Portability Paper BLN MS

download Portability Paper BLN MS

of 37

Transcript of Portability Paper BLN MS

  • 7/28/2019 Portability Paper BLN MS

    1/37

    We would like to thank George Baker, Adam Brandenburger, Peter Cappelli, Robert Gibbons, Jerry Green, William Greene, Paul Healy, CaseyIchniowski, David Levine, Will Mitchell, Nitin Nohria, Paul Oyer, Mikolaj Piskorski, Joel Podolny, and Ezra Zuckerman, as well as participants inseminars at Columbia Business School, Econometric Society 2004 North American Winter conference, Harvard Business School, HarvardUniversity Applied Statistic series, London Business School, Ohio State University, Stanford Business School, the University of Pennsylvania,and the University of Washington. We appreciate William Greenes help with estimating the recently developed ordered probit fixed-effectsmodels. We are grateful to professionals at CS First Boston, Deutsche Bank, Goldman Sachs, Institutional Investor, J. P. Morgan, LehmanBrothers, Merrill Lynch, Morgan Stanley, Salomon Smith Barney, and Sanford C. Bernstein for interviews and comments on previous drafts.We also wish to thank Kathleen Ryan and James Schorr for research assistance. We gratefully acknowledge the Division of Research at the

    Harvard Business School for financial support for this study. 1

    Can They Take It With Them? The Portability of Star Knowledge Workers Performance

    Forthcoming Management Science

    Boris Groysberg, Linda-Eling Lee, and Ashish Nanda

    October, 2007

    Abstract

    This paper examines the portability of star security analysts performance. Star analysts who switched employers

    experienced an immediate decline in performance that persisted for at least five years. This decline was most

    pronounced among star analysts who moved to firms with lesser capabilities and those who moved solo, without

    other team members. Star analysts who moved between two firms with equivalent capabilities also exhibited a drop

    in performance, but only for two years. Those who switched to firms with better capabilities and those who moved

    with other team members exhibited no significant decline in short-term or long-term performance. These findings

    suggest that firm-specific skills and firms capabilities both play important roles in star analysts performance. In

    addition, we find that firms that hire star analysts from competitors with better capabilities suffered more extreme

    negative stock-market reactions than those that hire from comparable or lesser firms. These findings suggest that

    hiring stars may be perceived as value-destroying and may not improve a firms competitive advantage.

    JEL Classification J24, J44

  • 7/28/2019 Portability Paper BLN MS

    2/37

    2

    A Nobel Prize-winning scientist may be a unique resource, but unless he has firm-specific ties, his perfect mobilitymakes him an unlikely source of sustainable advantage. Managers should ask themselves if his productivity has todo, in part, with the specific team of researchers of which he is a part. Does it depend on his relationship withtalented managers who are exceptionally adept at managing creativity? Does it depend on the spirit of the workersor the unique culture of the firm? (Margaret A. Peteraf, 1993, p. 187)

    As the labor market shifts toward information- and knowledge-based work, organizations are increasingly

    preoccupied with the quality of their workers as a source of competitive advantage (Pfeffer, 1994, 1998). Top

    performersreferred to in this paper as starsare regarded as disproportionately productive and valuable, and

    organizations view it as imperative to attract and retain such talent (e.g. Ernst and Vitt, 2000; Hunter, Schmidt, and

    Judiesch, 1990; Narin and Breitzman, 1995). Though stars may be extraordinarily productive, they cannot constitute

    a sustained competitive advantage if their skills are mobile and transferable across firms.

    According to Barney (1991), a firm enjoys a competitive advantage only if its strategic resources are

    valuable, rare, difficult to imitate, and lacking in substitutes. Peteraf (1993) specifies four conditions that underlie

    competitive advantage: resource heterogeneity, ex-post limits to competition, ex-ante limits to competition, and

    imperfect resource mobility. With regard to resource mobility, Peteraf (1993) notes that even a superstar like a Nobel

    Prize-winning scientist cannot represent a competitive advantage for an organization unless firm-specific factors

    contribute to his or her performance (1993). Hence the resource-based view of the firm has emphasized the tacit

    knowledge embedded in organizational structures and relationships among workers (Cohen and Levinthal, 1990;

    Kogut and Zander, 1996; Nahapiet and Ghoshal, 1998) rather than capabilities that reside in individual star workers.

    Research on knowledge management, meanwhile, has shown that the mobility of individual workers, particularly

    high-performing knowledge workers like engineers, is an important means of transferring, dispersing, or buying

    knowledge assets (Song, Almeida, and Wu, 2003; Kim 1997; Zander and Kogut, 1995). The extent to which a stars

    performance is transferable across organizations remains a key strategic concern in knowledge-based industries.

    In knowledge-intensive industries like finance, accounting, law, and technology, companies and workers

    often share the assumption that stars and their talent are highly portablethat is, that they can apply their skills just

    as well for one employer as for another. The business media promote this assumption with reports on stars who

    defect to competing firms and presumably take their innovative ideas with them (e.g., see Sessa, 1999). Stars ability

  • 7/28/2019 Portability Paper BLN MS

    3/37

    3

    to transfer their value to a new firm is viewed as particularly pronounced in industries in which clients loyalties flow to

    the individuals who provide a service rather than the firm that employs those individuals (Greenwood, Hinings, and

    Brown, 1990). Furious bidding for star performers (Lazear, 1986) also promotes the perception that stars are

    essentially free agents, not unlike star athletes whose ability can be bought by the highest bidder.

    Human-capital theory distinguishes between general human capital, which is applicable to many

    organizational contexts, and firm-specific human capital, which is valuable only to a specific organization (Becker,

    1962). The firm-specificity of workers skills is the degree to which the human capital they acquired at a particular firm

    is idiosyncratic and therefore useless at other firms. Investment in general training raises workers productivity in a

    manner equally valuable to all comparable employers, whereas firm-specific training increases the value of workers

    marginal products at only one firm. Firm-specific human capital includes familiarity with unique routines and

    procedures, tacit knowledge embedded in interpersonal relationships and corporate culture, skills specific to internal

    networks (team production), and the content of in-house training programs and on-the-job experience peculiar to the

    firm. As Mailath and Postlewaite (1990, pp. 369-370) put it, a firm is a network of people, each with an

    understanding about how information and goods move within the firm. They know whom to contact about particular

    problems that may arise and they know the strengths and weaknesses of their co-workers.

    The perception that star knowledge workers can take their talent with them to competing firms assumes that

    their performance draws entirely on general human capital. This paper will address the question of when star

    knowledge workers can in fact take their performance with them to competing firms. We will argue that the human

    capital of star performers has a firm-specific component that cannot be easily transferred across firms. We will

    consider how much one component of firm-specific human capitalthe knowledge embedded in relationships with

    colleaguesmay contribute to the portability of a stars performance. And we will address whether hiring stars

    constitutes a value-creating or value-destroying proposition for firms.

    We tested our hypotheses on star performers in the security-analyst market. Because an analysts core

    activities, clients, and geographic location typically remain unchanged after changing employers, analysts and the

    firms that employ them share a conviction that their performance is highly portable. As research executive Fred

    Fraenkel put it, "Analysts are one of the most mobile Wall Street professions because their expertise is portable. I

  • 7/28/2019 Portability Paper BLN MS

    4/37

    4

    mean, youve got it when youre here and youve got it when youre there. The client base doesn't change. You need

    your Rolodex and your files, and youre in business.

    We have compiled a unique data set that captures the performance and turnover of 799 equity analysts and

    254 fixed-income analysts across 78 firms over a period of nine years. This longitudinal data allows us to capture

    both short- and long-term changes in performance. The quality of our data presents a unique opportunity to advance

    empirical knowledge on human capital and drivers of performance. Previous empirical investigations of portability of

    performance have been hobbled by incomplete data on the workers in a given firm, job, or industry; performance that

    is difficult to observe given the nature or structure of the jobs in question; and a low incidence of turnover (Chapman

    and Southwick, 1991). Thus it has been impossible to disentangle the effects on worker productivity of human capital

    and other factors (Garen, 1988). Measuring the performance of knowledge workers has proven particularly difficult

    (e.g. Ernst and Vitt, 2000). What little performance data were available relied on self-reports or were limited to a

    single firm, preventing cross-firm comparisons (Barrett and O'Connell, 2001). The external rankings we use in this

    study provide a clear and public distinction between outstanding and ordinary performers, and the availability of rich

    data at the demographic, departmental, firm-specific, sectoral, and macroeconomic levels makes it feasible to control

    for all these variables together. Furthermore, few other studies have employed longitudinal data on individual

    performance, which is crucial to disentangle individual and organizational contributions to performance.

    Star Performers

    Two factors distinguish star performers from average or merely competent performers. First, star performers are

    disproportionately more productive. Studies of research-and-development scientists and academic researchers have

    found that a few individuals are many times more productive than their colleagues (e.g., Cole and Cole, 1973; Ernst,

    Leptein, and Vitt, 2000; Narin and Breitzman, 1995). In knowledge work, the ability and experience of top performers

    are assets that cannot be compensated for by larger number of poorer performers, or by non-human assets (Narin,

    1993; Rosen, 1981).

    Second, stars are more visible in their labor markets than more ordinary performers. Any industry will have

    many high-performing individuals, but the handful of superstars at the top will receive disproportionate attention from

    competitors and clients (and, in some industries, the media), making their performance public and observable.

  • 7/28/2019 Portability Paper BLN MS

    5/37

    5

    Consequently, as Lazear (1986) noted, star workers are more mobile: the visibility of their high performance may

    prompt rival organizations to try to woo them away. Greater opportunities for mobility in turn increase star performers

    bargaining power. The mobility of stars has been studied extensively in the motion-picture industry (e.g., Ravid 1999)

    and in baseball (e.g., Cymrot and Dunlevy, 1987; Krautmann and Oppenheimer, 1994; MacDonald and Reynolds,

    1994). Workers in both industries suddenly found themselves free to offer their talents to the highest bidder when the

    studio system collapsed in motion pictures and when free agency replaced the reserve clause in baseball. Ravid

    (1999) argues that star artists, such as Oscar winners, are free agents who can quickly adjust their fees to reflect

    their market value, thus capturing most of their expected value added; as a consequence, hiring stars does not

    increase return on investment.

    These two factorsextraordinary productivity and greater visibilitypose a dilemma for organizations intent

    on attracting and retaining star performers. Given the strategic importance of excellent individual performance, it is a

    crucial question for managers and star performers alike whether and how such performance can be transferred

    across organizational contexts. If the contribution of context to extraordinary performance is overlooked, stars may

    switch firms in the mistaken belief that they can take it with them, only to find their performance declining in a new

    setting. And firms may hire stars whose performance, divorced from its previous context, fails to meet expectations.

    General and Firm-Specific Human Capital

    General human capital consists of non-firm-specific skills that are acquired through via education and on-the-job

    general training (Rees, 1973; Rosen, 1981). Williamson (1986, p. 120) asserts that there are individuals, such as

    artists, researchers, and administrators, whose unique skills are rarely of a transaction-specific kind. On the

    contrary, most of these individuals could move to another organization without significant productivity loss.

    In knowledge work, star performance has traditionally been attributed to general human capital, or the skills,

    characteristics, and competencies of the individual performer (see Felin & Hesterly, forthcoming, for an explication of

    this view). Drucker argues, for example, that knowledge workers, unlike manual workers in manufacturing, own the

    means of production: they carry that knowledge in their heads and can therefore take it with them (1998, p. ix).

    Frequently cited examples of such knowledge workers include management consultants (Maister, 1993), attorneys

    (Henning, 1993; Kordana, 1995), and security analysts (Mikhail et al., 1997).

  • 7/28/2019 Portability Paper BLN MS

    6/37

    6

    Individuals and firms in these knowledge-intensive markets tend to share this position and to discount the

    notion that organizational context contributes to star performance. Asked to explain how a security analyst becomes

    a star, for example, a veteran of Wall Street answered, This is a little like asking what it was that made Rembrandt or

    Van Gogh great artists. If theres an answer, its probably that the greats in any profession are driven by an inner fire,

    and are gifted with a special spark (Lurie, 1967).

    As Simonton (1999) pointed out, [T]he notion that some people are born with more talent than others is

    firmly ingrained in everyday psychology. Researchers have also found that people raised in individualistic Western

    cultures are more likely than participants in collectivist Asian cultures to attribute success to innate factors like

    intelligence, creativity, or talent, and are more susceptible to self-enhancement bias (Kitayama et al., 1997). These

    cultural biases reinforce the perception that knowledge workers, even more than other kinds of workers, can

    justifiably attribute their performance to their own individual talents.

    Despite the characterization of star knowledge workers as free agents, such individuals rarely work as

    independent contractors. They develop and exercise their skills in specific organizational contexts. Though some

    research has shown that both individual and organization-specific factors are likely to contribute to individual

    performance (Pfeffer, 1994), few studies of knowledge workers have attempted to disentangle their effects on star

    performance. Some recent studies, however, point to an influential role for firm-specific human capital in knowledge-

    based work. Bakss (2003) economic model of mutual-fund managers direct contribution suggests that the fund is

    more important than the manager as a determinant of performance. (Baks estimates the individual managers

    contribution to fund performance at 1050 percent.) Huckman and Pisanos (2006) study of cardiac surgeonswho

    in essence work as freelancersdemonstrates that the quality of a surgeons performance at a given hospital

    improves as his or her experience at that hospital increases. This effect does not carry over, however, to other

    hospitals at which the surgeon practices. Given the extreme invariability of surgeons worka triple bypass is a triple

    bypass, no matter where the operating table is locatedthis study provides evidence that firm-specific human capital

    can account for variability in what would appear to be highly transferable skills. Interestingly enough, Huckman and

    Pisano note that the surgeons themselves did not perceive a difference in their performance from one hospital to

    another, an observation consistent with the notion that individuals tend to attribute their own performance to their

  • 7/28/2019 Portability Paper BLN MS

    7/37

    7

    innate talent and skills that are relatively stable traits.

    Research on organizational knowledge has demonstrated that a group of colleagues who may appear to be

    merely an aggregation of high-performing individuals actually relies on intangible knowledge embedded in the shared

    experience of working together (Berman, Down, and Hill, 2002). Learning is often built internally through experience

    within an organization (Cohen and Levinthal, 1990). This kind of complex social knowledge, or tacit knowledge, which

    can constitute a competitive advantage for an organization (e.g., Nelson and Winter, 1982; Barney, 1991; Lippman

    and Rumelt 1982), is by nature uncodifiable. Nor can individuals easily transport this kind of critical knowledge, which

    may underlie star-quality performance, because it is embedded in a specific organizational context.

    If at least some of the knowledge that contributes to individual performance is firm-specific, we would expect

    performance to suffer when stars move to a new firm.

    H1: Stars suffer a performance decline when they move to new firms.

    Firm Capabilities

    A performance decline after changing employers could occur not because of the loss of firm-specific human capital

    but because the new firm offers lower-quality support. That is, the new firms systems and practices could affect

    individual performance (Eccles and Crane, 1988). Research has shown, for example, that complementary innovative

    work practices (practices that reinforce each other) can lead to higher productivity, independent of the quality of

    individual management (Ichniowski, Shaw, and Prennushi, 1997). The literature on high-performance work practices

    has also demonstrated a link between human-resource practices and higher performance (e.g. Huselid, 1995).

    Furthermore, such organizational practices as promotion criteria, the system of resource allocation (Henderson and

    Cockburn, 1994), and managerial practices (Castanias and Helfat, 1991; Kaplan, Murray, and Henderson, 2003) can

    all have an effect on productivity. In workplaces that pursue scientific research, studies have shown that

    departmental context has a powerful effect on individual productivity over and above the selection effect whereby

    higher-prestige institutions recruit better scientists (Allison and Long, 1990; Long and McGinnis, 1981).

    A firms status may also affect a workers productivity. Zuckerman and Merton (1971) drew a distinction

    between performance (current) and eminence (cumulative, and often persistent after performance has flagged).

    Affiliation with a prestigious institution can provide a worker greater external credibility and greater access to

  • 7/28/2019 Portability Paper BLN MS

    8/37

    8

    resources that can contribute to performance (Allison and Long, 1990).

    To confidently attribute any performance decline to the loss of firm-specific human capital, we would have to

    restrict our focus to moves between firms with comparable capabilities.

    H2: Stars suffer a performance decline when they move to firms with equivalent capabilities.

    Colleague Relationships

    Knowledge work is often organized by project teams, requiring close collaboration between individuals (e.g. Henning,

    1993; Kordana, 1995; Maister, 1993). Thus in many cases a key component of the firm-specific knowledge that stars

    lose when they move to a new firm is knowledge arising from close collaboration with colleagues (Becker, 1976).

    Proximity and frequent interaction with colleagues facilitates the transfer of tacit knowledge, a circumstance difficult to

    replicate with new colleagues. Weick and Roberts (1993) demonstrated that a collective mind develops among

    colleagues who work in teams that require seamless integration of their knowledge and skills. Evidence from baseball

    suggests that players are aware of the importance of such team-specific knowledge. Players in positions requiring

    greater coordination with team members are less likely to be traded or to move to another team than players whose

    positions are relatively independent (Glenn, McGarrity, and Weller, 2001). Evidence from basketball also supports

    the importance of team-specific experience in performance (Berman, Down, and Hill, 2002).

    Research on social networks offers further support to the thesis that internal relationships are a central

    component of the firm-specific capital that stars lose when they move to a new firm. Individuals often rely on

    colleagues with different but related areas of expertise for information they would not otherwise encounter (Galbraith,

    1977; March and Simon, 1958; Clark and Fujimoto, 1991). Access to such diverse and novel information can help

    star performers maintain an edge in formulating innovative ideas (e.g. Burt, 1987). Studies also suggest that

    outstanding performers tend to develop and maintain networks of colleagues who contribute to their advancement

    (Ibarra, 1995; Burt, 1987).

    The frequency with which workers move in teams suggests that at least some individuals are aware of the

    value embedded in these relationships. Lawyers, doctors, consultants, and security analysts often leave with a team

    of colleagues to join a competitor (e.g. McGregor, 2006; Weisman, 2006). The term lift outs has been coined by the

    business press to characterize this phenomenon, observed in industries as diverse as medicine, advertising,

  • 7/28/2019 Portability Paper BLN MS

    9/37

    9

    software development, and apparel manufacture (Groysberg and Abrahams, 2006; Weisman, 2006; McGregor,

    2006). A team move obviates the need for a star to get acquainted with new colleagues or to establish shared

    objectives, mutual accountability, or group normsneeds that can detract from performance. Hence stars who move

    with a team of colleagues are likely to retain a goodly portion of the firm-specific human capital they enjoyed at their

    previous employer.

    H3: Stars who move with a team of colleagues suffer less severe performance decline than those who move

    solo.

    Firm Value

    Whether or not a stars performance will be portable is important when assessing a potential hire as a value-creating

    proposition for the firm. It is certainly possible that a star could generate value for the new firm despite a

    performance decline. Stars could generate positive externalities, for example, such as boosting the performance of

    existing employees or giving the firm access to more profitable clients. Research from the film industry also suggests

    that firms hire stars as a way to signal their quality: Ravid (1999) hypothesized that a studio signals the seriousness

    and quality of a project by hiring a star.

    But firms could lose value-creating opportunities if stars manage to capture their economic rent. Ravids

    study showed that movie stars did in fact recoup their rents; as a result, though movies with stars attracted more

    revenue than those without stars, they were not more profitable because stars are highly paid. Similar results were

    found in baseball, where experienced free-agent players recoup their marginal revenue products (MacDonald and

    Reynolds, 1994).

    A firm that succeeds in hiring a star can be viewed as the highest bidder in the labor market. As research in

    diverse fields has shown, such winners may experience a winners curse and overpay for workers. Spencer (1974)

    noted that when all firms in a market are uncertain about a workers ability, the individual will be offered a wage equal

    to his or her expected ability. In most cases, though, a stars firm of origin has private information about his or her

    ability, based on performance history, that other firms lack (Acemoglu and Pischke, 1998). When the firm that

    possesses an informational advantage fails to make a counter-offer to keep the employee from leaving, the hiring

    firm is likely to suffer a winners curse. The hiring firm is also likely to have made an offer that exceeds the value that

  • 7/28/2019 Portability Paper BLN MS

    10/37

    10

    the new employee will generate. In such cases, hiring a star is value-destroying. In baseball, for example, Cassing

    and Douglas (1980) concluded that the owners of major-league teams consistently overpay for free-agent

    acquisitions. The gap between a stars pay and the value he or she will generate for the hiring firm is likely to be even

    greater if the value that the star generated for the prior firm depended in part on firm-specific resources.

    Research on corporate takeovers also suggests that the acquisition of new capabilities, technology, or talent

    does not always generate value. One explanation for the consistent finding of zero or negative return in research on

    mergers and acquisitions (see Sirower, 1997 for a review of literature) is that firms tend to overpay for their targets

    (Bradley, Desai and Kim, 1988). Roll (1986) argued that overpayment occurs because acquiring firms' managers are

    prompted by hubris to systematically overestimate their own ability to run new units and create takeover gains.

    Research on the post-integration process suggests that complex issues of strategic and organizational fit and timing

    increase the difficulty of extracting value from an acquisition (e.g., Zollo and Singh, 2004; Haspeslagh and Jemison,

    1991. Similarly, hiring stars and fully extracting their value is likely to be a difficult proposition.

    H4: Hiring a star destroys value for the hiring firm.

    Research Approach

    We tested our hypotheses by looking at the job histories and performance records of star Wall Street security

    analysts. To test whether research analysts possess firm-specific human capital, we examined whether changing

    employers has an effect on their short-term and long-term performance. Determining whether a given individuals

    performance changes when he or she changes firms is problematic, in that we cannot control for what would have

    happened to an individuals performance had he or she stayed put. Our data, however, capture the performance of

    many stayers at the originating firms. Hence, we can compare a movers performance to that of a comparable

    individual who chose to stay at the same firm (i.e. control group). This approach has been used in research on labor

    migration to address a similar empirical problem (e.g., Friedberg, 2000; Nakosteen and Zimmer, 1980; Robinson and

    Tomes, 1982).

    If performance is primarily driven by firm-specific skills, a decline in performance can be expected when an

    individual changes jobs because it takes time to develop skills specific to the new firm (Hypothesis 1).

    Yet, changes in performance may reflect either the loss of firm-specific human capital or the new employers different

  • 7/28/2019 Portability Paper BLN MS

    11/37

    11

    capabilities. Only when the original and destination firms possess equal capabilities can we assert that a decline in

    performance confirms the contribution of firm-specific skills to productivity (Hypothesis 2). In a similar fashion, we

    also tested whether moving with colleagues affects subsequent performance by comparing the performance of

    stayers and movers to firms with equal capabilities (Hypothesis 3).

    Furthermore, workers do not move at random. Changing employers is endogenous if the decision to do so

    correlates with unobservables that affect performance. Prior studies have demonstrated the importance of accounting

    for self-selection in estimating returns to migration (e.g. Nakosteen and Zimmer, 1980; Robinson and Tomes, 1982).

    Therefore our econometric methodology takes into account the self-selection process by which workers become

    movers or stayers, permitting consistent estimates of the performance of both groups (see online supplement for

    methods and analyses).

    Finally, the best way to determine whether the acquisition or loss of a high-performing worker is value-

    reducing or value-enhancing for a firm would be to calculate a profit-and-loss statement for each worker. The

    unavailability of detailed compensation data makes this method unfeasible. In its stead we use the event study

    methodology to determine how the stock market treats the share price of an investment bank in reaction to news of

    its unforeseen loss or acquisition of a star analyst. Stock-market movement is a well-established proxy for the value

    created or lost for a given firm in reaction to a specific event. This measure has been successfully used in research in

    accounting (Dyckman, Philbrick, and Stephan, 1984), finance (Asquith and Mullins, 1986), law (Mitchell and Netter,

    1994), and strategic management (Brindisi, 1985). It has also been used to measure the effects on firm value of

    announced changes in top management (Warner, Watts, and Wruck, 1988). We used stock-price movement to

    assess whether acquiring firms gain or lose value when they hire a star analyst (Hypothesis 4).

    The Security Analyst Market

    Security analysts are employed by investment banks to analyze companies in a particular industry, such as

    telecommunications, pharmaceuticals, or food and beverages. Analysts produce earnings forecasts, buy and sell

    recommendations, detailed reports on individual companies, and other analyses of interest to investors.

    The primary recipients of the information that analysts produce are money-management firms (also known

    as institutional investors), including pension funds and mutual funds, which invest their clients money by purchasing

  • 7/28/2019 Portability Paper BLN MS

    12/37

    12

    stocks, bonds, and other investment products for their clients' portfolios. Wall Street distinguishes between

    investment banks and money-management firms by referring to investment banks as the sell side of the investment

    process, and money-management firms as the buy side. (The buy side also employs analysts, whose research is

    far less specialized; buy-side analysts thus rely heavily on sell-side research.) Our study focuses exclusively on sell-

    side equity and fixed-income analysts, who work at investment banks.

    Investment banks make money in three principal ways: merger-and-acquisition advisory services,

    underwriting (raising funds for companies by issuing stocks or bonds), and trading of securities for institutional

    clients. The ultimate purpose of research at an investment bank is to help generate business from trading securities

    for institutional clients (Cowen et al., 2006). Security analysts write in-depth reports on the companies they cover and

    issue recommendations as to whether investors should buy or sell the companies securities and bonds, or hold on to

    stocks and bonds already in their portfolios. On average, an analyst writes 53.1 company-specific research reports

    (two pages or longer) annually on 13.6 companies that they cover. It is not unusual for analysts to have more than

    800 institutional clients who receive their reports and seek their advice.

    An analysts compensation and visibility in the industry both depend on his or her ranking in an annual

    survey conducted since 1972 by the trade journal Institutional Investor (II). Every year the magazine asks sell-side

    analysts clients (portfolio managers and analysts at buy-side money-management firms, mutual funds, and pension

    funds) to rate analysts on their effectiveness. Those ranked highest are celebrated in the magazine as members of

    Institutional Investors All-America Research Team.1The II survey reaches a large proportion of the investment

    community. In October 1996, for example, II ranked analysts in each of 80 industry sectors and investment

    specialties, based on ratings from roughly 1,300 individual respondents whose firms represented approximately 68

    percent of the 300 largest institutional investors in the United States. These institutions include state pension funds,

    which invest enormous pools of money, along with other investment-management institutions like Fidelity

    Investments, Putnam Investments, and Wellington Management Company.

    In each industry sector, the four analysts with the highest aggregate ratings are ranked first, second, third,

    and runner-up. (More than four analysts may be ranked if there is a tie.) In 1996, less than 3 percent of all U.S.

    1We use the terms ranked analysts andstar analysts interchangeably to refer to sell-side analysts ranked by Institutional Investor.

  • 7/28/2019 Portability Paper BLN MS

    13/37

    13

    analysts were ranked. The II survey constitutes a core component of the internal performance evaluation for security

    analysts at every investment bank. The II survey enables securities firms to determine how their most important

    clients rate the service of their analysts (Siconolfi, 1992). Prior research has provided direct empirical evidence on

    the relationship between rankings and forecast accuracy (e.g., Brown and Chen, 1991). Within the firm, being ranked

    by II wins an analyst enhanced credibility, greater power, and substantially higher compensation (Dorfman, 1991). At

    the major investment banks, top analysts could easily earn from $2 million to $5 million per year during the period of

    our study (Laderman, 1998). In the larger financial world, II ranking brings heightened visibility and prestige.

    Newspaper and TV reporters frequently seek out star analysts opinions on companies and stocks in their sectors.

    There are many advantages to testing our hypotheses in the security analysts market. The II rankings

    provide clear, observable, industry-accepted performance measures that are comparable across firms on a yearly

    basis. Because star analysts enjoy high visibility in the financial industry, it is possible to compile thorough data on

    each analysts performance and career history. The skills of security analysts are perceived in the labor market as

    highly portable: the star power of top-performing analysts is attributed to individual ability that transcends

    organizational support (Howard, 1967; Lurie, 1967; Institutional Investor, 1991). And even after moving to a new firm,

    analysts continue to run the same financial models, follow the same sectors and companies, and maintain the same

    client lists. (Institutional investors do not have exclusive relationships with particular investment banks; they receive

    research reports from more than a dozen banks at the same time). For all these reasons, this market represents a

    near-ideal sample against which to test our hypothesis that star performance is based in part on non-transferable,

    firm-specific human capital.

    Data

    From the annual All-America Team issues ofInstitutional Investorpublished between 1988 and 1996, we collected

    the following information for equity analysts (ranked in October) and fixed-income analysts (ranked in August): name;

    industry specialty/sector; type (equity or fixed income); rank; year of the ranking; and company affiliation. The nine-

    year period of the study produced a total of 4,200 analyst-year combinations (3,514 in equity and 686 in fixed

    income). If each analyst were counted only once, the list would include 799 equity analysts and 254 fixed-income

    analysts. Ranked analysts were employed by 78 investment banks; the 24 firms employing the most number of

  • 7/28/2019 Portability Paper BLN MS

    14/37

    14

    ranked analysts accounted for 4,036 ranked analyst-year combinations (96 percent). To collect information on

    analysts tenure with their current employers and total industry experience, we searched databases maintained by

    Lexis-Nexis, the National Association of Securities Dealers, and Dow Jones News. Data on analysts tenure at their

    firms were available for 3,639 analyst-year combinations (87 percent), and information on analysts experience was

    collected for 3,653 analyst-year combinations (87 percent).

    We accounted for every ranked analyst who left or joined an investment bank within one year of being

    ranked during the period 19881996. Each of these incidents is identified as an analyst-year move in this paper.

    Analysts affiliations in the year subsequent to being ranked, and the specific dates of their moves, were identified

    using the databases of Nelsons Directory of Investment Research, Lexis-Nexis, and Dow Jones News Service. We

    identified 546 analyst-year moves: 500 were from one firm to another, and 46 were promotions or transfers to non-

    research positions within the same investment bank. Of the 500 analyst-year moves from one firm, 134 were exits

    from research altogether.2

    The remaining 366 moves (made by 316 individual analysts) were switches to

    competitors research departments. The average annual turnover of analysts in this sample was 11.9 percent.

    News announcements on the hiring of ranked analysts indicated that ranked analysts occasionally moved in

    teams, a phenomenon referred to by investment bankers as block trading in people or lift outs. Of the 366 analyst-

    moves, 100 involved such colleagues as other ranked analysts, junior analysts, institutional salespeople, and traders.

    Variables

    Dependent Variable

    The dependent variable in this study is the analysts performance, operationalized as rank in the Institutional Investor

    All-America Research Team poll, Rankt+1. Each year the magazines editor sends a letter asking institutional

    investors to rank the analysts who "have been most helpful to you and your institution in researching U.S. equities

    over the past twelve months." Voters are asked to evaluate analysts using six criteria: earnings estimates, servicing

    initiatives, accessibility and responsiveness, stock selection, industry knowledge, and written reports. The

    respondents award a single overall numerical score to each analyst in each industry sector. Votes are cumulated

    2One hundred thirty-four analysts left sell-side research: 69 joined buy-side firms; 30 founded new companies; 20 retired; 8 took non-researchpositions in the securities industry; 5 joined a company that they had covered as analysts; one died in a car accident; and one died of a heartattack.

  • 7/28/2019 Portability Paper BLN MS

    15/37

    15

    using weights based on the size of the voting institution. The identities of the respondents and their institutions are

    kept confidential. A very small percentage of analysts achieve rankings in multiple sectors. Some, but not all, stars in

    a given year continue to be ranked in subsequent years. In each sector, there are five levels of the dependent

    variable (categorical and ordinal): the first, second, third, and runner-up ranks and unranked.

    Independent Variables

    Switching firms. We test whether the analysts movement across firms has an effect on his or her

    Institutional Investorranking. The independent variable of interest is the analysts mobility. TheAnalyst move variable

    is 1 if a ranked analyst switched to another sell-side research department and 0 if a ranked analyst did not move

    during the year.

    Firm capability. For each of the 366 job changes, we determine whether the destination firm had lesser,

    equivalent, or better capabilities relative to the originating firm by using the bulge-bracket distinction. Bulge-bracket

    investment banks are those responsible for the bulk of securities underwritten in the United States; historically, the

    six bulge firms are CS First Boston, Goldman Sachs, Lehman Brothers, Merrill Lynch, Morgan Stanley, and Salomon

    Brothers. These banks and their employees enjoy a competitive edge due to the firms exceptional capabilities:

    economies of scale in marketing, sales, and technology; a broad product base; wide distribution network for its

    services, including analysts research products; and specialized units (investment banking, sales, trading, and

    research) capable of solving complicated customer problems (Eccles and Crane, 1988).

    We assign the job changes of ranked analysts to three groups: better firm capability, equal firm capability,

    and lesser firm capability. The Firm capability direction categorical variable takes the value no move if a ranked

    analyst does not move during the year, moving to a weaker firm if the move is from a bulge to a non-bulge firm,

    moving to a better firm if the move is from a non-bulge to a bulge firm, and moving to a comparable firm if the

    move is from bulge to bulge or non-bulge to non-bulge.

    Team movement. We also test the effects of moving with a team of colleagues. Such a team can consist of

    colleagues of several types. One is other security analysts who cover complementary sectors (such as the food-and-

    beverage sector and the gaming-and-lodging sector), and who can benefit mutually from information sharing and

    collaboration. Jacob, Lys, and Neale (1999) find that as the percentage of analysts at a firm who follow similar

  • 7/28/2019 Portability Paper BLN MS

    16/37

    16

    industries increases, any given analysts forecast accuracy improves.

    Analysts may also develop team rapport with colleagues in other departments, such as institutional

    salespeople and traders who cover the same sectors. The institutional sales force is a particularly significant

    contributor to analysts successes, as already discussed. Traders, too, affect analysts performance by keeping them

    informed about developments on the trading floor. Analysts and traders also discuss clients plans to buy, sell, or

    hold, information that can help analysts in their short-term action research. Traders also make calls to clients, and

    can help disseminate analysts ideas. Over time, ranked analysts are apt to develop relationships with institutional

    salespeople and traders that benefit their performance. If the performance of a ranked analyst is to some extent

    reliant on relationships with in-house colleagues, switching firms is likely to be less damaging to performance if some

    of these colleagues make the same move.

    TheCoworker move categorical variable takes the value of no move if a ranked analyst does not move in

    a given year, moving solo if the analyst switches to another sell-side research department solo, and moving in

    teams if he or she makes such a move with other professionals (junior and senior research analysts, institutional

    salespeople, or traders who specialize in the same sector).

    Control Variables

    The variables included in the model are operationalized into four categories: individual, firm, sector, and macro-

    economic. Table 1 lists the specific individual-level variables, their univariate statistics, and their correlations.

    Individual analyst variables. Firm tenure and overall experience are important variables to control for

    when analyzing performance (Becker, 1962; Topel, 1991).Analyst firm tenure is the number of years an analyst has

    worked at the firm at the end of each year.Analyst experience is the number of years an analyst has worked as an

    analyst at the end of each year. We also control forAnalyst type, because equity and fixed-income analysts pursue

    different activities and have different customer bases.

    Analysts prior performance has an effect on their future performance (Sinha et al., 1997). Some analysts

    are able to repeat their outstanding performance and rank again in subsequent years. Others are not. To control for

    prior performance, we collected information on the number of years a ranked analyst had been ranked as of the end

    of the year and created theAnalyst star tenure variable. Finally, theAnalyst rank dummy t = 0, which represents an

  • 7/28/2019 Portability Paper BLN MS

    17/37

    17

    analysts rank in the yeart = 0, controls for rank-specific effects on analysts rankings.

    Firm variables. We useFirm dummy to control for effects specific to firms, since research points to

    differences in forecasting performance across banks (Jacob, Lys and Neale, 1999; Sinha, Brown and Das, 1997).

    Sector variables. The Sector dummy variable controls for effects specific to the sectors that analysts cover.

    Sector membership is considered an important variable in evaluation of an analysts performance (Jacob, Lys and

    Neale, 1999; Sinha, Brown and Das, 1997). We identified sectors using the Nelsons Investment Research Database.

    Macroeconomic variables. To control for intertemporal changes, we use the Year dummy variable.

    Model Specifications

    The Ordered Probit Model

    We used an ordered probit model because the dependent variable, analysts Institutional Investorrankings, is

    categorical and ordinal in nature (Greene, 2000). The model is estimated using panel data on ranked analysts for the

    nine-year period 19881996. Heterogeneity across individual analysts is modeled using the robust clustered

    estimators of variance -- Huber/White or sandwich estimator (Huber, 1967; White, 1982; Greene, 2000) -- because it

    produces correct standard errors (in the measurement sense). In comparison to the conventional estimator of

    variance, which requires independence not only across individual analysts but also across observations for a given

    analyst, the robust clustered estimate of variance requires only that the observations be independent across the

    individual-ranked analysts (clusters). We utilize the Firm capability direction andCoworker move variables when we

    examine whether ranked analysts performance is affected by (1) whether they move to a firm with better, equal, or

    lesser capabilities, and (2) whether they move in teams or solo.

    Event Study Data Set and Methodology

    We use the event study methodology to determine whether and how the stock market reacts to the unexpected news

    of the departure or hiring of a star analyst. The dates on which analyst departures or hirings are first announced were

    chosen as the event dates. We conduct a short window study of daily excess returns over the event period of -1 to +1

    days (the actual announcement date plus the days prior to and after the announcement date). The data set consists

    of 269 observations for ranked analysts leaving publicly quoted firms and 228 observations of analysts joining such

    firms. Subsidiaries of larger diversified firms that generated less than 50 percent of those companies revenues were

  • 7/28/2019 Portability Paper BLN MS

    18/37

    18

    then excluded. The reduced data set consists of 188 observations for analysts leaving and 156 observations for

    analysts joining investment banks. The data set was then checked for confounding announcements in the event

    period. Following Brown and Warner (1980), the event window was examined for the following confounding effects:

    restructuring/divestiture, dividend/earnings announcements, buy/hold/sell recommendations by investment banks,

    joint venture, acquisitions, new products, litigation/labor unrest, major executive changes, forecasted changes in

    earnings or sales, layoffs, debt or equity related events, and contract awards. Sixty-four observations for analysts

    leaving and 47 data points for analysts joining firms were deleted for confounded effects. Furthermore, 13

    observations on the leaving side and 8 observations on the joining side were excluded because they overlapped in

    time and involved identical companies. The final data set consists of 111 exit announcements and 101 hiring

    announcements. Stock-returns data were provided by the Center for Research in Security Prices (CRSP) at the

    University of Chicago.

    Empirical Tests and Results

    In this section we first determine whether, controlling for individual, firm, sector, and intertemporal variables, ranked

    analysts movement across firms affects their performance (Rankt+1, Rankt+2, Rankt+3, Rankt+4, and Rankt+5). Next we

    examine whether ranked analysts performance is affected by whether they (1) move to a firm with better, equal, or

    lesser capabilities, and (2) move solo or in teams. This section concludes with our findings on stock-market reactions

    to announcements of movements into and out of firms by ranked analysts.

    Switching Firms and Ranked Analysts Performance

    The portability of ranked analysts performance is examined by focusing on the sign and the significance level of the

    Analyst move variable. In models M1 through M5 (see Table 2) we examine the effects of switching firms on analysts

    performance, controlling for analyst-specific (Analyst type, Analyst firm tenure,Analyst experience,Analyst star

    tenure,Analyst rank dummy t = 0), firm-specific (Firm dummy), sector-specific (Sector dummy), and intertemporal

    (Year dummy) characteristics. Coefficients in these models are similar. Consequently, unless otherwise noted, the

    following comments apply to all models.

    In model M1, theAnalyst move coefficient is negative and significant (p < 0.01), suggesting that ranked

    analysts short-term performance declines after switching jobs. (See Appendix A and online supplement, for analysis

  • 7/28/2019 Portability Paper BLN MS

    19/37

    19

    relating to endogeneity.) The findings from models M2 through M5 suggest that movement across firms has a

    significant negative effect on ranked analysts long-term performance. TheAnalyst move coefficient is negative and

    significant (p < 0.01) in model M2 (Rankt+2), (p < 0.05) in model M3 (Rankt+3), (p < 0.05) in model M4 (Rankt+4), and (p

    < 0.05) in model M5 (Rankt+5). Even after five years at a new firm, ranked analysts who switched employers

    underperform ranked analysts who stayed put. Thus, Hypothesis 1 is supported.

    As previously noted, a coefficient in the ordered probit model provides cannot be easily interpreted. Not only

    is the effect of a given regressor nonlinear in the ordered probit model, but its influence also varies on each rank

    probability. Examining change in the outcome probabilities is a useful way to summarize the effects of the

    independent variable. Table 2 reports measures of discrete change for theAnalyst move variable. For example, for a

    ranked analyst who does not move, the probability of being ranked first in year t+1 is 0.106. If a ranked analyst

    changes employers, the predicted probability of being ranked first in yeart+1 declines to 0.056 (= 0.106-0.050).

    The findings from models M1, M4, andM5 also suggest that being an equity analyst, relative to a fixed

    income analyst, has a weakly positive impact on performance (p < 0.10). Interestingly, in all five models, the effect of

    Analyst star tenure is significant and negative (p < 0.01), suggesting that the longer analyst has remained ranked, the

    prospects of higher rankings are diminished.3

    Firm Capabilities and Ranked Analysts Short-Term and Long-Term Performance

    This section examines whether the capabilities of firms to which analysts move (better, comparable, or weaker) have

    an effect on their performance (Rankt+1, Rankt+2, Rankt+3, Rankt+4, andRankt+5). Coefficients for the control variables

    (Analyst type, Analyst firm tenure,Analyst experience,Analyst star tenure,Analyst performance, Firm dummy, Sector

    dummy, Year dummy) are similar to coefficients in models M1 through M5. Therefore Table 3 only reports the

    coefficients for the different categories of firm capabilities.

    The portability of ranked analysts performance is examined by focusing on the sign and the significance

    3TheAnalyst star tenure coefficient is also affected by top-rated analysts inability to move up in rankings. Furthermore, using theAnalyst newstarvariable, we examine whether being ranked for the first time affects performance.Analyst new startakes the value of 1 if an analyst hasbeen ranked for the first time in a given year, and 0 otherwise. Newly ranked analysts might be on their way up or might merely have gottenlucky and are thus expected to lose ranking the next year. TheAnalyst new starcoefficient is positive and insignificant. Finally, in order to rejectalternative explanations for our results, we test whether there are significant interactions between Analyst move andAnalyst firm tenure,Analyst experience,Analyst star tenure,Analyst performance andAnalyst new star. None of the interactions are found to be significant.

  • 7/28/2019 Portability Paper BLN MS

    20/37

    20

    level of the Firm capability direction variable. The findings suggest that star analysts who move between two

    comparable firms (firms of equivalent capabilities) also exhibit a drop in performance but only for two years. Since the

    origin and destination firms have similar capabilities, differences in firm capability cannot account for this drop in

    performance. This finding provides evidence that the loss of firm-specific skills accounts for the diminished

    performance of analysts who move between firms of comparable capabilities. During the first two years after

    switching firms those analysts are able to acquire new firm-specific skills, and their performance in the third, fourth,

    and fifth years is not statistically different from the performance of ranked analysts who stay put. Thus, Hypothesis 2

    is supported for short-term performance.

    Our findings suggest that performance decline is most pronounced among star analysts who move to firms

    with weaker capabilities. Relative to comparable analysts who stay put, these analysts underperform for five years.

    Stars who switch to firms with better capabilities exhibit no significant decline in short- or long-term performance. For

    this category of analysts, the loss of firm-specific skills associated with decline in performance might have been

    mitigated by their new employers valuable capabilities. Even after five years at a new firm, however, analysts who

    switched to better firms are unable to outperform analysts who did not move. Star analysts who moved to firms with

    worse capabilities appeared to experience the worst outcome among analysts who moved. If an analyst switches to a

    firm with better capabilities, for instance, the probability of achieving the first rank in yeart+1 is 0.083 (=0.106-0.023),

    compared with a probability of 0.058 (=0.106-0.048) for an analyst who moves to a firm with worse capabilities.4

    Team Movement and Ranked Analysts Short-Term and Long-Term Performance

    Next we examine whether moving to a new firm solo or with a team has an effect on analyst performance (Rankt+1,

    Rankt+2, Rankt+3, Rankt+4, and Rankt+5). Ranked analysts who move solo show an immediate decline in performance

    that persists for at least five years (see Table 3). Switching firms has no significant effect, by contrast, on the

    performance of ranked analysts who move with teammates. This finding suggests the value of skills embedded in

    4 We also examined whether the effect of comparable moves differ between moves between bulge firms and moves betweennon-bulge firms, i.e. how better, comparable bulge, comparable non-bulge, or weaker affect performance (Rankt+1, Rankt+2,Rankt+3, Rankt+4, and Rankt+5). We find that star analysts who move between two comparable non-bulge firms exhibit a drop inperformance for three years. Stars who switched between comparable bulge firms also exhibit a drop in performance but only forone year. Within the moving to comparable category (both bulge and non-bulge), most of the moves are between non-bulgebracket firms (78%). 22% of moves between comparable firms are moves between bulge firms.

  • 7/28/2019 Portability Paper BLN MS

    21/37

    21

    colleague or team relationships. For instance, the probability of achieving the first rank in year t+1 is only 0.053 (=

    0.106-0.061) for analysts who changed firms solo, but 0.100 (= 0.106-0.006) for those who switched employers with

    teammates, suggesting the contribution of team-specific skills to an analysts performance. Thus, H3 is supported.5

    Figure 1 provides graphical interpretation of these results for all independent variables (Analyst move, Firm

    capability direction, Coworker move) for two individual years (t+1 and t+5).

    Stock-Market Reaction to Announcements of Movement by Ranked AnalystsTable 4 presents stock-market reactions to announcements of moves by ranked analysts. The direction of cumulative

    stock-market reactions is intriguing. The event itself evokes a significant negative stock-market reaction for the hiring

    firm, suggesting that, in aggregate, the stock market views such a hire as value-reducing. Hiring firms experience

    significant negative abnormal return (-0.74 percent) during the event period. The negative stock-market reaction for

    the hiring firm is consistent with corporate-takeover studies suggesting that acquirers tend to suffer negative stock-

    market reactions during the announcement period (Haspeslagh and Jemison, 1991).

    On average, the size of the stock-market reaction to such a hiring announcement is a loss of about $24

    million for the acquiring firm. Thus the negative stock-market reaction far exceeds the analysts entire compensation.

    During the period of this study, even the highest reported salaries received by ranked analysts did not exceed $3

    million per year for more than six years. If discounted, this amounts to just half of the stock-market reaction.

    The magnitude of the abnormal returns depends on the type of move. Announcements of a ranked analysts

    move to a firm with inferior capabilities evoke a strong and statistically significant negative stock-market reaction (-

    1.67 percent). Announcements of moves between firms with equivalent capabilities are associated with a -0.63

    percent return. Announcements of moves to firms with better capabilities elicit a smaller negative return (-0.26

    percent). Clearly, the stock-price impact of hiring announcements by lesser firms is more severe than that of

    comparable announcements by firms with equivalent or better capabilities (p < 0.05). Investors may believe that

    inferior firms have to pay a high premium to entice a star analyst from a superior firm. Investors might also be

    anticipating a drop in performance on the part of analysts who move to a firm with worse capabilities.

    5 In our analysis, we are not measuring how many colleagues moved. We only measure whether any colleagues moved. We diduse the linear data in our analysis, which did not meaningful affect the results.

  • 7/28/2019 Portability Paper BLN MS

    22/37

    22

    Finally, abnormal returns are subdivided into two categories: (1) entries of individual analysts, or solo

    entries, and (2) entries by analysts with other employees, or team entries. News of the hiring of an individual analyst

    is greeted with significant negative abnormal returns (-0.62 percent), as is news of the hiring of an analyst with a

    team (-0.99). Attracting a star along with his or her team appears to destroy more value, as measured by share price,

    than hiring an individual star.

    Discussion

    Our results indicate that hiring stars is advantageous neither to stars themselves, in terms of their performance, nor

    to hiring companies in terms of their market value. The performance of an outstanding worker is not owned by the

    worker alone; it is a property of the worker/firm combination, and encompasses firm-specific human capital

    embedded in colleague relationships and firm capabilities.

    Star analysts who change employers suffer a decline in performance compared to that of analysts who stay

    put, thus providing evidence of the importance of firm-specific human capital. Our findings support research on the

    socialization of newcomers into organizations showing that such transitions are more disruptive and challenging than

    anticipated. Newcomers often find that their expectations don't fit their actual experiences (Hill, 1992) and that their

    status shifts from insider to outsider. Organizational socialization, or "learning the ropes," is an integral part of the

    joining-up process (Van Maanen and Schein, 1979). Veteran employees, resentful of a newly hired stars high

    compensation and favored status, may withhold crucial information that is needed to succeed (Harding, 1998). A

    star's performance would decline if long-tenured employees withheld cooperation in this way. Previous research has

    shown that newcomers suffer a drastic decline in performance, especially if their success depends on the

    contributions of others, as they cope with adjusting to an unfamiliar organizational setting (Louis, 1980).

    Mobile analysts can preserve their performance to some extent under two conditions: when they move to a

    firm with better capabilities and when they take firm-specific human capital with them in the form of existing colleague

    relationships. The relative quality of the two firms affects a stars post-move performance. This result supports

    research that emphasizes the contribution of organizational context to individual performance (e.g., Allison and Long,

    1990). Though our data do not pinpoint the specific components of firm capability that help mitigate performance

    decline, research in various domains suggests that factors like a superior human-resource system (e.g., Huselid,

  • 7/28/2019 Portability Paper BLN MS

    23/37

    23

    1995), superior intellectual capital embedded in existing social systems (e.g., Nahapiet and Ghoshal, 1998), and

    high-quality colleagues (e.g., Groysberg and Lee, forthcoming) all play a role in supporting individual performance.

    Our study provides strong evidence that colleague relationships constitute an important component of firm-

    specific human capital. Previous research has pointed out that social relationships at work are important for

    mentorship, advice, advancement, friendship, and satisfaction. Our study suggests, further, that these relationships

    contribute directly to outstanding performance and are not readily replicated in a new organizational setting. The tacit

    knowledge embedded in these relationships constitutes a valuable resource both for firms and for the stars whose

    performance depends on it. This finding supports the resource-based view of the firm that tacit knowledge embedded

    in relationships can constitute a competitive advantage, but it also points out that competitors can access some of

    that knowledge by luring away an entire team of valuable workers. Research on knowledge and learning has shown

    that the mobility of workers is one means whereby knowledge is disseminated or transferred. Our study highlights the

    flip side of that process: mobility, especially on the part of teams of knowledge workers, is also a means to lose

    strategic knowledge assets.

    Our findings indicate that equity research is highly interdependent work, reliant on collaboration among

    teams of co-workers. Researchers have long emphasized the importance of teamwork (e.g., Hackman, 1990) and of

    the knowledge embedded in social ties (e.g., Burt, 1987), but our study suggests further that some workers

    themselves might be aware of the importance of specific colleagues. The increasing prevalence of team moves may

    thus have important implications not only for firms but also for researchers on turnover and mobility (Groysberg and

    Abrahams, 2006). If both the nature of work and patterns of mobility are increasingly team-based, teams might

    become increasingly relevant as a unit of analysis in research. To our knowledge, no previous research has

    investigated the consequences of moving in teams. Our study provides evidence that movement in teams may

    exhibit very different dynamics than the solo mobility that researchers are accustomed to studying.

    We encountered significant evidence that hiring stars is, from a stock-market perspective, a value-

    destroying move. Three factors might account for the size of the stock-market reaction. First, investors might believe

    that hiring firms suffer a winners curse and overpay stars relative to their future performance. Second, hiring a star

    analyst might alert investors that a firm is unable to develop its own analysts and may even be planning an expensive

  • 7/28/2019 Portability Paper BLN MS

    24/37

    24

    hiring spree. Finally, investors might anticipate the cost to the firm of integrating a newly hired star, including conflicts

    and other negative effects on existing analysts leading to decline in their performance.

    The literature on corporate acquisitions can shed light on the problems of bringing in stars. In both cases,

    organizations are looking to acquire strategic, knowledge-based resources. Acquiring a new company can prove

    problematic because of internal boundaries and defenses against accepting new capabilities (Song, Almeida & Wu,

    2003). Puranam, Singh, and Zollo (2003), examining the integration of acquired companies in the technology sector,

    point out that a goal and strategy of acquisitions are often at odds: the pursuit of short-term wins calls for giving the

    newly acquired company maximum independence, while long-term productivity requires building the kind of

    organizational linkages that take time and may be disruptive in the short term. Building on their earlier work,

    Puranam, Singh, and Zollo (2006) suggest that loss of autonomy during exploitation stage of innovation process is

    better than during exploration phase. Other literature suggests that acquisitions often have a depressing effect on

    productivity (Ernst and Vitt, 2000), and nearly all the research on the subject suggests that integration is a slow

    process best accomplished in phases (Chaudhuri and Tabrizi, 1999), implying high cost in both time and effort.

    Limitations and Future Research

    Our results are based on a sample of star analysts and may not be generalizable to other knowledge workers or to

    star employees in other professions. Much of the prior work on tacit knowledge and firm- or team-specific human

    capital has been performed in settings in which work is primarily or partially physical in nature, such as sports (e.g.,

    Berman, Down and Hill, 2002; Glenn, McGarrity and Weller, 2001) and surgery (Huckman and Pisano, 2006). The

    operation of tacit knowledge in groups may differ in purely intellectual work, such as that performed by security

    analysts: it may not be as tacit as work that is partly physical. Our findings need to be replicated in other settings to

    determine their generalizability.

    Disentangling the effects of firm status and firm capability on performance would also be a valuable addition

    to the literature. As noted by Zuckerman and Merton (1971), reputation and performance are different phenomena,

    though closely correlated. It would also be helpful for future work to determine the specific components of firm

    capabilities that affect individual performance. This study has determined that colleague relationships constitute an

    important firm-specific resource, but it does not delve into the structure or the content of such ties, which no doubt

  • 7/28/2019 Portability Paper BLN MS

    25/37

    25

    determines their contribution to the performance of a focal individual. Which types of relationship are crucial to

    maintain, and to take to a new organizational setting, are important questions to pursue. Both for individuals

    contemplating a move and for firms intent on preserving firm-specific knowledge capabilities, the ability to distinguish

    and prioritize colleague ties has important performance and strategic consequences.

    Implications

    This paper has normative implications for managers of firms looking to acquire stars. The outside brain-collecting

    strategies practiced by some firms might create less value than they anticipate because some newly hired stars will

    be less productive in their new environments. Few hiring firms managers recognize that analysts performance is not

    portable. Firms seeking to hire a top performer cannot accurately value the likely return on their investment on the

    strength of that individuals record elsewhere. Yet many firms in professional business services continue to bid away

    top talent from rival firms on the assumption that the new hire can and will easily replicate his or her top performance

    in a new organizational context.

    This papers findings should also matter to star analysts and other high-performing employees, who may

    discount the firm-specificity of their skills and the likely impact on their performance of switching firms. A short-term

    increase in compensation should be weighed against expected future performance losses. Our interviews revealed,

    however, that star analysts systematically undervalue the role of their firm-specific skills and their firms capabilities.

    Meanwhile, firms eager to retain their stars would do well to promote awareness of the firms contribution to

    its stars success. In support of Peterafs (1993) observation, such firms might also want to promote talented workers

    dependence on the organization by offering opportunities to develop firm-specific skills and by making strategic

    investments in firm capabilities. Even if a star eventually leaves, the rival organization that hired him or her away

    might not recoup its investment and might even suffer a winners curse.

    Finally, our study contributes to an important debate in the regulatory arena. In the money-management

    industry, the question of who owns fund performance has become a contentious issue. The U.S. Securities and

    Exchange Commission generally supports the idea that star fund managers have the right to tout their fund-

    management performance at a different firm when raising new funds for their own firms. By contrast, neither the

    National Association of Security Dealers nor the Association for Investment Management and Research recognizes

  • 7/28/2019 Portability Paper BLN MS

    26/37

    26

    performance portability. These associations argue that even a portfolio manager who operated as the sole manager

    of a given fund benefited from exchanging investment-strategy ideas with other members of the firm. These

    organizations do not allow portfolio managers to include their prior records accrued at other firms when advertising

    their past returns at their new firms. Though our study shows that a stars past performance is a good indicator of

    future performance, it suggests support for the latter view that stars do not entirely own their past performance.

  • 7/28/2019 Portability Paper BLN MS

    27/37

    1. Analyst type 4200 0.837 0.370 0 1

    2. Analyst firm tenure 3639 7.190 5.779 0.011 37.060 0.124 ***3. Analyst experience 3653 10.776 6.018 2.174 44.966 0.100 *** 0.5

    4. Analyst star tenure 4200 6.635 5.604 1 26 0.314 *** 0.45. Analyst move 4059 0.090 0.286 0 1 -0.004 -0.0

    p

  • 7/28/2019 Portability Paper BLN MS

    28/37

    28

    M1 M2 M3 M4 M5Rank (t +1 ) Rank (t +2 ) Rank (t +3 ) Rank (t +4 ) Rank (t +5 )

    Year dummya

    yes yes yes yes yes

    Sector dummyb

    yes yes yes yes yes

    Firm dummy c yes yes yes yes yes

    Analyst rank dummy t = 0d

    yes yes yes yes yes

    Analyst type 0.174

    0.086 0.101 0.266

    0.341

    (0.094) (0.116) (0.129) (0.152) (0.190)

    Analyst firm tenure 0.000 -0.006 0.000 0.000 -0.003

    (0.005) (0.006) (0.008) (0.010) (0.011)

    Analyst experience 0.007 0.008 0.007 0.007 0.003

    (0.004) (0.006) (0.008) (0.009) (0.011)

    Analyst star tenure -0.024 *** -0.032 *** -0.042 *** -0.048 *** -0.051 ***

    (0.004) (0.006) (0.007) (0.008) (0.010)

    Analyst move -0.340 *** -0.263 ** -0.229 * -0.218 * -0.263 *

    (0.076) (0.089) (0.098) (0.111) (0.130)

    - Predicted probabilities

    for analysts who do not move:

    First rank 0.106 0.150 0.156 0.157 0.154

    Second rank 0.234 0.215 0.199 0.186 0.187

    Third rank 0.356 0.279 0.237 0.211 0.193

    Runner up 0.238 0.252 0.258 0.256 0.258

    Unranked 0.066 0.105 0.150 0.191 0.207

    - Marginal change in probabilities

    for analysts who move:e

    First rank -0.050 -0.053 -0.049 -0.047 -0.054

    Second rank -0.064 -0.040 -0.033 -0.029 -0.036

    Third rank -0.013 -0.008 -0.010 -0.011 -0.014

    Runner up 0.071 0.046 0.031 0.022 0.022

    Unranked 0.056 0.056 0.060 0.065 0.083

    Avg. Effect 0.051 0.041 0.036 0.035 0.042

    Cut Point 1f

    -0.960 -1.194 -1.209 -0.882 -0.624

    Cut Point 2 0.030 -0.307 -0.407 -0.141 0.106

    Cut Point 3 0.954 0.408 0.197 0.398 0.602

    Cut Point 4 1.791 1.098 0.837 1.000 1.212Log (likelihood) -4413.808 -4006.221 -3381.890 -2844.371 -2075.233

    No. of observationsg

    3511 2966 2451 2033 1501

    Pseudo-R2

    0.211 0.157 0.140 0.125 0.130

    p

  • 7/28/2019 Portability Paper BLN MS

    29/37

    29

    Rank (t +1 ) Rank (t +2 ) Rank (t +3 ) Rank (t +4 ) Rank (t +5 )

    Moving to a weaker firm

    Coefficient -0.338 * -0.407 * -0.312

    -0.590 ** -0.480

    Robust Std. Err. (0.163) (0.172) (0.191) (0.212) (0.280)

    N 90 81 64 48 32

    Moving to a comparable firm

    Coefficient -0.409 *** -0.250 * -0.199 -0.064 -0.137

    Robust Std. Err. (0.099) (0.121) (0.132) (0.145) (0.163)

    N 209 176 145 122 98

    Moving to a better firm

    Coefficient -0.144 -0.083 -0.187 -0.128 -0.358

    Robust Std. Err. (0.148) (0.164) (0.167) (0.191) (0.247)

    N 67 64 55 45 35

    Moving solo

    Coefficient -0.440 *** -0.270 ** -0.269 ** -0.167 -0.242

    Robust Std. Err. (0.086) (0.097) (0.103) (0.118) (0.146)

    N 266 233 195 157 124

    Moving in teams

    Coefficient -0.033 -0.149 -0.070 -0.267 -0.275

    Robust Std. Err. (0.132) (0.170) (0.188) (0.204) (0.206)

    N 100 88 69 58 41

    p

  • 7/28/2019 Portability Paper BLN MS

    30/37

    Figure 1Effect of Switching Firms on the Predicted Probability to Achieve First Rank by Direction and Type of Move: Year (t +1) and

    This figure provides graphical interpretation of the probabilities of achieving a first rank for all independent variables (Analyst move, Firm capability direction, and

    individual years (t+1 and t+5).

    0

    0.02

    0.04

    0.06

    0.08

    0.1

    0.12

    0.14

    0.16

    FirstRankProbability

    Probability of Achieving First Rank (t +1): Stay vs. Move

    Ranked analystswho did not change

    firms

    Ranked analystswho changed firms

    0

    0.04

    0.08

    0.12

    0.16

    FirstRankProbability

    Probability of Achieving First Rank (t +1): Stay vs. Moving Solo

    or w ith Teammates

    Ranked analystswho did not changefirms

    Ranked analystswho changed firmswith teammates

    Ranked analystswho changed firmssolo

    0

    0.02

    0.04

    0.06

    0.08

    0.1

    0.12

    0.14

    0.16

    FirstRankProbability

    Probability of Achieving First Rank (t +5): Stay v

    0

    0.04

    0.08

    0.12

    0.16

    FirstRankProbability

    Probability of Achieving First Rank (t +5): Stay vs.

    Comparable Firm

    0

    0.04

    0.08

    0.12

    0.16

    FirstRankProbability

    Probability of Achieving First Rank (t +5): Stay vs. M

    or wit h Teammates

    0

    0.04

    0.08

    0.12

    0.16

    FirstRankProbability

    Probability of Achieving First Rank (t +1): Stay vs. Moving to a

    Comparable Firm

    Ranked analystswho did not changefirms

    Ranked analystswho moved tocomparable firms

  • 7/28/2019 Portability Paper BLN MS

    31/37

    31

    References

    Acemoglu D., Pischke J.-S. 1998. Why Do Firms Train? Theory and Evidence. The Quarterly Journal of Economics113(1) 79-119.

    Allison P. D., Long J. S. 1990. Departmental Effects on Scientific Productivity.American Sociological Review55(4)469-478.

    Asquith P., Mullins D. 1986. Equity Issues and Offering Dilution. Journal of Financial Economics15(1/2) 61-89.

    Baks K. P. 2003. On the performance of mutual fund managers. Emory University, Unpublished paper.

    Barney J. 1991. Firm Resources and Sustained Competitive Advantage. Journal of Management17(1) 99-120.

    Barrett A., O'Connell P. J. 2001. Does training generally work? The returns to in-company training. Industrial andLabor Relations Review54(3) 647-662.

    Becker G. S. 1962. Investment in Human Capital: A Theoretical Analysis. The Journal of Political Economy70(5) 9-49.

    Becker G. S. 1976. The economic approach to human behavior. University of Chicago Press, Chicago.

    Berman S. L., Down J., Hill C. W. L. 2002. Tacit Knowledge as a Source of Competitive Advantage in the National

    Basketball Association.Academy of Management Journal45(1) 13-31.

    Bradley M., Desai A., Kim E. H. 1988. Synergistic gains from corporate acquisitions and their division between thestockholders of target and acquiring firms. Journal of Financial Economics21(1) 3-40.

    Brindisi L. J. 1985. Shareholder Value and Executive Compensation. Planning Review 13(5) 14-17.

    Brown L., Chen D. 1991. How good is the All-America Research Team in forecast earnings? Journal of BusinessForecasting9 14-18.

    Brown S. J., Warner J. B. 1980. Measuring Security Price Performance. Journal of Financial Economics8(3) 205-258.

    Burt R. S. 1987. Social Contagion and Innovation: Cohesion Versus Structural Equivalence. The American Journal of

    Sociology92(6) 1287-1335.Cassing J., Douglas R. W. 1980. Implications of the Auction Mechanism in Baseball's Free Agent Draft. Southern

    Economic Journal47(1) 110-121.

    Castanias R., Helfat C. 1991. Managerial Resources and Rents Journal of Management17(1) 155-171.

    Chapman K., Southwick L. 1991. Testing the Matching Hypothesis: The Case of Major League Baseball.AmericanEconomic Review89(5) 1352-1360.

    Chaudhuri S., Tabrizi B. 1999. Capturing the Real Value in High-Tech Acquisitions. Harvard Business Review77(5)123-130.

    Clark K. B., Fujimoto T. 1991. Product development performance: Strategy, organization, and management in theworld auto industry. Harvard Business School Press, Boston, MA.

    Cohen W. M., Levinthal D. A. 1990. Absorptive Capacity: A New Perspective on Learning and Innovation.Administrative Science Quarterly35(1) 128-152.

    Cole J. R., Cole S. 1973. Social stratification in science. University of Chicago Press, Chicago.

    Cowen A.P., Groysberg B., Healy P. 2006. Which Types of Analyst Firms Are More Optimistic? Journal of Accountingand Economics 41(1-2) 119-146.

    Cymrot D. J., Dunlevy J. A. 1987. Are Free Agents Perspicacious Peregrinators? The Review of Economics andStatistics69(1) 50-58.

  • 7/28/2019 Portability Paper BLN MS

    32/37

    32

    Dorfman J. 1991. Analysts devote more time to selling as firms keep scorecard on performance. Wall Street JournalOctober 29 1.

    Drucker P. F. 1998. On the Profession of Management. Harvard Business School Press, Cambridge, Mass.

    Drucker P. F. 1999. Management Challenges for the 21st Century. Harper Business, New York.

    Dyckman T., Philbrick D., Stephan J. 1984. A Comparison of Event Study Methodologies Using Daily Stock Returns:A Simulation Approach. Journal of Accounting Research22(Supplement) 1-30.

    Eccles R. G., Crane D. B. 1988. Doing deals: Investment banks at work. Harvard Business School Press, Boston,Mass.

    Ernst H., Leptien C., Vitt J. 2000. Inventors are not alike: The distribution of patenting output among industrial R & Dpersonnel. IEEE Transactions on Engineering Management47(2) 184-199.

    Ernst H., Vitt J. 2000. The influence of corporate acquisitions on the behaviour of key inventors. R and DManagement30(2) 105-120.

    Felin T., Hesterly W. S. forthcoming. The Knowledge-Based View, Heterogeneity, and New Value Creation:Philosophical Considerations on the Locus of Knowledge.Academy of Management Review.

    Friedberg R. M. 2000. You Can t Take It With You? Immigrant Assimilation and the Portability of Human Capital.Journal of Labor Economics18(2) 221-251.

    Galbraith J. R. 1977. Organization design. Addison-Wesley, Reading, Mass.

    Garen J. E. (Ed.). 1988. Empirical Studies of the Job Matching Hypothesis. JAI Press, Greenwich.

    Glenn A., McGarrity J. P., Weller J. 2001. Firm-specific human capital, job matching, and turnover: Evidence frommajor league baseball, 1900-1992. Economic Inquiry39(1) 86-93.

    Greene W. H. 2000. Econometric analysis (4th ed.). Prentice Hall, Upper Saddle River, N.J.

    Greenwood R., Hinings C. R., Brown J. 1990. "P2-Form" Strategic Management: Corporate Practices in ProfessionalPartnerships. The Academy of Management Journal33(4) 725-755.

    Groysberg B., Abrahams, R. 2006. Lift Outs: How to Acquire a High-Functioning Team. Harvard Business Review84(12) 133-140.

    Groysberg B., Lee L.-E. forthcoming. The Effects of Colleague Quality on Top Performance: The Case of SecurityAnalysts. Journal of Organizational Behavior

    Hackman J. R. 1990. Groups that work (and those that don't): Creating conditions for effective teamwork (1st ed.).Jossey-Bass, San Francisco.

    Harding F. 1998. Creating rainmakers: The managers guide to training professionals to attract new clients . AdamsMedia Corporation, Holbrook, Mass.

    Haspeslagh P., Jemison D. 1991. Managing Acquisitions. Free Press, New York.

    Heckman J. J. 1979. Sample Selection Bias as a Specification Error. Econometrica47(1) 153-161.

    Henderson R., Cockburn I. 1994. Measuring Competence? Exploring Firm Effects in Pharmaceutical Research.Strategic Management Journal15(Special Issue: Competitive Organizational Behavior) 63-84.

    Henning J. F. 1993. Maximizing Law Firm Profitability: Hiring, Training and Developing Productive Lawyers. LawJournal Seminars-Press, New York.

    Hill L. A. 1992. Becoming a Manager: Mastery of a New Identity. Harvard Business School Press, Cambridge, Mass.

    Howard G. G. 1967. What Makes a Good Analyst? Well... Institutional InvestorMay 10-15.

  • 7/28/2019 Portability Paper BLN MS

    33/37

    33

    Huber P. J. 1967. The behavior of maximum likelihood estimates under non-standard conditions, Proceedings of theFifth Berkeley Symposium on Mathematical Statistics and Probability, Vol. 1 221-233.

    Huckman R. S., Pisano G. P. 2006. The Firm Specificity of Individual Performance: Evidence from Cardiac Surgery.Management Science52(4) 473-488.

    Hunter J. E., Schmidt F. L., Judiesch M. K. 1990. Individual differences in output variability as a function of job

    complexity. Journal of Applied Psychology75(1) 28-42.

    Huselid M. A. 1995. The impact of human resource management practices on turnover, productivity, and corporatefinancial performance.Academy of Management Journal38(3) 635-672.

    Ibarra H. 1995. Race, Opportunity, and Diversity of Social Circles in Managerial Networks. The Academy ofManagement Journal38(3) 673-703.

    Ichniowski C., Shaw K., Prennushi G. 1997. The Effects of Human Resource Management Practices on Productivity:A Study of Steel Finishing Lines. The American Economic Review87(3) 291-313.

    Institutional Investor. 1991. The 1991 All-America Fixed Income Research Team. Institutional InvestorOctober 81-87.

    Jacob J., Lys T. Z., Neale M. A. 1999. Expertise in forecasting performance of security analysts. Journal ofAccounting and Economics28(1) 51-82.

    Kaplan S., Murray F., Henderson R. 2003. Discontinuities and senior management: assessing the role of recognitionin pharmaceutical firm response to biotechnology. Industrial and Corporate Change12(2) 203-233.

    Kim L. S. 1997. The dynamics of Samsung's technological learning in semiconductors. California ManagementReview39 86-100.

    Kitayama S., Markus H. R., Matsumoto H., Norasakkunkit V. 1997. Individual and collective processes in theconstruction of the self: Self-enhancement in the United States and self-criticism in Japan. Journal ofPersonality and Social Psychology72(6) 1245-1267.

    Kogut B., Zander U. 1996. What firms do? Coordination, identity, and learning. Organization Science7 502-518.

    Kordana K. A. 1995. Law Firms and Associate Careers: Tournament Theory Versus the Production-imperativeModel. The Yale Law Journal104(7) 1907-1934.

    Krautmann A. C., Oppenheimer M. 1994. Free Agency and the Allocation of Labor in Major League Baseball.Managerial & Decision Economics15(5) 459-469.

    Laderman J. M. 1998. Who Can You Trust? Wall Street's Spin Game.Business Week October 5 148-156.

    Lazear E. P. 1986. Raids and offer matching. Research in Labor Economics8(A) 141-165.

    Lippman S. A., Rumelt R. P. 1982. Uncertain Imitability: An Analysis of Interfirm Differences in Efficiency underCompetition. The Bell Journal of Economics13(2) 418-438.

    Long J. S., McGinnis R. 1981. Organizational Context and Scientific Productivity.American Sociological Review46(4) 422-442.

    Louis M. R. 1980. Surprise and Sense Making: What Newcomers Experience in Entering Unfamiliar OrganizationalSettings.Administrative Science Quarterly25(2) 226-251.

    Lurie S. B. 1967. What makes a good analyst? Institutional InvestorJuly 33, 42, 44.

    MacDonald D. N., Reynolds M. O. 1994. Are Baseball Players Paid their Marginal Products? Managerial & DecisionEconomics15(5) 443-457.

    Maddala G. S. 1983. Limited-dependent and qualitative variables in econometrics. Cambridge University Press,Cambridge.

  • 7/28/2019 Portability Pape