Move to markets? An empirical analysis of privatization in developing countries

28
Journal of International Development J. Int. Dev. 16, 213–240 (2004) Published online in Wiley InterScience (www.interscience.wiley.com). DOI: 10.1002/jid.1072 MOVE TO MARKETS? AN EMPIRICAL ANALYSIS OF PRIVATIZATION IN DEVELOPING COUNTRIES SUDESHNA GHOSH BANERJEE 1 and MICHAEL C. MUNGER 2 * 1 Europe and Central Asia Region, The World Bank, Washington DC, USA 2 Department of Political Science and Department of Economics, Duke University, Durham, North Carolina, USA Abstract: Aspects of the privatization experience are analysed for a group of 35 low or middle-income developing countries, over the period 1982 through 1999. The theory turns on net political benefits, which in our model are the primary determinant of privatization policies. The decision to privatize is captured here in three related, but distinct, dependent variables: (i) timing; (ii) pace; and (iii) intensity. Our notion of the independent variable, ‘net political benefits’, is not measured directly, but is instead proxied by an array of macroeconomic, political, and institutional variables. Our key finding is that, though political benefits turn out to explain the timing, pace, and intensity of privatization, the effects are very different in each case. The timing hypothesis is tested using a Cox proportional hazard model, the pace hypothesis is tested using a random effects negative binomial model and the intensity hypothesis is tested using the random effects model. We find that the factors that improve timing delay intensity—early adopters are later implementers. Furthermore, we find that a privatization policy is much more likely to be a crisis-driven, last ditch effort to turn the economy around, rather than a carefully chosen policy with explicit, long-term goals. A related, and very important, finding in our analysis has to do with the ‘lock-in’ of institutions. The particular form of political institutions, foreign aid regimes, and level of development of property rights systems in the nation have significant conditioning influences on the extent of lock-in. These relationships may be important for informing policy decisions, and for understanding apparent ‘failures’ of privatization policies. Copyright # 2004 John Wiley & Sons, Ltd. I had to fight. The government was going to sell our companies ... our wealth ... and enrich another country. This was my voice, my protest. —Fanny Puntaca, 66, shopkeeper, at a protest march in Arequipa, Peru, 13 July 2002. Quoted in Forero (2002), New York Times story on sale of two state-owned electrical plants to a private Belgian company. Copyright # 2004 John Wiley & Sons, Ltd. * Correspondence to: M. C. Munger, Department of Political Science, and Department of Economics, Duke University, Box 90204, Durham, North Carolina 27708, USA. E-mail: [email protected]

Transcript of Move to markets? An empirical analysis of privatization in developing countries

Page 1: Move to markets? An empirical analysis of privatization in developing countries

Journal of International Development

J. Int. Dev. 16, 213–240 (2004)

Published online in Wiley InterScience (www.interscience.wiley.com). DOI: 10.1002/jid.1072

MOVE TO MARKETS? AN EMPIRICALANALYSIS OF PRIVATIZATION IN

DEVELOPING COUNTRIES

SUDESHNA GHOSH BANERJEE1 and MICHAEL C. MUNGER2*1Europe and Central Asia Region, The World Bank, Washington DC, USA

2Department of Political Science and Department of Economics, Duke University, Durham,

North Carolina, USA

Abstract: Aspects of the privatization experience are analysed for a group of 35 low or

middle-income developing countries, over the period 1982 through 1999. The theory turns on

net political benefits, which in our model are the primary determinant of privatization policies.

The decision to privatize is captured here in three related, but distinct, dependent variables: (i)

timing; (ii) pace; and (iii) intensity. Our notion of the independent variable, ‘net political

benefits’, is not measured directly, but is instead proxied by an array of macroeconomic,

political, and institutional variables. Our key finding is that, though political benefits turn out

to explain the timing, pace, and intensity of privatization, the effects are very different in each

case. The timing hypothesis is tested using a Cox proportional hazard model, the pace

hypothesis is tested using a random effects negative binomial model and the intensity

hypothesis is tested using the random effects model. We find that the factors that improve

timing delay intensity—early adopters are later implementers. Furthermore, we find that a

privatization policy is much more likely to be a crisis-driven, last ditch effort to turn the

economy around, rather than a carefully chosen policy with explicit, long-term goals. A

related, and very important, finding in our analysis has to do with the ‘lock-in’ of institutions.

The particular form of political institutions, foreign aid regimes, and level of development of

property rights systems in the nation have significant conditioning influences on the extent of

lock-in. These relationships may be important for informing policy decisions, and for

understanding apparent ‘failures’ of privatization policies. Copyright # 2004 John Wiley

& Sons, Ltd.

I had to fight. The government was going to sell our companies . . . our wealth . . . andenrich another country. This was my voice, my protest.

—Fanny Puntaca, 66, shopkeeper, at a protest march in Arequipa, Peru, 13 July

2002. Quoted in Forero (2002), New York Times story on sale of two state-owned

electrical plants to a private Belgian company.

Copyright # 2004 John Wiley & Sons, Ltd.

* Correspondence to: M. C. Munger, Department of Political Science, and Department of Economics, DukeUniversity, Box 90204, Durham, North Carolina 27708, USA. E-mail: [email protected]

Page 2: Move to markets? An empirical analysis of privatization in developing countries

1 INTRODUCTION

Consider a nation contemplating privatization. Almost by definition, this is a profound

reversal of decades of public policy. For starters, for privatization to be controversial, the

nation must have pervasive public ownership of assets. And this public ownership is no

accident: for decades, in the 1930s through the 1980s, the trend was toward centralization.

But for years the new trend, fostered by economic conditions, international agencies and

neo-conservative political ideology, has been away from state domination of production,

and toward private ownership and free enterprise. In the process, the role of the state has

been transformed as well. Where states had been producers of goods and services, in a

successful private economy the state is much more likely to focus on fostering private

investment, protecting property rights, and providing basic services to the poor.

But, for the angry Peruvian shopkeeper quoted above, and for thousands like her all over

the world, privatization is controversial. At this point, there are many anecdotal accounts

of patterns of privatization, but policy makers have little systematic knowledge about the

patterns of conditions that lead to success, or failure in general. In this paper we identify a

set of conditions that have led to ‘success’, in a variety of nations over a period of nearly

two decades.

Privatization can mean denationalization (direct sale of public assets), deregulation

(introduction of competition in previously monopoly sectors such as electrical power,

natural gas, and water), or contracting out (lease, contract for concessions, build-

own-operate, build-own-operate-transfer etc.). For most nations, the privatization ex-

perience is a complex combination of all three kinds of activity. But this paper only deals

with the most easily measured and clearest form of privatization—the direct sale of public

assets and state-owned enterprises. It is important to recognize that privatization is at

most a means to an end, rather than an end in itself. But we proceed under the

assumption that policymakers have decided, for whatever reason, that privatization is a

desirable goal.

Plan of the paper

Our goal is to explain the underlying political–economic interactions affecting privatiza-

tion decisions. The argument rests on the claim that there are different components of what

is loosely called ‘privatization’: (i) timing; (ii) pace; and (iii) intensity. The timing of

privatization decisions—the year when first privatization transaction was adopted—is a

critical point in the country’s development path because it marks a fundamental change in

direction at the highest levels of policy-making. The pace (number of enterprises sold) and

intensity (total value of enterprises sold) are two different ways of conceptualizing

whether the change in policy choice leads to a change in policy implementation. Even

after a government decides to privatize, implementation may be completely blocked,

gradually accepted, or immediately embraced by those who hold stakes in the process.

This paper asks the following questions:

* When and how have economies privatized?

* What are the factors that affect their decision-making?

* Do the same factors affect the timing, pace, and intensity decisions, and do these factors

matter differently for different aspects of privatization? It so, how?

* How does the institutional infrastructure affect the timing and implementation of

privatization strategy?

214 S. G. Banerjee and M. C. Munger

Copyright # 2004 John Wiley & Sons, Ltd. J. Int. Dev. 16, 213–240 (2004)

Page 3: Move to markets? An empirical analysis of privatization in developing countries

* Are all the three decisions—timing, pace, and intensity, critical to the success of

privatization policy?

In the following section, we present a conceptual framework of the paper, which rests on

‘net political benefits’ (NPB). We will argue that NPB is determined (in the reduced form

sense, for this model) by three components: (i) macroeconomic variables; (ii) political

variables; and (iii) institutional variables. In Section III, we describe the methods we use to

analyse each of our three related dependent variables (timing, pace, and intensity). We

discuss the results in Section IV. In the fifth and final section, a summary of our results is

offered, and some tentative conclusions drawn.

2 CONCEPTUAL FRAMEWORK

The key dependent variable causing the decision to privatize is ‘net political benefits’

(NPB)—which we define as the difference between the benefits and costs of divestiture,

from the perspective of political elites. Costs are usually immediate, while prospective

benefits occur in the future. Consequently, the politicians with short time horizon will

avoid privatization preferring status quo (Przeworski and Limongi, 1991). A related issue

is the free-rider problems for the reform-minded politicians. In the coordination or

collective action framework discussed by Geddes (1994) and Haggard and Kaufman

(1992), political power is dispersed. As a result, the politicians who benefit from the

privatization reforms may not be the ones who initiated it.

Thus, privatization occurs only when the present value of political benefits from

efficiency gains are higher than political costs of redistribution.1 It is difficult to

operationalize NPB directly, or structurally. But factors that determine NPB can be

categorized into (i) macroeconomic, (ii) political and (iii) institutional variables.

The description and data sources of dependent and explanatory variables are presented

in Table 1 and 2. A number of explanatory variables have been used as proxies

for macroeconomic, political and institutional determinants of privatization. The justifica-

tion of using these variables is based on the political economy of reform literature, as we

will discuss next.

Figure 1. A model of net political benefits. Source: Ghosh (2001)

1Our approach is a variant of the Rodrik’s (1994) political cost–benefit ratio (PCBR) of trade reforms. He arguesthat since redistributing income is politically costly, this cost must be weighed against the benefits arising fromeconomic efficiency of trade reforms. He defines PCBR as the ratio of redistribution generated by reform to itsefficiency benefits. The PCBR concept is difficult to operationalize empirically because the ‘decision to privatize’is based on estimates of ex-ante efficiency gains and redistributive cost.

Move to Markets? 215

Copyright # 2004 John Wiley & Sons, Ltd. J. Int. Dev. 16, 213–240 (2004)

Page 4: Move to markets? An empirical analysis of privatization in developing countries

Table 1. Definition, description, and sources of dependent variables

Explanatory variables—definitionand description Sources

Timing—0 for the years of no privatization and 1 Privatization database (The World Bank, 2000) and

for the year of first privatization and thereafter Candoy-Sekse (1988)

Pace—Annual frequency of privatization transactions Privatization database (The World Bank, 2001) and

Candoy-Sekse (1988)

Intensity—Annual value of privatization proceeds Privatization database (The World Bank, 2001)

Table 2. Definition, description, and sources of explanatory variables

Explanatory variables—definition and description Sources

Macroeconomic variables

FISCALBAL—Budget balance as a percentage of Gross IMF International Finance statistics, 2000

Domestic Product (excluding grants); lagged one period

INFLA—Annual inflation rate; lagged one period World Development Indicators, 2000

GROWTH—Annual growth rate; lagged one period World Development Indicators, 2000

AIDGNI—Foreign Aid as a percentage of Gross World development indicators, 2000

National Investment

AGRGDP—Agriculture value added as a percentage of GDP World development indicators, 2000

INEQ—Degree of inequality in the economy Deininger and Squire (1996)

(average Gini coefficient in 1982–99)

SOEGDP—Size of the public sector as a percentage of GDP Haggarty and Shirley (1997)

SOEINITIAL—Size of public sector in the year of first privatization

Political variables

YRSOFFC—Number of years the chief-executive Beck et al. (2001)

has been in office

IDEOLOGY—Dummy for ‘right’ ideology of the Beck et al. (2001)

chief executive’s party

COHESION—Index of political cohesion Beck et al. (2001)

DEMOC—Aggregate indicator of democracy. Addition Freedom House (2001)

of POLRTS and CIVLIB

POLRTS—Political rights available to citizens Freedom house (2001)

CIVLIB—Civil liberties available to citizens

Institutional variables

GOV—Aggregate indicator of quality of governance. International Country Risk Guide (Political

Addition of following five variables: Risk Services Group)

CORRUPTION—Corruption in government; degree International Country Risk Guide (Political

to which business transactions involve corruption Risk Services Group)

or questionable payments; varies from 0–6

RULELAW—Rule of law; degree to which the citizens International Country Risk Guide (Political

of a country are willing to accept the established institutions Risk Services Group)

to make and implement laws and adjudicate disputes;

ranges from 0–6

BURQLTY—Quality of bureaucracy; measures the International Country Risk Guide (Political

regulatory environment the domestic and foreign firms Risk Services Group)

must face when seeking approvals and permits;

ranges from 0–6

REPUCON—Risk of repudiation of contracts by International Country Risk Guide (Political

government; measures the ‘possibility that foreign Risk Services Group)

businesses, contractors and consultants face the risk

of contract modification, postponement or scaling

Continues

216 S. G. Banerjee and M. C. Munger

Copyright # 2004 John Wiley & Sons, Ltd. J. Int. Dev. 16, 213–240 (2004)

Page 5: Move to markets? An empirical analysis of privatization in developing countries

2.1 Macroeconomic Variables

2.1.1 Crisis (FISCALBAL, INFLA, GROWTH)

We hypothesize that countries adopt privatization as a response to crisis. The pace of

privatization would also be affected by crisis; countries in worse fiscal crisis situations

would privatize faster to raise resources.

Gourevitch (1986) defines crisis as ‘moments of critical choice when old relationships

crumble and new ones have to be constructed creating a more open political environment’.

Most of the studies that analyzed the impact of crisis on economic reforms conclude that

the crises (wage, fiscal deficit/inflation, growth) become so unbearable that political cost

of continuing is higher than cost of policy reform. Crisis increases the cost of delaying

privatization and hence the net political benefits. Reform after crisis has been labeled as

the ‘new conventional wisdom’ (Tommasi and Valesco, 1996). For example, public sector

deficits led to high inflation in the early eighties in several Latin American countries. The

high inflation countries subsequently undertook reforms while the no-inflation countries

were much less likely to take action. It appears that recent reforms are ‘inflation’s

children’ (Bruno and Easterly, 1996). In his analysis of trade reforms in developing

countries, Rodrik (1994) has noted that ‘no significant case of trade reform in a developing

country in the 1980s took place outside the context of a serious economic crisis’.

There are two related trade-offs with respect to crisis and reform. (i) Long-term versus

short-term—when is the right time to undertake reforms in crisis and how long should a

country wait before taking action? Drazen and Grilli (1993) argue that distortions and

crisis as a result of years of inefficiencies in the public sector can raise welfare if it is the

only way to undertake privatization. Hence crises may be desirable if it places the

economy on a welfare-superior path. How bad does it have to get before government takes

the necessary reform steps? If the beneficiaries from public enterprises are a large fraction

of the government’s support base, then the economic downturn has to be very serious for

the political decision-maker to undertake the privatization action. Then serious reforms are

more likely to take place in periods of crisis as an increase in the cost of waiting makes

Table 2. (Continued )

Explanatory variables—definition and description Sources

down as a result of change in government, income drop,

budget cutbacks, indigenization pressure or change in

government priorities’; ranges from 0–10

EXPRORISK—Risk of expropriation of private International Country Risk Guide (Political

investment; measures the risk of ‘outright confiscation Risk Services Group)

and forced nationalization’ of property; ranges from 0–10

MARKETLAG—Stock market capitalization as a Beck et al. (2000).

percentage of GDP; lagged one period

MARKET—Stock market capitalization as a percentage of GDP

ETHNIC—Ethnic tension; measures ‘degree of tension International Country Risk Guide (Political

within a country attributable to racial, nationality Risk Services Group)

and language divisions; from 0–6

Control variables

GDPCAP—Initial GDP per capita World Development Indicators, 2000

AFRICA, LAC—Dummy for the continents World Development Indicators, 2000

TRADE—Trade openness World Development Indicators, 2000

ILLITERACY—Adult illiteracy (age 15 and above) World Development Indicators, 2000

Move to Markets? 217

Copyright # 2004 John Wiley & Sons, Ltd. J. Int. Dev. 16, 213–240 (2004)

Page 6: Move to markets? An empirical analysis of privatization in developing countries

political agreement more likely.2 (ii) Winners versus losers—how does the government

manage the distributional effects of reforms? The Alesina and Drazen (1991) war of

attrition framework argues that conditions must be intolerable for one of the groups to

accept the rising cost of stabilization. Reform may be blocked by transactions costs, or the

inability to guarantee Pareto improvement. This is true even if privatization satisfies the

‘potential Pareto’, or Kaldor–Hicks criterion.3 Generally, the groups that bear the burden

are the poor and the politically weak.

In the case of privatization, the ‘transactions cost’ have mostly to do with guaranteeing

streams of rents that meet or exceed streams under the current system. An economic cost-

benefit analysis is inefficient, because the question has less to do with size of the net gains

than with their distribution. So, the role of crisis becomes clear—crisis lowers the

expected rent streams under the current system, making reform relatively more attractive.

2.1.2 Dependence of foreign aid (AIDGNI)

The evidence on the effect of aid on economic reforms is ambiguous. On one hand, higher

levels of aid dependence may delay the privatization decision as unsustainable public

sector policies can continue indefinitely.4 On one other hand, privatization can be

undertaken if the international aid donors insist on the countries’ adopting privatization

as a condition of aid. Then privatization becomes imperative for the aid-dependent

economies. In recent times, aid has included a labor-adjustment component. The technical

assistance component of aid can facilitate the privatization process by setting up the

institutional infrastructure to conduct privatization transactions. Therefore, the net effect

of foreign aid on privatization outcomes is indeterminate.

2.1.3 Size of the public sector relative to the rest of the economy (SOEINITIAL, SOEGDP)

Larger the size of the public sector, the more likely it would include activities that are in

competitive sectors. Divesting them would involve higher potential efficiency gains

(Campos and Esfahani, 1995). But a large public sector also means a more powerful

voice of its stakeholders in the decision-making process that implies higher interest group

stake in maintaining the status quo. Consequently, higher would be the costs of

privatization. Economic gains are higher but political gains may well be lower because

of transactions costs. Affected interest groups are likely to be both highly motivated and

well organized. Of course, as was discussed above, crisis may ‘solve’ this problem, by

loosening the ‘lock in’ conditions.

2.1.4 Size of the agricultural sector (AGRGDP)

This indicator, measured as share of agriculture in GDP, serves as a proxy for the structure

of the economy, whether the country already has a large manufacturing and services sector

2This is a specific instance of North’s (1990) general ‘transactions cost’ analysis. As North (1990, p. 8) points out:‘Transactions costs in political and economic markets make for inefficient property rights, but the imperfectsubjective models of the players as they attempt to understand the complexities of the problems they confront canlead to the persistence of such property rights’.3For a comparison of the Kaldor-Hicks and Pareto criteria, see Munger (2000).4Aid-dependent countries may be able to delay privatization by using aid to manage economic downturn or tofund government expenditure. Foreign aid represents additional sources of funds to reduce the fiscal deficitwithout undertaking public sector reform. Aid dependence can be counterproductive if it delays undertakingpolicy reforms (Casella and Eichengreen, 1996). Large public deficits were sustained through foreign aid,especially in sub-Saharan economies (Knack, 2000). Rodrik (1996) notes that aid helps governments survive byreducing the cost of not doing anything and increasing the cost of doing something. Aid increases the benefits ofprivatization as divestiture proceeds can be used to retire debt.

218 S. G. Banerjee and M. C. Munger

Copyright # 2004 John Wiley & Sons, Ltd. J. Int. Dev. 16, 213–240 (2004)

Page 7: Move to markets? An empirical analysis of privatization in developing countries

and consequently, a functioning private sector. A large agricultural sector increases the

cost of privatization, because it is less likely that such countries would have functioning

market institutions to facilitate private activity.5

2.1.5 Degree of inequality (INEQ)

The distributional concerns affecting a majority of the population would determine the

policy choices. If the economy’s wealth is unequally distributed, the ex-ante uncertainty is

higher and privatization decision is more difficult.6 An alternate explanation is that in more

unequal societies, power is concentrated in the hands of a few, which makes it easier to

take decisions and in some cases, to gather privatization rents. The more unequal the

distribution of income, the higher would be the cost of privatization, or more would be the

benefits of privatization to a select few. Therefore, the relationship between the degree of

inequality and privatization is ambiguous.

2.2 Political Variables

2.2.1 Honeymoon hypothesis (YRSOFFC)

Pinera (1994) has shown empirically that reforms make things worse before they get

better. As a result, reformist governments want to implement reform in the initial years of

their power so they can take corrective measures. No less important, they have time to

benefit politically from privatization’s improved outcomes in later years. So, we expect,

timing pace, and intensity of privatization to be inversely related to ‘years in office’.

The honeymoon hypothesis can be derived from Alesina and Drazen’s (1991) ‘war of

attrition’ framework. The cost of avoiding the burden of policy change would increase as

the crisis worsens. The gaps in payoffs to the winners and losers would widen and

powerful groups would spend resources until the other weaker groups concede (condi-

tional on the fact that different groups don’t have the same access to resources or power,

this is especially true for poor). A major policy reform programme is thus associated

with elections: victory by one side will make it more difficult for the opposing parties to

block the programme and shelter themselves from the burden of policy reform. Countries

with political institutions that make it relatively more difficult for opposing groups to

‘veto’ policy reform not to their benefit will undertake the program sooner. Further,

recent empirical evidence contradicts the conventional wisdom that visible benefits

for much of the population arise after a long time (Nelson, 1989). Rather than requiring

a decade or more, privatization has shown positive benefits in terms of economic

efficiency and economic welfare within 3–4 years of implementation. Therefore,

undertaking a difficult decision such as privatization makes political sense in the

honeymoon period.

An alternate explanation relates to the time required to build credibility to implement

economic reforms. Governments that have been in power for sometime and gained

5It is possible that public enterprises and the rest of the economy would be more interlinked and hence potentialgains from privatization would be higher (Campos and Esfahani, 1996).6In addition, countries with higher income inequality will, at a given level of debt, find it more difficult to adoptpolicies to assure solvency (Berg and Sachs, 1988).

Move to Markets? 219

Copyright # 2004 John Wiley & Sons, Ltd. J. Int. Dev. 16, 213–240 (2004)

Page 8: Move to markets? An empirical analysis of privatization in developing countries

credibility through prior reformist signals can undertake more difficult reforms success-

fully (Cukierman and Leviatan, 1992).

2.2.2 Ideology of the executive (IDEOLOGY)

NPB of privatization increases when a ‘right wing’ executive is in power compared to ‘left

wing or centrist’ governments. This argument follows from the seminal work of Shleifer

and Vishny (1994) who present a model of bargaining between the politicians and

managers of state firms and the consequences of commercialization and privatization. In

this view, the decision to privatize arises as the outcome of competition between politicians

who benefit from government spending (bribes) and politicians who benefit from lower

taxes that might result from privatization. Privatization usually occurs when interests of the

treasury and taxpayers win against the private interests of politicians and the coalition of

interests they represent or when conservative government favored by taxpayers win against

leftist governments favoured by labor unions. Shleifer and Vishny (1994) contend that the

concerns about the treasury would dominate and privatization would happen, when

political benefits of public control are low and the demands for subsidy control are high.

2.2.3 Political rights (POLRTS)

Conflicting evidence on possible relationships between democracy and economic reforms

exist. Some studies have shown that there is no systematic evidence of relationship

between regime type and the ability to undertake reform (Nelson, 1989). On one hand,

authoritarian regimes may be better at taking decisions during a crisis, because there is less

need to secure consent from different stakeholders. Roubini and Sachs (1989) argue that to

agree on reforms is difficult, especially in conditions of crisis. In case of a democracy,

welfare-increasing policies may not be undertaken as the ex-ante uncertainty associated

with privatization turns many voters against privatization, though they know that ex-post

they could be better off. On the other hand, rent-seeking authoritarian regimes can slow

down stabilization policies needed in the first stage of transition. Democracy is more

suited to dealing with adverse shocks. Empirical analysis on the transition economies has

found that democracy facilitates the adoption of market-oriented reforms. The presence of

democracy may be a meta-institution for the existence of other non-market institutions

(Rodrik, 2000). The checks and balances implicit in the democratic system facilitate the

lock-in that blocks privatization reforms (Dethier et al., 1999). The checks and balances

penalize self-interested politicians and hence limiting rent-seeking opportunities (Aslund

et al., 1996). Dewatripont and Roland (1992) argue that a democratic government with the

legitimacy to undertake reforms can overcome political constraints and win acceptance of

transition measures, even if those reforms are painful for a majority of voters.

2.2.4 Degree of political cohesion (COHESION)

Fragmented governments are less able to achieve a consensus on adopting privatization,

adversely affecting NPB. Lack of political cohesion means political actors fail to

cooperate, so that pareto-improving policies are not implemented and economic outcomes

are sub-optimal. Alesina and Drazen (1991) argue that the lower cohesion delays

stabilization. It raises the uncertainty regarding policy outcomes because the associated

instability makes commitment incredible (Knack and Keefer, 1995). Consequently,

inefficient systems are maintained, as the incumbent government cannot change the status

quo. Government is unable to undertake efficient policies because it does not expect to

reap its benefits in the future (Cukeirman et al., 1992). Uncertainty about future re-election

220 S. G. Banerjee and M. C. Munger

Copyright # 2004 John Wiley & Sons, Ltd. J. Int. Dev. 16, 213–240 (2004)

Page 9: Move to markets? An empirical analysis of privatization in developing countries

possibilities and lack of political cohesion makes the government unwilling to undertake

distributionally challenging policies (Edwards and Tebellini, 1991).7

2.3 Institutional Variables

Among the institutional variables, we have included governance or institutional quality

(GOV) created by aggregating rule of law, bureaucratic quality, corruption, risk of

expropriation, and repudiation of property (the variable ‘gov’). Knack and Keefer

(1995) and Hall and Jones (1998) have previously used such aggregation. Doubts can

be raised about the ordinal nature of the governance variable, so we created a dummy

variable that took the value 1 if the quality of governance was higher than the mean value

of 3.5 (high quality of governance), or else it took the value 0 (low quality of governance).

The results did not change with respect to the effect of better quality institutions on

privatization, so we decided to use the ordinal variable, as a dummy variable specification

would mean loss of information with respect to the range of institutional quality.

2.3.1 Property rights/Rule of law (RULELAW)

Effective rule of law increases the NPB of privatization.8 Low security of property stunts

the incentives to invest, innovate, and obtain foreign technology (Mauro, 1995). It is

important for private investment that ownership rights be defined as the right to use and

control assets, draw economic benefits from ownership, to dispose off assets, and transfer

ownership rights to others (Guslain, 1997). Rules of the game that lead to transparent and

accountable economic transactions would improve the overall returns to investment

(Isham and Kaufman, 1999).

2.3.2 Corruption (CORR)

Corruption can facilitate economic growth because of ‘speed money’ to avoid bureaucratic

delays and the incentives to the bureaucrats to work harder (Huntington, 1968). It can be

argued that the countries with rampant corruption would view privatization activity as a

way to expropriate state property and would actively support privatization that they expect

will give them ownership of public assets. As a result, it would increase the pace of

privatization. In the recent years however, the evidence on negative effects of corruption

on private investment and economic growth has been overwhelming (Shleifer and Vishny

1993; Rose-Ackerman, 1978; Mauro, 1995). The credibility of the privatization program

is higher for domestic and foreign investors if corruption is controlled, so that transactions

are transparent and accountable.

2.3.2 Quality of bureaucracy (BURQLTY)

We hypothesize that quality of bureaucracy will positively affect the privatization process.

This indicator measures the extent to which national bureaucracy enjoys autonomy from

7This argument is similar to Krueger’s (1993) idea of a factional state where inefficient policies are maintaineduntil the system becomes weak and unsustainable. More politically fragile countries will experience delayedstabilization programs, by this logic Dornbusch and DePablo (1989) argued that failure to stabilize in the face ofsevere macroeconomic crisis is concomitant with continued fiscal polarization, instability, and the failure of anygroup to consolidate its power effectively. Roubini and Sachs (1989) argued that governments composed of large,short-lived, and incohesive coalitions appear to cause large budget deficits.8North (1990) has emphasized the existence of a functioning legal system as a precondition to investment andgrowth. As North asserts, ‘the inability of the societies to develop effective, low-cost enforcement of contracts isthe most important source of both historical stagnation and contemporary underdevelopment of the thirdworld . . . ’.

Move to Markets? 221

Copyright # 2004 John Wiley & Sons, Ltd. J. Int. Dev. 16, 213–240 (2004)

Page 10: Move to markets? An empirical analysis of privatization in developing countries

political pressure, has the strength and expertise to govern in a stable manner without drastic

changes in policy, and has effective mechanisms for training and recruiting. Often, the

bureaucrats in developing countries are ‘captured’ by the interests they are supposed to

regulate. They provide services to interest groups who then support those politicians who

defend the governments’ budget (Bates and Krueger, 1993). As a result, the greater the

independence of bureaucrats from politicians, the less attractive is public ownership to

politicians, and hence less sustainable public ownership will be in the long run (Shleifer and

Vishny, 1994). They contend that privatization is more likely to occur in a country with an

autonomous civil service with stringent criteria for selection of bureaucrats. This is because,

even if governments change, the policies of the state firms will remain constant. Also, a

government with high quality of bureaucracy will be more responsive to citizens’ demands

and consequently, would have greater commitment to service delivery (Campos, 2000).

2.3.4 Ethnic tensions (ETHNIC)

We hypothesize that the countries with higher ethnic tensions will demonstrate lower

privatization activity. Social fragmentation, riots, and demonstrations negatively affect

private incentives to invest and NPB. If the ethnic tensions were high, the security of life

and property would be low. In addition, diversity might make it more difficult for political

actors to negotiate and cooperate with each other for solutions. This variable is important

in countries that depend more on foreign participation in the privatization programme.

2.3.5 Capital market development (MARKET)

We hypothesize that the countries with well-developed stock markets would exhibit higher

privatization activity.9 Capital market development reflects the supply side institutional

response to privatization. Unless there exists appropriate financial infrastructure to sell the

public assets, implementation of privatization strategy would be difficult. Because of

concerns about endogeneity—market development is often an objective for privatization—

we have lagged this variable (market capitalization as share of GDP) by one period. We

estimate the model using both simultaneous and lagged values of MARKET.

2.3.6 Civil Liberties (CIVLIB)

We hypothesize that the countries with higher civil liberties would exhibit higher

privatization activity. Civil liberties can be considered an indicator of informal institu-

tional infrastructure. The appropriate legal and market institutions necessary for privatiza-

tion can be imposed on the majority of population only if civil society organizations are

developed. The civil society norms or behavior ease the coordination problems and makes

transactions easier and less costly (North, 1990). Scully (1988) has argued that nations that

have chosen to suppress economic, political, and civil liberties have greatly reduced the

standard of living of their citizens. Isham et al. (1995) empirically demonstrate that higher

civil liberties are associated with better economic returns on government projects. In an

empirical study of transition economies, Dethier et al. (1999) conclude that the existence

9Recent studies have found a positive relationship between development of a nation’s stock market and greaterefficiency and growth (Levine, 1997) and between stock market development and privatization (Demirguc-Kuntand Levine, 1994). Positive experiences in Mexico and Chile highlight the impact of well-developed stockmarkets on privatization choices while experiences in Ghana and Senegal showcase negative impact. A well-developed financial system helps privatization by allocating funds to more efficient firms, making less efficientfirms to restructure or fail and efficiently redeploying the assets of the bankrupt firms (Demirguc-Kunt andLevine, 1994).

222 S. G. Banerjee and M. C. Munger

Copyright # 2004 John Wiley & Sons, Ltd. J. Int. Dev. 16, 213–240 (2004)

Page 11: Move to markets? An empirical analysis of privatization in developing countries

of vibrant civil society has the maximum power to explain the adoption of economic

liberalization measures.

2.4 Control Variables (AFRICA, LAC, TRADE, GDPCAP, ILLITERACY)

Two regional dummy variables for Latin America and Africa (Asia is the default category)

are used to control for geographical location and peer-group effect of privatization. An

indicator of trade dependence is used to control for the country’s global integration. This

variable is also an indicator for non-natural or endogenous rents accruing to some

politicians and bureaucrats. The lower the trade dependence in an economy or higher

the level of protectionism, the higher would be the potential for rent. In addition, previous

reform experience in terms of trade reform with similar distributional trade-offs would

make it easier to undertake privatization reforms. Finally, we control for development by

using initial GDP per capita (corrected for differences in purchasing power parity) and

adult illiteracy. Developed countries may have better institutional structure and market

mechanisms, facilitating private sector reform.

3 METHODS

The sample in the empirical analysis includes 35 diversified groups of low-income or

middle-income countries from the developing world. The countries in the sample are from

Latin America, Africa, and Asia: (a) Argentina, Mexico, Colombia, Bolivia, Venezuela,

Ecuador, Peru, Brazil, Honduras, Guatemala, El Salvador, Paraguay, Panama, Uruguay,

Trinidad and Tobago, and Costa Rica are from Latin America; (b) Cote d’Ivoire, Egypt,

Table 3. Descriptive statistics of explanatory variables

Variable Obs Mean Standard Deviation Min Max

FISCALBAL 566 �3.8 4.5 �45.1 5.1

INFLA 584 98.1 640.9 �.8 11749.6

GROWTH 629 3.2 4.2 �13.4 13.3

AIDGNI 619 3.3 5.2 �0.5 62.9

AGRGDP 621 18.5 9.8 1.4 59.7

INEQ 630 45.2 8.0 31.4 62.3

SOEINITIAL 630 10.9 7.6 1.6 32.8

SOEGDP 596 10.0 8.4 0 44.0

YRSOFFC 630 7.0 8.2 1 38

IDEOLOGY 630 0.34 0.5 0 1

COHESION 630 0.54 0.8 0 4

DEMOC 630 8.9 2.7 2 14

MARKETLAG 355 26.4 43.4 0.3 329.4

MARKET 356 26.3 43.3 0.3 329.4

GOV 630 3.5 1.0 1.1 6.3

ETHNIC 630 3.8 1.7 0 9

GDPCAP 630 1848.7 1530.8 235.9 6572.1

AFRICA 630 0.3 0.5 0 1

LAC 630 0.5 0.5 0 1

ILLITERACY 630 26.2 19.3 2.3 74.4

TRADE 623 84.6 46.1 16.1 333.7

Move to Markets? 223

Copyright # 2004 John Wiley & Sons, Ltd. J. Int. Dev. 16, 213–240 (2004)

Page 12: Move to markets? An empirical analysis of privatization in developing countries

Tunisia, Ghana, Nigeria, Morocco, Zambia, Kenya, Zimbabwe and South Africa are from

Africa; and (c) India, Indonesia, Bangladesh, Pakistan, Sri Lanka, Malaysia, Philippines,

Thailand, and Turkey are from Asia. Annual data for 18 years (1982–99) on the 35

countries are used to construct a pooled cross-section/time-series dataset with 630

observations. Since our objective is to explain the privatization process overtime, the

pooled dataset is best suited as the analysis identifies both cross-section and temporal

dynamics of privatization. The dependent variables and empirical methods are discussed

in the context of timing, pace and intensity of privatization. The descriptive statistics of

dependent variables—timing, pace and intensity, is presented in Table 4. We use the Cox

proportional hazards model to test the timing, random effects negative binomial model for

the pace, and random effects model for the intensity of privatization decision.

3.1 Timing Model

We use the hazard analysis to model the transition from no privatization to a formal

privatization policy. The hazard model is appropriate to model our problem as it includes

time-varying covariates.10 The speed at which privatization occurs depends on the rate at

which the explanatory variables change. The dependent variable in our analysis is

dichotomous, reflecting whether privatization occurred or not. At each year, if the country

experienced privatization, the dependent variable is coded 1; if not, it is coded 0. As the

variable becomes 1, the later observations are dropped from the analysis as we are

Table 4. Descriptive statistics of dependent variables

Variable Observations Mean Standard Deviation Min Max

Timing1 630 0.6 0.5 0 1

Latin America 289 0.6 0.5 0 1

Africa 180 0.6 0.5 0 1

Asia 161 0.7 0.5 0 1

Pace2 630 4.0 8.3 0 57

Latin America 289 3.8 8.7 0 57

Africa 180 3.7 6.8 0 40

Asia 161 4.8 8.8 0 51

Intensity3 266 4.8 2.2 0 10.4

Latin America 106 5.3 2.5 0 10.4

Africa 75 4.1 1.8 0 7.9

Asia 85 4.9 2.1 0 8.1

Intensity4 404 0.7 1.5 0 12.6

Latin America 186 0.7 1.6 0 11.8

Africa 117 0.7 1.9 0 12.6

Asia 101 0.4 0.8 0 4.9

1Timing of first privatization.2Number of privatization transactions each year.3Log annual privatization proceeds in millions (in constant USD, 1996¼ 100).4Annual privatization proceeds as a share of GDP.

10The explanatory variables in our model include both time-varying and time-invariant covariates. This leads toinsights about the full span of the privatization process. It is superior to cross-section or panel study designs. Incross-section studies, the dynamics of privatization cannot be modeled. Panel studies, though they involve cross-section time-series data, may not lead to accurate conclusions of rates and timing of change. It would depend onthe spacing of panels (Box-Steffensmeier and Jones, 1998).

224 S. G. Banerjee and M. C. Munger

Copyright # 2004 John Wiley & Sons, Ltd. J. Int. Dev. 16, 213–240 (2004)

Page 13: Move to markets? An empirical analysis of privatization in developing countries

studying the change to a privatization regime. In hazard models, it is important to specify

the time when analysis begins. In this paper, time is measured from 1982 because most

of the countries adopted privatization in the early eighties and because data is available

since then. All of the sample countries for this analysis experienced a transition within the

sample period except for Thailand and Bangladesh that began earlier.

The change to privatization from a no-privatization state can be modeled as a function

of the explanatory covariates:

hit (t, X)¼�þ �1 (FISCALBAL)itþ �2(INFLA)itþ �3(GROWTH)itþ �4 (AGRDGP)itþ�5(AIDGNI)itþ �6(INEQ)itþ �7(YRSOFFC)itþ �8(IDEOLOGY)itþ �9(COHESION)itþ�10(SOEINITIAL)itþ �11(GOV)itþ �12(DEMOC)itþ �13(MARKET)itþ �14(GDPCAP)itþ�15 (LAC)itþ �16(AFRICA)itþ �17(ILLITERACY)itþ �18(TRADE)it

3.2 Pace/Frequency Model

Pace is defined as the annual number of privatization transactions. Our estimation equation

is:

PACE¼�þ �1(FISCALBAL)itþ �2(INFLA)itþ �3(GROWTH)itþ �4(AGRGDP)itþ �5

(AIDGNI)itþ �6 (INEQ)itþ �7(YRSOFFC)itþ �8(IDEOLOGY)itþ �9(COHESION)itþ�10(SOEINITIAL)itþ �11(GOV)itþ �12(DEMOC)itþ �13(MARKET)itþ �14(GDPCAP)itþ�15(LAC)itþ �16(AFRICA)itþ �17(ILLITERACY)itþ �18(TRADE)itþ "

A random effects Poisson model can be used to analyze the determinants of the event

(privatization) count. Event counts are ‘variables that have for observations i(i¼ 1 . . .N) the

number of occurrences of an event in a fixed domain’. The Poisson assumption is appropriate

as the events occur randomly in time. In a Markov sense, ‘random’ means that the expected

rate of occurrence of the next event either remains constant (¼ �) or is uncorrelated with the

number of observed events. The random error around � in one instant of time is independent

and uncorrelated with random error in the next instant of time (King, 1988). The dependent

variable; therefore is the number of annual privatization transactions. It can also include non-

negative integers and 0 as natural outcome of the process. The dependent variable has

non-negligible probabilities of zero. In addition, the random effects model assumes an equi-

correlated covariance matrix, so it takes care of the serial correlation.

A restrictive assumption of the Poisson model is the equality between mean and

variance of the distribution. This assumption may not take into account over dispersion,

meaning that variance may be higher than the mean. As a result, the estimated covariance

matrix is biased downward, resulting in overstated significance levels (Liao, 1994). In this

case, the alternative hypothesis considers the local alternatives to the Poisson distribution

of yt. If the Poisson goodness of fit test is significant, then Poisson model does not fit the

data. Then more generalized models like the negative binomial model can be used. In

these generalized models, Poisson parameter is also a random variable and not a

deterministic function of independent covariates.

3.3 Intensity/Value Model

In the third model of privatization decision-making, we define two definitions of

‘intensity’: (i) log annual privatization proceeds in constant USD, 1996¼ 100 and (ii)

annual privatization proceeds as share of GDP. Due to unavailability of credible

Move to Markets? 225

Copyright # 2004 John Wiley & Sons, Ltd. J. Int. Dev. 16, 213–240 (2004)

Page 14: Move to markets? An empirical analysis of privatization in developing countries

privatization proceeds data before 1988; this estimation is based on 1988–99. In effect, the

dependent variable is a function of:

INTENSITY¼�þ �it(FISCALBAL)itþ �2(INFLA)itþ �3(GROWTH)itþ�4(AGRGDP)itþ �5 (AIDGNI)it þ �6(INEQ)itþ �7(YRSOFFC)itþ �8(IDEOLOGY)it þ �9(COHE-

ION)it þ �10(SOEINITIAL)itþ �11(GOV)itþ �12(DEMOC)itþ �13(MARKET)itþ �14

(GDPCAP)itþ �15(LAC)itþ �16(AFRICA)itþ �17(ILLITERACY)itþ �18(TRADE)itþ "

The pooled cross-section time-series design enables the use of a number of specifica-

tions that control for heterogeneity bias. It controls for the time-invariant country specific

effects that may be omitted from the regression model. In a panel dataset, the country

specific effects are included in the country specific intercept that may be fixed or random

(Nielsen and Grady, 2000).

In cases where the design is cross section dominant and there are significant unit specific

effects, random effects model is most useful. Unlike the fixed effects specification, it

removes only a fraction of the country-specific means and permits the use of time-

invariant regressors. In effect, it does not include any ‘between country’ variation in the

sample. But the ‘between country’ variation is important in determining dynamics of

privatization. Random effects model is appropriate as the sample group of countries is

drawn from the large population of countries where country specific constant terms are

randomly distributed across units. In addition, the random effects model is asymptotically

efficient compared to fixed effects model (Tuma and Hannan, 1984). One of the problems

of random effects models is the lack of concern for autocorrelation. Our data do not suffer

from the biases of autocorrelated errors because the data matrix is ‘wide’ (cross-section

dominant) rather than ‘tall’ (Stimson, 1985). The consistency of the specifications can be

tested using the Hausman test. In random effects specification, this consistency depends on

zero correlation between the error term and the regressors. The insignificant �2 statistic

(recorded below Tables 7 and 8) in the hausman test suggested that random effects’ is an

appropriate specification.

4 DISCUSSION

The macroeconomic, political, and institutional factors explain the timing, pace, and

intensity—the three parameters of the privatization. The discussion of the results follows

from the Tables 5, 6, 7 and 8. In our paper, the decision to privatize and its implementation

have emerged as two distinct entities. A number of factors that actually facilitate the

privatization decision later hamper its implementation and delay the process. The results

from the timing model suggest that in countries with homogenous population, high growth

rate, lower inequality, higher share of manufacturing sectors and market capitalization, an

open policy to trade actually delay privatization compared to countries that do not have the

above attributes. It appears that instability hastens privatization. Instead of a planned and

cautious decision, privatization is often a response to instability and crisis. The forces are

aligned momentarily to cope with crisis and to take controversial decisions.

Economic crisis is an important variable in determining the privatization decisions. This

result supports the previous research that ‘economic reforms are inflation’s children’ (Bruno

and Easterly, 1996). In fact, none of the recent reform initiatives have happened without

serious macroeconomic crisis in the economy. This result confirms the traditional wisdom

that domestic political economy drives economic reforms. By increasing the cost of delay, it

226 S. G. Banerjee and M. C. Munger

Copyright # 2004 John Wiley & Sons, Ltd. J. Int. Dev. 16, 213–240 (2004)

Page 15: Move to markets? An empirical analysis of privatization in developing countries

Tab

le5

.T

imin

gm

od

el

(1)

(2)

(3)

(4)

(5)

(6)

(7)

(8)

Dep

enden

tvar

iable

:ti

me

till

pri

vat

izat

ion

FIS

CA

LB

AL

0.0

09

0.0

5�

0.0

42

0.0

15

�0

.048

�0

.017

�0

.007

0.0

17

�0

.04

�0

.048

�0

.034

�0

.04

�0

.034

�0

.041

�0

.038

�0

.048

INF

LA

00

00

00

00

(0.0

00)*

**

(0.0

00)*

**

(0.0

00)*

**

(0.0

00)*

**

(0.0

00)*

**

(0.0

00)*

**

(0.0

00)*

**

(0.0

00)*

**

GR

OW

TH

�0

.004

�0

.017

�0

.037

�0

.043

�0

.033

�0

.037

0�

0.0

12

�0

.025

�0

.021

(0.0

18)*

*(0

.01

6)*

**

(0.0

17)*

(0.0

16)*

*�

0.0

23

�0

.02

AID

GN

I�

0.0

07

0.0

26

�0

.01

0.0

24

�0

.003

0.0

08

�0

.002

0.0

09

�0

.024

�0

.028

�0

.025

�0

.031

�0

.012

�0

.012

�0

.01

�0

.01

AG

RG

DP

0.0

15

0.0

29

�0

.002

�0

.018

�0

.004

�0

.002

0.0

12

0.0

37

�0

.011

(0.0

14)*

*�

0.0

09

�0

.015

�0

.009

�0

.016

�0

.01

(0.0

16)*

*

INE

Q0

.009

0.0

51

0.0

04

0.0

61

�0

.002

0.0

37

0.0

04

0.0

35

�0

.013

(0.0

20)*

**

�0

.016

(0.0

21)*

**

�0

.016

(0.0

21)*

�0

.013

(0.0

16)*

*

YR

SO

FF

C0

.001

0.0

06

0.0

07

0.0

12

0.0

06

0.0

11

0.0

01

0.0

06

�0

.012

�0

.01

�0

.013

�0

.013

�0

.014

�0

.013

�0

.012

�0

.011

IDE

OL

OG

Y0

.471

0.3

89

0.1

29

�0

.21

0.0

96

�0

.259

0.3

89

0.2

51

(0.2

07)*

*�

0.2

91

�0

.18

�0

.298

�0

.177

�0

.288

(0.2

14)*

�0

.294

CO

HE

SIO

N�

0.0

59

�0

.246

�0

.276

�0

.509

�0

.239

�0

.421

�0

.057

�0

.21

�0

.093

(0.1

08)*

*(0

.09

4)*

**

(0.1

68)*

**

(0.0

82)*

**

(0.1

45)*

**

�0

.087

(0.1

08)*

SO

EIN

ITIA

L0

.027

0.0

49

0.0

24

0.0

43

(0.0

11)*

*(0

.01

2)*

**

(0.0

12)*

(0.0

11)*

**

MA

RK

ET

LA

G�

0.0

01

�0

.006

�0

.009

�0

.02

�0

.003

�0

.004

(0.0

04)*

*(0

.00

5)*

**

GO

V�

0.1

11

�0

.152

�0

.11

�0

.159

�0

.182

�0

.243

�0

.175

�0

.238

�0

.173

�0

.177

�0

.179

�0

.173

�0

.165

�0

.167

�0

.155

�0

.162

ET

HN

IC�

0.1

67

�0

.155

�0

.174

�0

.156

�0

.146

�0

.126

�0

.147

�0

.143

(0.0

63)*

**

(0.0

70)*

*(0

.06

0)*

**

(0.0

68)*

*(0

.06

5)*

*(0

.07

1)*

(0.0

68)*

*(0

.07

6)*

DE

MO

C0

.035

0.0

80

.072

0.1

83

0.0

58

0.1

22

0.0

32

0.0

55

�0

.032

(0.0

47)*

(0.0

38)*

(0.0

66)*

**

�0

.036

(0.0

65)*

�0

.029

�0

.042

GD

PC

AP

00

00

Continues

Move to Markets? 227

Copyright # 2004 John Wiley & Sons, Ltd. J. Int. Dev. 16, 213–240 (2004)

Page 16: Move to markets? An empirical analysis of privatization in developing countries

Tab

le5

.(C

ontinued

)

(1)

(2)

(3)

(4)

(5)

(6)

(7)

(8)

(0.0

00)*

**

(0.0

00)*

*(0

.00

0)*

**

(0.0

00)*

**

AF

RIC

A�

1.2

29

�1

.152

�0

.883

�0

.973

(0.3

40)*

**

(0.3

47)*

**

(0.2

97)*

**

(0.2

83)*

**

LA

C�

1.2

38

�1

.86

�1

.256

�0

.889

(0.4

41)*

**

(0.3

44)*

**

(0.4

30)*

**

(0.3

76)*

*

ILL

ITE

RA

CY

0.0

18

0.0

22

0.0

16

0.0

12

(0.0

07)*

*(0

.00

9)*

*(0

.00

9)*

(0.0

07)*

TR

AD

E0

�0

.005

�0

.004

0

�0

.002

�0

.003

�0

.003

�0

.002

MA

RK

ET

�0

.006

�0

.013

0�

0.0

02

(0.0

03)*

*(0

.00

6)*

*�

0.0

02

�0

.002

SO

EG

DP

0.0

18

0.0

36

0.0

15

0.0

27

�0

.013

(0.0

16)*

*�

0.0

13

(0.0

15)*

Robu

stst

and

ard

erro

rsin

par

enth

eses

.*

sig

nifi

cant

at1

0%

;*

*si

gn

ifica

nt

at5

%;

**

*si

gnifi

cant

at1

%.

228 S. G. Banerjee and M. C. Munger

Copyright # 2004 John Wiley & Sons, Ltd. J. Int. Dev. 16, 213–240 (2004)

Page 17: Move to markets? An empirical analysis of privatization in developing countries

accelerates privatization. Though crisis is a catalyst for divestiture, it does not sustain it.

Fiscal prosperity actually increases the pace and intensity of privatization. Macroeconomic

management in the form of budget surplus, low inflation, and high growth rates increases the

credibility of the reformist government and raises the value of the enterprises. This is

consistent with Dollar and Svensson’s (1998) argument that reforms in a recession involve a

higher political cost and will be more difficult to implement.

Most countries go through small crisis situations before undertaking reform when crisis

is really severe. In such situations, the countries not only face burgeoning deficits,

inflation, and growth rates but also high debt service payments. In many poor countries,

the ‘aid-for-reform’ packages are allocated in crisis to countries unprepared for reform.

Though such countries privatize early, the constraints that increase the political costs

surface during the implementation of the privatization process. While they announce the

adoption of economic reforms, implementation depends on supporting institutional

infrastructure. In most economies, these institutions either have to be created (as in

many transition economies) or have to be tailored to support privatization.

The size of the public sector speeds up the timing but slows down the pace and intensity

of privatization. The timing of the privatization policy is hastened by the size of the public

sector. For instance, one percentage point increase in SOEINITIAL (initial size of public

sector as percent of GDP) increases the hazard by 1.03 times (model 4, Table 5). But a

large public sector also means rent-seeking institutional structure that has a stake in

perpetuating the present arrangement. The institutions are often locked-in and the interest

groups present barriers to delay the privatization process. Thus, the transactions cost of

undertaking divestiture is high, adversely affecting the pace of privatization.

Countries with large manufacturing structures have capital-intensive processes and an

existing market infrastructure to raise capital. Since agriculture is usually not capital

intensive, likelihood of existence of supporting market institutions to raise debt and equity

capital is low. One standard deviation increase in AGRGDP (agriculture as a share of GDP),

that amounts to 9.7 per cent, results in a 0.3 years decrease in the time till privatization

(model 2, Table 5). As a result, the pace of privatization will be delayed by lack of

supporting market infrastructure in agrarian economies. But the existence of a large agrarian

sector hastens the timing of privatization. Privatization appears as a way to raise scarce

resources in agrarian economies. Though more agrarian economies announce the divestiture

plans sooner, the implementation is impacted by lack of market supporting institutions.

The institutional infrastructure of the economy has emerged as a significant determinant

of privatization decisions. But the effect is not uniform across the three decisions. Though

countries with poor institutions privatize sooner, but the pace and intensity is higher for

countries with superior institutions. The implementation of the process requires an

adequate social infrastructure. Good governance makes the privatization process more

credible and positively affects its outcomes. The results empirically prove Nellis’s (1999)

argument that ‘in an institutional vacuum privatization can and has led to stagnation and

decapitalization rather than better financial results and increased efficiency’. For example,

a one-unit increase in GOV (quality of governance) increases the expected number of

privatization transactions by 66 per cent, holding all other variables constant (model 4,

Table 6). ‘Ethnic tension’ emerges as a significant determinant of timing of privatization.

More homogenous societies would actually delay privatization and they gather more

resources from privatization.

Market infrastructure unambiguously impacts privatization decisions. Countries with

superior market infrastructure privatize later, one standard deviation increase in

Move to Markets? 229

Copyright # 2004 John Wiley & Sons, Ltd. J. Int. Dev. 16, 213–240 (2004)

Page 18: Move to markets? An empirical analysis of privatization in developing countries

Tab

le6.

Pac

e/fr

equen

cym

odel

(1)

(2)

(3)

(4)

(5)

(6)

(7)

(8)

Dep

end

ent

var

iab

le:

ann

ual

pri

vat

izat

ion

tran

sact

ion

s

FIS

CA

LB

AL

0.0

44

0.0

36

0.0

36

0.0

35

0.0

17

0.0

12

0.0

19

0.0

14

(0.0

22)*

*�

0.0

23

�0

.025

�0

.025

�0

.023

�0

.024

�0

.021

�0

.022

INF

LA

00

00

00

00

00

00

00

00

GR

OW

TH

0.0

18

0.0

17

0.0

22

0.0

19

0.0

32

0.0

33

0.0

32

0.0

34

�0

.018

�0

.019

�0

.019

�0

.019

(0.0

18)*

(0.0

19)*

(0.0

19)*

(0.0

19)*

AID

GN

I0.0

41

0.0

49

0.0

33

0.0

28

0.0

06

0.0

05

0.0

11

0.0

12

�0

.029

�0

.031

�0

.027

�0

.034

�0

.012

�0

.014

�0

.013

�0

.013

AG

RG

DP

�0

.032

�0

.013

�0

.018

�0

.027

�0

.012

�0

.009

�0

.023

0.0

03

(0.0

17)*

�0

.021

�0

.014

�0

.02

�0

.014

�0

.02

�0

.016

�0

.021

INE

Q�

0.0

22

�0

.02

�0

.037

�0

.038

�0

.043

�0

.061

�0

.018

�0

.014

�0

.017

�0

.023

(0.0

17)*

*(0

.02

1)*

(0.0

17)*

*(0

.02

2)*

**

�0

.017

�0

.022

YR

SO

FF

C�

0.0

16

�0

.002

�0

.026

�0

.017

�0

.03

�0

.024

�0

.022

�0

.007

�0

.013

�0

.015

(0.0

14)*

�0

.016

(0.0

14)*

*�

0.0

16

(0.0

13)*

�0

.015

IDE

OL

OG

Y0

.27

0.3

26

0.3

85

0.4

17

0.4

74

0.5

02

0.2

64

0.2

57

�0

.22

�0

.23

(0.2

20)*

(0.2

47)*

(0.2

05)*

*(0

.23

9)*

*�

0.2

12

�0

.224

CO

HE

SIO

N0

.067

0.1

01

0.0

05

0.0

17

0.0

01

0.0

60

.012

0.0

57

�0

.097

�0

.108

�0

.105

�0

.121

�0

.098

�0

.113

�0

.095

�0

.107

SO

EIN

ITIA

L�

0.0

21

0.0

1�

0.0

14

0.0

2

�0

.018

�0

.022

�0

.017

�0

.021

MA

RK

ET

LA

G0

�0

.001

�0

.003

�0

.004

�0

.002

�0

.002

�0

.004

�0

.004

GO

V0

.558

0.4

95

0.5

89

0.5

06

0.2

98

0.2

60

.40

.347

(0.1

06)*

**

(0.1

16)*

**

(0.1

13)*

**

(0.1

21)*

**

(0.1

22)*

*(0

.12

9)*

*(0

.11

4)*

**

(0.1

21)*

**

ET

HN

IC�

0.0

10

.045

0.0

32

0.1

05

0.1

05

0.1

18

0.0

30

.091

�0

.067

�0

.077

�0

.068

�0

.078

�0

.069

�0

.08

�0

.066

�0

.078

DE

MO

C�

0.1

11

�0

.137

�0

.135

�0

.124

�0

.167

�0

.184

�0

.117

�0

.151

(0.0

42)*

**

(0.0

48)*

**

(0.0

42)*

**

(0.0

50)*

*(0

.04

2)*

**

(0.0

50)*

**

(0.0

41)*

**

(0.0

46)*

**

230 S. G. Banerjee and M. C. Munger

Copyright # 2004 John Wiley & Sons, Ltd. J. Int. Dev. 16, 213–240 (2004)

Page 19: Move to markets? An empirical analysis of privatization in developing countries

GD

PC

AP

00

00

00

00

AF

RIC

A�

0.5

31

�0

.069

0.3

09

�0

.54

�0

.461

�0

.45

�0

.421

�0

.446

LA

C�

0.3

01

�0

.408

0.2

47

�0

.201

�0

.427

�0

.436

�0

.441

�0

.416

ILL

ITE

RA

CY

�0

.026

�0

.021

�0

.021

�0

.024

(0.0

11)*

*(0

.01

1)*

(0.0

10)*

*(0

.01

0)*

*

TR

AD

E�

0.0

03

�0

.004

�0

.003

�0

.004

�0

.002

�0

.003

�0

.003

�0

.003

SO

EG

DP

�0

.048

�0

.04

�0

.054

�0

.049

(0.0

13)*

**

(0.0

15)*

**

(0.0

14)*

**

(0.0

16)*

**

MA

RK

ET

0.0

08

0.0

10

.003

0.0

03

(0.0

04)*

*(0

.00

5)*

*�

0.0

02

�0

.002

CO

NS

TA

NT

0.3

55

0.9

61

.014

2.4

56

2.2

09

3.7

71

0.4

62

0.7

43

�1

.273

�1

.576

�1

.146

�1

.538

(1.1

51)*

(1.4

87)*

*�

1.2

49

�1

.553

Nu

mb

ero

fco

un

trie

s3

53

53

33

33

43

43

53

5

Sta

nd

ard

erro

rsin

par

enth

eses

.*

sig

nifi

can

tat

10

%;

**

sig

nifi

cant

at5

%;

**

*si

gn

ifica

nt

at1

%.

Move to Markets? 231

Copyright # 2004 John Wiley & Sons, Ltd. J. Int. Dev. 16, 213–240 (2004)

Page 20: Move to markets? An empirical analysis of privatization in developing countries

Tab

le7

.In

ten

sity

/val

ue

mo

del

I

(1)

(2)

(3)

(4)

(5)

(6)

(7)

(8)

Dep

enden

tvar

iable

:lo

gpri

vat

izat

ion

pro

ceed

sin

const

ant

US

D(1

996¼

10

0)

FIS

CA

LB

AL

0.0

62

0.0

70

.06

30

.07

50

.03

50

.03

70

.04

20

.04

7

�0

.04

5�

0.0

47

�0

.04

9�

0.0

5�

0.0

45

�0

.04

6�

0.0

42

�0

.04

3

INF

LA

00

00

00

00

(0.0

00

)*(0

.00

0)*

0(0

.00

0)*

0(0

.00

0)*

(0.0

00

)*(0

.00

0)*

GR

OW

TH

0.0

13

0.0

11

0.0

17

0.0

14

0.0

03

�0

.00

20

.00

2�

0.0

01

�0

.03

5�

0.0

36

�0

.03

8�

0.0

39

�0

.03

7�

0.0

37

�0

.03

5�

0.0

35

AID

GN

I�

0.0

97

�0

.08

9�

0.1

08

�0

.10

2�

0.0

35

�0

.03

5�

0.0

31

�0

.03

3

�0

.06

3�

0.0

68

(0.0

65

)*�

0.0

72

�0

.03

2�

0.0

33

�0

.03

1�

0.0

32

AG

RG

DP

�0

.08

8�

0.0

89

�0

.07

4�

0.0

9�

0.0

95

�0

.10

6�

0.1

14

�0

.12

8

(0.0

41

)**

(0.0

54

)*(0

.04

0)*

�0

.05

5(0

.03

7)*

**

(0.0

51

)**

(0.0

37

)**

*(0

.05

1)*

*

INE

Q�

0.0

02

0.0

01

0.0

01

0.0

01

�0

.03

3�

0.0

58

�0

.02

9�

0.0

37

�0

.04

4�

0.0

58

�0

.04

6�

0.0

6�

0.0

46

�0

.05

4�

0.0

44

�0

.05

6

YR

SO

FF

C�

0.0

27

�0

.03

2�

0.0

3�

0.0

4�

0.0

3�

0.0

39

�0

.03

�0

.03

5

�0

.03

2�

0.0

34

�0

.03

4�

0.0

37

�0

.03

4�

0.0

35

�0

.03

2�

0.0

33

IDE

OL

OG

Y�

0.5

65

�0

.66

5�

0.2

51

�0

.37

80

.25

60

.25

1�

0.1

37

�0

.18

3

�0

.48

5�

0.5

06

�0

.55

8�

0.6

17

�0

.51

1�

0.5

47

�0

.45

6�

0.4

71

CO

HE

SIO

N0

.05

40

.06

20

.07

70

.03

20

.13

90

.16

30

.08

0.1

13

�0

.19

7�

0.2

06

�0

.22

6�

0.2

36

�0

.21

9�

0.2

3�

0.1

96

�0

.20

5

SO

EIN

ITIA

L�

0.0

36

�0

.02

8�

0.0

46

�0

.04

7

�0

.04

7�

0.0

56

�0

.04

6�

0.0

54

MA

RK

ET

LA

G0.0

03

0.0

05

0.0

03

0.0

04

�0

.00

4�

0.0

05

�0

.01

�0

.01

1

GO

V0

.22

30

.18

0.2

21

0.1

63

0.2

38

0.1

38

0.3

26

0.2

84

�0

.23

5�

0.2

55

�0

.26

6�

0.2

8�

0.2

53

�0

.26

9�

0.2

31

�0

.25

ET

HN

IC�

0.0

31

�0

.01

6�

0.0

44

0.0

23

�0

.03

6�

0.0

32

�0

.05

�0

.06

6

�0

.14

1�

0.1

66

�0

.16

�0

.18

8�

0.1

58

�0

.17

7�

0.1

35

�0

.15

4

DE

MO

C�

0.2

07

�0

.23

�0

.20

3�

0.2

04

�0

.25

7�

0.3

03

�0

.26

�0

.29

4

(0.1

05

)**

(0.1

21

)*(0

.10

8)*

�0

.12

8(0

.10

5)*

*(0

.12

1)*

*(0

.10

3)*

*(0

.11

9)*

*

GD

PC

AP

00

00

00

00

232 S. G. Banerjee and M. C. Munger

Copyright # 2004 John Wiley & Sons, Ltd. J. Int. Dev. 16, 213–240 (2004)

Page 21: Move to markets? An empirical analysis of privatization in developing countries

AF

RIC

A�

0.0

36

0.1

12

0.7

39

0.4

62

�1

.23

5�

1.2

89

�1

.12

2�

1.1

67

LA

C�

0.1

55

�0

.31

1.1

07

0.5

22

�1

.16

3�

1.3

4�

1.1

45

�1

.10

1

ILL

ITE

RA

CY

�0

.00

6�

0.0

08

�0

.00

7�

0.0

08

�0

.02

7�

0.0

28

�0

.02

6�

0.0

26

TR

AD

E�

0.0

07

�0

.01

2�

0.0

12

�0

.00

7

�0

.00

6�

0.0

08

(0.0

07

)*�

0.0

06

SO

EG

DP

�0

.02

4�

0.0

22

�0

.04

1�

0.0

46

�0

.03

�0

.03

4�

0.0

30

.03

2

MA

RK

ET

0.0

15

0.0

27

0.0

10

.01

4

�0

.00

9(0

.01

1)*

*(0

.00

4)*

*(0

.00

5)*

**

CO

NS

TA

NT

8.6

18

9.5

27

8.0

07

9.7

87

9.5

89

12

.34

99

.89

11

.66

5

(3.0

38

)**

*(3

.89

6)*

*(2

.88

3)*

**

(3.8

37

)**

(2.7

96

)**

*(3

.51

8)*

**

(2.9

58

)**

*(3

.73

1)*

**

Nu

mb

ero

fco

un

trie

s3

53

53

33

33

43

43

53

5

Sta

nd

ard

erro

rsin

par

enth

eses

.*

sig

nifi

can

tat

10

%;

**

sig

nifi

can

tat

5%

;*

**

sig

nifi

can

tat

1%

.H

ausm

ante

st:

Mo

del

2:�

8.7

8;

(pro

b>�

2)¼

0.8

4.

Mo

del

4:�

8.5

8;

(pro

b>�

2)¼

0.9

0.

Mo

del

6:�

9.0

5;

(pro

b>�

2)¼

0.8

7.

Mo

del

8:�

10

.02

;(p

rob>�

2)¼

0.7

7.

Move to Markets? 233

Copyright # 2004 John Wiley & Sons, Ltd. J. Int. Dev. 16, 213–240 (2004)

Page 22: Move to markets? An empirical analysis of privatization in developing countries

Tab

le8

.In

ten

sity

/val

ue

mo

del

II

(1)

(2)

(3)

(4)

(5)

(6)

(7)

(8)

Dep

enden

tvar

iable

:pri

vat

izat

ion

pro

ceed

sas

shar

eof

GD

P

FIS

CA

LB

AL

0�

0.0

11

�0

.002

�0

.008

�0

.007

�0

.028

0�

0.0

2

�0

.042

�0

.044

�0

.044

�0

.047

�0

.036

�0

.039

�0

.035

�0

.038

INF

LA

00

00

00

00

00

00

00

00

GR

OW

TH

RA

TE

0.0

08

0.0

06

0.0

05

�0

.007

0.0

13

0.0

10

.013

0.0

17

�0

.034

�0

.034

�0

.035

�0

.036

�0

.032

�0

.032

�0

.03

�0

.031

AID

GN

I0.0

61

0.0

32

0.0

73

0.0

29

0.0

37

0.0

10.0

37

0.0

17

�0

.051

�0

.057

�0

.049

�0

.054

�0

.025

�0

.027

�0

.025

�0

.027

AG

RG

DP

�0

.027

�0

.041

�0

.025

�0

.061

�0

.015

�0

.042

�0

.013

�0

.027

�0

.032

�0

.041

�0

.027

(0.0

34)*

�0

.019

(0.0

25)*

�0

.022

�0

.029

INE

Q0

.01

�0

.012

�0

.013

�0

.059

�0

.022

�0

.078

0.0

01

�0

.037

�0

.034

�0

.045

�0

.031

�0

.038

�0

.021

(0.0

28)*

**

�0

.023

�0

.031

YR

SO

FF

C�

0.0

1�

0.0

11

�0

.019

�0

.034

�0

.013

�0

.026

�0

.002

�0

.004

�0

.027

�0

.029

�0

.026

�0

.027

�0

.02

�0

.021

�0

.02

�0

.022

IDE

OL

OG

Y�

0.1

34

�0

.076

�0

.041

0.1

88

�0

.059

0.1

56

�0

.079

�0

.035

�0

.4�

0.4

24

�0

.405

�0

.436

�0

.311

�0

.339

�0

.328

�0

.353

CO

HE

SIO

N0

.042

0.0

82

0.0

20

.034

0.0

29

0.1

31

0.0

39

0.1

56

�0

.192

�0

.206

�0

.211

�0

.223

�0

.173

�0

.189

�0

.159

�0

.18

SO

EIN

ITIA

L�

0.0

03

�0

.005

�0

.003

�0

.013

�0

.036

�0

.044

�0

.024

�0

.03

MA

RK

ET

LA

G0

0.0

03

�0

.003

0.0

02

�0

.004

�0

.005

�0

.008

�0

.009

GO

V�

0.1

1�

0.1

17

�0

.107

�0

.185

�0

.142

�0

.245

�0

.154

�0

.162

�0

.204

�0

.219

�0

.222

�0

.226

�0

.181

�0

.186

�0

.17

�0

.183

ET

HN

IC0

.14

0.1

08

0.2

12

0.2

47

0.2

05

0.1

94

0.1

34

0.0

82

�0

.12

�0

.144

(0.1

26)*

(0.1

44)*

(0.1

03)*

*(0

.11

6)*

�0

.098

�0

.116

DE

MO

C�

0.0

72

�0

.084

�0

.098

�0

.06

�0

.088

�0

.104

�0

.036

�0

.083

�0

.085

�0

.099

�0

.082

�0

.097

�0

.062

�0

.075

�0

.064

�0

.077

GD

PC

AP

0�

0.0

01

00

0(0

.00

0)*

*(0

.00

0)*

*0

234 S. G. Banerjee and M. C. Munger

Copyright # 2004 John Wiley & Sons, Ltd. J. Int. Dev. 16, 213–240 (2004)

Page 23: Move to markets? An empirical analysis of privatization in developing countries

AF

RIC

A0

.764

1.6

29

1.6

88

1.0

91

�0

.977

(0.8

32)*

(0.5

89)*

**

�0

.667

LA

C0

.913

1.1

14

1.5

51

1.3

75

�0

.93

�0

.892

(0.6

33)*

*(0

.64

4)*

*

ILL

ITE

RA

CY

�0

.017

�0

.017

�0

.017

�0

.019

�0

.021

�0

.018

�0

.013

�0

.015

TR

AD

E�

0.0

04

�0

.011

�0

.007

�0

.004

�0

.005

(0.0

05)*

(0.0

04)*

�0

.004

SO

EG

DP

�0

.049

�0

.073

�0

.052

�0

.079

(0.0

23)*

*(0

.02

5)*

**

(0.0

18)*

**

(0.0

20)*

**

MA

RK

ET

0.0

03

0.0

11

0.0

05

0.0

11

�0

.006

�0

.007

�0

.003

(0.0

04)*

**

CO

NS

TA

NT

1.4

59

3.7

03

2.8

98

7.0

43

2.9

72

7.2

21

1.1

93

4.0

9

�2

.461

�3

.097

�2

.18

(2.6

61)*

**

(1.5

89)*

(1.9

97)*

**

�1

.77

(2.2

44)*

Nu

mb

ero

fco

un

trie

s3

53

53

33

33

43

43

53

5

Sta

nd

ard

erro

rsin

par

enth

eses

.*

sig

nifi

cant

at1

0%

;*

*si

gn

ifica

nt

at5

%;

**

*si

gnifi

cant

at1

%.

Hau

sman

test

:M

odel

2:�

15

.10

;(p

rob>�

2)¼

0.3

7.

Mo

del

4:�

17

.28

;(p

rob>�

2)¼

0.3

0.

Move to Markets? 235

Copyright # 2004 John Wiley & Sons, Ltd. J. Int. Dev. 16, 213–240 (2004)

Page 24: Move to markets? An empirical analysis of privatization in developing countries

MARKETLAG (lagged value of market capitalization as per cent of GDP) would decrease

privatization by 0.9 years. But such countries have an easier time implementing privatiza-

tion. For example, the existence of capital markets and the necessary support structure in the

form of investment bankers, lawyers, financial advisors provide the institutional mechanisms

that hasten and facilitate the implementation of the privatization policy. The implementation

of divestiture follows a standard but complicated process—company selection, preparation

for privatization, asset valuation, preparation of the sales guidelines, sales announcement

and promotion, registration of interest, pre-qualification, bid evaluation, authorization and

contract adjudication, and finally divestiture (Megyery and Sader, 1997). If the country

already has experience with private sector and market supporting institutions exist, it would

facilitate the divestiture process. In addition, the existence of capital markets facilitates

broad based ownership of privatized shares and enhances the transparency and credibility of

the process. Also, it signifies an institutional mechanism to channel scarce resources to

productive activities and reduce dependence on foreign investment.

Degree of inequality affects divestiture differentially. Divestiture decision is hastened in

highly unequal societies. The ex-ante expectation of efficiency benefits of privatization

outweighs the real costs in highly unequal societies. The real distribution costs emerges

during the implementation of divestiture decisions, adversely affecting the pace and

intensity of privatization. The decisions regarding the individual enterprises are delayed or

resisted as a result. Intensity is positively affected in case of more equitable societies. In

response to exogenous crisis, equality reduces disagreement with privatization policy

(Knack and Keefer, 1995). One unit increase in the gini coefficient increases the hazard by

1.6 times (model 4, Table 4).

Among the political variables, ‘ideology’ and ‘political cohesion’ are significant. There

is some evidence that new governments privatize more. For example, a new government

would privatize more by 1.03 times (model 5, Table 5). The dummy variable IDEOLOGY

(right-wing ideology) captures the ideological and political dimension of the government.

It is evident that ‘right wing’ ideology positively affects the privatization decisions—the

‘market-oriented’ ideology of conservatives is easier to negotiate with stakeholders and

convince the investors that the process is irreversible. ‘Right-wing’ ideology has emerged

as a significant factor in privatization decisions. In fact, incidence rate of undertaking

larger number of privatization transactions is higher by 1.52 times or 52 per cent in

countries where right-wing politicians control the executive (model 6, Table 6). This result

is consistent with Shleifer and Vishny’s (1994) theoretical model that claimed that

privatization occurs when conservative government favored by taxpayers wins against

leftist governments favored by labor unions. We also find evidence of fragmented

governments delaying privatization; fragmentation in governments’ decreases the hazard

by 1.6 times. The fragmented governments will take more time to arrive at a decision.

Democracy has emerged as a significant variable in the privatization process. Recent

research (Devarajan et al., 2001) concurs that there is no relationship between formal

democratic institutions and good economic policy. Successful reformers encourage a broad

consultative process to arrive at a consensus on economic reformers, but this can happen

irrespective of the type of political structure. Authoritarian regimes of Ghana and Uganda

adopted reforms while those in Nigeria and Zaire did not. Similarly, democratic govern-

ments in Zambia and India have struggled with economic reforms. We find the democratic

societies privatize sooner but their implementation is delayed. Hazard increases 1.2 times

for each unit increase in democracy indicator or one standard deviation increase in the

indicator hastens privatization by 0.5 years (model 4, Table 5). In more autocratic societies,

236 S. G. Banerjee and M. C. Munger

Copyright # 2004 John Wiley & Sons, Ltd. J. Int. Dev. 16, 213–240 (2004)

Page 25: Move to markets? An empirical analysis of privatization in developing countries

the process is facilitated by small number of decision makers while the more open system

in democratic societies puts pressure on the existing governments to undertake efficiency

enhancing economic reforms. As a result, implementation takes longer.

Among the control variables, geographical location matters in the timing of privatiza-

tion. We find that Africa and Latin America have delayed their privatization compared to

Asia but Asia lags behind in privatization volumes. Not surprising since Malaysia,

Thailand and Bangladesh were early pioneers. More illiterate countries privatize sooner

but their pace is delayed. Countries with lower literacy rate privatize sooner with the ex-

ante goal of using the proceeds in social sectors. But during implementation, the illiteracy

becomes a burden, slowing down the process. We also find that more open countries delay

privatization and their pace is slower. It is possible that urgency to undertake private sector

reform for fiscal gains is less for more globally integrated economies.

5 CONCLUSION

Though not as dramatic as evidenced in the transition economies in Eastern Europe, the

move from the planned economies to the markets has brought about profound structural

changes in the developing countries. Now, divestiture has been completed in some

countries while other countries are still in the process. The potential efficiency and fiscal

gains from privatization is enormous—reasons that propelled it in the first place. But

privatization does not succeed in a vacuum, the process requires facilitating political and

institutional structure. A lot of discontentment with privatization in recent years can be

attributed to countries moving into divesting public assets without enough preparation

with respect to strengthening regulatory structure, maintaining government commitment,

and protecting equity considerations.

Thus, it is important for policymakers in emerging markets to understand the factors

that maximize the gains from privatization and economic reforms. The results from this

paper will be useful not only to the countries devising the privatization strategy to

anticipate policy outcomes but also in other areas of economic reform. Privatization like

many other policies; is controversial as it has significant distributional consequences. The

holistic treatment of the problem can be useful for analyzing other reform efforts like trade

and financial liberalization that have similar distributional costs.

We find that gains from privatization can be realized and maximized when the market

supporting institutional structure exists in the form of functioning capital markets and

high quality of governance. The existence of market infrastructure to raise debt and equity

capital and mechanisms to channel scarce resources for productive uses is a crucial

ingredient to successful divestiture experience. Using the capital markets for privatization

creates shareholders out of the citizens and ‘ownership’ in the privatization program.

In summary, public sector reform or divestiture is successful if it is desirable, feasible,

and credible (The World Bank, 1995). The factors that unambiguously affects the three

criteria are existence of supporting market institutions, overall quality of governance, non-

agrarian economy, technical assistance from foreign donors, small public sector, fiscal

stability, and right wing, new, cohesive, government. It is a combination of all these factors

that facilitate the privatization decisions and enhance the gains from divestiture. After two

decades of privatization efforts around the world, it is time to reflect and understand how

and why privatization occurred. The results from this paper are a step toward under-

standing these varied privatization outcomes.

Move to Markets? 237

Copyright # 2004 John Wiley & Sons, Ltd. J. Int. Dev. 16, 213–240 (2004)

Page 26: Move to markets? An empirical analysis of privatization in developing countries

ACKNOWLEDGEMENTS

The authors wish to thank Michael Luger, Dennis Rondinelli, Daniel Gitterman and

Ronald Johnson for their advice and support. This paper is adapted from the first author’s

Ph.D. thesis at University of North Carolina at Chapel Hill, under the supervision of the

second author. This project has not been funded by the World Bank or any other agency.

All findings and errors are our own.

REFERENCES

Alesina A, Drazen A. 1991. Why are stabilizations delayed? American Economic Review 81(5):

1170–1188.

Arthur WB. 1989. Competing technologies, increasing returns, and lock-in by historical events. The

Economic Journal 99: 116–131.

Arthur WB. 1994. Increasing Returns and Path-Dependence in the Economy, University of

Michigan Press: Ann Arbor, Michigan.

Aslund A, Boone P, Johnson S. 1996. How to stabilize: lessons from post-communist countries.

Brookings Papers on Economic Activity 1: 217–313.

Bardhan P. 1999. Understanding underdevelopment: challenges for institutional economics from the

point of view of poor countries. Background paper for World Development Report, 2002.

Bates R, Krueger AO (eds). 1993. Political and Economic Interactions in Economic Policy Reform:

Evidence from Eight Countries, Blackwell Publishers: Cambridge, MA.

Beck T, Clarke G, Groff A, Keefer P, Walsh P. 1999. New tools and new tests in comparative political

economy: the database of political institutions. Policy Research Working Paper 2283. The World

Bank: Washington DC.

Beck T, Demirguc-Kunt A, Levine R. 1999. A new database on financial development and structure.

Policy Research Working Paper 2146. The World Bank: Washington DC.

Berg A, Sachs J. 1988. The debt crisis: structural explanations of country performance. Journal of

Development Economics 29: 271–306.

Box-Steffensmeier JM, Jones BS. 1997. Time is the essence: event history models in political

science. American Journal of Political Science 41(4): 336–383.

Bruno M, Easterly W. 1996. Inflation’s children: tales of crisis that beget reforms. American

Economic Review 86(2): 213–217.

Campos JE, Esfahani HS. 1995. Public enterprise reform. World Bank Economic Review 10(3):

451–485.

Candoy-Sekse R. 1988. Techniques of privatization of state-owned enterprises, Vol. III, Inventory of

Country Experience and Reference Materials. The World Bank: Washington DC.

Casella A, Eichengreen B. 1996. Can foreign aid accelerate stabilization? The Economic Journal

106: 605–619.

Cukierman A, Leviatan N. 1992. Dynamics of optimal gradual stabilization. World Bank Economic

Review 6(3): 439–458.

Cukierman A, Edwards S, Tabellini G. 1992. Seignorage and political instability. American

Economic Review 82: 537–555.

Demirguc-Kunt A, Levine R. 1994. The financial system and public enterprise reform. Policy

Research Working Paper 1319, The World Bank: Washington DC.

Dewatripont M, Roland G. 1992. The virtues of gradualism and legitimacy in the transition to a

market Economy. The Economic Journal 102: 291–300.

238 S. G. Banerjee and M. C. Munger

Copyright # 2004 John Wiley & Sons, Ltd. J. Int. Dev. 16, 213–240 (2004)

Page 27: Move to markets? An empirical analysis of privatization in developing countries

Deininger K, Squire L. 1996. Measuring income inequality: a new database. The World Bank

Economic Review 10(3): 565–591.

Dethier J, Ghanem H, Zoli E. 1999. Does democracy facilitate economic transition: an empirical

study of Central and Eastern Europe and the former Soviet Union. Policy Research Working Paper

2194, The World Bank: Washington DC.

Devarajan S, Dollar D, Holmgren T. 2001. Aid and reform in Africa. The World Bank: Washington

DC.

Dollar D, Svensson J. 1998. What explains the success or failure of structural adjustment programs?

Policy Research Working Paper 1938, The World Bank: Washington DC.

Dornbusch R, Depablo J. 1989. Argentina: debt and economic performance. NBER Working Paper

W2378, National Bureau of Economic Research.

Drazen A, Grilli V. 1993. The benefit of crises for economic reforms. American Economic Review

83(3): 598–607.

Edwards S, Tabellini G. 1991. Political instability, political weakness and inflation: an empirical ana-

lysis. Working Paper W3721, National Bureau of Economic Research; Cambridge: Massachusetts.

Forero J. 2002. Still poor, Latin Americans protest push for open markets. New York Times Freedom

House. 2001. www.freedomhouse.com [accessed on 19 July 2002].

Geddes B. 1994. Politician’s Dilemma: Building State Capacity in Latin America. University of

California Press Series on Social Choice and Political Economy: California.

Ghosh S. 2001. Move to markets? An empirical analysis of privatization in developing countries.

Ph.D. dissertation, University of North Carolina at Chapel Hill.

Guslain P. 1997. The Privatization Challenge: A Strategic, Legal, and Institutional Analysis of

International Experience. The World Bank: Washington DC.

Gourevitch P. 1986. Politics in hard times: Comparative Responses to International Economic

Crises. Cornell University Press: NY.

Haggard S, Kaufman R. 1992. The Politics of Economic Adjustment. Princeton University Press:

Princeton, NJ.

Haggerty L, Shirley MM. 1997. A new database on state-owned enterprises. The World Bank

Economic Review 11(3): 491–513.

Hall R, Jones C. 1999. Why do some countries produce so much more output per worker than others?

Quarterly Journal of Economics 114: 83–116.

Huntington SP. 1968.Political Order in Changing Societies.Yale University Press, New Haven: Conn.

International Monetary Fund. 2000. International Finance Statistics. IMF: Washington DC.

Isham J, Kaufman D. 1999. The forgotten rationale for policy reform: the productivity of investment

projects. Quarterly Journal of Economics 114(1): 83–116.

Isham J, Kaufmann D, Pritchett L. 1995. Governance and returns on investment: an empirical

investigation. Policy Research Working Paper 1550. The World Bank: Washington DC.

King G. 1988. Statistical models for political science event counts: bias in conventional procedures

and evidence for the exponential Poisson regression model. American Journal of Political Science

32(3): 838–863.

Knack S. 2000. Aid dependence and quality of governance: a cross-country empirical analysis.

Policy Research Working Paper 2396, The World Bank: Washington DC.

Knack S, Keefer P. 1995. Institutions and economic performance: cross-country tests using

alternative institutional measures. Economics and Politics 7(3): 207–227.

Krueger AO. 1993. Political Economy of Policy Reform in Developing Countries. MIT Press:

Cambridge and London.

Levine R. 1997. Financial development and economic growth: views and agenda. Journal of

Economic Literature 35: 688–726.

Move to Markets? 239

Copyright # 2004 John Wiley & Sons, Ltd. J. Int. Dev. 16, 213–240 (2004)

Page 28: Move to markets? An empirical analysis of privatization in developing countries

Liao TF. 1994. Interpreting Probability Models: Logit, Probit, and Other Generalized Linear

Models. Sage Publication: Thousand Oaks.

Mauro P. 1995. Corruption and Growth. The Quarterly Journal of Economics 110: 681–712.

Munger MC. 2000. Analyzing Policy: Choices, Conflicts, and Practices. WW Norton and Company:

NY.

Nielsen F, Gaddy G. Pooled time series of cross section. (Special Lecture, UNC-CH, www.unc.edu/

courses/soci209/s1/s1/htm)

Nelson J. 1989. Fragile Coalitions: The Politics of Economic Adjustment. Transactions Books: New

Brunswick.

Megyery K, Sader F. 1997. Facilitating foreign participation in privatization. FIAS Occasional Paper

8. The World Bank: Washington DC.

Nellis J. 1999. Time to rethink privatization in transition economies? Discussion paper 38.

International Finance Corporation: Washington DC.

North DC. 1990. Institutions, Institutional Change, and Economic Performance. Cambridge

University Press: New York.

Pinera J. 1994. ‘Chile’. In Political Economy of Policy Reform, Williamson J (ed.). Institute for

international economics: Washington DC.

Political Risk Services Group. 2000. International Country Risk Guide. East Syracuse: NY.

Przeworski A, Limongi F. 1993. Political regimes and economic growth. The Journal of Economic

Perspectives 7(3): 51–69.

Rodrik D. 1996. Understanding economic reforms. Journal of Economic Literature 34(1): 9–41.

Rodrik D. 1994. The rush to free trade in the developing world: Why so late? Why now? Will it last?

In Voting for reform: Democracy, political liberalization, and economic adjustment, Haggard S,

Webb S (eds.). Oxford University Press: Oxford.

Rodrik D. 2000. Institutions for high quality growth: what are they and how to acquire them.

Studies in Comparative International Development 35(3). (http://ksghome.harvard.edu/� .drodrik.

academic.ksg/institutions.PDF)

Rose-Ackerman S. 1978. Corruption: A Study in Political Economy. Academic Press: NY.

Roubini N, Sachs J. 1989. Political and economic determinants of budget deficits in industrial

democracies. European Economic Review 33: 903–938.

Scully GW. 1988. The institutional framework and economic development. Journal of Political

Economy 96(3): 652–662.

Shleifer A, Vishny RW. 1994. Politicians and Firms. Quarterly Journal of Economics 109(4): 995–

1025.

Shleifer A, Vishny RW. 1993. Corruption. The Quarterly Journal of Economics 108: 599–617.

Stimson J. 1985. Regression in space and time: a statistical essay. American Journal of Political

Science 29: 914–947.

Szekely M, Hilgert M. 1999. The 1990s in Latin America: another decade of persistent inequality.

Working Paper WP-410, Inter-American Development Bank: Washington DC.

Tommasi M, Velasco A. 1996. Where are we in the political economy of reform? Journal of Policy

Reform 1: 187–238.

Tuma N, Hannan M. 1979. Dynamic analysis of event histories. American Journal of Sociology

84(4): 820–854.

World Bank. 2000. Global Development Finance. World Bank: Washington DC.

World Bank. 2000. World Development Indicators. World Bank: Washington DC.

World Bank. 1995. Bureaucrats in Business. Policy Research Report. World Bank: Washington DC.

World Institute of Development Economics Research. 2002. World income inequality database.

(http://www.wider.unu.edu/wiid/wiid.htm)

240 S. G. Banerjee and M. C. Munger

Copyright # 2004 John Wiley & Sons, Ltd. J. Int. Dev. 16, 213–240 (2004)