POPPER'S PARADOX OF DEMOCRACY

5
Think http://journals.cambridge.org/THI Additional services for Think: Email alerts: Click here Subscriptions: Click here Commercial reprints: Click here Terms of use : Click here POPPER'S PARADOX OF DEMOCRACY Bastiaan Rijpkema Think / Volume 11 / Issue 32 / September 2012, pp 93 96 DOI: 10.1017/S147717561200019X, Published online: 27 September 2012 Link to this article: http://journals.cambridge.org/ abstract_S147717561200019X How to cite this article: Bastiaan Rijpkema (2012). POPPER'S PARADOX OF DEMOCRACY. Think, 11, pp 9396 doi:10.1017/S147717561200019X Request Permissions : Click here Downloaded from http://journals.cambridge.org/THI, IP address: 137.99.31.134 on 05 May 2013

Transcript of POPPER'S PARADOX OF DEMOCRACY

Page 1: POPPER'S PARADOX OF DEMOCRACY

Thinkhttp://journals.cambridge.org/THI

Additional services for Think:

Email alerts: Click hereSubscriptions: Click hereCommercial reprints: Click hereTerms of use : Click here

POPPER'S PARADOX OF DEMOCRACY

Bastiaan Rijpkema

Think / Volume 11 / Issue 32 / September 2012, pp 93 ­ 96DOI: 10.1017/S147717561200019X, Published online: 27 September 2012

Link to this article: http://journals.cambridge.org/abstract_S147717561200019X

How to cite this article:Bastiaan Rijpkema (2012). POPPER'S PARADOX OF DEMOCRACY. Think, 11, pp 93­96 doi:10.1017/S147717561200019X

Request Permissions : Click here

Downloaded from http://journals.cambridge.org/THI, IP address: 137.99.31.134 on 05 May 2013

Page 2: POPPER'S PARADOX OF DEMOCRACY

POPPER’S PARADOX OF DEMOCRACYBastiaan Rijpkema

In a footnote to Chapter 7 of ‘The Open Society and ItsEnemies’ Karl Popper describes what he calls the ‘Paradoxof Democracy’: the possibility that a majority decides for atyrant to rule.1 This is the lesser known paradox of thethree to which he pays attention, the other two being the‘paradox of freedom’ – total freedom leads to suppressionof the weak by the strong – and the ‘paradox of tolerance’– unlimited tolerance leads to the disappearance oftolerance.

Popper’s paradoxes are of course closely related. Whentaken to their extremes, freedom, tolerance and democracycarry their own negation within them. Absolute freedom leadsto oppression, complete tolerance to intolerance, pure democ-racy to tyranny. Should we then – regarding democracy –simply draw the conclusion that it is in the nature of democracythat it can abolish itself? Or, as Hans Kelsen puts it: ‘eineDemokratie, die sich gegen den Willen der Mehrheit zubehaupten, gar mit Gewalt sich zu behaupten versucht, hataufgehort, Demokratie zu sein’.2

Popper is not willing to draw that conclusion, althoughhis arguments for not doing so are rather unsatisfactory.Basically he says: there can be no democracy for the anti-democrats, just as there can be no tolerance for the intoler-ant and, so he reminds us: a system with some form ofmajority rule is the best, but not infallible, form of govern-ment control.3 Popper thus presents us with a rather prag-matic solution to the paradox of democracy: we simplyneed to deny anti-democrats the right to democracy fordemocracy to survive. This is disappointing from a rationalthinker like Popper. For it seems that he does not see (ormore likely: does not want to see) the seemingly iron logic

doi:10.1017/S147717561200019X # The Royal Institute of Philosophy, 2012

Think 32, Vol. 11 (Autumn 2012)

ThinkA

utu

mn

2012†

93

Page 3: POPPER'S PARADOX OF DEMOCRACY

of ‘democracy as majority-rule’. The consequence of therelativism majority-rule implies, is that for democracy allbeliefs and convictions are equal, so they can freelycompete with each other in a Holmsian way. The theoreti-cal Popper we know from his work in the philosophy ofscience seems to be replaced by a more pragmatic or utili-tarian Popper when it comes to political philosophy.

The problem here is in the fact that Popper tacitlyaccepts that the essence of democracy – as Kelsenargues – is in majority-rule, and then argues, on groundsof desirability, that we cannot tolerate anti-democraticparties. This maneuver is understandable. When oneaccepts majority-rule as the defining aspect of democracy,the conclusion is inescapable:

P1 Democracy is majority ruleP2 Anti-democratic parties can seize a majorityC A democracy can abolish itself

Rather than denying the consequences afterwards, itseems prudent to take a closer look at the premises of thisargument. Although the truth of the second premise seemsobvious, the rightness of the first premise is less certain. Isdemocracy actually defined by ‘majority rule’?

The Dutch constitutional scholar George van den Berghdid not think so. His 1936 inaugural lecture at the Universityof Amsterdam is an impassioned defense of democracy intimes where the future of democracy was no longercertain.4 Van den Bergh dedicates much of his lecture to ananalysis of a rather outdated Dutch law on the basis ofwhich it would be possible to ban anti-democratic parties.He is, however, also concerned with the theoretical issue, inother words: the democratic paradox. Democracy, accordingto Van den Bergh, is not solely defined by majority-rule.Democracy is a system of self-correction. Characteristic ofdemocracy is that it is always able to revoke its owndecisions: every decision is subject to revocation. Thisleads Van den Bergh to conclude that all-but-one-decision

Rijp

kem

aPo

pp

er’

sPa

rad

ox

of

De

mo

cra

cy

†94

Page 4: POPPER'S PARADOX OF DEMOCRACY

for democracy has to be treated equally, namely: thedecision to abolish democracy. The latter decision is incom-patible with the nature of democracy, since the decision isirrevocable.

One could wonder, however, if this is really the sole irre-vocable decision in a democracy. What to think, forinstance, of a democratic decision to demolish some age-old monuments? There is, nevertheless, a subtle differencebetween such a decision and the decision to abolishdemocracy. Of course, due to factors in our outside world,the consequences of a democratic decision may be irre-versible to some extent, but this does not make thedecision itself irrevocable. When a democracy decides totear down a monument and the monument is demolishedaccordingly, it can decide to revoke the former decision –within the framework of democracy – and try to reverse theconsequences, i.e. rebuild the lost monument. When, onthe other hand, a democracy decides to abolish itself, thewhole framework is lost, which makes the decision not onlyirreversible, but also irrevocable: democracy decides not todecide any more.

Van den Bergh’s approach thus makes it – in contrast toPopper – also theoretically justifiable to ban antidemocraticparties. When we therefore change the first premise to‘democracy is government by self-correction’, it seemsquite possible to develop a coherent theory of democracyin which anti-democratic parties can be expelled from thedemocratic arena. It is then no longer necessary to repudi-ate, out of desirability, a logically compelling conclusion inretrospect.

Bastiaan Rijpkema is a PhD-Candidate at the Departmentof Jurisprudence, School of Law, Leiden University. [email protected]

Notes1 The Open Society and Its Enemies (Routledge,

1995), 602–3.

ThinkA

utu

mn

2012†

95

Page 5: POPPER'S PARADOX OF DEMOCRACY

2 Verteidigung der Demokratie’, in: Verteidigung derDemokratie: Abhandlungen zur Demokratietheorie (MohrSiebeck, 2006), 237.

3 Popper 1995, 603.4 De democratische Staat en de niet-democratische partijen

[De Arbeiderspers, 1936]; see on this in detail: Cliteur andRijpkema, ‘The Foundations of Militant Democracy’, in TheState of Exception and Militant Democracy in a Time of Terror,eds, Ellian and Molier, Republic of Letters, forthcoming 2012.

Rijp

kem

aPo

pp

er’

sPa

rad

ox

of

De

mo

cra

cy

†96