goods.1

As a starting point, we may take the situationdepicted in Fig. 2, and suppose that consumers saveand invest an amount of money equivalent to onefourth of their income of one period. We may assumefurther that these savings are made continuously,exactly as they can be used for building up the newprocess of production. The proportion of the demandfor consumers' goods to the demand for intermediateproducts will then ultimately be changed from 40:80

1 I am deliberately discussing here the " strong case " wheresaving implies a reduction in the demand for all consumers' goods,although this is a highly unlikely case to occur in practice, since itis in this case that many people find it so difficult to understandhow a general decrease in the demand for consumers' goods shouldlead to an increase of investment. Where, as will regularly be thecase, the reduction in the demand for consumers' goods affect onlya few kinds of such goods, these special difficulties would, of course,be absent.

Page 63: Prices and Production (1931) - F. A. Hayek

CONSUMERS' AND PRODUCERS' GOODS 51

to 30:90, or 1:2 to 1:3. The additional amounts ofmoney available for the purchase of intermediateproducts must now be so applied that the output ofconsumers' goods may be sold for the reduced sum ofthirty now available for that purpose. It should nowbe sufficiently clear that this will only be the caseif the average length of the roundabout processes ofproduction and, therefore, in our instance, also thenumber of successive stages of production, is increasedin the same proportion as the demand for intermediateproducts has increased relatively to the demand forconsumers' goods, i.e., from an average of two to anaverage of three (or from an actual number of four toan actual number of six) stages of production. Whenthe transition is completed, the structure of productionwill have changed from that shown in Fig. 2 to the oneshown in Fig. 3. (It should be remembered that therelative magnitudes in the two figures are valuesexpressed in money and not physical quantities, thatthe amount of original means of production used hasremained the same, and that the amount of moneyin circulation and its velocity of circulation are alsosupposed to remain unchanged.)

If we compare the two diagrams, we see at once thatthe nature of the change consists in a stretching of themoney stream flowing from the consumers' goods tothe original means of production. It has, so to speak,become longer and narrower. Its breadth at thebottom stage, which measures the amount of moneyspent during a period of time on consumers' goods and,

Page 64: Prices and Production (1931) - F. A. Hayek

PRICES AND PRODUCTION

ORIGINAL MEANS OF PRODUCTION

I ii I

= 86 =

I

I129

21 **

257-

30o

OUTPUT OF CONSUMERS GOODSFIG. 3.

Page 65: Prices and Production (1931) - F. A. Hayek

CONSUMERS' AND PRODUCERS' GOODS 53

at the same time, the amount of money received asincome in payment for the use of the factors of produc-tion, has permanently decreased from forty to thirty.This means that the price of a unit of the factors ofproduction, the total amount of which (if we neglectthe increase of capital) has remained the same, willfall in the same proportion, and the price of a unit ofconsumers' goods, the output of which has increasedas a consequence of the more capitalistic methods ofproduction, will fall in still greater proportion. Theamount of money spent in each of the later stages ofproduction has also decreased, while the amount usedin the earlier stages has increased, and the total spenton intermediate products has increased also becauseof the addition of a new stage of production.1

Now it should be clear that to this change in thedistribution of the amounts of money spent in thedifferent stages of production there will corresponda similar change in the distribution of the total amountof goods existing at any moment. It should also beclear that the effect thus realised,—given the assump-tions we are making,—is one which fulfils the objectof saving and investing, and is identical with the effectwhich would have been produced if the savings weremade in kind instead of in money. Whether it has been

1 To avoid misunderstandings I have now substituted the terms" earlier" and " later" stages used by Professor Taussig in thisconnection, for the expression " higher" and " lower" which areunequivocal only with reference to the diagrams but are liable tobe confused with such expressions as " highly finished " products,particularly as A. Marshall has used the terms in this reverse sense(cf. Industry and Trade, p. 219).

Page 66: Prices and Production (1931) - F. A. Hayek

54 PRICES AND PRODUCTION

brought about in the most expeditious way, andwhether the price changes which follow from ourassumptions provide a suitable stimulus to the re-adjustment are not questions with which we needconcern ourselves at this juncture. Our presentpurpose is fulfilled if we have established, that underthe assumptions we have made, the initial variationin the proportional demand for consumers' goods andfor intermediate products respectively becomes perman-ent, that a new equilibrium may establish itself on thisbasis, and that the fact that the amount of moneyremains unchanged, in spite of the increase of theoutput of consumers' goods and of the still greaterincrease of the total turnover of goods of all kinds andstages, offers no fundamental difficulties to such anincrease of production, since total expenditure on thefactors of production, or total costs, will still be coveredby the sums received out of the sales of consumers' goods.

But now the question arises : does this remaintrue if we drop the assumptions that the amount ofmoney remains unchanged and that, during the processof production, the intermediate products are exchangedagainst money at equal intervals of time ?

(10) Let us begin by investigating the effects of achange in the amount of money in circulation. Itwill be sufficient if we investigate only the case mostfrequently to be encountered in practice : the case ofan increase of money in the form of credits granted toproducers. Again we shall find it convenient to startfrom the situation depicted in Fig. 2 and to suppose

Page 67: Prices and Production (1931) - F. A. Hayek

CONSUMERS' AND PRODUCERS' GOODS 55

that the same change in the proportion between thedemand for consumers' goods and the demand forintermediate products, which, in the earlier instance,was supposed to be produced by voluntary saving,is now caused by the granting of additional credits toproducers. For this purpose, the producers mustreceive an amount of forty in additional money. Aswill be seen from Fig. 4, the changes in the structureof production which will be necessary in order to findemployment for the additional means which havebecome available will exactly correspond to the changesbrought about by saving. The total services of theoriginal means of production will now be expendedin six instead of in four periods; the total value ofintermediate goods produced in the different stagesduring a period will have grown to three times insteadof twice as large as the value of consumers' goodsproduced during the same period ; and the output ofeach stage of production, including the final one,measured in physical units will accordingly be exactly asgreat as in the case represented in Fig. 3. The onlydifference at first apparent is that the money values ofthese goods have grown by one-third compared withthe situation depicted in Fig. 3.

There is, however, another and far more importantdifference which will become apparent only with thelapse of time. When a change in the structure ofproduction was brought about by saving, we werejustified in assuming that the changed distribution ofdemand between consumers' poods and producers' goods

Page 68: Prices and Production (1931) - F. A. Hayek

i

Ifa

PRICES AND PRODUCTION

ORIGINAL MEANS OF PRODUCTION

111

22B

286

.343

40o

OUTPUT OF CONSUMERS GOODSFIG. 4.

Page 69: Prices and Production (1931) - F. A. Hayek

CONSUMERS' AND PRODUCERS' GOODS 57

would remain permanent, since it was the effect ofvoluntary decisions on the part of individuals. Onlybecause a number of individuals had decided to spenda smaller share of their total money receipts onconsumption and a larger share on production wasthere any change in the structure of production. Andsince, after the change had been completed, thesepersons would get a greater proportion of the increasedtotal real income, they would have no reason again toincrease the proportion of their money receipts spentfor consumption.1 There would accordingly exist noinherent cause for a return to the old proportions.

In the same way, in the case we are now considering,the use of a larger proportion of the original means of •production for the manufacture of intermediateproducts can only be brought about by a retrenchmentof consumption. But now this sacrifice is not volun-tary, and is not made by those who will reap the benefitfrom the new investments. It is made by consumersin general who, because of the increased competitionfrom the entrepreneurs who have received the addi-tional money, are forced to forego part of what they usedto consume. It comes about not because they want toconsume less, but because they get less goods for theirmoney income. There can be no doubt that, if theirmoney receipts should rise again, they would immedi-ately attempt to expand consumption to the usualproportion. We shall see in the next lecture why,

1 It is important to bear in mind that, though the total moneyincome would diminish, the total real income would increase.

Page 70: Prices and Production (1931) - F. A. Hayek

58 PRICES AND PRODUCTION

in time, their receipts will rise as a consequence of theincrease of money in circulation. For the momentlet us assume that this happens. But if it does,then at once the money stream will be re-distributedbetween consumptive and productive uses accordingto the wishes of the individual concerned, and theartificial distribution, due to the injection of the newmoney, will, partly at any rate, be reversed. If weassume that the old proportions are adhered to, then thestructure of production too will have to return to theold proportion, as shown in Fig. 5. That is to sayproduction will become less capitalistic, and that partof the new capital which was sunk in equipmentadapted only to the more capitalistic processes will belost. We shall see in the next lecture that such atransition to less capitalistic methods of productionnecessarily takes the form of an economic crisis.

But it is not necessary that the proportion betweenthe demand for consumers' goods and the demandfor intermediate products should return exactly toits former dimensions as soon as the injection ofnew money ceases. In so far as the entrepreneurshave already succeeded, with the help of the additionalmoney, in completing the new processes of longerduration,1 they will, perhaps, receive increased money

1 It should, however, be remembered that a process cannot beregarded as completed in this sense, just because an entrepreneurat any one stage of production has succeeded in completing his sectionof it. A complete process, in the sense in which this concept is usedin the text, comprises all the stages of any one line of production,whether they are part of one firm or divided between several. I havefurther elaborated this point in my article on " Capital and IndustrialFluctuations", Econometrica, April, 1934.

Page 71: Prices and Production (1931) - F. A. Hayek

CONSUMERS' AND PRODUCERS' GOODS 59

returns for their output which will put them in a positionto continue the new processes, i.e., to expend perman-ently a larger share of their money receipts upon

ORIGINAL MEANS OF PRODUCTION

53?

OUTPUT OF CONSUMERS GOODSFIG. 5.

intermediate products without reducing their ownconsumption. It is only in consequence of the pricechanges caused by the increased demand for consumers'goods that, as we shall see, these processes too becomeunprofitable.

Page 72: Prices and Production (1931) - F. A. Hayek

60 PRICES AND PRODUCTION

But for the producers who work on a process wherethe transition to longer roundabout processes is notyet completed when the amount of money ceases toincrease the situation is different. They have spentthe additional money which put them in a positionto increase their demand for producers' goods and inconsequence it has become consumers' income ; theywill, therefore, no longer be able to claim a larger shareof the available producers' goods, and they will accord-ingly have to abandon the attempt to change over tomore capitalistic methods of production.

(n) All this becomes easier to follow if we considerthe simpler case in which an increase in demand forconsumers' goods of this sort is brought about directlyby additional money given to consumers. In recentyears, in the United States, Messrs. Foster and Catch-ings have urged that, in order to make possible the saleof an increased amount of consumers' goods producedwith the help of new savings, consumers must receivea proportionately larger money income. What wouldhappen if their proposals were carried out ? If westart with the situation which would establish itselfas a consequence of new savings if the amount ofmoney remained unchanged (as shown in Fig. 3), andthen assume that consumers receive an additionalamount of money sufficient to compensate for the rela-tive increase of the demand for intermediate productscaused by the savings (i.e., an amount of 15) and spend iton consumers' goods, we get a situation in which the pro-portion between the demand for consumers' goods, and

Page 73: Prices and Production (1931) - F. A. Hayek

CONSUMERS' AND PRODUCERS' GOODS 61

the demand for producers' goods, which, in consequenceof the new savings, had changed from 40:80 to 30:90or from 1:2 to 1:3 would again be reduced to 45:90

ORIGINAL MEANS OF PRODUCTION

fcfUJ

== 9 =

27

36

OUTPUT OF CONSUMERS GOODSFIG. 6.

or 1:2. That this would mean a return to the lesscapitalistic structure of production which existedbefore the new savings were made, and that the onlyeffect of such an increase of consumers' money incomes

Page 74: Prices and Production (1931) - F. A. Hayek

62 PRICES AND PRODUCTION

would be to frustrate the effect of saving followsclearly from Fig. 6. (The difference from the originalsituation depicted in Fig. 2 is again only a difference inmoney values and not a difference in the physicalquantities of goods produced or in their distributionto the different stages of production.)

(12) It is now time to leave this subject and to passon to the last problem with which I have to deal in thislecture. I wish now to drop the second of my originalassumptions, the assumption, namely, that during theprocess of production the intermediate products areexchanged against money between the firms at succes-sive stages of production in equal intervals. Insteadof this very artificial assumption, we may consider twopossible alternatives: we may suppose (a) that inany line of production the whole process is completedby a single firm, so that no other money payments takeplace than the payments for consumers' goods and thepayments for the use of the factors of production :or we may suppose (b) that exchanges of intermediateproducts take place, but at very irregular intervals,so that in some parts of the process the goods remainfor several periods of time in the possession of one andthe same firm, while in other parts of the process .theyare exchanged once or several times during each period.

(13) (a) Let us consider first the case in which thewhole process of production in any line of productionis completed by a single firm. Once again we may useFig. 1 to illustrate what happens. In this case the baseof the triangle represents the total payments for con-sumers' goods and the hypotenuse (or, more correctly,

Page 75: Prices and Production (1931) - F. A. Hayek

CONSUMERS' AND PRODUCERS' GOODS 63

its horizontal projection) represents the amounts ofmoney paid for the original means of production used.No other payments would be made and any amountof money received from the sale of consumers' goodscould immediately be spent for original means of pro-duction. It is of fundamental importance to rememberthat we can assume only that any single line of produc-tion is in this way integrated into one big firm. Itwould be entirely inappropriate in this connection tosuppose that the production of all goods is concentratedin one enterprise. For, if this were the case, of coursethe manager of this firm could, like the economicdictator of a communistic society, arbitrarily decidewhat part of the available means of production shouldbe applied to the production of consumers' goods andwhat part to the production of producers' goods.There would exist for him no reason to borrow and,for individuals, no opportunity to invest savings.Only if different firms compete for the available meansof production will saving and investing in the ordinarysense of the word take place, and it is therefore sucha situation which we must make the starting point ofour investigation.

Now, if any of these integrated industries decidesto save and invest part of its profits in order to intro-duce more capitalistic methods of production, it mustnot immediately pay out the sums saved for originalmeans of production. As the transition to morecapitalistic methods of production means that it willbe longer until the consumers' goods produced by the

Page 76: Prices and Production (1931) - F. A. Hayek

64 PRICES AND PRODUCTION

new process are ready, the firm will need the sumssaved to pay wages, etc., during the interval of timebetween the sale of the last goods produced by theold process, and the getting ready of the first goodsproduced by the new process. So that, during the wholeperiod of transition, it must pay out less to consumersthan it receives in order to be able to bridge the gapat the end of this period, when it has nothing to sellbut has to continue to pay wages and rent. Onlywhen the new product comes on the market and there isno need for further saving will it again currently payout all its receipts.

In this case, therefore, the demand for consumers'goods, as expressed in money, will be only temporarilyreduced, while in the case where the process of produc-tion was divided between a number of independentstages of equal length, the reduction of the amountavailable for the purchase of consumers' goods was apermanent one. In the present case, the prices ofthe consumers' goods will, accordingly, fall only ininverse proportions as their quantity has increased,while the total paid as income for the use of thefactors of production will remain the same. Theseconclusions are, however, only provisional as they donot take account of the relative position of the onefirm considered to all other firms which will certainlybe affected by a change of relative prices and interestrates which are necessarily connected with such aprocess. Unfortunately, these influences are toocomplicated to allow of treatment within the scope

Page 77: Prices and Production (1931) - F. A. Hayek

CONSUMERS' AND PRODUCERS' GOODS 65

of these lectures, and I must ask you, therefore, tosuspend judgment upon the ultimate effects of the pricechanges which will take place under these conditions.

But there is one point to which I must particularlydirect your attention : The reason in this case whythe unchanged amount of money used in productionremains sufficient, in spite of the fact that a largeramount of intermediate products now exists, whereasin the former case, the use of an increased amountof intermediate products required the use of an increasedquantity of money is this. In the former case theintermediate products passed from one stage of produc-tion to the next by an exchange against money. Butin the present case this exchange is replaced by internalbarter, which makes money unnecessary. Of course,our division of the continuous process of productioninto separate stages of equal length is entirely arbitrary :it would be just as natural to divide it into stages ofdifferent lengths and then speak of these stages asexhibiting so many more or less instances of internalbarter. But the procedure which has been adoptedserves to bring out a concept, which I shall need in alater lecture, the concept of the relative volume of theflow of goods during any period of time, as comparedwith the amount of goods exchanged against moneyin the same period. If we divide the path traversedby the elements of any good from the first expenditureof original means of production until it gets in the handsof the final consumer into unit periods, and thenmeasure the quantities of goods which pass each of these

Page 78: Prices and Production (1931) - F. A. Hayek

66 PRICES AND PRODUCTION

lines of division during a period of time, we securea comparatively simple measure of the flow of goodswithout having recourse to higher mathematics. Thus,we may say that, in the instance we have been consider-ing, money has become more efficient in moving goods,in the sense that a given amount of exchanges againstmoney has now become /sufficient to make possible themovement of a greater volume1 of goods than before.

(14) (b) Perhaps this somewhat difficult conceptbecomes more intelligible if I illustrate it by supposingthat two of the independent firms which we havesupposed to represent the successive stages of produc-tion in our diagrams 2 and 6 are combined into onefirm. This is the second of the alternative possibili-ties I set out to consider. Once this has happened,the passage of the intermediate products from the oneto the next stage of production will take place withoutmoney payments being necessary, and the flow of goodsfrom the moment they enter the earlier of the twostages until they leave the later will be effected by somuch less money. A corresponding amount of moneywill thus be released and may be used for other pur-poses. The reverse effect will, of course, be witnessed

1 Even if this total of goods moving towards consumptionduring each period is not actually exchanged against money in eachperiod, it is not an imaginary, but a real and important magnitude,since the value of this total is a magnitude which continually restswithin our power to determine. It probably stands in close relationto what is commonly called free capital, and it is certainly the supplyof this factor which—together with new saving—determines therate of interest; the capital which remains invested in durableinstruments affects the interest rate from the demand side only,i.e., by influencing opportunities for new investment.

Page 79: Prices and Production (1931) - F. A. Hayek

CONSUMERS' AND PRODUCERS' GOODS 67

if the two firms separate again. An increased amountof money payments will be required to effect the samemovement of goods and the proportion of moneypayments to the flow of goods advancing towardsconsumption will have increased.

(15) Unfortunately, all names which might be usedto designate this kind of monetary effectiveness havealready been appropriated for designating differentconcepts of the velocity of money. Until somebodyfinds a fitting term, therefore, we shall have to speaksomewhat clumsily of the proportion between theamount of goods exchanged against money and thetotal flow of goods or of the proportion of the totalmovements of goods which is effected by exchangeagainst money.

Now this proportion must on no account be con-fused with the proportion of the volume of moneypayments to the physical volume of trade. Theproportion I have in mind may remain the same whilethe volume of trade increases relatively to the totalof money payments and the price level falls, if onlythe same proportion of the total flow of goods is ex-changed against money, and it may change thoughthe proportion of the total of money payments to thephysical volume of trade remains the same. It is,therefore, not necessarily influenced either by changesin the amount of money or by changes in the physicalvolume of trade; it depends only upon whether, incertain phases of the process of production, goods do ordo not change hands.

Page 80: Prices and Production (1931) - F. A. Hayek

68 PRICES AND PRODUCTION

So far I have illustrated this concept only byinstances from the sphere of production. It may beapplied also to the sphere of consumption. Here, too,sometimes a larger and sometimes a smaller shareof the total output of consumers' goods is exchangedfor money before it is consumed. Accordingly, here,too, we may speak about the proportion which the totaloutput of consumers' goods in a period of time bearsto the output which is sold for money. And thisproportion may be different in the different stagesof production. But in its effect upon the structure ofproduction, the efficiency of a given amount of moneyspent in any stage of production (including the laststage—consumption) is determined by the proportionin that stage; and any change in that proportion hasthe same effects as an alteration in the amount of moneyspent in this particular stage of production.

So much for the complications which arise when wedrop the assumption that production is carried on inindependent stages of equal length. It has beennecessary to discuss them here at some length in orderto clear the way for an investigation, into which Iwish to enter in the last lecture, in connection withthe arguments for and against an elastic money supply.But for the tasks which I shall have to face tomorrow,it will be expedient again to make use of the simplestassumption and to suppose that production is carriedon in independent stages of equal length, as we didin our schematic representations, and that this pro-portion is not only the same in all stages of production,but also that it remains constant over time.

Page 81: Prices and Production (1931) - F. A. Hayek

LECTURE III

THE WORKING OF THE PRICE MECHANISM

IN THE COURSE OF THE CREDIT CYCLE

" The first effect of the increase of productive activity,initiated by the policy of the banks to lend below the naturalrate of interest is . . . to raise the prices of producers'goods while the prices of consumers' goods rise only moderately. . . But soon a reverse movement sets in : prices ofconsumers' goods rise and prices of producers' goods fall,i.e., the loan rate rises and approaches again the natural rateof interest."

L. v. MISES,Theorie des Geldes und der Utnlaufsmittel, 1912, p. 431.

(1) In the last lecture I dealt with the problems ofchanges in the structure of production consequentupon any transition to more or less capitalistic methodsof production, in terms of the total sums of moneyavailable for the purchase of the product of each stageof production. It might seem, therefore, that nowI come to the problem of explaining those changes inrelative prices which bring it about that goods aredirected to new uses—the central problem of theselectures1—the explanation should run in terms of sec-tional price levels, that is to say in terms of changes

1 As has already been mentioned in the first chapter, the effectsof a divergence between the money-rate and the equilibrium-rate ofinterest on relative prices were originally shortly discussed byProfessor Mises. On the actual working of the price mechanism

Page 82: Prices and Production (1931) - F. A. Hayek

70 PRICES AND PRODUCTION

in the price levels of the goods of the different stagesof production. But to do this would mean that atthis stage of the explanation I should fall back uponjust that method of using price averages which I con-demned at the outset.

At the same time, it should by now be clear that, atthis stage of the explanation, a treatment in terms ofprice averages would not be adequate to our purposes.What we have to explain is why certain goods which havethus far been used in one stage of production can nowbe more profitably used in another stage of production.Now this will only be the case if there are changes in theproportions in which the different producers' goodsmay be profitably used in any stage of production,and this in turn implies that there must be changes inthe prices offered for them in different stages of produc-tion.

which brings about the changes in the structure of production hiswork contains however hardly more than the sentences quotedat the beginning of this lecture. It seems that most people havefound them difficult to understand and that they have remainedcompletely unintelligible to all who were not very familiar withBohm-Bawerk's theory of interest on which they are based. Themain difficulty lies in Professor Mises' short statement that therise of the prices of consumers' goods is the cause of the crisis, whileit seems natural to assume that this would rather make productionmore profitable. This is the main point which I have here triedto clear up. So far the most exhaustive previous exposition of theseinter-relationships, which anticipates in some points what is saidin the following pages is to be found in R. Strigl, " Die Produktionunter dem Einfiuss einer Kreditexpansion", Schriften des Vereins furSozialpolitik, 173 '2 Munchen, 1928, particularly p. 203 et seq. Morerecently Professor Strigl has further developed his views on thesubject in a book, Kapital und Produktion, Vienna, 1934. Somereferences to earlier anticipations of the ideas developed in thislecture will now be found in an additional note at the end of thislecture.

Page 83: Prices and Production (1931) - F. A. Hayek

THE PRICE MECHANISM 71

(2) At this point, it is necessary to introduce the new1

distinction between producers' goods to which I alludedin the last lecture : the distinction between producers'goods which may be used in all, or at least, manystages of production, and producers' goods which canbe used only in one, or at the most, a few stages ofproduction. To the first class belong not only almostall original means of production, but also most rawmaterials and even a great many implements of a notvery specialised kind—knives, hammers, tongs, and soon.2 To the second class belong most highly special-ised kinds of machinery or complete manufacturingestablishments, and also all those kinds of semi-manufactured goods which can be turned into finishedgoods only by passing a definite number of furtherstages of production. By adapting a term of vonWieser's, we may call the producers' goods which canbe used only in one or a few stages of production,

1 Since the publication of the first edition of this book my atten-tion has been drawn to the fact that this distinction is clearlyimplied in some of Bdhm-Bawerk's discussions of these problems.Qf. his Positive Theorie des Kapitalzinses (third edit.), pp. 195 and 199.

2 This class will, in particular, comprise most of the goods whichat one and the same time belong to different stages. " Of course ",says Marshall (Principles, first edit., p. iogn.), " a good many belongto several orders at the same time. For instance, a railway trainmay be carrying people on a pleasure excursion, and so far it is agood of the first order ; if it happens to be carrying at the same timesome tins of biscuits, some milling machinery and some machinerythat is used for making milling machinery, it is at the same time agood of the second, third and fourth order." In cases like this atransfer of its services from a later to an earlier stage (or, to U9eMenger's terminology, from a lower to a higher order) is, of course,particularly easy. A plant manufacturing equipment for the produc-tion of consumers' goods as well as for the production of furthermachinery will sometimes be used mainly for the former and some-times mainly for the latter purpose.

Page 84: Prices and Production (1931) - F. A. Hayek

72 PRICES AND PRODUCTION

producers' goods of a specific character, or moreshortly " specific " go'ods, to distinguish them fromproducers' goods of a more general applicability,which we may call " non-specific " goods.1 Of course,this distinction is not absolute, in the sense that we arealways in a position to say whether a certain good isspecific or not. But we should be able' to say whetherany given good is more or less specific as comparedwith another good.

(3) It is clear that producers' goods of the same kindwhich are used in different stages of production cannot,for any length of time, bring in different returns or obtaindifferent prices in these different stages. On the otherhand, it is no less clear that temporary differences betweenthe prices offered in the different stages of production arethe only means of bringing about a shift of producers'goods from one stage to another. If such a temporarydifference in the relative attractiveness of the differentstages of production arises, the goods in question willbe shifted from the less to the more attractive stagesuntil, by the operation of the principle of diminishingreturns the differences have been wiped out.

Now, if we neglect the possibility of changes intechnical knowledge, which may change the usefulnessof any particular producers' goods, it is obvious thatthe immediate cause of a change in the return obtainedfrom producers' goods of a certain kind used in differentstages of production must be a change in the price of

1 Cf. Fried rich von Wieser, Social Economics, translated by A.Ford Hinrichs, New York, 1927, Book I, Chap. 15.

Page 85: Prices and Production (1931) - F. A. Hayek

THE PRICE MECHANISM 73

the product of the stage of production in question.But what is it which brings about variations of therelative price of such products ? At first glance itmight seem improbable that the prices of the successivestages of one and the same line of production shouldever fluctuate relatively to one another because theyare equally dependent upon the price of the finalproduct. But, having regard to what was said in thelast lecture concerning the possibility of shifts betweenthe demand for consumers' goods and the demand forproducers' goods, and the consequent changes in therelation between the amount of original means of pro-duction expended and the output of consumers' goods,and how an elongation of the process of productionincreases the return from a given quantity of originalmeans of production—this point should present nodifficulty.

Now so far I have not expressly referred to the pricemargins which arise out of these relative fluctuationsof the prices of the products of successive stages ofproduction. This has been because I have intention-ally neglected interest, or, what amounts to the samething, I have treated interest as if it were a paymentfor a definitely given factor of production, like wagesor rent. In a state of equilibrium these margins areentirely absorbed by interest. Hence my assumptionconcealed the fact that the total amount of moneyreceived for the product of any stage will regularlyexceed the total paid out for all goods and servicesused in this stage of production. Yet that margins

Page 86: Prices and Production (1931) - F. A. Hayek

74 PRICES AND PRODUCTION

of this kind must exist is obvious from the considera-tion that, if it were not so, there would exist noinducement to risk money by investing it in productionrather than let it remain idle. To investigate the rela-tionship of these margins to the peculiar advantagesof the roundabout methods of production would leadus too far into the problems of the general theory ofinterest. We must therefore be content to acceptit as one of the definite conclusions of this theory that—other things remaining the same—these marginsmust grow smaller as the roundabout processes of pro-duction increase in length and vice versa. There isone point, however, which we cannot take for granted.The fact that in a state of equilibrium those pricemargins and the amounts paid as interest coincidedoes not prove that the same will also be true in a periodof transition from one state of equilibrium to another.On the contrary, the relation between these twomagnitudes must form one of the main objects of ourfurther investigations.

The close interrelation between these two pheno-mena suggests two different modes of approach to ourproblem: Either we may start from the changes inthe relative magnitude of the demand for consumers'goods and the demand for producers' goods, andexamine the effects on the prices of individual goodsand the rate of interest; or we may start from thechanges in the rate of interest as an immediate effectof the change in the demand for producers' goods andwork up to the changes in the price system which are

Page 87: Prices and Production (1931) - F. A. Hayek

THE PRICE MECHANISM 75

necessary to establish a new equilibrium betweenprice margins and the rate of interest. It will be foundthat whichever of these two alternatives we choose asa starting point, our investigation will, in the end,lead us to those aspects of the problem which are thestarting point for the other. For the purposes of thislecture, I choose the first as being more in line withmy previous argument.

(4) I begin, as I began in the last lecture, with thesupposition that consumers decide to save and investa larger proportion of their income. The immediateeffect of the increase in the demand for producers'goods and the decrease in demand for consumers'goods will be that there will be a relative rise in theprices of the former and a relative fall in the prices ofthe latter. But the prices of producers' goods will notrise equally, nor will they rise without exception.In the stage of production immediately precedingthat in which the final touches are given to consumers'goods, the effect of the fall in the prices of consumers'goods will be felt more strongly than the effect of theincrease of the funds available for the purchase ofproducers' goods of all kinds. The price of the productof this stage will, therefore, fall, but it will fall less thanthe prices of consumers' goods. This means a narrow-ing of the price margin between the last two stages.But this narrowing of the price margin will make theemployment of funds in the last stage less profitablerelatively to the earlier stages, and therefore some ofthe funds which had been used there will tend to be

Page 88: Prices and Production (1931) - F. A. Hayek

76 PRICES AND PRODUCTION

shifted to the earlier stages. This shift of funds willtend to narrow the price margins in the precedingstages, and the tendency thus set up towards a cumu-lative rise of the prices of the products of the earlierstages will very soon overcome the tendency towardsa fall. In other words, the rise of the price of the pro-duct of any stage of production will give an extraadvantage to the production of the preceding stage, theproducts of which will not only rise in price becausethe demand for producers' goods in general has risen,but also because, by the rise of prices in the precedingstages, profits to be obtained in this stage have becomecomparatively higher than in the later stages. Thefinal effect will be that, through the fall of prices in thelater stages of production and the rise of prices in theearlier stages of production, price margins betweenthe different stages of production will have decreasedall round.

This change of relative prices in the different stagesof production must inevitably tend to effect the pros-pects of profits in the different stages, and this, in turn,will tend to cause changes in the use made of theavailable producers' goods. A greater proportionof those producers' goods which can be used in differentstages of production—the non-specific goods—willnow be attracted to the earlier stages, where, sincethe change in the rate of saving, relatively higher pricesare to be obtained. And the shifting of goods andservices of this type will go on until the diminutionof returns in these stages has equalised the profits

Page 89: Prices and Production (1931) - F. A. Hayek

78 PRICES AND PRODUCTION

on the other hand, the good belongs to a relativelyearly stage of production, its price and the amountof it produced will increase. At the same time, theadditional stages of production which have beenstarted as a consequence of this transition to morecapitalistic methods of production will probablyrequire new goods of a specific character. Some ofthese will be new products, some natural resourceswhich formerly it was not profitable to use.

Exactly the reverse of all these changes will takeplace if the demand for consumers' goods increasesrelatively to the demand for producers' gocds. Thiswill cause not only an increase of the difference betweenthe prices of consumers' goods or products of the}ast stage of production, and the prices of the productsof the previous stage, but also an all round increaseof the price margins between the products of thesuccessive stages of production. Prices in the laterstages will rise relatively to prices in the earlier stages,producers' goods of a non-specific character will movefrom the earlier stages to the later, and the goodsof specific character in the earlier stages of productionwill lose part of their value or become entirely useless,while those in the later stages of production willincrease in value. I shall discuss certain exceptionsto this parallelism later on.

It will, perhaps, facilitate the understanding ofthese complications if we think of production in itssuccessive stages as a fan, the sticks of which corre-spond to the prices of the different stages. If more

Page 90: Prices and Production (1931) - F. A. Hayek

T H E P R I C E MECHANISM J>J

to be made in all stages. In the end, the returnsand the prices obtained for these goods in the differentstages of production will be generally higher and alarger proportion of them will be used in the earlierstages of production than before. The generalnarrowing of the price margins between the stages ofproduction will even make it possible to start produc-tion in new and more distant stages which have notbeen profitable before, and in this way, not only theaverage time which elapses between the applicationof the first unit of original mean of production andthe completion of the final product, but also theabsolute length of the process of pioduction—thenumber of its stages—will be increased.1

But while the effect on the prices of non-specificproducers' goods has been a general rise, the effecton the prices of goods of a more specific character—those goods which can only be used in one or a very fewstages of production—will be different. If a goodof this sort is only adapted to a comparatively latestage of production, the relative deficiency of thenon-specific producers' goods required in the samestage of production will lower its return, and if it isitself a product, its production will be curtailed. If,

1 This lengthening of the structure of production need, however,by no means take exclusively or even mainly the form that themethods used in any individual line of production are changed.The increased prices in the earlier stages of production (the loweredrate of interest) will favour production in the lines using muchcapital and lead to their expansion art the expense of the lines usingless capital. In this way the aggregate length of the investmentstructure of society might in the extreme case take place withouta change of the method employed in any one line of production.

Page 91: Prices and Production (1931) - F. A. Hayek

THE PRICE MECHANISM 79

demand is concentrated towards the one extreme—consumers' goods—the fan opens, the differencesbetween the stages become larger, and goods gravitatetowards the stages where higher prices are obtained,that is, towards the stages nearer consumption. Themost distant stages are abandoned, and within theremaining stages more goods are concentrated towardthe one end. The opening of the price fan is thusaccompanied by a reduction of the number of stagesof production, i.e., of the number of sticks.1 If, how-ever, a shift of demand from consumers' goods towardsproducers' goods takes place, the price fan will close,i.e., the differences between the stages will becomesmaller and goods will tend to gravitate towards thehigher stages where prices are now relatively higher,and new and hitherto unused possibilities of furtherextension of the process of production will be exploited.The closing of the price fan has brought a greaternumber of stages of production within the range ofpractical possibilities and thus initiated the transitionto longer roundabout methods of production.

(5) A more exact representation of this process canbe given by means of a diagram. This has the specialadvantage of making quite clear a point which is ofconsiderable importance but on which a merely verbalexplanation is likely to mislead. It is necessary in such

1 At this point the simile becomes liable to mislead and it isimportant to keep in mind all the time that the " fan " refers toprice relationships only, but that the length of the structure ofproduction will move in the reverse direction compared with thewidth of the fan. When the price fan opens, the structure ofproduction is shortened, and vice versa.

Page 92: Prices and Production (1931) - F. A. Hayek

8o PRICES AND PRODUCTION

an exposition, if one wants to avoid too cumbersomeexpressions, to speak of actual changes in the relativeprices of goods in the different stages, where it wouldbe more correct to speak of tendencies towards such achange, or of changes in the demand function for theparticular commodity. Whether and to what extentsuch changes in demand will lead to an actual changein price will of course depend on the elasticity of supply,which in the particular case depends in turn in everystage on the degree of specificity of the intermediateproducts and the factors from which they are made.

The way in which this shifting of the demand curvesfor any single factor in the different stages of productionoperates can be illustrated in the following way. Inthe diagram below the successive curves representthe marginal productivity of different quantities of onefactor in the successive stages of production, the earlierstages being shown on the left and the later stages to-wards the right. To make the main point come outclearer it has been assumed that the physical quantityof the product due to every additional unit of the factordecreases at the same rate in all stages and that in con-sequence the general shape of the curves is the same.

Price

QuantityFIG. 7.

Page 93: Prices and Production (1931) - F. A. Hayek

THE PRICE MECHANISM 81

The value of the marginal product attributable to eveiyunit of factors will, however, be equal to the value ofthe physical product which is due to it only in the verylast stage where no interval of time elapses between theinvestment of the factors and the completion of theproduct. If we assume, then, the curve on the rightto represent not only the physical magnitude but alsothe value of the marginal product of successive unitsof factors applied in that stage, the other curves repre-senting the physical marginal product of the factorsinvested in earlier stages will have to be somewhatadjusted if they are to represent the discounted value ofthe marginal product of successive units of factorsapplied in the respective stages. And if we assume thepoints to which these curves refer, to be equidistantstages as were those discussed before, the adjustmentnecessary at any given rate of interest can be shownby drawing a discount curve (or a family of discountcurves) connecting every point on the curve on theright with the corresponding points of the curves furtheron the left, and lowering each of these curves by theamount indicated by the discount curves. (Since everypoint on these curves will have to be adjusted separately,i.e., "will have to be lowered not by the same amountbut by the same percentage, this will involve a changenot only of the position but also of the shape of thesecurves.) The set of fully drawn curves in the abovediagram shows the position at a given rate of interestindicated by the one discount curve which is also fullydrawn. And since these curves show the discounted

Page 94: Prices and Production (1931) - F. A. Hayek

82 PRICES AND PRODUCTION

value of the marginal product of one kind of factorwhich must of course be the same in the differentstages of production, they enable us to determine howmuch of this factor will be used in every stage if eitherits price or the total quantity of it to be used in thisprocess are known. This distribution of the factorbetween the different stages at an arbitrarily assumedprice is shown by the fully drawn horizontal lines.

Assume now that the rate of interest is reduced.The new position is indicated by the dotted discountcurve and the correspondingly changed shape andposition of the marginal productivity curves for theindividual stages. Under these conditions the old dis-ti Ibution of factors between the stages would evidentlynot represent an equilibrium position but one at whichthe discounted value of the marginal product would bedifferent in every stage. And if the total quantity ofthe factor which is available remains the same thenew equilibrium distribution will apparently be oneat which not only the price of the factor will be higherbut at which also a considerably greater quantity ofit is used in the earlier stages and correspondingly lessin the later stages.

This accounts for the change in the price and the dis-tribution of factors which can be used in different stages.To what extent and in what proportion the prices ofdifferent factors will be affected by a given change inthe rate of interest will depend on the stages in whichthey can be used and on the shape of their marginalproductivity curves in these stages. The price of a

Page 95: Prices and Production (1931) - F. A. Hayek

THE PRICE MECHANISM 83

factor which can be used in most early stages and whosemarginal productivity there falls very slowly will risemore in consequence of a fall in the rate of interest thanthe price of a factor which can only be used in rela-tively lower stages of reproduction or whose marginalproductivity in the earlier stages falls very rapidly.

It is essentially this difference between the pricechanges of the different factors which accounts for thechanges of the relative prices of the intermediate pro-ducts at the successive stages. At first it might seemas if, since relative prices of the different intermediateproducts must correspond to their respective costs,they could change only to the relatively small extent towhich the direct interest element in their cost changes.But to think of interest only as a direct cost factor isto overlook its main influence on production. Whatis much more important is its effect on prices throughits effect on demand for the intermediate products andfor the factors from which they are produced. It isin consequence of these changes in demand and thechanges in cost which it brings about by raising theprices of those factors which are in strong demand inearly stages compared to those which are less demandedthere, that the prices of the intermediate products areadjusted.

(6) As the initial changes in relative prices whichare caused by a change of the relative demand forconsumers' goods and producers' goods give rise toa considerable shifting of goods to other stages of pro-duction, definite price relationships will only establish

Page 96: Prices and Production (1931) - F. A. Hayek

84 PRICES AND PRODUCTION

themselves after the movements of goods have beencompleted. For reasons which I shall consider in amoment, this process may take some time and involvetemporary discrepancies between supply and demand.But there is one medium through which the expectedultimate effect on relative prices should make itselffelt immediately, and which, accordingly, should serveas a guide for the decisions of the individual entre-preneur : the rate of interest on the loan market.Only in comparatively few-eases-will, the people whohave saved money and the people who want to useit in production be identical. In the majority ofcases, therefore, the money which is directed to newuses will first have to pass into other hands. Thequestion who is going to use the additional funds avail-able for investment in producers' goods will be decidedon the loan market. Only at a lower rate of interestthan that formerly prevailing will it be possible to lendthese funds, and how far the rate of interest will fallwill depend upon the amount of the additional fundsand the expectation of profits on the part of the entre-preneurs willing to expand their production. Ifthese entrepreneurs entertain correct views about theprice changes which are to be expected as a result ofthe changes in the method of production, the new rateof interest should correspond to the system of pricemargins which will ultimately be established. In thisway, from the outset, the use of the additional fundswhich have become available will be confined to thoseentrepreneurs who hope to obtain the highest profits

Page 97: Prices and Production (1931) - F. A. Hayek

THE PRICE MECHANISM 85

out of their use, and all extensions of production,for which the additional funds would not be sufficient,will be excluded.

(7) The significance of these adjustments of theprice mechanism comes out still more clearly when weturn to investigate what happens if the " natural"movement of prices is disturbed by movements in thesupply of money, whether by the injection of newmoney into circulation or by withdrawal of part ofthe money circulating. We may again take as ourtwo typical cases, (a) the case of additional moneyused first to buy producers' goods and (b) the case ofadditional money used first to buy consumers' goods.The corresponding cases of a diminution of the amountof money we may neglect because a diminution of thedemand for consumers' goods would have essentiallythe same effects as a proportional increase of thedemand for producers' goods, and vice versa.1 I havealready outlined in the last lecture the general ten-dencies involved in such cases. My present task is to fillin the details of that rough sketch and to show whathappens in the interval before a new equilibrium isattained.

As before, I commence with the supposition that theadditional money is injected by way of credits toproducers. To secure borrowers for this additionalamount of money, the rate of interest must be kept

1 As" I have tried to show in another place (Econometrica, April,I934» P- 164) it is even conceivable, although highly unlikely tooccur in practice, that hoarding of money income before spent onconsumers' goods, might give rise to some additional investment.

Page 98: Prices and Production (1931) - F. A. Hayek

86 PRICES AND PRODUCTION

sufficiently below the equilibrium rate to make pro-fitable the employment of just this sum and no more.Now the borrowers can only use the borrowed sumsfor buying producers' goods, and will only be ableto obtain such goods (assuming a state of equilibriumin which there are no unused resources) by outbiddingthe entrepreneurs who used them before. At first sightit might seem improbable that these borrowers who wereonly put in a position to start longer processes by thelower rate of interest should be able to outbid thoseentrepreneurs who found the use of those means of pro-duction profitable when the rate of interest was stillhigher. But when it is remembered that the fall in therate will also change the relative profitableness of thedifferent factors of production for the existing concerns,it will be seen to be quite natural that it should give arelative advantage to those concerns which use propor-tionately more capital. Such old concerns will now findit profitable to spend a part of what they previouslyspent on original means of production, on intermediateproducts produced by earlier stages of production,and in this way they will release some of the originalmeans of production they used before. The risein the prices of the original means of productionis an additional inducement. Of course it mightwell be that the entrepreneurs in question wouldbe in a better position to buy such goods even at thehigher prices, since they have done business whenthe rate of interest was higher, though it must notbe forgotten that they too will have to do business

Page 99: Prices and Production (1931) - F. A. Hayek

THE PRICE MECHANISM 87

on a smaller margin. But the fact that certain pro-ducers' goods have become dearer will make it profit-able for them to replace these goods by others. Inparticular, the changed proportion between the pricesof the original means of production and the rate ofinterest will make it profitable for them to spend partof what they have till now spent on original meansof production on intermediate products or capital.They will, e.g., buy parts of their products, which theyused to manufacture themselves, from another firm, andcan now employ the labour thus dismissed in orderto produce these parts on a large scale with the helpof new machinery. In other words, those originalmeans of production and non-specific producers'goods which are required in the new stages of produc-tion are set free by the transition of the old concernsto more capitalistic methods which is caused by theincrease in the prices of these goods. In the oldconcerns (as we may conveniently, but not quiteaccurately, call the processes of production which werein operation before the new money was injected) atransition to more capitalistic methods will take place ;but in all probability it will take place without anychange in their total resources: they will invest lessin original means of production and more in inter-mediate products.

Now, contrary to what we have found to be the casewhen similar processes are initiated by the investmentof new savings, this application of the original meansof production and non-specific intermediate products

Page 100: Prices and Production (1931) - F. A. Hayek

88 PRICES AND PRODUCTION

to longer processes of production will be effected withoutany preceding reduction of consumption. Indeed,for a time, consumption may even go on at an unchangedrate after the more roundabout processes have actuallystarted, because the goods which have already advancedto the lower stages of production, being of a highlyspecific character, will continue to come forward forsome little time. But this cannot go on. When thereduced output from the stages of production, fromwhich producers' goods have been withdrawn for usein higher stages, has matured into consumers' goods, ascarcity of consumers' goods will make itself felt, andthe prices of those goods will rise. Had saving precededthe change to methods of production of longer duration,a reserve of consumers' goods would have been accumu-lated in the form of increased stocks, which could nowbe sold at unreduced prices, and would thus serve tobridge the interval of time between the momentwhen the last products of the old shorter processcome on to the market and the moment when thefirst products of the new longer processes are ready.But as things are, for some time, society as a wholewill have to put up with an involuntary reduction ofconsumption.

But this necessity will be resisted. It is highlyimprobable that individuals should put up with anunforeseen retrenchment of their real income withoutmaking an attempt to overcome it by spending moremoney on consumption. It comes at the very momentwhen a great many entrepreneurs know themselves

Page 101: Prices and Production (1931) - F. A. Hayek

THE PRICE MECHANISM 89

to be in command—at least nominally—of greaterresources and expect greater profits. At the same timeincomes of wage earners will be rising in consequenceof the increased amount of money available for invest-ment by entrepreneurs. There can be little doubt thatin the face of rising prices of consumers' goods theseincreases will be spent on such goods and so contributeto drive up their prices even faster. These decisionswill not change the amount of consumers' goodsimmediately available, though it may change theirdistribution between individuals. But—and this isthe fundamental point—it will mean a new and reversedchange of the proportion between the demand for con-sumers' goods and the demand for producers' goods infavour of the former. The prices of consumers' goodswill therefore rise relatively to the prices of producers'goods. And this rise of the prices of consumers' goodswill be the more marked because it is the consequencenot only of an increased demand for consumers'goods but an increase in the demand as measured inmoney. All this must mean a return to shorter or lessroundabout methods of production if the increasein the demand for consumers' goods is not compensatedby a further proportional injection of money by newbank loans granted to producers. And at first this isprobable. The rise of the prices of consumers' goodswill offer prospects of temporary extra profits toentrepreneurs. They will be the more ready to borrowat the prevailing rate of interest. And, so long as thebanks go on progressively increasing their loans it will,

Page 102: Prices and Production (1931) - F. A. Hayek

90 PRICES AND PRODUCTION

therefore, be possible to continue the prolongedmethods of production or perhaps even to extendthem still further. But for obvious reasons the bankscannot continue indefinitely to extend credits; andeven if they could, the other effects of a rapid andcontinuous rise of prices would, after a while, make itnecessary to stop this process of inflation.1

Let us assume that for some time, perhaps a yearor two, the banks, by keeping their rate of interestbelow the equilibrium rate, have expanded credit,and now find themselves compelled to stop furtherexpansion. What will happen ? (Perhaps it shouldbe mentioned at this point that the processes I shallnow describe are processes which would also take placeif existing capital is encroached upon, or if, in a pro-gressive sc ̂ iety, after a temporary increase in saving, therate should suddenly fall to its former level. Such cases,however, are probably quantitatively less important.)

Now we know from what has been said alreadythat the immediate effect of the banks ceasing toadd to their loans is that the absolute increase ofthe amount of money spent on consumers' goods isno longer compensated by a proportional increasein the demand for producers' goods. The demand forconsumers' goods will for some time continue to increasebecause it will necessarily always lag somewhat behind

1 For a fuller discussion of the reasons why this process ofexpansion must ultimately come to an end, whether the banks arerestricted by reserve regulations, etc., or not, and of some of thepoints alluded to in the next paragraphs, see my article on " Capitaland Industrial Fluctuations", Econometrica, April, 1934, p. 161.

Page 103: Prices and Production (1931) - F. A. Hayek

THE PRICE MECHANISM 91

the additional expenditure on investment which causesthe increase of money incomes. The effects of sucha change will, therefore, be similar to what wouldhappen in the second case we have to consider, the caseof an increase of money by consumers' credits. Atthis point, -accordingly, the two cases can be coveredby one discussion.

(8) Speaking generally, it might be -said that theeffects of a relative increase in the demand for con-sumers' goods are the reverse of the effects of anincrease in the relative demand for producers' goods.There are, however, two important differences whichmake a detailed account necessary.

The first effect of the rise of the prices of consumers'goods is that the spread between them and the prices ofthe goods of the preceding stage becomes greater thanthe price margins in the higher stages of production.The greater profits to be obtained in this stage will causeproducers' goods in use elsewhere which may be usedin this stage to be transferred to it, and the all roundincrease of price margins between the stages of produc-tion which will follow will cause a widespread transferof non-specific producers' goods to lower stages. Thenew demand for these goods will cause a relative riseof their prices, and this rise will tend to be considerablebecause, as we have seen, there will be a temporaryrise in the price of consumers' goods, due to the transientdiscrepancy between demand and supply, greater thanwill be the case after the supply of consumers' goodshas caught up with demand. These temporary

Page 104: Prices and Production (1931) - F. A. Hayek

92 PRICES AND PRODUCTION

scarcity prices of consumers' goods will, furthermore,have the effect that at first production will tend toshrink to fewer stages than will be necessary afterequilibrium prices of consumers' goods have estab-lished themselves.

Very soon the relative rise of the prices of theoriginal factors and the more mobile intermediateproducts will make the longer processes unprofitable.The first effect on these processes will be that theproducers' goods of a more specific character, whichhave become relatively abundant by reason of thewithdrawal of the complementary non-specific goods,will fall in price. The fall of the prices of these goodswill make their production unprofitable; it will inconsequence be discontinued. Although goods in laterstages of production will generally be of a highly specificcharacter, it may still pay to employ original factors tocomplete those that are nearly finished. But the fall inthe price of intermediate products will be cumula-tive; and this will mean a fairly sudden stoppage ofwork in at least all the earlier stages of the longerprocesses.

But while the non-specific goods, in particular theservices of workmen employed in those earlier stages,have thus been thrown out of use because their amounthas proved insufficient and their prices too high for theprofitable carrying through of the long processes ofproduction, it is by no means certain that all thosewhich can no longer be used in the old processes canimmediately be absorbed in the short processes which

Page 105: Prices and Production (1931) - F. A. Hayek

THE PRICE MECHANISM 93

are being expanded. Quite the contrary ; the shorterprocesses will have to be started at the very beginningand will only gradually absorb all the available pro-ducers' goods as the product progresses towards con-sumption and as the necessary intermediate productscome forward. So that, while, in the longer processes,productive operations cease almost as soon as the changein relative prices of specific and non-specific goods infavour of the latter and the rise of the rate of interestmake them unprofitable, the released goods will findnew employment only as the new shorter processes areapproaching completion.1 Moreover, the final adapta-tion will be further retarded by initial uncertainty asregards the methods of production which will ultimatelyprove profitable once the temporary scarcity of con-sumers' goods has disappeared. Entrepreneurs, quiterightly, will hesitate to make investments suited tothis overshortened process, i.e., investments whichwould enable them to produce with relatively littlecapital and a relatively great quantity of the originalmeans of production.

1 The reason for this assymetry between a transition to longerprocesses of production, which need not bring about any of thesepeculiar disturbances, and a transition to shorter processes, whichwill regularly be accompanied by a crisis, will perhaps become moreevident if it is considered that in the former case there will neces-sarily be time to amortize the capital invested in the existing structurebefore the new process is completed, while in the latter case thiswill evidently be impossible and therefore a loss of capital and areduction of income inevitable. (In all these discussions it isassumed that technical knowledge remains the same ; a shorteningof the structure of production which is due to technical progresshas an altogether different significance from that due to an increaseof consumption.)

Page 106: Prices and Production (1931) - F. A. Hayek

94 PRICES AND PRODUCTION

It seems something of a paradox that the self-samegoods whose scarcity has been the cause of the crisiswould become unsaleable as a consequence of thesame crisis. But the fact is that when the growingdemand for finished consumers' goods has taken awaypart of the non-specific producers' goods required,those remaining are no longer sufficient for the longprocesses, and the particular kinds of specific goodsrequired for the processes which would just be longenough to employ the total quantity of those non-specific producers' goods do *not yet exist. Thesituation would be similar to that of a people ofan isolated island, if, after having partially con-structed an enormous machine which was to providethem with all necessities, they found out that they hadexhausted all their savings and available free capitalbefore the new machine could turn out its product.They would then have no choice but to abandontemporarily the work on the new process and todevote all their labour to producing their daily foodwithout any capital. Only after they had put them-selves in a position in which new supplies of food wereavailable could they proceed to attempt to get the newmachinery into operation.1 In the actual world,however, where the accumulation of capital haspermitted a growth of population far beyond the numberwhich could find employment without capital, as ageneral rule the single workman will not be able to

1 Cf. the very similar example now given by C. Landauer,Planwirtschaft und Verkehrswirtschaft, 1931, p. 47.

Page 107: Prices and Production (1931) - F. A. Hayek

THE PRICE MECHANISM 95

produce enough for a living without the help ofcapital and he may, therefore, temporarily becomeunemployable. And the same will apply to all goodsand services whose use requires the co-operation ofother goods and services which, after a change in thestructure of production of this kind, may not be avail-able in the necessary quantity.

In this connection, as in so many others, we areforced to recognise the fundamental truth, so frequentlyneglected nowadays, that the machinery of capitalisticproduction will function smoothly only so long as we aresatisfied to consume no more than that part of our totalwealth which under the existing organisation of produc-tion is destined for current consumption. Every in-crease of consumption, if it is not to disturb production,requires previous new saving, even if the existing equip-ment with durable instruments of production should besufficient for such an increase in output. If the increaseof production is to be maintained continuously, it isnecessary that the amounts of intermediate products inall stages is proportionately increased ; and these addi-tional quantities of goods in process are of course noless capital than the durable instruments. The impres-sion that the already existing capital structure wouldenable us to increase production almost indefinitely is adeception. Whatever engineers may tell us about thesupposed immense unused capacity of the existingproductive machinery, there is in fact no possibility ofincreasing production to such an extent. These en-gineers and also those economists who believe that

Page 108: Prices and Production (1931) - F. A. Hayek

96 PRICES AND PRODUCTION

we have more capital than we need, are deceived bythe fact that many of the existing plant and machineryare adapted to a much greatei output than is actuallyproduced. What they overlook is that durable means ofproduction do not represent all the capital that is neededfor an increase of output and that in order that the exist-ing durable plants could be used to their full capacityit would be necessary to invest a great amount of othermeans of production in lengthy processes which wouldbear fruit only in a comparatively distant future.The existence of unused capacity is, therefore, by nomeans a proof that there exists an excess of capital andthat consumption is insufficient: on the contrary, itis a symptom that we are unable to use the fixed plantto the full extent because the current demand for con-sumers' goods is too urgent to permit us to invest currentproductive services in the long processes for which(in consequence of " misdirections of capital") thenecessary durable equipment is available.

(9) Here then we have at last reached an explanationof how it comes about at certain times that someof the existing resources cannot be used, and how, insuch circumstances, it is impossible to sell them at all—or, in the case of durable goods, only to sell them atvery great loss. To provide an answer to this problemhas always seemed to me to be the central task ofany theory of industrial fluctuations; and, thoughat the outset I refused to base my investigation onthe assumption that unused resources exist, nowthat I have presented a tentative explanation of this

Page 109: Prices and Production (1931) - F. A. Hayek

THE PRICE MECHANISM 97

phenomenon, it seems worth while, rather than spend-ing time filling up the picture of the cycle by elaboratingthe process of recovery, to devote the rest of thislecture to further discussion of certain importantaspects of this problem. Now that we have accountedfor the existence of unused resources, we may even goso far as to assume that their existence to a greateror lesser extent is the regular state of affairs saveduring a boom. And, if we do this, it is imperativeto supplement our earlier investigation of the effectsof a change in the amount of money in circulationon production, by applying our theory to such asituation. And this extension of our analysis is themore necessary since the existence of unused resourceshas very often been considered as the only fact whichat all justifies an expansion of bank credit.

If the foregoing analysis is correct, it should befairly clear that the granting of credit to consumers,which has recently been so strongly advocated as acure for depression, would in fact have quite thecontrary effect; a relative increase of the demand forconsumers' goods could only make matters worse.Matters are not quite so simple so far as the effects ofcredits granted for productive purposes are concerned.In theory it is at least possible that, during the acutestage of the crisis when the capitalistic structure ofpioduction tends to shrink more than will ultimatelyprove necessary, an expansion of producers' creditsmight have a wholesome effect. But this could onlybe the case if the quantity were so regulated as exactly

Page 110: Prices and Production (1931) - F. A. Hayek

98 PRICES AND PRODUCTION

to compensate for the initial, excessive rise of therelative prices of consumers' goods, and if arrangementscould be made to withdraw the additional creditsas these prices fall and the proportion between thesupply of consumers' goods and the supply of inter-mediate products adapts itself to the proportionbetween the demand for these goods. And even thesecredits would do more harm than good if they maderoundabout processes seem profitable which, evenafter the acute crisis had subsided, could not be keptup without the help of additional credits. Frankly,I do not see how the banks can ever be in a positionto keep credit within these limits.

And, if we pass from the moment of actual crisis tothe situation in the following depression, it is stillmore difficult to see what lasting good effects can comefrom credit-expansion. The thing which is neededto secure healthy conditions is the most speedy andcomplete adaptation possible of the structure of pro-duction to the proportion between the demand forconsumers' goods and the demand for producers' goodsas determined by voluntary saving and spending.If the proportion as determined by the voluntarydecisions of individuals is distorted by the creationof artificial demand, it must mean that part of theavailable resources is again led into a wrong directionand a definite and lasting adjustment is again post-poned. And, even if the absorption of the unemployedresources were to be quickened in this way, it wouldonly mean that the seed would already be sown for

Page 111: Prices and Production (1931) - F. A. Hayek

THE PRICE MECHANISM 99

new disturbances and new crises. The only waypermanently to " mobilise" all available resourcesis, therefore, not to use artificial stimulants—whetherduring a crisis or thereafter—but to leave it to timeto effect a permanent cure by the slow process ofadapting the structure of production to the meansavailable for capital purposes.

(10) And so, at the end of our analysis, we arriveat results which only confirm the old truth that we mayperhaps prevent a crisis by checking expansion in time,but that we can do nothing to get out of it beforeits natural end, once it has come. In the next lectureI shall be dealing with some of the problems connectedwith a monetary policy suitable for the preventionof crises. Meanwhile, although so far our investiga-tion has not produced a preventive for the recurrenceof crises, it has, I hope, at least provided a guide tothe maze of conflicting movements during the creditcycle which may prove useful for the diagnosis of thesituation existing at any moment. If this is so,certain conclusions with regard to the methodscommonly used in current statistical analysis ofbusiness fluctuations seem to follow immediately. Thefirst is that our explanation of the different behaviourof the prices of specific and non-specific goods shouldhelp to substitute for the rough empirical classificationof prices according to their sensitiveness, a classificationbased on more rational considerations. The second,that the average movements of general prices showus nothing of the really relevant facts; indeed, the

Page 112: Prices and Production (1931) - F. A. Hayek

ioo PRICES AND PRODUCTION

index-numbers generally used will, as a general rule, faileven to attain their immediate object because, beingfor practical reasons almost exclusively based on pricesof goods of a non-specific character, the data usedare never random samples in the sense required bystatistical method, but always a biased selectionwhich can only give a picture of the peculiar movementsof prices of goods of this class. And the third is thatfor similar reasons every attempt to find a statisticalmeasure in the form of a general average of the totalvolume of production, or the total volume of trade,or general business activity, or whatever one maycall it, will only result in veiling the really significantphenomena, the changes in the structure of productionto which I have been drawing your attention in the lasttwo lectures.

Page 113: Prices and Production (1931) - F. A. Hayek

APPENDIX TO LECTURE III

A NOTE ON THE HISTORY OF THE DOCTRINESDEVELOPED IN THE PRECEDING LECTURE

The central idea of the theory of the trade cycle whichhas been expounded in the preceding lecture is by no meansnew. That industrial fluctuations consist essentially inalternating expansions and contractions of the structure ofcapital equipment has often been emphasised. At onetime, at the beginning of the second half of the last century,such theories even enjoyed considerable vogue and thefinancial journalists of those days frequently used a termino-logy which, intelligently interpreted, seems to imply essentiallythe same argument as that used here. The creation of" fictitious capital", it was said, leads to the conversion oftoo much circulating into fixed capital which ultimatelybrings about a scarcity of disposable or floating capital whichmakes it impossible to continue or to complete the newundertakings and so causes the collapse. The reason whythese theories did not prove more fruitful seems to have beenthat the concepts employed, particularly the concepts of thedifferent kinds of capital, were too uncertain in their meaningto give a clear idea of what was really meant. But even iffor this reason their popularity in the 'sixties and 'seventieswas of a transient nature, they are of considerable interestas an expression of a fairly long and continuous strand ofthought which occasionally came very near to modern ideasand in some instances leads very directly to some of the bestknown theories of today.

I have made no special study of the development of thesedoctrines (which they would well deserve) and I can thereforedo no more than give a brief sketch of the main lines ofdevelopment as I see them. It seems that all these doctrinestrace back to Ricardo's doctrine of the conversion of circulatinginto fixed capital, developed in the chapter " On Machinery "in the third edition of his Principles. A relatively earlyattempt to apply these ideas to the explanation of crises was

Page 114: Prices and Production (1931) - F. A. Hayek

102 PRICES AND PRODUCTIONmade in 1839 by the American Condy Raguet.1 But theauthor who mainly developed and widely popularised it wasJames Wilson, the first editor of the Economist* It seemsto be from him that a host of English and French writersadopted it. In England it was particularly the group ofeconomists connected with the Manchester Statistical Societywho took up the idea. Mr. T. S. Ashton in his recent CentenaryHistory of this Society3 quotes several extremely interestingextracts from lectures given to this society by T. H. Williamsin 1857 a n d John Mills in 1867 which show clearly the greatimportance which they all attached to the " excessive con-versions of floating into fixed capital " ; and he particularlydraws attention to a significant passage in W. St. Jevons'early tract On the Serious Fall in the Value of Gold, publishedin 1863 soon after he came to Manchester, where he says thatthe remote cause of the commercial tides " seems to lie in thevarying proportions which the capital devoted to permanent andremote investment bears to that which is but temporarily investedsoon to reproduce itself."A From the author who later on wasto be the first to provide the basis for that modern theoryof capita] which now enables us to give more definite meaningto these ideas, this statement is of special interest and makesone wonder whether it may not be due to his early pre-occupation with the problem of the trade cycle that he wasled to a correct appreciation of the r61e the time elementplayed in connection with capital.

A little later Bonamy Price developed these ideas inconsiderable details and from him they were taken over inFrance, where other authors like J. G. Courcelle-Seneuil

1 Condy Raguet, A Treatise on Currency and Banking, London,1839, p. 62 et seq.

2 James Wilson, Capital, Currency and Banking, London, 1847,articles XI, XIII and XVI, particularly p. 152 et seq. (articlesXI, XIII and XVII in the second edit, of 1859)."

3 T. S. Ashton, Economic and Social Investigations in Manchester,1833-1933. A Centenary History of the Manchester Statistical Society,London, 1934, P- 72 e* se<2-

4 W. St. Jevons, A Serious Fall in the Value of Gold Ascertainedand its Social Effects set Forth, London, 1863, p. 10, in the reprint inthe Investigations in Currency and Finance, London, 1884, p. 28.

5 Bonamy Price discussed these problems on numerous occasions.Cf. however, particularly his Chapters on Practical Political Economy,London, 1878, pp. 110-24.

Page 115: Prices and Production (1931) - F. A. Hayek

THE PRICE MECHANISM 103and V. Bonnet1 had been working on similar lines, by YvesGuyot, who not inappropriately summarised this theory bysaying the " Commercial and financial crises are produced,not by over-production, but by over-consumption."*

In the German literature similar ideas were introducedmainly by the writings of Karl Marx. It is on Marx thatM. v. Tougan-Baranovsky's work is based which in turnprovided the starting point for the later work of ProfessorSpiethoff and Professor Cassel. The extent to which the theorydeveloped in these lectures" corresponds with that of the twolast-named authors, particularly with that of ProfessorSpiethoff, need hardly be emphasised.

Another contemporary author who is evidently indebtedto the same strand of thought and whose views on theseproblems are even more closely related to those taken in theselectures, but'with whose work on this point I have unfortun-ately only became acquainted since he has collected his earlierscattered articles in book-form, is Professor C. Bresciani-Turroni. His monumental study of the German inflation(Le Vicende del Marco Tedesco, Milano, 1931) appears to me tobe one of the most important contributions to the study ofmoney which have appeared in recent years. Particularlythe chapters on the influence of inflation on production andon the scarcity of capital after the stabilisation (Chapters 5and 10, an abridged German version of the latter appearedin the Wirtschaftstheorie der Gegenwart, ed. by H. Mayer, vol. II,Vienna, 1931) seem to me of extraordinary interest and tocontain a wealth of concrete illustrations of these difficulttheoretical questions which is not to be found elsewhere.Few other foreign books on economic problems would equallydeserve being made available in an English translation.

In view of the importance which so many theories of thetrade cycle attach to the inter-relationships between the differentforms of " capital " one might expect that investigations inthis field should have received considerable help from the theoryof capital. That this has hitherto been the case only to a verylimited degree is mainly due to the rather unsatisfactory state

1 On these authors, cf. E. v. Bergmann, Geschichte der natio-nalokonomischen Krisentheorien, Stuttgart, 1895, where the readerwill find references to still further authors belonging to the samecategory.

3 Yves Guyot, La Science £conomique, English translation,Principles of Social Economy, London, 1884, p. 249.

Page 116: Prices and Production (1931) - F. A. Hayek

104 PRICES AND PRODUCTIONof this theory which was mainly concerned with barrenterminological debates or the question whether capital was tobe regarded as a separate factor of production and how thisfactor was to be defined, instead of making its main task thegeneral question of the way in which production was carried on.It would not be surprising if it would ultimately be that theoryof the trade cycle, which consciously utilises the results of theonly satisfactory theory of capital which we yet possess, thatof Bohm-Bawerk, which should prove to be successful. Itmust be admitted, however, that, *so far, the further elabora-tion of the ideas of Bdhm-Bawerk, apart from two notableexceptions, have not helped us much further with the problemsof the trade cycle. The two exceptions are Knut Wickselland his pupil, Professor G. Akerman. Particularly thedifficult but important investigations in the Realkapital undKapitalzins of the latter author (two parts, Stockholm, 1923and 1924), which I did not yet know at the time when I wrotethese lectures, seems to me to deserve particular attentionas one of the few attempts to clear up the difficult problemswhich arise out of the existence of very durable capital goods.

It seems, however, not improbable that in the future therelationship between the theory of capital and the theoryof the trade cycle may be reversed and that the former willbe benefited by the progress of the latter. Only by studyingthe changes of the capitalistic structure of production willwe learn to understand the factors which govern it, and itseems that the trade cycle is the most important manifestationof these changes. It is therefore not surprising that the studyof the problems of the trade cycle should lead to the study ofthe theory of capital. As has been suggested before, thismay have been the case with Jevons, and more recently ithas certainly been true of Professor Spiethoff (cf. already his'* Vorbemerkungen zu einer Theorie der Ueberproduktion ",Schmollers Jahrbuch, XXVI, 1902, particularly page 299 andhis essay on " Die Lehre vom Kapital " in Die Entwicklungder Deutschen Volkswirtschaft im 19. Jahrhundert, vol. I, 1908).

Page 117: Prices and Production (1931) - F. A. Hayek

LECTURE IV

THE CASE FOR AND AGAINST AN " ELASTIC "

CURRENCY

" The notion common . . . to 90 per cent, of thewritings of monetary cranks is that every batch of goods isentitled to be born with a monetary label of equivalent valueround its neck, and to carry it round its neck until it dies."

D. H. ROBERTSON,

Economica, No. 23, June, 1928, p. 142.

(1) If the considerations brought forward in thelast lecture are at all correct, it would appear that thereasons commonly advanced as a proof that thequantity of the circulating medium should vary asproduction increases or decreases are entirely un-founded. It would appear rather that the fall of pricesproportionate to the increase in productivity, whichnecessarily follows when, the amount of money remain-ing the same, production increases, is not only entirelyharmless, but is in fact the only means of avoidingmisdirections of production. So far as an increase ofproduction caused by a transition to more capitalisticmethods of production is concerned, this result bearssome resemblance to the theory underlying certainproposals for stabilising the value of money so as tokeep, not the prices of consumers' goods, but incomes,or the prices of the factors of production constant,

105

Page 118: Prices and Production (1931) - F. A. Hayek

io6 PRICES AND PRODUCTION

the prices of consumers' goods being allowed to fallas costs fall and vice versa.1 Complete invariabilityof the effective money stream would, as we have seen,however, have the further effect that any transitionto more capitalistic methods of production would alsomake a reduction of money income necessary, exceptin the case of complete vertical integration of production.This necessity, which in view of the notorious rigidityof wages is certainly very undesirable, could howeveronly be avoided without causing misdirections of pro-duction, if it were possible to inj ect the required additionalquantities of money in such a way into the economicsystem that the proportion between the demand forconsumers' goods and the demand for producers' goodswould not be affected. This is no doubt a task whichcannot be solved in practice. But apart from the specialdifficulties which may arise from the existence ofrigidities I believe that the conclusion stated aboveholds here not only for this case of the transition to morecapitalistic methods of production but also for an in-crease of production caused by the absorption of unusedresources. Furthermore, by another chain of reasoning—which is too long and complicated to reproduce here,

1 That there is no harm in prices falling as productivity increaseshas been pointed out again and again, e.g. by A. Marshall, N. G.Pierson, W. Lexis, F. Y. Edgeworth, F. W. Taussig, L. Mises, A. C.Pigou, D. H. Robertson and G. Haberler. (For more detailedreferences see my article on " The' Paradox ' of Saving ", Economica,May, 1931, p. 161.) Cf. also the stabilisation proposal made byDr. Maurice Leven, mentioned by W. J. King in the Journal of the4.i,ierican Statistical Association of March, 1928, Supplement, p. 146,and the article by R. G. Hawtrey in the Journal of the Royal StatisticalSociety, vol. XCIII, Part I, 1930.

Page 119: Prices and Production (1931) - F. A. Hayek

AN " ELASTIC " CURRENCY 107

and which I have sketched elsewhere1—it might beshown to apply in principle even to the particularlydifficult case of an increase of production caused by thegrowth of population, the discovery of new naturalresources, and the like. But however that may be, ourresult is in sufficient contrast to generally receivedopinions to require further elucidation.

(2) We can best observe how deeply the notionthat it is the " natural" thing for the quantity ofmoney to fluctuate with fluctuations in the volume ofproduction is ingrained in the minds of many moderneconomists if we look at the use they make of it in theirtheoretical analysis. Professor Cassel, for instance,who is of course the outstanding representative of thispoint of view, discussing the treatment of priceproblems* in a recent article, writes as follows : " Thesimplest assumption is, then, that a country has apaper currency so regulated as to keep the generallevel of prices constant." And again—to quoteanother well-known authority—Professor Pigou isexpressing the same opinion when he argues3 that ifcountries with paper currencies will regulate themwith a view to keeping the general price level in somesense stable, there will be no impulses from the sideof money which can properly be called "autonomous".Both statements imply that changes in the quantity

1 In an article, " Das intertemporale Gleichgewichtssystem derPreise und die Bewegungen des ' Geldwertes' ", Welttvirtschaft-liches Archiv, vol. 28, July, 1928.

* Economic Journal, vol. 38, December, 1929, p. 589.3 Industrial Fluctuations, second tedit., 1929, p. 101.

Page 120: Prices and Production (1931) - F. A. Hayek

108 PRICES AND PRODUCTION

of the circulating medium which are only just sufficientto keep the general price level steady exert no activeinfluence on the formation of prices, and that, accord-ingly, a money so regulated would remain " neutral "towards prices in the sense in which I have used theword. I see no foundation at all for this hypothesis,although by most it seems to be considered as anobvious platitude requiring no further justification.Everything that has been said in the earlier lecturesseems to me to prove that changes in the volume ofthe circulation which are supposed to be justified bychanges in the volume of production will have effectswhich are just as disturbing as those changes of thecirculation which cause changes in the general pricelevel. Prima facie, I suggest that we should expectrather that, to be neutral in this sense, the supply ofmoney should be invariable. The question is, can thisbe true ? Are there not many other reasons besidesa change in the volume of production which experi-ence suggests justify changes in the quantity ofmoney in circulation if serious disturbances are to beavoided ?

I suppose that, to most economists, the idea of acirculating medium which does not vary in amountwill seem perfectly absurd. We have all been broughtup upon the idea that an elastic currency is somethinghighly to be desired, and it is considered a great achieve-ment of modern monetary organisation, particularlyof the recent American Federal Reserve system, to havesecured it. It does not seem open to doubt that the

Page 121: Prices and Production (1931) - F. A. Hayek

AN " ELASTIC " CURRENCY 109

amount of money necessary to carry on the trade ofa country fluctuates regularly with the seasons, andthat central banks should respond to these changesin the " demand for money ", that not only can theydo this without doing harm, but that they must do soif they are not to cause serious disturbances. It isalso a fact which has been established by long experi-ence, that in times of crisis central banks should giveincreased accommodation and extend thereby theircirculation in order to prevent panics, and that theycan do it to a great extent without effects which areinjurious. How are we to reconcile all this with theconclusions of my earlier lectures ?

(3) To begin with certain terminological elucida-tions. It should be fairly clear that the magnitudewhich in the course of my theoretical analysis I havecalled " quantity of money in circulation " and thatcommonly referred to under the same name in dealingwith the practical problems mentioned before are notidentical, but different in two respects. When, inthe course of analysis, I speak of changes in the quantityof money, this is always meant to include that totalof all kinds of media of exchange (including all so-called " substitutes " for money) used in either a closedeconomic system (i.e. in a country which has no com-munication with the outside world) or in the worldas a whole. But when in dealing with practical problemswe speak of the quantity of money in circulation,we always mean the quantity of any particular kindor kinds of media of exchange used within one or

Page 122: Prices and Production (1931) - F. A. Hayek

n o PRICES AND PRODUCTION

several countries which form a part of a larger economicunit. Now, as we shall see, it follows from the defini-tion of the quantity of money in circulation in opencommunities that the quantity of money thus definedwill always be liable to fluctuations even if we supposethat the quantity included in the more comprehensivetheoretical concept remains unchanged. It is probablythis fact which makes it so difficult even theoreticallyto conceive the possibility or usefulness of an invari-able circulation.

The fact that the monetary circulation of any onecountry, whatever we include under the heading money,will always show natural fluctuations in conformingwith an increase or decrease of the volume of localproduction is probably the main reason why elasticityis generally considered a self-evident necessity forthe amount of money in general. But the questionwe have to answer is just this. Do the reasons whichmake fluctuations of the circulation of any singlecountry necessary apply when we are considering thequantity of money as a whole ?x The answer is simple.The increase or decrease of the quantity of money circu-lating within any one geographical area serves a functionjust as definite as the increase or decrease of "themoney incomes of particular individuals, namely thefunction of enabling the inhabitants to draw a larger orsmaller share of the total product of the world. Therelative magnitude of the total incomes of all individuals

1 For a more detailed discussion of this problem, see my articlein the Weltivirtschaftliches Archiv (vol. 28), quoted above, sect. 12.

Page 123: Prices and Production (1931) - F. A. Hayek

AN " ELASTIC " CURRENCY in

in an " open" community will always stand in adefinite proportion to the share of the total productof the world which the people of that communitycommand. And, if the money circulating within thatnation regularly increases as a consequence of anincrease of its product, this is only one of the stepsin the process of adjustment which are necessary toenable that nation to procure a larger portion of theproduct of the world for itself. What appears to bean absolute increase of the amount of money in circula-tion consequent upon an increase of production, ifviewed from the standpoint of a single country, provesto be nothing but a change in the relative local distribu-tion of the money of all nations, which is a necessarycondition of a change in the distribution of the productof the world as a whole. The same thing wouldhappen, and would be just as necessary to restoreequilibrium, if the product of this country were notabsolutely increased but the products of all othercountries were absolutely diminished. The fact thatthe increase of the product of any one country is regu-larly accompanied by an increase of the quantity ofmoney circulating there, is therefore not only no proofthat the same would be necessary for an isolatedcommunity, it rather shows by contrast how uselesswould be an increase of its monetary circulation eitherfor such a community or for the world as a whole.While for any single country among others an increaseof its possession of money is only a means of obtain-ing more goods, for the world as a whole the increase

Page 124: Prices and Production (1931) - F. A. Hayek

H2 PRICES AND PRODUCTION

of the amount of money only means that somebodyhas to give up part of his additional product to theproducers of the new money.

(4) The second source of the prevalent belief that,in order to prevent dislocation, the quantity of thecirculating medium must adapt itself to the changingneeds of trade arises from a confusion between thedemand for particular kinds of currency and the demandfor money in general.1 This occurs especially inconnection with the so-called seasonal variations ofthe demand for currency which in fact arises because,at certain times of the year, a larger proportion of thetotal quantity of the circulating medium is requiredin cash than at other times. The regularly recurringincrease of the " demand for money " at quarter days,for instance, which has played so great a role in dis-cussions of central bank policy since attention wasfirst drawn to it by the evidence of J. Horsley Palmerand J. W. Gilbart before the parliamentary committeesof 1832 and 1841, is mainly a demand to exchangemoney held in the form of bank deposits into banknotes or coin.2 The same thing is true in regard to the" increased demand for money " in the last stages ofa boom and during a crisis. When, towards the endof a boom period, wages and retail prices rise, notes

1 This confusion is particularly obvious in the writings of ThomasTooke. Cf. T. E. Gregory, Introduction to Tooke and Newarch'sA History of Prices and the State of the Circulation, London, 1928,p. 87 et seq.

2 On this point, see, however, the recent discussion by F. Machlup,Bdrsenkredit, Industriekredit und Kapitalbildung, Vienna, 1931,particularly chaps. 8 and 9.

Page 125: Prices and Production (1931) - F. A. Hayek

AN " ELASTIC " CURRENCY 113

and coin will be used in proportionately greater amounts,and entrepreneurs will be compelled to draw a largerproportion of their bank deposits in cash than theyused to do before. And when, ia a serious crisis,confidence is shaken, and people resort to hoarding,this again only means that they will want to keep apart of their liquid resources in cash which they usedto hold in bank money, etc. All this does not neces-sarily imply a change in the total quantity of thecirculating medium, if only we make this conceptcomprehensive enough to comprise everything whichserves as money, even if it does so only temporarily.

(5) But at this point we must take account of a newdifficulty which makes this concept of the totalquantity of the circulating medium somewhat vague,and which makes the possibility of ever actually fixingits magnitude highly questionable. There can be nodoubt that besides the regular types of the circulatingmedium, such as coin, bank notes and bank deposits,which are generally recognised to be money or currency,and the quantity of which is regulated by some centralauthority or can at least be imagined to be so regulated,there exist still other forms of media of exchange whichoccasionally or permanently do the service of money.Now while for certain practical purposes we areaccustomed to distinguish these forms of media ofexchange from money proper as being mere substitutesfor money, it is clear that, ceteris paribus, any increaseor decrease of these money substitutes will haveexactly the same effects as an increase or decrease

Page 126: Prices and Production (1931) - F. A. Hayek

H4 PRICES AND PRODUCTION

of the quantity of money proper, and should therefore,for the purposes of theoretical analysis, be counted asmoney.

In particular, it is necessary to take account ofcertain forms of credit not connected with banks whichhelp, as is commonly said, to economise money, or to dothe work for which, if they did not exist, money in thenarrower sense of the word would be required. Thecriterion by which we may distinguish these circulat-ing credits from other forms of credit which do not actas substitutes for money is that they give to somebodythe means of purchasing goods without at the same timediminishing the money spending power of somebodyelse. This is most obviously the case when the creditorreceives a bill of exchange which he may pass on inpayment for other goods. It applies also to a numberof other forms of commercial credit, as, for example,when book credit is simultaneously introduced in anumber of successive stages of production in the placeof cash payments, and so on. The characteristicpeculiarity of these forms of credit is that they springup without being subject to any central control, butonce they have come into existence their converti-bility into other forms of money must be possible ifa collapse of credit is to be avoided. But it is importantnot to overlook the fact that these forms of creditsowe their existence largely to the expectation that itwill be possible to exchange them at the banks againstother forms of money when necessary, and that, accord-ingly, they might never come into existence if people

Page 127: Prices and Production (1931) - F. A. Hayek

AN " ELASTIC " CURRENCY 115

did not expect that the banks would in the futureextend credit against them. The existence of thiskind of demand for more money, too, is therefore noproof that the quantity of the circulating mediummust fluctuate with the variations in the volume ofproduction. It is only a proof that once additionalmoney has come into existence in some form or other,convertibility into other forms must be possible.

(6) Before proceeding to investigate whether thereexist any genuine reasons which would make changesin the amount of the circulation necessary in order tokeep money entirely neutral towards the economicprocess (i.e., to prevent it from exercising any activeinfluence on the formation of prices), it is useful to askwhether, under the circumstances just described, it isat all conceivable that the quantity of the circulatingmedium can be kept invariable, and by what meansa monetary authority could attain that end. I maysay at once that, in spite of the qualifications thatI shall introduce later, this question seems to menot merely a question of theoretical interest, but alsoa question the answer to which may prove veryimportant in the shaping of a more rational monetarypolicy.

The credit system of a country has very often beencompared to an inverted pyramid, a simile which servesvery well for our purpose. The lowest part of thepyramid corresponds of course to the cash basis of thecredit structure. The section immediately above tocentral bank credit in its various forms, the next part

Page 128: Prices and Production (1931) - F. A. Hayek

n 6 PRICES AND PRODUCTION

to the credits of commercial banks, and on thesefinally is built the total of business credits outside thebanks. Now it is only in regard to the two lowerparts, cash and central bank credit, that an immediatecontrol can be exercised by the central monetaryauthority. So far as the third part, the credits of thecommercial banks, are concerned, it is at least con-ceivable that a similar control could be exercised.But the uppermost section of the pyramid—privatecredits—can be controlled only indirectly througha change in the magnitude of their basis, i.e., in themagnitude of bank credit. The essential thing isthat the proportion between the different parts of thepyramid is not constant but variable, in other wordsthat the angle at the apex of the pyramid may change.It is a well-known fact that, during a boom, the amountof central bank credits erected upon a given cash basisincreases, and likewise the amount of credits of thecommercial banks based on a given amount of centralbank credit, and even the amount of private creditsbased on a given amount of central bank credit. Thisis certainly true on the continent of Europe, where thepossibility of rediscounting takes to a large extent theplace of actual cash reserves. So that, even if centralbanks should succeed in keeping the basis of the creditstructure unchanged during an upward swing of a cycle,there can be no doubt that the total quantity of thecirculating medium would none the less increase. Toprevent expansion, therefore, it would not be sufficientif central banks, contrary to their present practice,

Page 129: Prices and Production (1931) - F. A. Hayek

AN " ELASTIC " CURRENCY 117

refrained from expanding their own credits. To com-pensate for the change in the proportion between thebase furnished by the credit and the superstructureerected upon it, it would be necessary for themactually to contract credit proportionally. It is pro-bably entirely Utopian to expect anything of thatkind from central banks so long as general opinionstill believes that it is the duty of central banks toaccommodate trade and to expand credit as the increas-ing demands of trade require. Unfortunately, we arevery far from the more enlightened times when, asJohn Fullarton complained, " the words * demand'and ' legitimate demand ' could not even be mentionedin Parliament in connection with this subject un-accompanied by a sneer ".* None the less, I amstrongly convinced that, if we want to prevent theperiodic misdirections of production caused by addi-tional credit, something very similar to the policyoutlined above, absurd as it may seem to those accus-tomed to present-day practice, would be necessary.I do not delude myself that, in the near future, therewill be any opportunity of experimenting with sucha policy. But this is no excuse for not following theimplications of our theoretical arguments right throughto their practical consequences. On the contrary,it is highly important that we should become fullyconscious of the enormous difficulties of the problemof the elimination of disturbing monetary influences,

1 John Fullarton, On the Regulation of Currencies, second edit.,London, 1845, p. 206.

Page 130: Prices and Production (1931) - F. A. Hayek

n 8 PRICES AND PRODUCTION

difficulties which monetary reformers are always soinclined to underrate. We are still very far from thepoint when either our theoretical knowledge or theeducation of the general public provide justificationfor revolutionary reform or hope of carrying suchreforms to a successful conclusion.

(7) As a matter of fact, the course of our argumentso far understates rather than overstates the realdifficulties. I think that I have shown that changesin the physical volume of production offer no sufficientreason for variations in the supply of money. Nonethe less there do seem to me to exist other causes whoseoperation may necessitate such changes if the" natural" price system or the equilibrium of theeconomic process is not to be disturbed. So far, Ihave been able to neglect these causes, since whatI have said has been subject to an assumption,which I expressly introduced at the outset, theassumption, namely, that the proportion betweenthe total flow of goods and the part which takesthe form of an exchange against money, or therate at which goods are exchanged against money,remains constant. But this assumption must now beremoved.

Now it will be remembered that the proportionin question is not necessarily changed by changes inthe physical volume of production while the amountof money in circulation remains the same, nor by avariation of the quantity of money in circulation,while the physical volume of production remains the

Page 131: Prices and Production (1931) - F. A. Hayek

AN " ELASTIC " CURRENCY 119

same; it changes only if movements of goods whichbefore have been effected without the use of moneynow require the transfer of money, or if movements ofgoods which before could only be effected by means ofmoney payments can now be effected without the useof money. It will be remembered further that changesin that proportion are caused by certain changes ofthe business organisation, as the amalgamation of twofirms into one, or the division of one firm into two,by the extension of the money economy into sphereswhere before everybody had only consumed his ownproduct, or where barter had predominated, and thelike. The question to which we must now address ourattention is this : Will not such changes in the propor-tions of money transactions to the total flow of goodsmake a corresponding change in the quantity of thecirculating medium necessary ?

The answer to that question depends upon whether,without such a corresponding change in the quan-tity of money, the change in business organisation/would cause shifts in the directions of demand andconsequential shifts in the direction of productionnot justified by changes in the " real " factors. Thatthe simple fact that a money payment is inserted ata point in the movement of goods from the originalmeans of production to the final stage where none hasbeen necessary before (or the reverse) is no " real "cause in the sense that it would justify a change inthe structure of production, is a proposition whichprobably needs no further explanation. If, therefore,

Page 132: Prices and Production (1931) - F. A. Hayek

120 PRICES AND PRODUCTION

we can show that, without a corresponding change inthe amount of the circulation, it has such an effect,this would provide sufficient reason, in these circum-stances, to consider a change in the amount of moneyto be necessary.

(8) Let us examine what happens when a firm whichrepresents two different stages of production, sayspinning and weaving, is divided into two independentfirms. The .movement of the yarn from the spinningto the weaving factory, which before required no money,will now be effected by a purchase against money.The new weaving firm, which before, as part of thelarger concern, had to keep money only for the pay-ment of wages, etc., will now require additional moneybalances to buy the yarns. The new owner, whom wewill assume to have bought the weaving mill from theold firm, will therefore need additional capital beyondwhat was needed to buy the existing plant and equip-ment and to replace the cash balances kept by theformer owner for that mill, in order to effect these newpayments. If no new money is added to the amountalready circulating, he will either have to take this sumfrom other employments where it cannot be replaced,causing an absolute reduction of the demand for capitalgoods, and consequently a shrinkage of the structureof production ; or he will have to use new savings forthat purpose, which would thus cease to be availablefor lengthening the roundabout processes—that is tosay, to use a phrase of Mr. Robertson's, they wouldbecome " abortive ". The effects would be the same

Page 133: Prices and Production (1931) - F. A. Hayek

AN " ELASTIC " CURRENCY 121

as if, other things remaining the same, the total amountof money in circulation had been reduced by a corre-sponding sum used before for productive purposes.The two cases are so far alike that the change in theproportion between the demand for consumers' goodsand the demand for producers' goods, which in thesecond case as in the first is not determined by " real "causes, will not be permanent: the old proportionwill tend to re-establish itself. But if, from the outset,the demand of the new entrepreneur for the additionalcash balances had been satisfied by the creation ofnew money, this change in the total quantity of cir-culation would not have caused a change in the direc-tion of the demand, and would only have helped topreserve the existing equilibrium.

It would be easy to show, if time permitted, thatin the contrary case, the merger of two firms, and ina number of similar changes in business organisation,money is set free and that this money, if not withdrawnfrom circulation, would have the same effects as if somuch money were added to the circulation. But Ithink that what I have already said on this point willbe sufficient to justify the conclusion that changes inthe demand for money caused by changes in the pro-portion between the total flow of goods to that partof it which is effected by money, or, as we may tenta-tively call that proportion, of the co-efficient of moneytransactions, should be justified by changes in thevolume of money if money is to remain neutral towardsthe price system and the structure of production.

Page 134: Prices and Production (1931) - F. A. Hayek

122 PRICES AND PRODUCTION

All this assumes a greater importance if we rememberthat this co-efficient of money transactions may notonly change in time, but that, at the same moment oftime, it may be different in different parts of aneconomic system, for instance because goods changehands at shorter intervals in the lower stages of pro-duction than they do in the higher stages. If this isthe case, any transfer of money from one part of theeconomic system to another or from one stage of pro-duction to another where the co-efficient of moneytransactions is different will also make a correspondingchange of the amount of money in circulation necessary.If, for instance, money is transferred from a lower toa higher stage of production where the interval betweentwo successive stages is twice as long, and, accordingly,only half as much money is needed to hold the samequantity of goods in that stage, half the money sotransferred would become free. In the opposite casean addition of new money of an equal amount wouldbe necessary. In such a situation, therefore, thetransition to more or less capitalistic methods ofproduction may also require a change in the quantityof money, not because the physical magnitude of thegoods-stream has changed, but because money has beentransferred from a sphere where the co-efficient of moneytransactions has been higher to one where it is lower, orvice versa.

(9) And this is not the only exception to which ouroriginal maxim of policy, that the quantity of moneyshould remain invariable, may be deemed to be subject.

Page 135: Prices and Production (1931) - F. A. Hayek

AN " ELASTIC " CURRENCY 123

The case just discussed is, in fact, only a special aspectof a more general and very familiar phenomenon whichso far has been entirely neglected in these lectures.I refer to changes in what is commonly called thevelocity of circulation. Up to this point I havetreated the quantity of money in circulation andthe number of payments effected during a givenperiod of time as equivalent concepts, a method ofprocedure which implied the assumption that thevelocity of circulation is constant. That is to say,the whole of my argument applies directly only to theamount of payments made during a period of time.It applies indirectly to the amount of money if weassume the " velocity of circulation " to be constant.So long as we make that assumption, or so long as weare speaking only of the volume of payments madeduring a period of time, the case just discussed seems tome the only exception to the general rule that, in orderthat money should remain neutral towards prices, theamount of money or the amount of money paymentsshould remain invariable. But the situation becomesdifferent as soon as we take into account the possi-bility of changes in methods of payment which makeit possible for a given amount of money to effect alarger or smaller number of payments during a periodof time than before. Such a change in the " velocityof circulation " has rightly always been considered asequivalent to a change in the amount of money incirculation, and though, for reasons which it wouldgo too far to explain here*, I am not particularly

Page 136: Prices and Production (1931) - F. A. Hayek

124 PRICES AND PRODUCTION

enamoured of the concept of an average velocity ofcirculation1 it will serve as sufficient justification of thegeneral statement that any change in the velocity ofcirculation would have to be compensated by a recipro-cal change in the amount of money in circulation ifmoney is to remain neutral towards prices.

(10) Even now our difficulties are not at an end.For, in order to eliminate all monetary influences onthe formation of prices and the structure of production,it would not be sufficient merely quantitatively toadapt the supply of money to these changes in demand,it would be necessary also to see that it came into thehands of those who actually require it, i.e., to that partof the system where that change in business organisa-tion or the habits of payment had taken place. It isconceivable that this could be managed in the case ofan increase of demand. It is clear that it would bestill more difficult in the case of a reduction. Butquite apart from this particular difficulty which, fromthe point of view of pure theory, may not prove insuper-able, it should be clear that only to satisfy the legiti-mate demand for money in this sense, and otherwiseto leave the amount of the circulation unchanged, cannever be a practical maxim of currency policy. Nodoubt the statement as it stands only provides another,and probably clearer, formulation of the old distinc-tion between the demand for additional money asmoney which is justifiable, and the demand for

1 Cf. L. v. Mises, Theorie des Geldes und der Umlaufsmittel, secondedit., Miinchen and Leipzig, 1924, p. i n et seq.

Page 137: Prices and Production (1931) - F. A. Hayek

AN " ELASTIC " CURRENCY 125

additional money as capital which is not justifiable.But the difficulty of translating it into the languageof practice still remains. The " natural" orequilibrium rate of interest which would exclude alldemands for capital which exceed the real supplycapital, is incapable of ascertainment, and, even ifit were not, it would not be possible, in times ofoptimism, to prevent the growth of circulatory credit.outside the banks.

Hence the only practical maxim for monetarypolicy to be derived from our considerations is probablythe negative one that the simple fact of an increaseof production and trade forms no justification for anexpansion of credit, and that—save in an acute crisis—bankers need not be afraid to harm production byovercaution. Under existing conditions, to gobeyond this is out of the question. In any case,it could be attempted only by a central monetaryauthority for the whole world : action on the partof a single country would be doomed to disaster. Itis probably an illusion to suppose that we shallever be able entirely to eliminate industrial fluctua-tions by means of monetary policy. The most wemay hope for is that the growing information of thepublic may make it easier for central banks both tofollow a cautious policy during the upward swingof the cycle, and so to mitigate the followingdepression, and to resist the well-meaning but dan-gerous proposals to fight depression by " a littleinflation ".

Page 138: Prices and Production (1931) - F. A. Hayek

126 PRICES AND PRODUCTION

(n) Anybody who is sceptical of the value of theor-etical analysis if it does not result in practical sugges-tions for economic policy will probably be deeplydisappointed by the small return of so prolonged anargument. I do not, however, think that effort spentin clearing up the conditions under which moneywould remain neutral towards the economic process isuseless because these conditions will never be givenin the real world. And I would claim for these investi-gations at least two things. The first is that, as I havesaid in my first lecture, monetary theory is still so veryfar from a state of perfection that even some of themost fundamental problems in this field are yet un-solved, that some of the accepted doctrines are of verydoubtful validity. This applies in particular to thewidespread illusion that we have simply to stabilisethe value of money in order to eliminate all monetaryinfluences on production and that, therefore, if thevalue of money is assumed to be stable, in theoreticalanalysis, we may treat money as non-existent. Ihope to have shown that, under the existing conditions,money will always exert a determining influence on thecourse of economic events and that, therefore, noanalysis of actual economic phenomena is completeif the role played by money is neglected. This meansthat we have definitely to give up the opinionwhich is still widely prevalent, that, in the words ofJohn Stuart Mill, " there cannot, in short, be intrinsic-ally a more insignificant thing, in the economy of society,than money" which " like many other kinds of

Page 139: Prices and Production (1931) - F. A. Hayek

AN " ELASTIC " CURRENCY 127

machinery only exerts a distinct and independentinfluence of its own when it gets out of order ".x Itmeans also that the task of monetary theory is a muchwider one than is commonly assumed; that its taskis nothing less than to cover a second time the wholefield which is treated by pure theory under the assump-tion of barter, and to investigate what changes in theconclusions of pure theory are made necessary by theintroduction of indirect exchange. The first steptowards a solution of this problem is to release monetarytheory from the bonds which a too narrow conceptionof its task has created.

The second conclusion to be drawn from the resultsof our considerations follows from the first: So longas we do not see more clearly about the most funda-mental problems of monetary theory and so long as noagreement is reached on the essential theoreticalquestions, we are also not yet in a position drasticallyto reconstruct our monetary system, in particularto replace the semi-automatic gold standard by amore or less arbitrarily managed currency. Indeed,I am afraid that, in the present state of knowledge,the risks connected with such an attempt are muchgreater than the harm which is possibly done bythe gold standard. I am not even convinced thata good deal of the harm which is just now generallyascribed to the gold standard will not by a future andbetter informed generation of economists be recognised

1 J. S. Mill, Principles of Political Economy, Book III, Chap. VII,para. 3, ed. Ashley, p. 488.

Page 140: Prices and Production (1931) - F. A. Hayek

128 PRICES AND PRODUCTION

as a result of the different attempts of recent yearsto make the mechanism of the gold standard inopera-tive. And there is still another and perhaps no lessimportant reason why it seems dangerous to me tooverstress at the present moment the urgency of achange in our monetary system ; it is the danger ofdiverting public attention from other and more pressingcauses of our difficulties. I must say a last word onthat point because it will help to prevent a misunder-standing which I am particularly anxious to avoid.Though I believe that recurring business depressionscan only be explained by the operation of our monetaryinstitutions, I do not believe that it is possible toexplain in this way every stagnation of business.This applies in particular to the kind of prolongeddepression through which some European countriesare passing today. It would be easy to demonstrateby the same type of analysis which I have used in thelast two lectures that certain kinds of State action,by causing a shift in demand from producers'goods to consumers' goods, may cause a continuedshrinking of the capitalist structure of production,and therefore prolonged stagnation. This may betrue of increased public expenditure in general or ofparticular forms of taxation or particular forms ofpublic expenditure. In such cases, of course, notampering with the monetary system can help. Onlya radical revision of public policy can provide theremedy.

Page 141: Prices and Production (1931) - F. A. Hayek

APPENDIX TO LECTURE IV

SOME SUf*PLEMENTARY REMARKS ON " NEUTRALMONEY "

The term "neutral money", as mentioned in Lecture^I,was apparently first used by Wicksell, but more or lessincidentally, and without the intention to introduce it as atechnical term. It was only comparatively recently that itcame to be more widely used, apparently first in Holland,probably owing to the influence of Mr. J. G. Koopmans, whohas for years been investigating this problem. The firstresults of Mr. Koopmans' studies have, however, appearedonly recently, since the present book was first published.1But Mr. Koopmans has carried his investigations consider-ably further than was possible in the present essay, and toanyone who is interested in that problem I can only warmlyrecommend Mr. Koopmans' study, with which I find myselfin general agreement.

A short but earlier discussion of the problem is to be foundin a German work by Mr. W. G. Behrens.* Mr. Behrens alsopoints out correctly that this is only a new name for theproblem which had been discussed by Carl Menger andProfessor Mises under the, in my opinion rather unfortun-ate, name of the invariability of the " innere objektiveTauschwert " of money, or shortly of the " innere Geldwert ".And it may also be added that it was essentially for the samepurpose that L. Walras and the later economists of theLausanne School used the concept of a " numeraire" asdistinguished from that of " monnaie ".

It is not intended here to go further into the extremelydifficult theoretical problems which this concept raises. Thereis, however, one respect in which recent discussions devotedto it have shown a certain ambiguity of the concept, whichit seems desirable to clear up. It is frequently assumed thatthe concept of neutrality provides a maxim which is immediatelyapplicable to the practical problems of monetary policy.

x J. G. Koopmans, " Zum Problem des ' Neutralen' Geldes",in Beitrdge zur Geldtheorie, ed. by F. A. Hayek, Vienna, 1933.

a Walter G. Behrens, Das Geldsch&pfungsproblem, Jena, 1928,particularly pp. 228, 286, 312 et seq.

129

Page 142: Prices and Production (1931) - F. A. Hayek

130 PRICES AND PRODUCTIONBut this need by no means be the case, and the conceptwas certainly not primarily intended for that purpose. Itwas destined in the first instance to provide an instrument fortheoretical analysis, and to help us to isolate the active influences,which money exercised on the course of economic life. Itrefers to the set of conditions, under which it would be con-ceivable that events in a monetary economy would take place,and particularly under which, in such an economy, relativeprices would be formed, as if they were influenced only by the" real " factors which are taken into account in equilibriumeconomics. In this sense the term points, of course, only toa problem, and does not represent a solution. It is evidentthat such a solution would be of great importance for thequestions of monetary policy. But it is not impossible thatit represents only one ideal, which in practice competes withother important aims of monetary policy.

TRe necessary starting point for any attempt to answer thetheoretical problem seems to me to be the recognition of thefact that the identity of demand and supply, which mustnecessarily exist in the case of barter, ceases to exist as soonas money becomes the intermediary of the exchange transac-tions. The problem then becomes one of isolating the one-sidedeffects of money—to repeat an expression which on an earlieroccasion I had unconsciously borrowed from von Wieser,*—which will appear when, after the division of the barter transac-tion into two separate transactions, one of these takes placewithout the other complementary transaction. In this sensedemand without corresponding supply, and supply without acorresponding demand, evidently seem to occur in the firstinstance when money is spent out of hoards (i.e., when cashbalances are reduced), when money received is not immediatelyspent, when additional money comes on the market, or when.money is destroyed. So this formulation of the problem leadsimmediately to the solution of a constant money stream,with the exceptions sketched in the last lecture. The argumenthas, however, been developed systematically only by Mr. J.G. Koopmans in the essay mentioned above.

In order to preserve, in the case of a money economy, thetendencies towards a stage of equilibrium which are described

1 Cf. F. v. Wieser, " Der Geldwert und seine Veranderungen",Zeitschrift fur Volkswirtschaft, Sozialpolitik und Verwaltung, vol.XIII, 1904, p. 54, also reprinted in the same author's GesammelteAbhandlungen, Tubingen, 1929, p. 178.

Page 143: Prices and Production (1931) - F. A. Hayek

AN " ELASTIC " CURRENCY 131by general economic theory, it would be necessary to securethe existence of all the conditions, which the theory of neutralmoney has to establish. It is however very probable thatthis is practically impossible. It will be necessary to take intoaccount the fact that the existence of a generally used mediumof exchange will always lead to the existence of long-term con-tracts in terms of this medium of exchange, which will havebeen concluded in the expectation of a certain future pricelevel. It may further be necessary to take into account thefact that many other prices possess a considerable degree ofrigidity and will be particularly difficult to reduce. All these" frictions" which obstruct the smooth adaptation of theprice system to changed conditions, which would be necessaryif,the money supply were to be kept neutral, are of courseof the greatest importance for all practical problems of mone-tary policy. And it may be necessary to seek for a compromisebetween two aims which can be realised only alternatively:the greatest possible realisation of the forces working towarda state of equilibrium, and the avoidance of excessive frictionalresistances. But it is important to realise fully that inthis case the elimination of the active influences of moneyhas ceased to be the only, or even a fully realisable, purposeof monetary policy; and it could only cause confusion todescribe this practical aim of monetary policy by the samename, which is used to designate the theoretically conceivablesituation, in which one of the two competing aims was fullyobtained.

The true relationship between the theoretical concept ofneutral money, and the practical ideal of monetary policy is,therefore, that the former provides one criterion for judgingthe latter; the degree to which a concrete system approaches thecondition of neutrality is one and perhaps the most important,but not the only criterion by which one has to judge theappropriateness of a given course of policy. It is quite con-ceivable that a, distortion of relative prices and a misdirectionof production by monetary influences could only be avoided if,firstly, the total money stream remained constant, and secondly,all prices were completely flexible, and, thirdly, all long termcontracts were based on a correct anticipation of future pricemovements. This would mean that, if the second and thirdconditions are not given, the ideal could not be realised by anykind of monetary policy.

Page 144: Prices and Production (1931) - F. A. Hayek

CAPITAL AND INDUSTRIAL FLUCTUATIONS

A REPLY TO A CRITICISM1

A SYMPATHETIC criticism of the kind to which the viewsof the present author have been subjected by Messrs.Hansen and Tout in a recent issue of Econometrica?offers a welcome opportunity of clearing up somepoints upon which I have obviously not yet been suffi-ciently explicit. The critical comments of the twoauthors are mostly directed against points where realdifficulties present themselves; and while I think Ican answer their main objections, it is probable that Ican do so more profitably by means of a further system-atic development of my thesis than by wasting time onthe comparatively unimportant discussion of whetherthese developments were already implied in my earlierstatements, or whether the interpretation put uponthese by Messrs. Hansen and Tout can, or cannot, bejustified from the admittedly sketchy and incompleteexposition in the preceding lectures.

Messrs. Hansen and Tout have stated my theoryin the following series of propositions:

Thesis Number i. That depression is brought about bya shrinkage in the structure of production (i.e., a shorteningof the capitalistic process). In Hayek's view, the phenomenon

1 Reprinted from Economeirica, vol. ii., no. 2, April 1934.2 A. Hansen and H. Tout, " Annual Survey of Business Cycle

Theory: Investment and Saving in Business Cycle Theory",EconomelHca, vol. i., no. 2, April 1933.

13a

Page 145: Prices and Production (1931) - F. A. Hayek

A REPLY TO A CRITICISM 133

of depression is a shrinkage in the structure of produc-tion. Dynamic forces may bring about various effectson economic life, but unless they have the specific effect ofshortening the process of production, depression will not followtherefrom. Nor does depression ever assume any other formthan that of a shrinkage in the structure of production. Inshort, depression may be defined as a shortening of thecapitalistic process of production.

Thesis Number 2. The leading cause (there are, however,others) which brings about, either directly or indirectly, ashortening in the process of production, is the phenomenonof forced saving.

Thesis Number 3. An elongation of the process of pro-duction caused by voluntary saving tends to remain intact;or at least, there is no inherent reason why such an elongationmust necessarily be followed by a shrinkage in the structureof production.

An increase in voluntary saving would cause an enlargeddemand for producers' goods in relation to consumers' goods,and this would raise the prices of goods in the higher stagesof production in relation to those of the lower stages. Theconsequent narrowing of the price margins or, in other words,the lower rate of interest, would thus make possible a permanentelongation of the process of production.

Thesis Number 4. A lengthening of the process of pro-duction caused by forced saving (the money supply nothaving been held neutral) cannot possibly be permanentlymaintained, but must necessarily be followed by a shorteningin the process of production.

An increase in money supply (bank credit) made availableto entrepreneurs would cause an increase in the demand forproducers' goods in relation to consumers' goods, and thiswould raise the prices of goods of the higher order in relationto those of the lower order. The consequent elongation ofthe process of production could not, however, be maintained,because a reversal in the price relationship of higher and lowerorder goods would appear as soon as the money supply ceasedto increase owing to the fact that spending and saving habitshad not changed. Thus, a shrinkage in the artificiallyelongated process of production would inevitably occur.

Thesis Number 5. An increase in consumer demandoccasioned by an increase in the supply of money (over andabove what may be necessary to hold money neutral)

Page 146: Prices and Production (1931) - F. A. Hayek

134 PRICES AND PRODUCTION

inevitably brings about a shortening in the process ofproduction, and so causes depression.

An increased supply of money made available directlyto consumers would cause an increase in the demand for con-sumers' goods in relation to producers' goods, and would thusraise the prices of goods of the lower order in relation to thoseof the higher order, and this would inevitably bring about ashortening in the process of production.

Thesis Number 6. That excessive public expendituresand taxation, by increasing the ratio of spending to saving,will force a shortening in the process of production and socause prolonged depression or business stagnation.

An increase in spending would cause an increased demandfor consumers' goods in relation to producers' goods, andthis would raise the prices of goods in the lower order inrelation to those of the higher order. The consequent widen-ing of the price margins between the lower and higher ordergoods, or, in other words, a higher rate of interest, would,therefore, bring about a shortening of the process ofproduction.

Thesis Number 7. That the supply of money should bekept constant, except for such increases and decreases asmay be necessary (1) to offset changes in the velocity ofcirculation, (2) to counteract such changes in the co-efficientof money transactions as are occasioned by the amalgamationof firms, and the like, and (3) to provide for any changes innon-monetary means of payment, such as book credit, thatmay be taking place. (A distinction is thus made betweena " constant "money supply and a " neutral " money supply.)

Thesis Number 8. That any change in money supply(other than that necessary to hold money neutral) is harmfulbecause it necessarily brings about, eventually, a shorteningin the process of production, (a) If the increased moneysupply goes to entrepreneurs, the process of production isfirst elongated, but, subsequently, necessarily shortened,returning to its previous status, or to a still shorter process.(b) If the increased money goes first to consumers, the shorten-ing of the process of production takes place at once, and theprocess remains permanently shortened.

Thesis Number 9. That an increase in production andtrade forms no justification for an increase in bank credit.

Thesis Number 10. That a period of depression shouldnot be counteracted by any inflation of the money supply,

Page 147: Prices and Production (1931) - F. A. Hayek

A REPLY TO A CRITICISM 135

though, in theory, there is the possibility that during theacute stages of the crisis, while the capitalistic structure istending to shrink more than will ultimately prove necessary,a nicely regulated increase might prove beneficial. Theimpossibility, of such skilful management makes this anunimportant exception.

I

With one exception, I fully agree that this formula-tion of my views is a fair and accurate summary of myposition. Even the unimportant exception is probablyonly a slip of the pen, and is satisfactorily cleared upin the later discussion. But, as it may have confusedsome readers, I should like to emphasise at the outsetthat I should never say, as stated in thesis number 2that forced saving can ever directly bring about ashortening of the process of production. Forcedsaving means essentially a lengthening of the processof production and the crucial point is that, in my view,it is these elongations which are likely to be partly orwholly reversed as soon as the cause of the forced savingdisappears.

The first major difficulty which Messrs. Hansen andTout discuss, is connected with what they call mythesis number 1, namely, that the phenomenon ofdepression is equivalent to a shrinkage of the structureof production. Their difficulty here seems to me toturn on the distinction between a completed and anuncompleted structure, which I have probably failedto make sufficiently clear, and which is closely connectedwith the distinction between the effects of mere

Page 148: Prices and Production (1931) - F. A. Hayek

136 PRICES AND PRODUCTION

fluctuations in the rate of saving (or, more correctly,in the rate of investment) and the peculiar instabilityof capital created by means of forced saving. Thebest way of making these distinctions clear is probablyto start with a general discussion of the effects of fluctua-tions in the means available for investment on thestructure of production in general, and on the profit-ableness of the early stages in particular. From thisdiscussion it will, I think, appear that, contrary to theopinion of Messrs. Hansen and Tout, it is not the merefluctuations in the rate of investment which tend tomake the earlier stages unprofitable but only, on theone hand, particularly violent fluctuations of this sort,and, on the other, fluctuations which make the netinvestment negative. Finally, concluding this partof the discussion, it will appear that, in the case of" forced savings ", it is not only impossible to keep therate of investment constant, but that there will exist,as a necessary consequence of the " forced saving ",strong forces which tend to make the rate of investmentnegative.

II

Any lengthening of the process of production canonly be completed over a period of time correspondingto the interval between the moment when the factorswhich are being shifted to an earlier stage are beinginvested, and the moment when their product matures.If the new, longer process is to be completed andmaintained, this requires not only that the investment

Page 149: Prices and Production (1931) - F. A. Hayek

A REPLY TO A CRITICISM 137

in the earlier stage must be constantly maintained,but also (except in a few rare cases, like the ageing ofwine and the growing of trees) that further comple-mentary investments must be made in the later stages.

From this it follows that, in any progressive society,the particular forms in which investments are beingmade are determined by the expectation that, for sometime to come, a similar stream of funds for investmentwill be forthcoming ; and that, at any moment of time,only a fraction of the funds available for new invest-ment will be used to start new processes, while the restwill be required to complete the processes alreadyunder way. On the simplifying assumption that thetotal length of the marginal processes which are madepossible by an increase in the supply of investible funds,is always greater than the total length of any processalready used, this situation can be represented by thefollowing diagram. The curvilinear1 triangle ABCrepresents, in the same way as the triangle I have usedin the preceding lectures, the stock of capital belongingto processes already completed. (The area of thecurvilinear triangle AB'C shows the stock of capitalbefore the additions were begun.) The fully drawnstripes, beginning between C and D, represent incom-plete processes, started at different moments in the past—and now in different stages of completion. Thepart of these stripes which is dotted represents the

1 The reasons which make a curvilinear triangle of the kindshown in the text a more appropriate representation than thesimplified form used in Lecture II are probably obvious. See p, 39.

Page 150: Prices and Production (1931) - F. A. Hayek

138 PRICES AND PRODUCTION

BFIG. 8.

Page 151: Prices and Production (1931) - F. A. Hayek

A REPLY TO A CRITICISM 139

additional investment which is required to completethe processes. During every successive period of invest-ment, part of the fund available will be used to startnew processes, part to advance processes which arealready under way, and part to complete the mostadvanced processes.

If at any moment savings fall by no more than hadpreviously been used to start new processes, thecompletion of the processes already under way willnot be endangered. And since, at any moment, someof the unfinished processes will be completed, theamount of saving may continually fall off at a certainrate, and may reach zero at the moment when all theprocesses under way are completed. There is, therefore,at any moment, a maximum rate at which the rate ofsaving may fall off, without interfering with the newprocesses already started. It is only when the decreasein saving is faster than this rate, at which the need forcapital for the purpose of completing processes underway decreases, that the incomplete structure cannotbe completed and some of the investments made in theearlier stages have to be abandoned.

Such an abandonment of early stages will, of course,mean that the average period for which the currentsupply of original factors is being invested, is shortenedeven if, at the same time, a good deal of investmentin new forms in later stages'is taking place. In thiscase, however, investment in new forms need not meannet investment, since the losses on the abandonedearlier stages have to be offset against it.

Page 152: Prices and Production (1931) - F. A. Hayek

140 PRICES AND PRODUCTION

III

It is only another way of stating the same con-clusions if one says that the total demand for producers'goods will fall off in consequence of a decrease in thedemand for new producers' goods only if the latterdeclines faster than the replacement demand increases,in consequence of the preceding growth of the stockof producers' goods. And this brings me to a discussionof the famous argument according to which any increasein the demand for productive equipment must lead tosurplus capacity of plant producing that equipment,as soon as the demand for it ceases to increase. Althoughthis is rarely recognised, this is a typical instancewhere an expansion of an earlier stage of productioncan be maintained only if the further increase of capitalmakes it possible to complete the structure by adequateincreases of capital in the later stages.1

From the very outset, it is important in this connectioncarefully to avoid a confusion which arises from thefailure to distinguish between fluctuations in the demandfor productive equipment of a particular industry,which arise from fluctuations in the demand for theproduct of that industry, and fluctuations in the demandfor new producers' goods in general, which are connected

1 A top-heavy structure of this kind is, therefore, an uncompletedstructure in the sense that its earlier stages will be permanentlyemployed only after they have helped to increase the equipmentin later stages to such a magnitude that its replacement demandwill fully use the capacity of the earlier stages. (The essentialthing here, however, is not capacity in a technical sense, but sufficientemployment to make amortisation of plant at current prices possible.)

Page 153: Prices and Production (1931) - F. A. Hayek

A REPLY TO A CRITICISM 141

with fluctuations in the supply of funds available fornew investment. Here I am mainly concerned withthe latter type of fluctuation. How far what is to besaid about this particular case is also applicable to theformer, depends upon the degree to which the concretecapital equipment in earlier stages is specialised to theproduction of equipment for a particular industry,or whether it can be more generally used. On thisquestion of fact, I can only refer to an interestingarticle which was recently published by Mr. Seltzer,1

who seems to show that the mobility of capital in thissense is far greater than is commonly supposed. Someother considerations on this point can be more appro-priately discussed after I have dealt with the firsttype of fluctuation.

At first, therefore, I shall assume that the increasein investment is due to an increase in the supply ofcapital, and that the plant required to provide the newequipment is not adapted to the requirements ofone industry only, but can be used fairly widely. Thequestion then is whether, on the expectation of a con-tinued growth of capital at about the same rate, it willappear profitable to expand the plant in the industriesproducing that equipment to a point where any declinein the current supply of new capital will make full useof that plant unprofitable.

The answer to this question is simply this: as long asthe supply of capital] does not decrease by more than the

* "The Mobility of Capital", Quarterly Journal of Economics,vol. 46, 1932.

Page 154: Prices and Production (1931) - F. A. Hayek

142 PRICES AND PRODUCTION

amount which has so far been used to construct the newplant1 making that equipment, there is no reason whythe demand for new equipment should fall off. Inother words, the effect of a decrease in saving will simplybe that the beginning of new roundabout processeswill be stopped but, if the decrease does not exceed acertain rate, there is no reason why the already existingplant should not be continuously used to add to theequipment in later stages. And as the replacementdemand due to earlier additions to this equipmentwill continue to rise, the supply of new savings may evencontinue to fall at a certain rate without affecting theemployment of the plant producing this equipment.The situation is, therefore, completely analogous to thecase of fluctuations in the rate of saving already

1 It is assumed here that the construction of this additionalplant for making the equipment in question can be carried out eitherwith the help of similar plant already in existence, or of some otherplant which can also be used to produce equipment for later stages.This, of course, will always be the case since no capital is createdwithout the help of some capital already in existence, which if it isa question of adding an earlier stage of production to those alreadyexisting, must, ex definitione, mean that these capital goods havehitherto been used in later stages. It may be mentioned here, sincethis has occasionally been a cause of confusion, that any givencapital good need not, and usually will not, belong to any one given" stage " of production only. If it is used to produce other capitalgoods employed in different stages, and still more if it helps to pro-duce durable goods, or is itself durable, it belongs to as many different" stages" as different periods of time elapse from the momentin which we consider it, to the moments when the different finalproducts which it has helped to produce are consumed. This,however, so far from making the concept of stages useless, is onlya necessary distinction in order to explain the different ways in whichthe value of individual capital goods will be affected by changesin the supply of capital, the rate of interest, or other factors affectingthe structure of production.

Page 155: Prices and Production (1931) - F. A. Hayek

A REPLY TO A CRITICISM 143

discussed: it need not have any harmful effects, solong as the decline in the rate of saving does not exceedthe amount, which will permit the processes alreadybegun to be completed.

IV

The confusion on this point seems to result from a verycommon mistake—that of applying what is true of asingle industry to industry as a whole. While, of course,the relative magnitude of the demand for equipmentfor a particular industry will depend upon the demandfor the product of that industry, it is certainly nottrue to say that the demand for capital goods in generalis directly determined by the magnitude of the demandfor consumers' goods. While it is true that somecontemporary economists have come so much underthe influence of the under-consumptionist fallacythat they are prepared to say that the savings willnever lead to a corresponding increase in investment,because they involve a decline in the demand forconsumers' goods, and are therefore only a harmfuland undesirable phenomenon, I certainly need notdiscuss this with economists who accept as much ofmy fundamental position as do Messrs. Hansen andTout. But, if one accepts the proposition that themagnitude of the total demand for producers' goodsis not a simple derivative of the demand for consumers'goods, but that any given demand for consumers' goodscan lead to methods of production involving very

Page 156: Prices and Production (1931) - F. A. Hayek

144 PRICES AND PRODUCTION

different demands for producers' goods, and that theparticular method of production chosen will dependupon the proportion of the total wealth not requiredfor immediate consumption, then we must certainlytake the fluctuations in the supply of free capital, andnot the fluctuations in the demand for consumers'goods, as the starting point for this kind of analysis.

There is, therefore, no reason to suppose that ageneral increase in the demand for new capitalgoods, which is due to an increase in the supplyof saving, must lead to a decrease in the demand forcapital goods, as soon as the rate of saving begins todecline. And since I am still abstracting from thecase where investment is financed by the creation ofcredit (" forced saving ") or any other purely monetarychanges, it is difficult to see what factors can affectthe total demand for new capital goods, other than thesupply of savings. Only if we assume that changesin the rate of interest which can be earned on newcapital lead to hoarding or dishoarding, would a newcause of change be introduced. But this is one of thecases of monetary changes in the demand for consumers'goods which I shall have to discuss later on.

On this point, my argument so far amounts to this :that in so far as we abstract from monetary changes,the demand for consumers' goods can only changeinversely with the demand for producers' goods, and inconsequence, so far from having a cumulative effectin the same direction as the latter, will tend to offsetit in the opposite direction.

Page 157: Prices and Production (1931) - F. A. Hayek

A REPLY TO A CRITICISM 145

There is, however, still the case of mere shifts ofdemand between different kinds of consumers' goodswhich, of course, will have some effect on the demandfor particular kinds of capital goods. An unexpectedshift of this kind will undoubtedly have the effect thatprovision made for the supply of new equipment inthe industry from which demand has turned away,will now prove excessive or, in other words, it will nowbecome unprofitable to complete the longer processesin the expected way. But the total demand for newequipment will not be changed, and whether the equip-ment-producing plant already in existence will continueto be used or whether new plant will have to be built,will depend upon the technical considerations alreadymentioned.

So much for the pure, or barter, theory of the subject(in the sense of the usual assumption of theory thatmoney exists to facilitate exchange but exercises nodetermining influence on the course of things, or, inother words, remains neutral—an assumption whichis almost always made though not expressed in theseterms). The discussion of the active influence whichmay be exercised by money in this connection is bestbegun with the peculiar effect of forced savings, whichwill lead us to another of the points of discussion,namely, the effect of monetary changes on the demandfor consumers' goods. For the peculiar characteristicof forced saving, which distinguishes its effects from those

Page 158: Prices and Production (1931) - F. A. Hayek

146 PRICES AND PRODUCTION

of voluntary saving, is simply that it leads necessarily toan increase in the means available for the purchaseof consumers' goods. For this reason, my thesisnumber 4 about the impermanence of capital accumu-lated by forced saving is directly bound up with mythesis number 5 as to the effects of a direct increasein the monetary demand for consumers' goods, whichMessrs. Hansen and Tout, quite consistently, alsoreject.

The reason why forced saving will always lead to asubsequent increase in the money available for thepurchase of consumers' goods, is fairly obvious and willprobably not be contested. Entrepreneurs are in thiscase enabled to attract factors of production from laterto earlier stages, not by a corresponding transfer offunds from consumers' to producers' goods, but byadditional money handed to them. This means thatthey will bid up the prices of these factors withoutthere being a corresponding fall in the prices of otherfactors, Total money income will therefore increase,and this increase will in turn lead to an increase in theamount of money expended on consumers' goods.This increase in the expenditure on consumers' goodswill necessarily follow in time upon the increase in thedemand for factors. This lag will mean that, for sometime after the demand for factors (or producers' goods)has ceased to increase (or when its rate of increasebegins to slow down), the demand for consumers'goods will continue to increase at a faster rate ; and solong as the increase in the demand for producers' goods

Page 159: Prices and Production (1931) - F. A. Hayek

A REPLY TO A CRITICISM 147

is slowing down—and for some time afterwards—themonetary proportion between the demand for producers'goods and the demand for consumers' goods will changein favour of the latter.

The question turns, therefore, upon the effect ofsuch a relative increase in the monetary demand forconsumers' goods. The reply, in the particular casein question, however, is simplified, in comparisonwith the general problem, because, on our assumptions,two relevant points are given. We have in this parti-cular case to assume that : (a) since it is the situationat the end of a boom, there are no unemployed resources,and (b) since the rate of credit expansion for productivepurposes tends to be slowed down in spite of a con-tinued rise in the monetary demand for consumers'goods, we cannot assume that the continued rise in thisdemand will lead to a renewed credit expansion. Themuch more difficult case of an increase in the monetarydemand for consumers' goods, where these assump-tions do not necessarily hold, as well as the problemwhy the rate of credit expansion cannot be sufficientlyhigh to avoid this type of reaction, will be consideredlater on.

The relative rise in the price of consumers' goodswill not only improve the competitive position of theirproducers on the market for original factors, but willalso make it profitable for these to increase their outputby the more rapid, even if more expensive, method ofemploying relatively more labour (original factors) inproportion to capital. And while their demand for all

Page 160: Prices and Production (1931) - F. A. Hayek

148 PRICES AND PRODUCTION

the non-specific factors of production (which can alsobe used in the latest stages of production) will continueto drive up the prices of these factors, the prices of theintermediate products specific to earlier stages of pro-duction will tend to fall relatively to their costs. Andsince the effect of this will not only tend to increasecumulatively towards the earlier stages but will alsocause a shift of free capital towards the more profitableearlier stages, it is easy to see how more and moreof the earlier stages will tend to become unprofitable,until unemployment finally arises and leads to a fallin the prices of the original factors of production as wellas in the prices of consumers' goods.

VI

Before I turn to the aspects of the situation whereunemployed factors and unused lending capacity ofall banks exist, and where, perhaps, delay in makingthe necessary adjustments has led to prolongedunprofitability causing deflation and a rapid generalfall of prices, a little more must be said about the rateof credit expansion which would have to continueuninterruptedly if a reaction of the kind just discussedis to be avoided.

Messrs. Hansen and Tout merely speak of a steadyrate of credit expansion as a sufficient condition for acontinuous and undisturbed rate of capital growth.I am not quite sure what " steady " means in thiscontext. But if it refers, as is probably the case, to a

Page 161: Prices and Production (1931) - F. A. Hayek

A REPLY TO A CRITICISM 149

constant rate of increase in the total media of circula-tion, I think it can be shown that this is not sufficientto maintain a constant rate of forced saving; whileit seems that any attempt to make the rate of creditexpansion great enough to secure a constant rate offorced saving will inevitably be frustrated by counter-acting forces which come into operation as soon as theprocess of inflation exceeds a certain speed.

A constant rate of forced saving (i.e., investmentin excess of voluntary saving) requires a rate of creditexpansion which will enable the producers of inter-mediate products, during each successive unit of time,to compete successfully with the producers of consumers'goods1 for constant additional quantities of the originalfactors of production. But as the competing demandfrom the producers of consumers' goods rises (in termsof money) in consequence of, and in proportion to,the preceding increase of expenditure on the factorsof production (income), an increase of credit which isto enable the producers of intermediate products toattract additional original factors, will have to be, notonly absolutely but even relatively, greater than thelast increase which is now reflected in the increaseddemand for consumers' goods. Even in order to attract

1 I am compelled here—as I was in the preceding lecture—tospeak, for the sake of brevity, in terms of competition between theproducers of intermediate products and the producers of consumers'goods (the present and future goods of Bohm-Bawerk's exposition)instead of speaking more correctly of competition between a con-tinuous range of entrepreneurs in all " stages " of production, whichleads to all original factors being invested for a shorter or longeraverage period.

Page 162: Prices and Production (1931) - F. A. Hayek

150 PRICES AND PRODUCTION

only as great a proportion of the original factors, i.e.,in order merely to maintain the already existing capital,every new increase would have to be proportional tothe last increase, i.e., credit would have to expandprogressively at a constant rate. But in order to bringabout constant additions to capital, it would have todo more : it would have to increase at a constantlyincreasing rate. The rate at which this rate of increasemust increase would be dependent upon the time lagbetween the first expenditure of the additional moneyon the factors of production and the re-expenditureof the income so created on consumers' goods.

It is true that in the preceding lectures I have notonly discussed in detail what rate of credit expansionis required to maintain a given rate of forced saving,but have simply assumed that that rate-—whateverit was—could not be permanently maintained forinstitutional reasons, such as traditional bankingpolicies or the operation of the gold standard. ButI think it can be shown without great difficulty that evenif these obstacles to credit expansion were absent,such a policy would, sooner or later, inevitably lead to arapid and progressive rise in prices which, in additionto its other undesirable effects, would set up movementswhich would soon counteract, and finally more thanoffset, the " forced saving ".

That it is impossible, either for a simple progressiveincrease of credit which only helps to maintain, and doesnot add to, the already existing " forced saving",or for an increase in credit at an increasing rate, to

Page 163: Prices and Production (1931) - F. A. Hayek

A REPLY TO A CRITICISM 151

continue for a considerable time without causing a risein prices, results from the fact that in neither case havewe reason to assume that the increase in the supplyof consumers' goods will keep pace with the increasein the flow of money coming on to the market forconsumers' goods. In so far as, in the second case,the credit expansion leads to an ultimate increase inthe output of consumers' goods, this increase will lagconsiderably and increasingly (as the period of pro-duction increases) behind the increase in the demandfor them. But whether the prices of consumers' goodswill rise faster or slower, all other prices, and parti-cularly the prices of the original factors of production,will rise even faster. It is only a question of timewhen this general and progressive rise of prices becomesvery rapid. My argument is not that such a develop-ment is inevitable once a policy of credit expansionis embarked upon, but that it has to be carried to thatpoint if a certain result—a constant rate of forcedsaving, or maintenance without the help of voluntarysaving of capital accumulated by forced saving—isto be achieved.

Once this stage is reached, such a policy will soonbegin to defeat its own ends. While the mechanismof forced saving continues to operate, the general risein prices will make it increasingly more difficult, andfinally practically impossible, for entrepreneurs tomaintain their existing capital intact. Paper profitswill be computed and consumed, the failure to repro-duce the existing capital will become quantitatively

Page 164: Prices and Production (1931) - F. A. Hayek

152 PRICES AND PRODUCTION

more and more important, and will finally exceed theadditions made by forced saving.

It is important in this connection to remember thatthe entrepreneur necessarily and inevitably thinksof his capita] in terms of money, and that, under chang-ing conditions, he has no other way of thinking of itsquantity than in value terms, which practically meansin terms of money. But even if, for a time, he resiststhe temptation of paper profits (and experience teachesus that this is extremely unlikely) and computes hiscosts in terms of some index number, the rate of depre-ciation has only to become fast enough, and such anexpedient will be ineffective. And since the gist of myargument is that, for the purpose under discussion,the rate of credit expansion and depreciation has toincrease at an increasing rate, it will in time reach anydesired magnitude.

VII

For these reasons, it seems to me that the hope ofMessrs. Hansen and Tout based on a steady rate offorced saving is illusory. Whether there may notexist conditions under which temporary forced savingmay take place without the evil consequences of a crisis,is quite another matter. That this will be possibleonly if the rate of forced saving is comparatively small,is probably obvious. Another condition which wealready know is that the fluctuations in investmentto which it gives rise keep well within the limits we have

Page 165: Prices and Production (1931) - F. A. Hayek

A REPLY TO A CRITICISM 153

described. In another place,11 have tried to show that,if these conditions are combined with a third, namely,the presence of a relatively high rate of voluntarysaving, which provides the means of taking over, as itwere, the real capital which has been created but cannotbe maintained by means of forced saving, the loss ofthis capital may be avoided. But in this case, the onlyone I know where such a loss will be avoided, the forcedsaving will only mean an anticipation but no netincrease of the circulation of capital, because it canonly be maintained if an equivalent amount of savingis to be forthcoming later. For this reason, I am evenmore doubtful than before whether forced saving canever be a blessing as Messrs. Hansen and Tout think.This is quite irrespective of the question whether thereis any sense in which the economist can legitimatelysay (as I have occasionally said myself) that suchdecisions made against the will of those concerned maybe " beneficial". But that touches the much widerproblem of whether we possess any gauge by whichto measure the satisfaction derived by those concerned,except their own preferences, shown in their decisions—a question which I cannot even begin to discuss here.

VIII

It will be impossible within the compass of thisarticle to discuss the further points made by Messrs.Hansen and Tout in the same orbit as those more

1 "Stand und Zukunftsaufgaben der Konjunkturforschung",Festschrift fUr Arthur Spiethoff, p. no .

Page 166: Prices and Production (1931) - F. A. Hayek

154 PRICES AND PRODUCTION

fundamental problems already taken up. Particularly,the next and very important point as to the effect of anexpansion of consumers' demand at a time when theproductive forces are not fully employed, and banksare in a position to expand credits to producers, couldbe answered completely only in connection with a fullydeveloped theory of the process going on during adepression. But, if it be assumed that these twoconditions exist as a consequence of a preceding crisis(and a definite assumption as regards the reason whythese conditions exist is essential for any answer),and if the explanation of the crisis which I have justdiscussed is accepted, it is difficult to see how the samephenomenon, which has brought about the crisis, i.e.,the rise in the relative demand for consumers' goods,should also be the cure for it. The scarcity of capital,which, of course, is nothing else but the relatively highprice of consumers' goods, could only be enhanced bygiving the consumers more money to spend on finalproducts. At least so long as there are no furthermonetary complications, particularly so long as it isnot assumed that the expectation of a further fall inprices has led to hoarding, I see no way of getting overthis difficulty. But before I proceed to the relationbetween these secondary monetary complications, andthe underlying real maladjustments which have causedit, I must try to clear away what seems to me to be aconfusion which has led Messrs. Hansen and Tout toapply their denial of the capital-destroying effectof additions to consumers' credits, not only to the

Page 167: Prices and Production (1931) - F. A. Hayek

A REPLY TO A CRITICISM 155

peculiar situation of an advanced depression, but alsogenerally.

The essence of the confusion on this point seems tome to lie in the contrast which my critics try to establishin several places between what they call " nominal "changes in the relative monetary demand for consumers'goods and producers' goods, and the " real changes inthe demand for consumers' goods occasioned by afundamental modification in time preference forpresent and future goods ". It seems to me that,to assume that this rate of time preference can haveany effect other than through the relative demand forthese two classes of goods, or can have any immediateeffects different from those of any other cause affectingthat relative demand, is an attempt to establish apurely mystical connection. The mere fact that, evenwithout a monetary change, any change in the distribu-tion of the command over existing resources will,under a given set of individual time preferences, leadto quite different proportions between capital andincome, should suffice to make this quite clear.1

1 This fact is partly realised by the authors who, however, seemto underestimate its importance, mainly because they think only ofthe effects of a change in the distribution of income ; and while thisis obviously the only factor which will affect new savings, the totalsupply of free capital depends even more on turnover or amortisationof existing capital. Any change in that stock of existing capital,brought about by monetary causes, will, by means of the consequentredistribution of the command over resources, tend to affect therelative demand for producers' and consumers' goods. If themonetary causes have led to a destruction of capital, this changewill necessarily be permanent. If they have led to the creation ofadditional capital goods, the effect on relative demand may be,at least to some extent, permanently to increase the relative demandfor capital goods.

Page 168: Prices and Production (1931) - F. A. Hayek

156 PRICES AND PRODUCTION

Nor can I see how the two authors can combine theiracceptance of the idea that forced saving can be broughtabout by monetary causes, without a change in the rateof time preference, with a general denial that monetarycauses may also lead to " forced dis-saving". Inprinciple, any change in the relative demand for thetwo categories of goods, whether brought about byactual shifts of monetary demand from one to the other,or merely by unilateral increases or decreases withoutcorresponding changes on the other side, will tendto lead to corresponding changes in the relative amountsproduced. The differences between these two cases(a shift and a unilateral change) are, first that the shiftof an amount of money from the demand for consumers'goods to the demand for producers' goods changes theproportion between the two much more effectivelythan a mere unilateral increase or decrease by the sameamount; and, second, that the changes in the quantityof money, which are implied in the second type ofchange, will lead to further changes which may counter-act or offset the tendency created by the change inrelative demand. This will be particularly true if achange in relative demand is accompanied by anabsolute reduction in demand and if, at the same time,costs (i.e., the prices of the original factors of production)are rigid. In this case, deflationary tendencies arelikely to set in, which may more than counter-balancethe effect of the changed relative demand. But, inspite of these further complications which seem likelyto arise, the principle seems to me to be true, and to

Page 169: Prices and Production (1931) - F. A. Hayek

A REPLY TO A CRITICISM 157

comprise even what seems to Messrs. Hansen and Touta reductio ad absurdum of the argument, namely thata unilateral decrease in the demand for consumers'goods may lead to a lengthening of the structure ofproduction. Although I fully admit that, becauseof the probable complications, this case is very unlikelyto materialise, I do not think that it is entirely imprac-tical. Would Messrs. Hansen and Tout deny that,e.g., increased hoarding on the part of a class of verysmall rentiers who reduced their consumption ofagricultural products, might not lead, via the reductionof wages, first in agriculture and then generally, to anincrease in the real quantity of labour correspondingto a constant amount of money invested in industry,and therefore of capital ?

IX

The analysis of this and similar cases would help tobring out an important distinction which Messrs.Hansen and Tout tend to overlook: the distinctionbetween the tendencies set up directly by a givenmonetary change, and the effects of the further mone-tary changes which may, and perhaps even probablywill, but need not, be induced by this first change.A sharp dividing line is the more necessary here sincethe tendency in current discussions is either to takethese secondary monetary changes for granted, withoutever mentioning them, or to fail to demonstrate why,and under what conditions, they should follow the firstchange.

Page 170: Prices and Production (1931) - F. A. Hayek

158 PRICES AND PRODUCTION

These considerations bring me back to the problemof the relation between the demand for consumers'goods and the prices of capital goods. I should notdeny that there may be conditions where, e.g., theexpectation of a general price fall has led to extensivehoarding, and where any change in this expectationmay lead to such dishoarding of funds available forinvestment as to outbalance the initial effect of theincrease in the demand for consumers' goods.1 Noris it inconceivable that a similar situation may prevailas regards bank lending. There can also be no doubtthat, in connection with these secondary monetarycomplications, general price movements, apart from thechanges in relative prices, will be of the greatest import-ance, and that anything which stops or reverses thegeneral price movement may lead to induced monetarychanges, the effect of which on the demand for con-sumers' goods, and producers' goods, may be strongerthan the initial change in the quantity of money.

But one has to be careful not to fall into the errorapparently made by Messrs. Hansen and Tout—thatof assuming that, in all cases, where the prices of con-sumers' goods and producers' goods move in the samedirection (e.g., upwards), this may not be accompaniedby changes in their relative height, which wouldproduce exactly the same effect as if there were nogeneral price movement. Their general propositionthat changes in the relative prices of consumers' goods

1 Cf. my contribution to the Festschrift fur Arthur Spiethoff,quoted above.

Page 171: Prices and Production (1931) - F. A. Hayek

A REPLY TO A CRITICISM 159

and producers' goods will not have the same effectwhen they are accompanied by a universal movementin the same direction as when they find expressionin an absolute movement in different direction, isonly true under the following assumptions : (1) thatthe expected general price movement is relativelygreat compared with the relative price changes; (2) that,at the same time, the general movement does notexceed the limits beyond which—as experience hasshown at least in cases of considerable inflation—costs begin to move more rapidly than prices; (3) thatmoney rates of interest do not adapt themselves tothe expected rate of general price change.1

Further, it is necessary to be careful to make clearthe special assumptions under which these * furthercomplications are likely to arise. The deflationary

1 It is a curious fact that the discussion of the supposedly differenteffect of changes in the relative demand which are due to changesin the supply of money leads the two authors to argue—in effect,if not explicitly, and on what seems to me to be wrong grounds—what they had previously denied, namely that capital accumulatedby means of " forced saving " will not be permanent. If it weretrue that when, after a change in the supply of money, " equilibriumis finally established, the relation (between the prices of consumers'goods and the prices of producers' goods) will be found unalteredunless the effects of the transition period have been such as to changepermanently the time preference of the income receivers " (p. 143),then, no doubt, the greater part of the real capital created by meansof forced saving would be lost. But I think it will be clear by nowwhy I should be very reluctant to use this argument in defence ofmy position.

Messrs. Hansen and Tout think that such a permanent change inthe time preference of the income receivers " is not unlikely, sincean increase or decrease in money supply is likely to increase the realincome of the community". This seems to show conclusivelythat what they have in mind is not the effect on the quantity anddistribution of resources, but on individual time preferences.

Page 172: Prices and Production (1931) - F. A. Hayek

160 PRICES AND PRODUCTION

tendencies, which are assumed to exist in most of thereasoning of the kind discussed, are not a necessaryconsequence of any crisis and depression, but areprobably due to resistances to the necessary readjust-ments, caused by rigidity of prices, the existence oflong term contracts, etc., I am far from underratingthe importance of these phenomena. What I ampleading for is only that, for analytical purposes, thesetendencies should carefully be kept separate and notconfused with one another. Only in this way can wehope ultimately to unravel the tangle of differentforces at work during a depression, and to arrive atthat detailed explanation of the depression whichI cannot even attempt here. But to deny the existenceof certain tendencies merely because they are likelyto be counteracted by others, does not seem to meto be a promising procedure.

XThe objections raised by Messrs. Hansen and Tout

to what they caJl my theses 7, 8, 9, and 10, are partlybased on arguments which I have already discussedand partly introduce further complications which anyprogramme of practical policy has to face and whichI admit I have not investigated sufficiently. But it isobviously impossible to develop my ideas further, inthis connection, or to try to make good these deficiencieshere.

There are only two more points upon which I wishto touch. The first is that the concept of neutral

Page 173: Prices and Production (1931) - F. A. Hayek

A REPLY TO A CRITICISM 161

money was meant in the first place to be an instrumentof theoretical analysis and not necessarily a tool ofpractical policy. Its purpose was to bring out clearlythe conditions under which we could expect the economicprocess in a money economy to correspond perfectlyto the picture drawn by the theory of equilibrium and,incidentally, to show what we should have to consideras the peculiar active effects caused by monetarychanges. In a sense, of course, this would also setup an ideal of policy. But it is by no means incon-ceivable that considerations other than the directmonetary influences on prices, such as the existenceof long term contracts in fixed sums of money, therigidity of prices, and such like institutional factors,may make such an attempt entirely impracticable,because it would set up frictions of a new kind. Inthat case, the task of monetary policy would be to finda workable compromise between the different incom-patible aims. But, in this case, one would have to beclear that certain important determining and disturb-ing influences arising from monetary causes wouldremain in existence, and that we should always have toremain conscious of this fact. Or, in other words, thateven under the best practicable monetary system, theself-equilibrating mechanism of prices might beseriously disturbed by monetary causes.

The second point is that up to 1927 I should, indeed,have expected that because, during the precedingboom period, prices did not rise—but rather tended tofall—the subsequent depression would be very mild.

Page 174: Prices and Production (1931) - F. A. Hayek

162 PRICES AND PRODUCTION

But, as is well known, in that year an entirely unpre-cedented action was taken by the American monetaryauthorities, which makes it impossible to compare theeffects of the boom on the subsequent depression withany previous experience. The authorities succeeded,by means of an easy-money policy, inaugurated assoon as the symptoms of an impending reaction werenoticed, in prolonging the boom for two years beyondwhat would otherwise have been its natural end. Andwhen the crisis finally occurred, for almost two moreyears, deliberate attempts were made to prevent, by allconceivable means, the normal process of liquidation.It seems to me that these facts have had a far greaterinfluence on the character of the depression than thedevelopments up to 1927, which from all we know,might instead have led to a comparatively milddepression in and after 1927.