Paper on moral foundation of collective action against economic crime (final)
date post
22-Mar-2016Category
Documents
view
215download
1
Embed Size (px)
description
Transcript of Paper on moral foundation of collective action against economic crime (final)
MORAL FOUNDATION OF COLLECTIVE ACTION AGAINST ECONOMIC CRIME
BY DAUD VICARY ABDULLAH
President & Chief Executive Officer
and
Professor Dr. Abbas Mirakhor
First Holder
INCEIF Chair of Islamic Finance
International Centre for Education in Islamic Finance (INCEIF)
Lorong Universiti A
59100 Kuala Lumpur
MALAYSIA
Daud Vicary Abdullah
Tel: +603 7651 4141
Fax: +603 7651 4143
E-mail: dvicary@inceif.org
Professor Dr. Abbas Mirakhor
Tel: + 603 7651 4010
Fax: +603 7651 4143
E-mail: abbas@mirakhor.com
2 | P a g e
MORAL FOUNDATION OF COLLECTIVE ACTION AGAINST ECONOMIC CRIME
I. INTRODUCTION
By whatever definition or measure, economic and financial crimes are on the rise at
such a rapid pace to resemble an epidemic 1. No country, society, culture or community
seems immune to their devastating impact on victims, economies, governments and
societies2. Not long ago, these activities were known as victimless crimes3.
Consideration of these crimes has evolved over the last four decades. General concern
about them however intensified post-9/11 and accelerated post-2007/08 financial
crisis4. Activities that used to be thought of as developing country crimes, such as
bribery, corruption and fraud, are now major concerns of rich countries as well. While
the financial crisis focused attention on crimes of the white collar elite, empirical
research was pointing to an alarming phenomenon: the everyday crimes of the middle
class, crimes being committed by those at the very core of contemporary society.6
Much analysis of the growth in economic and financial crimes have focused on rapid
economic changes resulting from globalization and the accelerated pace of global
expansion of information technology.7 Very little attention has been paid to what a
number of observers consider as the most fundamental of all changes: the erosion of
morality.8 To be sure, there are classes of sociological, political, and psychological
studies, theoretical and empirical, that have dealt with what is referred to as a market
anomie, meaning the weakening market morality or normlessness.9 To our
knowledge, however, there have been very few studies that relate directly the growth
3 | P a g e
of economic and financial crimes to the erosion of morality worldwide, even in societies
where the market does not have a dominant role in the economy.10 Some have
focused their sight on the rapidly weakening general moral standards and admit that the
humanity is facing a particularly acute moral confusion. The cause, however, is said to
be the rapid changes that have undermined many of the institutions or traditions that
previously formed and policed our values. Further, says Richard Holloway, the Bishop
of Edinburgh, there can be little argument about the agent that has caused this change;
it is the dominance of the global market economy and the social and cultural
movements that have accompanied its ascendance.11 Accordingly, globalization led to
the emergence of conservative administrations, in the 1980s and 1990s, that radically
restructured and removed traditional restraints on markets and on capital leading to
unleashing of greed, self-centered and self-interested behavior. Importantly, this
unfettering of the market has been accompanied by a number of cultural and social
movements that questioned traditional approaches to human relations. The result has
been described as the political triumph of the Right and the cultural triumph of the
Left.12
According to the above argument, causes of the particularly acute moral confusion
are to be sought in the political triumph of the Right and the cultural triumph of the
Left. There is no erosion, in other words, in the moral standard of humans. Holloway
argues that there can be little doubt that our confusions are particularly acutenot
because we are less interested in or committed to the moral life than we used to be
but, presumably because of unfettered market and cultural changes. For long,
4 | P a g e
however, causal direction has been assumed from erosion of mortality to crime. Those
with weak ethics are naturally more likely to commit crime in all circumstances13, and
that it is taken as axiomatic that weakening ethics is one cause of crime.14Moreover,
concern with white collar crimes preceded by decades the strengthening of
globalization, deregulation of the markets and cultural changes.
Whatever the cause(s) of erosion of morality across cultures, recovering a universal
moral principle, acceptable to all members of the human community, will have to form
the foundation of effective mobilization of international cooperation in collective action
against economic and financial crimes. For reasons that this paper hopes to argue, the
demand for international co-operation in combating these crimes has not succeeded
to elicit the desired results because of lack of a well-articulated, globally-shared moral
basis for collective action against economic crime. The basic thrust of this paper is that
such a moral foundation is urgently needed. Given the deep pluralism that characterizes
contemporary humanity, this is a daunting challenge. Holloway provides two helpful
suggestions by defining two characteristics for any emerging morality. First, the
principle of harmis a useful guide in steering our way through the currents of debate
about what is or is not allowable or moral behavior and, second, the emerging morality
must be characterized by the principle of consent.15
This paper argues that unlike other complex moral issues facing human society, no
one would deny the enormous, clear and unambiguous harm caused by economic and
financial crimes. The outrage against these crimes are so strong that at least one
5 | P a g e
observer refers to them as crimes against humanity.16 The extent, intensity and depth
of the harm these crimes cause are well-described by their victims, according to which
this paper classifies them as assault upon human dignity, trust, contract and property,
all of which constitute fundamental elements of the institutional infrastructure of
societies. Without these, no social cohesion or continuity would be possible leading to
what Hobbes envisioned as a war of all against all. The paper argues that the first
requirement suggested by Holloway is already met. The paper further argues that
Holloways second requirement, integrally related to the first, can also be met. The
paper suggests that a moral principle that can meet the requirement is the golden rule
with its long history, in one form or another, in all known systems of thought, in all
societies, cultures and religions.
Accordingly, the next section deals with the first principle. It discusses the clear and
unambiguous principle of harm as it pertains to the devastating damage caused by
economic and financial crimes to human dignity, trust, contract and property. The third
section argues that the changes brought about by globalization and technical progress in
our time are not too dissimilar to those in the seventeenth and eighteenth centuries
which also changed moral perception. The Scottish Enlightenment thinkers responded
by envisioning a new moral sense. The section argues that, given the will, humanity
can respond to the present state of moral confusion by redefining the prevailing moral
sense in terms of the golden rule. The fourth section discusses the golden rule as a
universal moral principle that could be adopted as a result of consent of a broad
representation of all segments of humanity who would not want each other harmed
6 | P a g e
by economic crime. Section four also discusses the golden rule, its history, its presence
in all cultures and religions, its attribute of universalizability and potential for
attracting global consent. Section five concludes the paper.
II. EXTENT AND INTENSITY OF HARM CAUSED BY ECONOMIC
CRIME: MANY BROKEN WINDOWS
Analytic thinking about economic and financial crimes has evolved over the last
four decades. The most important dimension of this evolution has been the change in
focus on economic crime as victimless to the recognition of its far reaching, adverse
impact on a broad spectrum of victims. In 1982, a leading American political scientist,
James Q. Wilson, advanced an idea that became known as the broken windows
theory. The metaphor argued that if a broken window in a vacant building in a given
neighborhood is left unrepaired, soon most of the windows of that building would be
broken. The first unrepaired broken window signals that no one really cared about the
building itself and its integrity.17 Generalized, the idea suggests that tolerating crimes
leads to epidemics and, eventually, to social disintegration. Recently, William Black, the
author of The Best Way to Rob a Bank is to Own One, has contextualized the broken
windows theory to elite white collar crime. He suggests that Wilsons idea that
tolerating widespread smaller crimes would lead to epidemic levels of larger crimes
because it undermined community and social restraint has been proven by the