Nardinelli & Meiners.schmoller, The Methodenstreit

download Nardinelli & Meiners.schmoller, The Methodenstreit

of 9

Transcript of Nardinelli & Meiners.schmoller, The Methodenstreit

  • 7/26/2019 Nardinelli & Meiners.schmoller, The Methodenstreit

    1/9

    The original controversy started with MENGER(1883],

    SCHMOLLBR

    11883], and

    MENon [1884]. The quarrel continued for several years thereafter, though it was carried

    on rnostly by other writers. Many historians of economic thought have discussed tbe

    controversy. See, especially, GIDE and RlsT [1948], pp. 383-409; SCHUMPETER [1954a),

    pp. 800-824. (1954b). pp. 152-201;

    PIlISRA >

    [1983], pp. 219-224; and

    BosTAPH

    (1978].

    Over one hundred years have passed since Gustav Schmoller and Carl.

    Menger engaged in their famous ethodenstreitthe battle over methods. The

    original controversy is remembered as much for its bitterness as for its content.

    Tlie bitterness arose partly because of the substantial differences between

    Schmoller and Menger. The subsequent and continuing appearance of smaller

    ethodenstreite

    implies that the issues that sparked the quarrel went well

    beyond the differences that separated Schmoller and Menger.

    The origins of the controversy can be traced to the reaction in Germany to

    what was considered to be the excessive abstraetion of the English classieal

    economists. The work of David Ricardo, in particular, was regarded as flawed

    by its exclusive reliance on pure theory. Tbe older historical school (represented

    byWilhelm Roscher, Bruno Hildebrand, and Karl Knies) advocated the use of

    bistorieal evidence in the construction of economic theory, The members ofthe

    older bistorieal school did not oppose the use of theory; they opposed the

    Ricardians use of deductive theory without regard to bistorieal and social

    conditions

    The younger bistorical school, lea by Gustav Schmoller, went beyond the

    older school and argued that the abstract, deductive theories of the English

    classical eeonomists liad no place in economics. To Schmoller, scientifie eco

    nomics consisted of generalizations from historical monographs. General eco

    nomic propositions would emerge from the detailed historical studies that were

    to be the main aetivity of economists.

    Schmoller s disdain for theoretieal economics did not represent the viewpoint

    of an isolated, neglected scholar. He was the dominant figure in Germn

    academic economies and used bis influence to keep theoretical economics out

    of German

    universities

    His students and followers produced a series of detailed

    by

    CLARK NARDlNELLI and ROGIlR E. MElNERS

    Schmoller, the Methodenstreit, and the Development

    of Economic History

    Journal of lr\S tiluliona1 and Thcomical Ec onomics (JllE ) 144 (1988). S43-SSt

    Zeitschrift fU r i se mte S~l wisscn. lChaft

  • 7/26/2019 Nardinelli & Meiners.schmoller, The Methodenstreit

    2/9

    2 Such viewsare lo

    e

    foundin GlDEand RIST1948],

    p

    400; SCHIJMI Bml1954a].

    p.

    814 ;

    nd

    SEL IOMAN[1962],

    p.

    274 .

    Por a different

    view,

    see

    HAY EK 1934].

    s Abstraet theory has, however, developed in ways quite differeut from the models of

    Menger.

    historieal and industrial studies. The historical generalizaticns from these stud

    ies appeared in SCHMOLLERS1900-1904] outline of general

    economics.

    M enger,

    the founder of the Austrian school of

    economcs,

    initiated the

    Methodenstreit because bis theoretical work was ignored in Germany. He

    attacked the methods of the historicaJ school, cJaiming that history without

    theory eould not lead to progress in economics MENGER1883 ] . SCHMOLLER S

    [1883 ] unfavorable review and MENGERS1884 ] bitter reply constituted the

    original Methodenstreit Furtber exehanges did Iittle more than draw the line

    more sharply between the two schools. The Austrian school defended theory,

    abstracton, and deduction. The bistorical school defended history, realism,

    and induction. The

    differences

    n methods n turn stemmed

    Irom

    fundamental

    differences in world views, with the cosmopolitan, individualist outlook of the

    Austrians standing in sharp contrast to the nationahstic, collectivist outlook of

    the bistoricaJ school.

    Historians of economie thought have mostly concJuded that the

    Methoden-

    streit was inconclusive or a pointless waste o time.Some scholars regret that

    Menger devoted sueh a large part o his scholarly Jifeto the controversy. Others

    believe that his work on method contributed as mueh to the development of

    economics as bis work in pure theory

    HAYEK

    [1934],

    BoSTAPH

    [1978]). Al

    though the debate itself proved

    in conclusiv e,

    in the long

    run

    the

    influence

    of

    Menger vastly exceeded the influence o Schmoller. Abstraet theory, not bisto

    ry, formed

    the

    basis for economics in the twentieth century. lnstitutionalists

    and others influenced by the historical school achieved some prominence early

    n tbe twentietb century. but were eventuaJly swept away by the theorists.

    Moreover, when empirical economics did arise, it took the form of economet

    ries based on mathematical statisties. Contemporary econometrics has far more

    in common with contemporary theory than witb tbe detailed empirical studies

    of the bistorical school,

    Tbe failure o f tbe historical school to influence the development o economies

    has led many historians of thought to dismiss it as having had no lasting effect,

    That was not the case. The German historicaJ school bad great influence on the

    development of economie history. As economic history emerged as a seprate

    discipline n England, America, and France the historical method predominat

    ed. The dominance of

    the

    bistorical metbod cannol be attributed solely to the

    German historical school; England, for example, had its own historical school

    of economies. The German school

    nevertheless

    greatly influenced the develop

    ment of economic history. The detailed bistorical studies advocated by

    Schmoller appeared n England and America, as well as in Germany. In Eng

    land, separa te departments of economie bistory emerged, dominated by the

    J J I I I I l E

    lark Nardineli and Roger E Meiners

    44

  • 7/26/2019 Nardinelli & Meiners.schmoller, The Methodenstreit

    3/9

    h isto rica l m eth o d HARTE1971 ), pp. x i-x xx ix ), A lth ou gh Iro m time te time an

    e c o n o m i st

    or historian made a plea for tbe interaction of economic

    h isto ry an d

    theory, the general attitude of economic historians might best b e typified as a

    desire te be left alone by theorists and theory,

    In America, e c o n o m i c history a lso developed as a sep rate discipline al

    though it remained within departments o f economics. T h e German h istor i c a l

    school e s pe e i a lly influenced American institutionalism, w hic h to o k the hi s t ori

    cal approacb as its basic method. Tbe strengtb of institutionalism led to the

    creation of departments in which history and theory represented the two basic

    approaches te the study of econornics. The historical and theoretical approach

    es coexisted, with some scholars specializing in history and others in tbeory.

    Although important cr os so v er s o cc ur re d, a division of labor emerged in Amer

    ican

    e c o n o m i c e .

    DilTerent

    a p p ro a c h e s

    to

    m eth o d

    accompanied the

    divisi n o f

    labor. The theorists took physics as their model; the historians took seientific

    h isto ry -

    induction

    fro rn fa cts - a s

    their model.

    T h e first

    task of the

    e co n o m i st,

    then, was te amass large collections of fa cts, The work eCAmerican institu

    tionalists such as Wesley Clair Mitchell and John R ., C o m m o n s were re m a rk

    able

    Io r

    tbe

    v o lu m e o f

    factual material tbey

    represen te d .

    Tbe institutienalist influence reached its peak in the first quarter of the

    twentieth century, Thereafter, the historical rnethod came increasingly te be

    restricted le wo rk s in ec o n o m ic h isto ry . The study o f econemic events as part

    of larger social developments became .the province of economic hlstorans

    A m ric a a n d

    England. However,

    E n g lish e c o n o m ic histo ria n s re ta i ne d

    closer

    ties te theory, and produced works that were not se defiantly non-theoretical

    as those of their American and German counterparts HARTE

    1971D .

    T h e

    split between

    e c o n o m i c

    theory and

    ec o n om ic h isto ry

    widened .aCterthe

    second world war. The study of macroeconomics was transfermed by John

    M a y n a r d KEYNES1936 ] a n d his th e o re tical sy ste m . Where the study o f b u sin e s s

    cycles had been tbe province of historical economists and a place where theo

    rists took their lead frorn historians, tbe Keynesian Revolution firmly estab

    lished a th eoretical model at tbe ce n te r o f m a c ro e c o n om ic s. The o ld studies o f

    the history ofbusiness cycles and the economic historians who did them) were

    made obsolete by the Keynesian theories. Moreover, when the Keynesian

    theories themselves declined, it was in favor of other theories, not a return te

    histerical studies. Contemporary macroeconemics remains remarkably given

    its subject matter) ahistorical.

    The rises of mathemalical economics and econometrics also helped bring

    about the decline of economic history. As econometrics and mathematics grew

    in importance, courses in those subjects began le push courses in economic

    history out of the economics curriculum. Econometrics replaced history as one

    of tbe twin pillars of gradate training in economics. Today, most American

    economists receive no. training in economic history,

    The development of matbematical economics and econometrics benefitted

    tbeory in another important way: it made theory scientific. In tbe nineteenth

    chmolle r and t ethodenstreit

    4 4/3 1988)

  • 7/26/2019 Nardinelli & Meiners.schmoller, The Methodenstreit

    4/9

    The history of cliometrics has been the subject of many articles. For a sample, see

    Fooa.

    1966),

    MCCLOSK6Y

    1978), and

    MElNERS

    and

    NARDlNEW

    1986).

    h

    new economic history also managed to generate its own Mcthodenstreit. See

    N E NO 1970).

    century, members o the historical school were the scientists . The historical

    method used facts and induetion from facts, The abstraer and subjective nature

    o theory especially Austrian) looked unscientific to nineteenth century schol

    ars. The development ofmathematical economics and econometrics, however,

    made economic theory look like physics, Theory now became scientific, while

    history was relegated to the inferior status of unscientific. The importance of

    mathematics in elevating theory to its present predominant position as scientific

    economics should not be underrated. should also be noted, however, that the

    reduction in the scientific status of economic history was helped along by the

    perceived poor quality of the work in that

    field

    Much of it - espeeially in

    America - was simply bad economcs combined with bad history,

    The break between economic history and ecooomics was never complete.

    Many scholars continued lo work

    in

    both fields. The most important develop

    ment in maintaining a link between the two was the growth of the new econom

    ie history, or cliometrics. The new economic history can be described as the

    application of economie theory and methods to the study of economic history.

    In effect, the new economie history turned the methodological doctrine ofthe

    historical school on its head. s Aocording to the historical school, detailed

    historical study was how to do economics. According to the cliometricians,

    economie theory and econometrics were how to do history. The work of new

    eeonomie historians is often indistinguishable from that of economists prop r

    The new economic history arose in the 1950s and quickly grew. Although

    there was much grumbling among the adherents to the older methodology, by

    the 1960s R. W. FOGEL[1965] eouId announce the reunification of economic

    history and economie theory. The results of the reunification were a revitaliza

    tion of economic history as well as important new results in such areas as the

    economics ofslavery, the role ofrailroads ineconomie development, historical

    trends in the distribution of income, and a host of others.

    The success of eliometrics in producing significant new scholarship has,

    however, been accompanied by sorne notable failures. One such failure is that

    economie history has not regained its place as a basie field in the training of

    economists. Indeed, economie history has not even held its ground, as eourses

    inmathematics, statistics, and now computer science continu to erowd history

    out of the currieulum. If new eeonomic historians have succeeded in dernon

    strating the sophistication of their work to their colleagues in economics, they

    have nOI convinced Ihose colleagues that studying economie history should

    form part of the initial or eontinuing education of the adult economist,

    The failure to regain lost influence among economists stems partly from the

    nature of the neweconomie history. The most influential works of neweconom-

    J l l 1 l l E

    lark NardiMIfi and Roger E in rs

    6

  • 7/26/2019 Nardinelli & Meiners.schmoller, The Methodenstreit

    5/9

    ic historian s can be described as econometric history (MElNERSnd NARDINELLI

    (1986. Econometric history involves explicit, often mathematical theorizing

    combined with econometric testing of hypotbeses. The haJlmark of much of this

    work is the application of techniques and Iheories developed in economies to

    the study of historlcal problems. To economists, the achievements of economet

    rie history provide further demonstration of the power and scientific methodol

    ogy of economies. However, note that the tlow is entirely from economies lo

    economic history, Nothing in econometrlc history convinces the economist of

    the value of economie history. In the Methodenstreit fought over the correet

    method in economic history, the theorsts have won yet another battle, Having

    driven history out of economics they now threaten to drive history out of

    history.

    We no doubt exaggerate the econometric eharaeter of eontemporary histor

    ieal econom ic s Much of the besi work in econometric history embodies both

    the historieal and theoretical approaches. We also note that many new eco

    nomie historians have been calling for a reorieutation of economie history.

    Douglass NORTH[1981,1986) has argued for a new institutional economies that

    will re-emphasze the bistorical approach, Other economiehistorians (and some

    economists) stress the importance of the missing historical perspective of con

    temporary economics (PA R K E R [J 986). particular, stress is laid upon the faet

    that constraints - institutions - ehange over time and that these changes affect

    the choices made by individuals and societies. The German historieal school, of

    course, made the same point.

    Many distinguished economists and econornie historians believe that eco

    nomie history should regain its place as part of the standard equipment of the

    economist (P

    RK R

    (1986). Yet, such a change does not appear Iikely. The

    Jatest generation of economists knows mueh lesshistory than the last: it is a safe

    predietion that the next generation will know stiU less The separation and

    decreasing contact between economics and econornie history is an accom

    plished faet. The question to which wenow turn iswhat role did Schmoller and

    the etho enstreu play in that separation. In order to assess that role, it is

    necessary to diseuss two explanations for why economie theory and economie

    history have parted company.

    One explanation is that the separation was an inevitable outcome of the

    progress of econornic science. Modern scholarship is dominated by speeialists:

    economists since Adam Smith have emphasized the gains in efficiency from

    specialization. As the generaJists of the nineteenth century gave way to the

    specialists of the twentieth century, it was inevitable that economics ano eco

    nomic history should split aparto The ethodenstreitthen, was merely a sign

    of things to come. Aceording to the view that specialization and the division of

    labor had to occur, Schmoller could have had no effect on the ultimate devel

    opment of twentieth century econornics. That developmentfollowed a path set

    by the nature of economics. The corree methodology (mathematical and statis

    tical) emerged as part of the disciplines progress toward objective truth.

    5 7chmoller and the ethodenstrelt

    44/3 (1988)

  • 7/26/2019 Nardinelli & Meiners.schmoller, The Methodenstreit

    6/9

    An alternative explanation for the break between economic history and

    theory is based on the belief that the current state of a discipline is indeed

    dependent upon its past. IC such be the case, then events in the history of

    economics led to the break. Under dfferent circumstances, then, history rnight

    have remained an integral part ofeconomics. We will atternpt lo assess the

    influence of Schmoller and the

    Methodenstreit

    on the assumptions that the

    development of economics

    not a movement along a fore-ordained path lo

    truth, and that particular scholars and movements have significantly altered the

    methods and content of contemporary economics.

    No single individual can be credited or blamed) fOI the

    rise

    of the historical

    approach in economics. In Germany itself the older historical school and other

    members of the younger school had great influence. France had its own tradi

    tion of positivism and the historical approach. In England, the development of

    the historical approach owed more to the English historical school Iban the

    Germn KOOT 1980)).With these qualifications in mind, we would argue that

    Schmoller himself significantly increased the useand influence ofthe historical

    method in economics and economic history.

    Schmoller exercised his influence both directly and indirectly. His direct

    influence stemmed from his many students and disciples in Germany. Through

    bis influence members of the younger historical school carne to domina te

    academic economics in Germany, holding a majority of the professorships,

    Frederick

    LANE

    1966] identified Werner Sombart, Arthur Spiethoff, Walter

    Eucken, and the Austrian Joseph Schumpeter as the heirs o f Schmoller. Promi

    nent students and disciples from outside Germany included William

    J.

    Ashley,

    Edwin F. Gay, W. A. S. Hewins, George Unwin, and WilIiam H. Cunningham.

    The indirect influence of Schmoller stemmed from the enormous prestige of

    German social science.

    As

    a major figure within Germany, bis ideas naturally

    filtered out to foreign scholars affected by German thought, The Germn

    influence is particularly apparent in much of the economics and economic

    history published in the United States in the late nineteenth and early twentieth

    century. Thousands of Americans studied at German universities during the

    era. In a 1908survey of 116 American economists, 59 had engaged in graduate

    study in Germany SEUGMAN1962], p. 615). The influence of Schmoller and

    the historical school, then, kept the historical approach alive in American

    economics. Indeed, one might argue that the break between economics and

    economic history would have come earlier but for the influence ofthe historicaJ

    school, The traditional place of historical studies in the currculum in econom

    ics could be a legacy of Ibat influence.

    another way, however, Schmoller s influence probably hurt the cause of

    economic history. His insistence that the historical method was the only way

    to conduct economic research contributed to the decline of German economics

    and economic history. lo the long ron, pertinacity in matters of method may

    have damaged American economic history as well. American institutionalism

    - first cousin to economic history - declined and virtually disappeared because

    tark Nardirtelliand Roge Meiners

    8

  • 7/26/2019 Nardinelli & Meiners.schmoller, The Methodenstreit

    7/9

    it failed to develop a th eoretical focus (NoR1lI 986, p. 235).That same lack

    of theoreticalfocus contributed

    the decline of the old economic history. In

    botb England and fue United States, economic history and economic theory

    lived under conditions of peaceful coexistence, sharing the task of educating

    future scholars but in other ways not interacting. As the theorists refined and

    improved their product, the historical method fell into disrepute as a way of

    doing economics. Although scholars madc occasional picas for history in eco

    nomic lheory or theory in economic history, the two fields drifted apart. The

    drift may in part be attributed to Schmoller, for two reasons.

    First, the extreme bitterness ofthe

    eth odenstreit

    may have caused scholars

    be wary of methodological conflict in general. Although an occasional

    Jlare-up occurred, theorists and historians mostly kepl

    Ihemselves. Second,

    the tradition that economic history dealt with facts, nOItheory, led lo Ihe failure

    to make important theoretical contributions. If economic historians had been

    enthusiastic consumers of economic theory, tbey might have become producers

    as well. Using economc theory lo answer historieal questions might have

    forced them io confront the inadequacies of completely ahistorical economic

    theory.

    What ultimately was missing, then, was a dialogue between economics and

    economic history. Such a dialogue would have increased the theoretical content

    of econornc history and the historical content of economic theory, As Clapham

    said, it is at the overlapping margins of disciplines and sciences that the most

    important discoveries are iusually rnade (CWHAM [1953), p.420). When

    the cliometricians re-introduccd economic theory into economic history,

    Claphams insight was vindicated many times overoWhen new economic histo

    rians, however, attempted

    re-introduce the historical method into econom

    ics, they met with no success. Indeed, the cliometric revolution appeared to

    justify the economic theorist s beliefin the power oftheory. Economic history

    was viewed as merely a field in applied economics, not an equal partner with

    theory. As Parker has pur it, the fields of economic history and economic

    institutions ha ve themselves been partially transformed or distorted into play

    grounds for the imagination ofthe theorist

    P RKER

    [1986 , p. 7 . The interac-

    tion between history and theory, tben. is not a conversation; it is a lecture.

    We therefore view the

    eth odenstreit

    primarily as a lost opportunity.

    Schmoller and Menger might have begun a conversation between the theoret

    ical and historical schools, a conversation that could have served as a model for

    other times and other places. Moreover, Schmoller must bear the greater part

    of the blame. Menger, the admirer of WiJliam Roscher, did not deny the

    importance of the historical approach; the treatment of his work by the histor

    ical school led him to the controversy.

    No single scholar determines the course of a discipline. Yet, the influence of

    Schmoller may well have affected in sorne way the course of the discipline of

    economic history. The emphasis upon the institutional aspects of economic life

    and upon the need for historical study are difficult lo fault. The products of

    549

    chmoller and the ethoenstrett44/3 1988

  • 7/26/2019 Nardinelli & Meiners.schmoller, The Methodenstreit

    8/9

    ANDIlEM

  • 7/26/2019 Nardinelli & Meiners.schmoller, The Methodenstreit

    9/9

    Profuso lark Nodinelli

    Professor Roger E Meiners

    Department of Economics and

    Center for

    Poticy

    Studies

    Clemso Universlty

    Clemson SC 29634

    U s

    S c H u M P 1 I T E R J. A. [1954a. History of Economic Analysis New York.

    -- [19S4b Econom tc

    Doctrine

    and

    Me/hod

    New York.

    SEUGMAN

    B. B.[1962

    Main Cwrents in Motkrn Economics

    New York.

    551chmoller and the Methodenstret44/3 1988