Morgan Stanley Article7 MCI

16
 Journal of Applied Corporate Finance SPRING 2000 VOLUME 13.1  Convertible Bonds: Matching Financial and Real Options by David Mayers, University of California at Riverside 

Transcript of Morgan Stanley Article7 MCI

Page 1: Morgan Stanley Article7 MCI

7/30/2019 Morgan Stanley Article7 MCI

http://slidepdf.com/reader/full/morgan-stanley-article7-mci 1/16

 

Journal of Applied Corporate FinanceS P R I N G 2 0 0 0 V O L U M E 1 3 . 1

 

Convertible Bonds: Matching Financial and Real Options

by David Mayers,

University of California at Riverside 

Page 2: Morgan Stanley Article7 MCI

7/30/2019 Morgan Stanley Article7 MCI

http://slidepdf.com/reader/full/morgan-stanley-article7-mci 2/16

8BANK OF AMERICA JOURNAL OF APPLIED CORPORATE FINANCE

CONVERTIBLE BONDS:

MATCHING FINANCIAL AND REAL OPTIONS

by David Mayers,University of California at Riverside* 

hy do companies issue convertible bonds instead of, say, straight

bonds or common stock? The popular explanation is that convert-

ibles provide the best of both worlds: they provide issuers with

*This research received support from the Charles A. Dice Center for Research in Financial Economics at Ohio StateUniversity. I thank Steve Buser, Peter Chung, Larry Dann, Tom George, Dan Greiner, Jeff Harris, Herb Johnson, WayneMikkelson, Tim Opler, John Persons, Cliff Smith, René Stulz, Ralph Walkling, Jerry Warner, and especially Paul Schultz forhelpful comments. I thank Arnold Cowan, Nandkumar Nayar, and Ajai Singh for graciously providing me the use of theirlisting of convertible bond calls.

1. Michael Brennan and Eduardo Schwartz, “The Case for Convertibles,”Chase Financial Quarterly (Fall 1981). Reprintedin Journal of Applied Corporate Finance (Summer 1988).

“cheap” debt in the sense that they carry lower rates than straight debt; and, if 

the firm performs well and the bonds convert into equity, they allow issuers to

sell stock “at a premium” over the current share price. Take the case of MCI

Communications Corp. In August of 1981, the company issued 20-year-

convertible subordinated debentures with a 10 1/4% coupon rate (as compared

to the 14 1/8% it was paying on 20-year sub bonds issued just four months

earlier). The conversion price of $12.825 was set at an 18% premium over MCI’s

then current price of $10.875. Eighteen months later, when the stock price had

risen to $40, the issue was called, the convertible bondholders chose to become

stockholders, and MCI received an infusion of equity in the midst of a major

capital investment program.But, as finance professors Michael Brennan and Eduardo Schwartz pointed

out in an article published in the same year as MCI’s first convertible bond issue,1

the argument that convertibles represent cheap debt and the sale of equity at

a premium involves a logical sleight of hand. It compares convertibles to straight

debt in one set of circumstances (when the company’s stock doesn’t rise and

there is no conversion) and to common stock under another (when the stock

price rises and the issue converts). What the argument fails to point out is that

convertible issuers may well have been better off issuing stock in the first set

of circumstances and straight debt in the second. That is, if the firm performs

 very well, straight debt may have preserved more value for the existing

shareholders by not cutting new investors into future appreciation. And, if the

 W 

Page 3: Morgan Stanley Article7 MCI

7/30/2019 Morgan Stanley Article7 MCI

http://slidepdf.com/reader/full/morgan-stanley-article7-mci 3/16

9 VOLUME 13 NUMBER 1 SPRING 2000

firm’s stock performs poorly after the new issue, thencommon stock would have been better than convert-ibles—not only because there is no dilution of value,

but because the firm may then have had the greatestneed for equity.

 As Brennan and Schwartz went on to say in their1981 article, convertibles do not provide issuers withthe financing equivalent of a “free lunch.” Investorsare willing to accept a lower coupon rate onconvertibles than on straight bonds only because theissuer is also granting them a valuable option on thecompany’s stock—an upside participation that candilute the value of existing stockholders’ claims. Andprovided the company’s stock is fairly valued at thetime of issue, there are no obvious reasons why convertibles should be less expensive than straightdebt or equity.

But there are some less obvious reasons why convertibles may be a value-conserving financingstrategy—reasons that depend on market “imperfec-tions” such as transaction and information costs, andmanagerial incentives that are not fully consistent

 with maximizing stockholder wealth. Beginning with the pioneering paper on agency cost theory by  Jensen and Meckling in 1976,2 financial academicshave proposed a number of ways that convertiblescan reduce the costs arising from such imperfections.

 And, in a study published in 1998 in the Journal of 

Financial Economics ( JFE ), I presented yet anotherrationale for convertibles that shows how they reduce new issue costs and agency problems facingcertain kinds of companies.3 Put as simply as pos-sible, my explanation views convertibles as the mostcost-effective way for companies with promisinggrowth opportunities to finance a sequence of majorcorporate investments of uncertain value and timing.Financial economists, along with a steadily increas-ing number of corporate practitioners, refer to suchfuture investment opportunities as “real options.”Such investments are options in the sense that,although they may not be worth undertaking today 

(i.e., they are currently “out-of-the-money”), they may become so in the future. And if and when suchoptions move “into the money,” the company willneed to have sufficient capital (or at least access tocapital) to “exercise” its real options and carry out itsstrategic plan. Convertible bonds are likely to prove

a cost-effective financing approach for companies with major growth options because of the ability they offer management to match capital inflows with

expected investment outlays. In particular, as thecompany’s real options move into the money and itsstock price rises to reflect that, the call provision inconvertibles effectively gives management the op-tion to call the bonds and so force conversion intoequity. And, besides eliminating the cash flow drainfrom servicing the debt, the new infusion of equity can in turn be used to support additional debt (orconvertible) financing.

In this article, after reviewing the theory andevidence on convertibles, I show how my own ex-planation and findings are both consistent with andextend the previous research. Like other theories— notably, Jeremy Stein’s “backdoor equity” hypoth-esis—my argument suggests that convertibles can be

 viewed as “deferred equity” offerings that add valuefor companies with promising future growth oppor-tunities (that may not be fully reflected in currentshare prices). Unlike past theories, I show how con-

 vertibles are uniquely suited to the sequential financ-ing problem faced by management in funding realinvestment options. Although there is considerableempirical support for my explanation in the pastresearch, the most persuasive evidence comes frommy recent study of the investment and financing

activity of a large sample of U.S. companies aroundthe time their convertible bonds are converted intocommon stock. In brief, my study of 289 conversion-forcing calls of convertible debt over the period 1971-1990 shows significant increases in corporate invest-ment activity beginning in the year of the call andcontinuing for the following three years. This invest-ment activity is matched with increased financingactivity, principally new long-term debt, that is sig-nificant primarily in the year of the call. Thus, al-though equity is being brought in “through the backdoor” by the conversion process, new debt is beingbrought in along with it. To return to our earlier

example, one month after MCI forced conversion of its first ($250 million) convertible bond issue, it floatedits second convertible issue, this time raising almost$400 million. In short, my study suggests that con-

 vertibles are designed to facilitate the future financ-ing of valuable real investment options.

2. See Michael C. Jensen and William H. Meckling, “Theory of the Firm:Managerial Behavior, Agency Costs, and Capital Structure,” Journal of Financial Economics (1976), pp. 305-360.

3. See my article, “Why Firms Issue Convertible Bonds: The Matching of Financial and Real Investment Options,” Journal of Financial Economics 47 (1998),pp. 83-102, from which article all tables and figures in this article are taken.

Page 4: Morgan Stanley Article7 MCI

7/30/2019 Morgan Stanley Article7 MCI

http://slidepdf.com/reader/full/morgan-stanley-article7-mci 4/16

10 JOURNAL OF APPLIED CORPORATE FINANCE

 THEORETICAL ARGUMENTS FOR CONVERTIBLES4

Given that financial markets are reasonably efficient and that convertibles are a fair deal forinvestors and issuers alike, finance theory says thatthe issuance of convertibles should not increase the

 value of the issuing company. In fact, there is evenreason to believe that the market’s response to theannouncement of new convertible offerings shouldbe negative, on average.

Convertibles and the Market’s “Information  Asymmetry” Problem 

In a 1984 paper entitled “Corporate Financingand Investment Decisions When Firms Have Infor-mation That Investors Do Not Have,” Stewart Myersand Nicholas Majluf offered an explanation for why the announcement of a convertibles issue is gener-ally not good news for the company’s stockholders.5

 A company’s managers have at least the potential toknow more about their firm’s prospects than outsideinvestors and, as representatives of the interests of existing stockholders, the managers have a strongerincentive to issue new equity when they believe thecompany is overvalued. Because part of a convert-ible issue’s value consists of an option on the

company’s stock, the same argument holds forconvertibles, although to a lesser degree. Recogniz-ing managers’ incentives to issue overpriced securi-ties, investors respond to announcements of bothequity and convertible offerings by lowering theirestimates of the issuers’ value to compensate for theirinformational disadvantage.

This argument is supported by empirical studiesthat show that, in the two-day period surroundingthe announcement of new equity issues, a company’sstock price falls by about 3%, on average. In responseto announcements of convertibles, the average market

response is roughly a negative 2%.6 (By contrast, themarket response to straight debt offerings is notreliably different from zero.) The negative market

reactions to announcements of new equity andconvertible offerings cause the new securities to beissued at a lower price than otherwise. And in thosecases where management believes the firm is fairly 

 valued (or even undervalued) prior to the announce-ment of the convertible offering, the negative marketresponse effectively dilutes value of the existingstockholders’ claims. In this sense, the negativemarket reaction represents a major cost of issuing thesecurity (potentially much larger than the investmentbanker fees and other out-of-pocket costs). Forexample, if the stock price of a (fairly valued) firm

 with an equity market cap of $1 billion drops by 5%upon the announcement of a new $500 millioncommon stock issue, the “information costs” associ-ated with the new issue amount to 3.3% of the valueof the firm (or 10% of the funds raised)—possibly agood reason not to issue common equity.

 The Risk Insensitivity Hypothesis

Up to this point, we have mentioned theinformation costs associated with issuing convert-ibles. And such costs come on top of out-of-pocketflotation costs that are estimated to run around 3.8%

(of funds raised) for the median convertible issue of $75 million.7 What are the benefits of convertiblesthat would make companies willing to incur suchcosts? And what kinds of companies are likely tofind the cost/benefit ratio for convertibles to bemost favorable?

The first theoretical justification for convertiblesconsistent with modern finance theory was providedby Michael Jensen and William Meckling in theirmuch-cited 1976 paper on agency costs. Among thesources of agency problems described by Jensen andMeckling are potential conflicts of interest between

4. This section draws heavily on Frank C. Jen, Dosoung Choi, and Seong-HyoLee, “Some New Evidence on Why Companies Use Convertible Bonds,” Journal of Applied Corporate Finance , Vol. 10 No. 1 (Spring 1997).

5. S. Myers and N. Majluf, “Corporate Financing and Investment Decisions When Firms Have Information That Investors Do Not Have,” Journal of Financial Economics 13 (1984).

6. See L. Dann and W. Mikkelson, “Convertible Debt Issuance, CapitalStructure Change, and Financing-Related Information,”  Journal of Financial Economics 13 (1984); D. Asquith and P. Mullins, “Equity Issues and OfferingDilution,”  Journal of Financial Economics  15 (1986); E. Eckbo, “Information

 Asymmetries and Valuation Effects of Corporate Debt Offerings,”  Journal of Financial Economics  15 (1986); R. Masulis and A. Kowar, “Seasoned Equity Offerings: An Empirical Investigation,” Journal of Financial Economics 15 (1986);

 W. Mikkelson and M. Partch, “Valuation Effects of Security Offerings and theIssuance Process,” Journal of Financial Economics 15 (1986); C. Smith, “Invest-ment Banking and the Capital Acquisition Process,” Journal of Financial Econom- ics 15 (1986); R. Hansen and C. Crutchley, “Corporate Earnings and Financing: AnEmpirical Analysis,”  Journal of Business  63 (1990); and E. Pilotte, “GrowthOpportunities and Stock Price Response to New Financing,” Journal of Business 65 (1992), among others.

7. See I. Lee, S. Lochhead, J. Ritter, and Q. Zhao, “The Costs of Raising Capital,”The Journal of Financial Research 19 (1996), pp. 59-74. In addition to the out-of-pocket flotation costs, there also is evidence that convertibles, like IPOs, areunderpriced, by about 1% on average. See J. Kang and Y. Lee, “The Pricing of Convertible Debt Offerings,” Journal of Financial Economics 41 (1996), pp. 231-248.

Page 5: Morgan Stanley Article7 MCI

7/30/2019 Morgan Stanley Article7 MCI

http://slidepdf.com/reader/full/morgan-stanley-article7-mci 5/16

11 VOLUME 13 NUMBER 1 SPRING 2000

a company’s bondholders and its stockholders (ormanagers acting on behalf of stockholders). Innormal circumstances—that is, when operations are

profitable and the firm can comfortably meet its debtservice payments and investment schedule—theinterests of bondholders and shareholders are united.Both groups of investors benefit from managerialdecisions that increase the total value of the firm. But,in certain cases, corporate managements find them-selves in the position of being able to increaseshareholder value at the expense of bondholders. Forexample, management can reduce the value of outstanding bonds by increasing debt or adding debtsenior to that in question. (In professional circles,this is known as “event risk”; in academic terms it isthe claims dilution problem .) Or, in highly leveragedcompanies, management could also choose—as didmany S&L executives—to invest in ever riskierprojects after the debt is issued (the risk-shifting or asset substitution problem ). Finally, a managementsqueezed between falling revenues and high interestpayments might choose to pass up value-addingprojects such as R&D or, if things are bad enough,basic maintenance and safety procedures (theunderinvestment problem ).8

Debtholders, of course, are aware that suchproblems can arise in leveraged firms, and they protect themselves by lowering the price they are

 willing to pay for the debt. For corporate manage-ment, such lower prices translate into higher interestpayments, which in turn further raise the probability of financial trouble. And for high-growth firms, inparticular, financial trouble can mean a large loss in

 value from underinvestment.Convertibles help to control such shareholder-

bondholder conflicts in two ways: First, by providingbondholders with the right to convert their claimsinto equity, management gives bondholders theassurance that they will participate in any increase inshareholder value that results from increasing therisk of the company’s activities—whether by further

leveraging, or by undertaking riskier investments.Second, by reducing current interest rates and so

reducing the likelihood of financial trouble, convert-ibles also reduce the probability that financially strapped companies will be forced to pass up

 valuable investment opportunities.9

 The Role of Convertibles in Reducing Information Costs

 As Brennan and Schwartz argued in their 1981paper, convertibles also are potentially useful inresolving any disagreements between managers andbondholders about how risky the firm’s activities are.

 As suggested above, the value of convertibles isrelatively insensitive to changes in company risk.Unexpected increases in company risk reduce the

 value of the bond portion of a convertible, but at thesame they increase the value of the embeddedoption on the company’s stock (by increasing the“volatility” of the stock price). And, as Brennan andSchwartz went on to show, it is largely because of thisrisk-neutralizing effect of convertibles that convert-ible issuers tend to be smaller, riskier, growth firmscharacterized by high earnings volatility.10

 The Backdoor Equity Financing Hypothesis

The next major development in the theory camein 1992, when Jeremy Stein published a paper in the

 JFE entitled “Convertibles Bonds as Backdoor Equity Financing.”11 Beginning with the recognition thatmany convertible bond issuers build equity throughforced conversion of convertibles, Stein developeda model that uses information asymmetry betweenmanagers and investors, and the resulting informa-tion costs, to explain why growth firms in particularfind it attractive to issue convertibles. As Steinsuggests, companies with limited capital and abun-dant growth opportunities often find themselves ina financing bind. On the one hand, they are reluctantto use significant amounts of straight debt becausethey face high expected costs of financial distress.

Often lacking an investment-grade bond rating, thekinds of companies that issue convertibles are likely 

8. For an account of the underinvestment problem, see Stewart Myers, “TheDeterminants of Corporate Borrowing,” Journal of Financial Economics (1977).For a more detailed examination of these sources of shareholder/debtholderconflict, see Clifford W. Smith and Jerold B. Warner, “On Financial Contracting: An

 Analysis of Bond Covenants,” Journal of Financial Economics , 7 (1979), pp. 117-161.

9. More technically, the underinvestment problem arises from the fact that, infinancially troubled firms, an outsized portion of the returns from new investmentsmust go to helping restore the value of the bondholders claims before the

shareholders receive any payoff at all. This has also been dubbed the “debtoverhang” problem.

10. In his 1991 Ph.D. dissertation at the University of Chicago, “ConvertibleSecurities and Capital Structure Determinants,” Stuart Essig reported that convert-ible bond financing tends to be used by risky firms, high-tech firms, and firms witha limited track record.

11. J. Stein, “Convertibles Bonds as Backdoor Equity Financing,” Journal of Financial Economics 32 (1992).

Convertibles do not provide issuers with the financing equivalent of a “free lunch.”

Investors are willing to accept a lower coupon rate on convertibles than on straight 

 bonds only because the issuer is also granting them a valuable option on the

company’s stock—an upside participation that can dilute the value of existing 

stockholders’ claims.

Page 6: Morgan Stanley Article7 MCI

7/30/2019 Morgan Stanley Article7 MCI

http://slidepdf.com/reader/full/morgan-stanley-article7-mci 6/16

12 JOURNAL OF APPLIED CORPORATE FINANCE

to face high coupon rates on straight debt. And, evenif they are able to issue high-yield bonds or raise asignificant amount through bank loans, a temporary 

shortfall in cash flow could force their managers tocut back on strategic investment—and tripping acovenant or failing to meet an interest payment couldeven mean relinquishing much of the value of thefirm to creditors or other outsiders.

But if straight debt financing is very costly inthese circumstances, conventional equity financingcould also have significant costs. For one thing, themanagement of some growth firms—particularly,those in a fairly early stage of a growth trajectory— may not feel the current stock price fairly reflectsthe firm’s growth opportunities, and so the issu-ance of equity would be expected to cause exces-sive dilution of existing stockholders’ claims. And,even if the firm is fairly valued, the informationasymmetry problem described earlier might causeinvestors to reduce the value of the company’sshares upon announcement of the offering, thereby diluting value.

In such circumstances, where both straight debtand equity appear to have significant costs, manag-ers with a great deal of confidence in their firm’sgrowth prospects may choose to build equity by issuing convertibles and planning to use the callprovision to force conversion when the stock price

rises in the future. Moreover, the stock market may actually encourage the use of convertibles in thefollowing sense: If investors are persuaded thatconvertible issuers have promising growth pros-pects but no other viable financing options (i.e.,there is little additional debt capacity and a straightequity issue has been ruled out by management astoo dilutive), the market is likely to respond lessnegatively (or, in some cases, even positively) to theannouncement of a new convertible issue. That is,management’s choice of a convertible bond financ-ing may function as a “signal” to investors thatmanagement is highly confident about the firm’s

future, thus allowing the issuer to avoid much of thenegative information costs that attend conventionalequity announcements. And there is some interest-ing evidence to support this view. In a 1997 study published in this journal, Frank Jen, Dosoung Choi,and Seong-Hyo Lee showed that the stock market

responds more favorably to announcements of convertible issues by companies with high post-issue capital expenditures and high market-to-book

ratios (both plausible proxies for growth opportuni-ties), but low credit ratings and high (post-offering)debt-equity ratios.12 And since high capital expendi-tures and market-to-book ratios are also reasonableproxies for the presence of the real options Idiscussed earlier, such findings also provide supportfor my own theory of convertibles.

 A NEW RATIONALE

In my 1998 article in the JFE , I offered a rationalefor convertibles that both is consistent with andextends Stein’s “backdoor equity” argument.13 Stein’smodel addresses itself mainly to the financing prob-lem that growth companies face at a given point intime. That is, given that the firm needs financing andcannot easily service a large amount of straight debt,how does management raise a form of equity financing that minimizes the dilution (“informationcosts”) suffered by the current stockholders at the time of issue ?

The problem I address is somewhat different:Given that the firm needs financing today to fundcurrent activities and may also require significantly more capital in the future (depending on how 

things turn out in the next few years), how doesmanagement minimize dilution and other costsover the expected sequence of current and futurefinancings. To cite once more the case of MCI, how does management minimize not just the costs asso-ciated with its present convertible bond issue, butalso that of the issue that is expected to follow itsconversion…and, if the latter issue is likely to be aconvertible, too, perhaps even the issue that isexpected to follow it. Thus, a key consideration inmy theory is the extent of both managers’ andinvestors’ uncertainty about both the value and thetiming of the firm’s future investment opportuni-

ties. As I suggested earlier, the presence of suchuncertainty means that today’s future investmentopportunities are really “growth options” thatmay (or may not) be “exercised” at some point inthe future—in most cases, by raising more out-side capital.

12. Jen, Choi, and Lee (1997), cited above.13. My explanation is also similar to recent explanations for other special

financing arrangements: unit initial public offerings, where warrants are issued

 with shares (Schultz (1993), and venture capital arrangements, where equity isprovided sequentially (Sahlman (1990).

Page 7: Morgan Stanley Article7 MCI

7/30/2019 Morgan Stanley Article7 MCI

http://slidepdf.com/reader/full/morgan-stanley-article7-mci 7/16

13 VOLUME 13 NUMBER 1 SPRING 2000

 The Analysis

To show how convertibles can minimize costs

over a sequence of financings, my study used a“two-period model” that works essentially as fol-lows. At time 0, the company has a (clearly) posi-tive-NPV investment project that requires immedi-ate funding, and it also has an investment “option”that may require funding at time 1, depending on

 what happens between time 0 and time 1. Inaddition to its positive-NPV project and investmentoption, the company also has an abundant supply of negative-NPV projects (think of them as diversi-fying acquisitions) that management might chooseto take if it has excess capital and no positive-NPV projects. All investment projects are assumed tohave a life of one period.

Given these conditions, the challenge for man-agement is to devise a financing strategy at time 0 thatminimizes the costs associated with funding both theinitial project and the investment option. My modelassumes that there are only two major categories of costs: (1) new issue costs and (2) overinvestmentcosts. By new issue costs I mean not only thetransactions costs associated with floating a new issue, but also the “information costs” discussedabove.14 Overinvestment costs can be described asthe reduction in value that results from companies

having too much capital—more than they can prof-itably reinvest in their core businesses. Excess capitalis assumed to lead to corporate investment innegative-NPV projects because of the managerialtendency to pursue size at the expense of profitabil-ity. In my model, investors automatically assume thatmanagers will invest excess capital in negative-NPV projects. Thus, if the firm announces its intent to raisemore capital than investors think it can profitably use, investors effectively charge a higher cost forsuch capital by reducing the value of the firm’s sharesin advance of the offering.

My model also assumes that the company can

choose among three debt financing alternativesavailable at time 0 (an equity offering is ruled outfrom the start as “too expensive,” making some formof debt the preferred choice). It can issue two-periodstraight debt (that is, debt issued at time 0 and

maturing at time 2); this way, the profits from theinitial project can be used to help fund the second-period investment if the prospects materialize. Alter-

natively, the firm can finance both projects sepa-rately by sequentially issuing single-period straightdebt (and forgoing the second issue if the investmentoption proves “out of the money”). The third possi-bility is that the firm can issue a convertible bond thatmatures at the end of the first period and must eitherbe redeemed or converted into equity at that point.

First, let’s consider the two-period straight-debtissue. The advantage of this financing arrangementis that the proceeds from the first-period investmentare left in the firm to help finance the second-periodproject if it turns out to be profitable (and this wouldalso be true of an equity offering). For example, if theproceeds from the first project are sufficient, the two-period contract provides complete financing for bothprojects up front and saves the entire second-periodissue cost. The problem with this financing alterna-tive, however—and this would be even more true of equity—is that the second-period project will befinanced, regardless of whether the investment op-tion turns out to be valuable or not. And because themarket anticipates this behavior, the firm’s securitiesare priced at a discount to reflect investors’ uncer-tainty about management’s use of the proceeds.

The second financing alternative—sequential

issues of single-period straight debt—avoids thisoverinvestment problem of two-period debt (andequity) by forcing managers to return to the marketto fund the second project. But this choice also hasa problem: if the investment option proves profit-able, the firm may be forced to bear heavy new issuecosts, particularly if managers have a more optimistic

 view of the new investment than the market.15 Andif it turns out that the firm really needs equity to fundthe investment option, such new issue costs will beeven higher.

The optimal solution to this sequential fi-nancing problem—the one that both economizes

on second-period issue costs and helps controlthe overinvestment problem—is to issue a con-

 vertible bond at time 0 that matures at the end of the first period. The bond is designed such that itsequity component is “out of the money” at issue

14. The issue (or “information”) cost function is assumed to contain fixed and variable components, so that issue costs exhibit economies of scale, and thefunction is the same in each period.

15. Short-term debt typically has issue costs that are quite low, and the readermay wish to solve the cost-of-issue problem by sequentially issuing short-termdebt. However, the periods are assumed long term, and long-term contracts areless costly.

My explanation views convertibles as the most cost-effective way for companies with 

promising growth opportunities to finance a  sequence of major corporate

investments of uncertain value and timing. Financial economists refer to such future

investment opportunities as “real options.”

Page 8: Morgan Stanley Article7 MCI

7/30/2019 Morgan Stanley Article7 MCI

http://slidepdf.com/reader/full/morgan-stanley-article7-mci 8/16

14 JOURNAL OF APPLIED CORPORATE FINANCE

and becomes “in the money” only if and when theNPV of the investment option is revealed (toinvestors as well as managers) to be positive. If the

second-period project looks sufficiently profit-able at time 1, the bondholders will convert theirbonds into equity at the bond maturity date. Thisleaves the funds both inside the firm and trans-formed into equity that can then be used tofinance the second-period project. But if theproject turns out not to be profitable, the bond-holders do not exercise the conversion option;instead they submit their bonds for redemption,thus controlling the overinvestment problem.

The Special Role of the Call Provision. Of course, like all models, this one is clearly unreal-istic in many respects. To cite one of its mostartificial assumptions, the model assumes that thematurity date of the investment option occurs atthe end of the first period. But what if theinvestment opportunity materializes before then?If the stock price has appreciated sufficiently (inpart to reflect the emergence of the new opportu-nity) to make the bond in the money, thenmanagement can use the call provision to forcethe bondholders to convert into equity.16

Forcing conversion has a number of benefitsin this situation. First of all, the bonds no longerhave to be redeemed at the end of time 1, thus

eliminating the need to raise new capital (and theassociated issue costs) to fund the new investmentproject. Second, since dividend yields are typically much lower than convertible coupon rates, forcingconversion halts the cash flow drain on the firmfrom required interest payments and allows thesavings to be channeled into the new project.Third, the resulting addition to the firm’s equity base allows it to raise additional debt financing forthe new project unencumbered by the outstandingdebt issue. As mentioned earlier, one month afterMCI forced conversion of its August 1981 10 1/4%convertible, the company issued a new 20-year

convertible carrying a coupon of 7 3/4%. Thus, amajor advantage of convertible debt is that immedi-ate conversion reduces leverage, thus making itless costly to sell additional securities when morefinancing is required.

Extension to Debt with Warrants and Con- vertible Preferreds. My model of convertiblebonds—and to some extent those of Stein and

Brennan and Schwarz as well—can also be appliedto the cases of debt with warrants and convertiblepreferreds. Like convertible bonds, issues of debt

 with warrants and convertible preferreds also in-clude options that provide additional financing (by allowing the firm to retain funds it would otherwisepay out) if the options are exercised; if not, thefunds are returned to investors. (And it’s interestingto note that MCI issued both convertible preferredsand debt with warrants before issuing its first con-

 vertible bonds.) Indeed, the attachment of thesefinancing options may make sense whenever a realinvestment option exists, regardless of whetherdebt, common, or preferred stock is the initialchoice. Thus, for any initial security type (debt,equity, or preferred), it can be advantageous to adda financial option as a hedge against incurringadditional issue costs.

 THE EVIDENCE

 What evidence do we have to back this theory?Consistent with the MCI story, my own recent study found striking evidence of increased investment andfinancing activity around the time convertible bonds

are converted. But, before reporting the results of my own recent study, let me briefly review some of therelevant findings of other studies of convertibles.

The focus of past research on convertibles canbe classified into the following four categories:(1)managers’ professed motives for issuing con-

 vertibles; (2) the frequency and timing of convertiblecalls and conversions; (3) the kinds of companiesthat choose to issue convertibles; and (4) the stockmarket’s reaction to announcements of new convert-ible issues.

The first academic research on convertiblestook the form of surveys of corporate issuers. Each

of the three best-known surveys, published in 1955,1966, and 1977,17 reported that about two thirds of the responding managers believed that their stockprices would rise in the future and accordingly 

 viewed their convertible offerings as ways of obtain-

16. The Stein model explains the purpose of the call provision as helping toavoid possible financial distress. The call provision allows companies “to get equity into their capital structures ‘through the backdoor’ in situations where . . .informational asymmetries make conventional equity issues unattractive.”Stein(1992, pp. 3-4).

17. C.J. Pilcher, “Raising Capital with Convertible Securities,” Michigan Business Studies, 21/2 1955); Eugene Brigham, “An analysis of ConvertibleDebentures: Theory and Some Empirical Evidence,” Journal of Finance 21 (1966);and J.R. Hoffmeister, “Use of Convertible Debt in the Early 1970s: A Reevaluationof Corporate Motives,” Quarterly Review of Economics and Business 17 (1977).

Page 9: Morgan Stanley Article7 MCI

7/30/2019 Morgan Stanley Article7 MCI

http://slidepdf.com/reader/full/morgan-stanley-article7-mci 9/16

15 VOLUME 13 NUMBER 1 SPRING 2000

ing deferred equity financing. Management’s belief that the convertible feature will be exercised becausethe stock price will rise is, of course, consistent with

my argument that convertible issuers have futureinvestment “options” that will require funding if they turn out to be profitable.

 And management’s expectations appear to beborne out by the subsequent experience of convert-ible issuers. For, as shown in a 1991 study by Paul

 Asquith, roughly two-thirds of all convertible bondsissued (and not subsequently redeemed in a merger)are eventually converted.18 Moreover, a 1991 study by Asquith and David Mullins showed that essen-tially all companies call their convertibles if theconversion value exceeds the call price and if thereare cash savings from the conversion (that is, if theafter-tax interest payments on the debt exceed thedividends on the new equity).19 The fact that such alarge fraction of convertible bonds is ultimately converted is consistent with my view of convertiblesas part of an anticipated financing sequence.

 Among studies of the kinds of companies thatissue convertibles, Stuart Essig’s 1991 Ph.D. disser-tation showed that convertible issuers tend to havehigher-than-average R&D-to-sales ratios, market-to-book ratios, and long-term debt-to-equity ratios(when the convertible issue is counted as debt).20

They also tend to have more volatile cash flows than

issuers of straight debt. At the same time, convertibleissuers have lower ratios of tangible assets (prop-erty, plant and equipment, and inventories) to totalassets. The association of convertibles with volatil-ity, intangible assets, and high R&D and market-to-book ratios is consistent with convertible issuershaving significant future growth opportunities, as

 well as considerable uncertainty about the value andtiming of those opportunities. The higher leverageratios also are consistent with my argument sincehigher leverage means larger potential cash flow savings from calling the bonds and replacing them

 with equity when additional financing is required

for new investment. As noted earlier, the stock market reaction to

announcements of convertible bonds is significantly negative, on average, though less negative than inthe case of equity issues. Such a finding in and of 

itself neither supports nor contradicts my explana-tion. But, as also mentioned earlier, the 1997 study by Jen, Choi, and Lee found considerable variation

in the market’s response to convertible offerings.The market reaction was significantly less negativeto announcements of convertibles by companies

 with high market-to-book ratios and high (post-offering) capital expenditures. These are the kinds of companies that fit my thesis—firms with significantinvestment options that may pan out and requirefuture funding, but may not.

New Evidence on After-Issue Investment and Financing Activity 

In my 1998 study of convertibles, I tested my sequential financing hypothesis by comparing thepost-issue investment and financing activity of con-

 vertible issuers with that of their industry competi-tors. I began by compiling a sample of all (436) callsof convertible bonds by NYSE or AMEX companiesduring the period 1968-1990. After combining mul-tiple calls by the same companies within the same

 year (there were 35 such cases) and deleting cases without Cusip numbers (5) or call announcementdates (2), the sample fell to 394. Finally, I was forcedto drop an additional 105 cases because some firmsare not listed in Standard and Poor’s Industrial 

Compustat  data files—my source of informationabout the company’s investment and financing. Thefinal sample contains 289 events that occur duringthe period 1971 to 1990.

Table 1 lists the (two-digit) industrial classifica-tion codes of the companies making the 289 calls. Asthe table shows, convertible issuers are not confinedto just a few industries, but nor are they randomly distributed among all sectors. For example, both theoil and gas extraction and computer equipmentindustries have large concentrations of companiescalling their convertibles. The firms in such indus-tries would seem to fit the profile of companies with

large ongoing financing requirements combined with significant investment options.

Table 2 contains summary statistics comparingthe sample firms with their industry medians at theclose of the year prior to the call. Like the findings

18. Paul Asquith, “Convertible Debt: A Dynamic Test of Call Policy,” Workingpaper, Sloan School of Management (1991).

19. Paul Asquith and David Mullins, Jr., “Convertible Debt: Corporate CallPolicy and Voluntary Conversion, Journal of Finance 46 (1991), 1273-1289.

20. Stuart Essig, “Convertible Securities and Capital Structure Determinants,”Ph.D. dissertation (Graduate School of Business, University of Chicago, 1991).

 The association of convertibles with volatility, intangible assets, and high R&D and 

market-to-book ratios is consistent with convertible issuers having significant 

growth opportunities, as well as considerable uncertainty about the value and timing 

of those opportunities.

Page 10: Morgan Stanley Article7 MCI

7/30/2019 Morgan Stanley Article7 MCI

http://slidepdf.com/reader/full/morgan-stanley-article7-mci 10/16

16 JOURNAL OF APPLIED CORPORATE FINANCE

 TABLE 1 DISTRIBUTION OF TWO-DIGIT INDUSTRY AFFILIATION OF 289 FIRMS CALLING CONVERTIBLE BONDSDURING THE PERIOD 1971 THROUGH 1990

 Two-Digit Two-Digit Code Industry No. Code Industry No.

01 Agriculture Production-Crops 1 48 Communications 7

10 Metal Mining 1 49 Electric, Gas, Sanitary Serv. 7

13 Oil and Gas Extraction 18 50 Durable Goods-Wholesale 7

15 Operative Builders (Bldg. Const.) 2 51 Nondurable Goods-Wholesale 7

16 Heavy Construction-Not Bldg. Const. 2 52 Bldg. Matl., Hardwr., Garden-Retl. 6

20 Food and Kindred Products 5 53 General Merchandise Stores 9

21 Tobacco Products 1 54 Food Stores 4

22 Textile Mill Products 2 56 Apparel and Accessory Stores 1

23 Apparel & Other Finished Pds., 2 57 Cmp. and Cmp. Software Stores 1

24 Lumber and Wood Pds. - Ex. Furn. 2 58 Eating Places 4

25 Wood-Hshld. Furniture 1 59 Miscellaneous Retail 3

26 Paper and Allied Products 5 60 Depository Institutions 9

27 Printing, Publishing & Allied Products 2 61 Nondepository Credit Instn. 4

28 Chemicals & Allied Products 12 62 Security Brokers and Dealers 6

29 Petroleum Refining 10 63 Insurance Carriers 3

30 Rubber & Misc. Plastics Products 2 65 Real Estate 5

32 Abrasives, Asbestos, Misc. Minrls. 1 67 Real Estate Investment Trust 5

33 Primary Metal Industries 6 70 Hotels, Other Lodging Places 1

34 Fabr. Metal 9 73 Business Services 12

35 Indl., Comml. Machy., Computer Eq. 21 75 Auto Rent and Lease 3

36 Electr., Oth. Elec. Eq., Ex. Cmp. 12 78 Motion Pic., Videotape Prodtn. 2

37 Transportation Equipment 16 79 Misc. Amusement & Rec. Services 3

38 Meas. Instr.; Photo. Gds.; Watches 16 80 Hospitals 539 Misc. Manufacturing Industries 3 82 Educational Services 1

40 Railroad Transportation 2 83 Social Services 1

44 Water Transportation 1 87 Engineering Services 1

45 Transportation by Air 17 Total 289

reported in Essig’s 1991 study (cited earlier), my sample of convertible-calling companies had higherleverage ratios, higher market-to-book ratios, more

R&D to sales, and lower tangible to total assets thanthe median values in their industries. Moreover, forthese sample firms, convertible bonds were an

 TABLE 2 SUMMARY STATISTICS COMPARING CHARACTERISTICS OF FIRMS CALLING CONVERTIBLE BONDS DURINGTHE PERIOD 1971 THROUGH 1990 WITH MATCHING INDUSTRY MEDIANS

Calling Firms Matching Industry   Two-sample Test p-values

Mean/Median N Mean/Median N t-test Wilcoxon  

Leverage (LTD/Equity) 0.94/0.47 286 0.53/0.30 248 0.0001 0.0012Convertible Debt/Total Debt 0.30/0.23 263 0.01/0.00 238 0.0001 0.0001

Total Convertible/Total Debt & Preferred 0.31/0.24 261 0.01/0.00 238 0.0001 0.0001

Market/Book of Equity 2.12/1.60 289 1.64/1.40 250 0.0090 0.0002

R&D/Sales 0.03/0.02 119 0.04/0.01 224 0.1842 0.0986

Tangible/Total Assets 0.97/0.99 228 0.99/1.00 250 0.0001 0.0001

Page 11: Morgan Stanley Article7 MCI

7/30/2019 Morgan Stanley Article7 MCI

http://slidepdf.com/reader/full/morgan-stanley-article7-mci 11/16

17 VOLUME 13 NUMBER 1 SPRING 2000

important part of the capital structure, representingon average 30% of total debt.21

The next issue my study addressed was theamount of time that elapses between the issuanceand call of convertibles. Figure 1 presents a fre-quency distribution of the number of years betweenissue and call (time to call) for the 286 called convert-ible bonds that are identified in Moody’s Industrial Manual.Although the original maturities of the calledconvertible bonds ranged from 10 to 35 years, witha median of 25 years, the time period between issue

and call was relatively short. The mean and mediantime to call were 6.8 and 5 years, and the mode was3 years. (MCI’s 1981 convertible had a maturity of 20

 years and was called in 18 months.)I also examined the stated uses of funds re-

ported in Moody’s  (by 279 issuers) at the time of issue. Although the most common is to repay otherindebtedness (cited by 162 of the 279 issuers), mostissuers mention other uses. And, in the majority of cases where debt repayment is cited, there is anotheruse that can be interpreted as providing funding forcorporate investment. For example, 95 issuers men-tioned a desire to fund increases in working capital

(including accounts receivable), 38 cited funding foracquisitions, and 74 mentioned various forms of investment, a category that includes “exploration,”“expansion,” “capital expenditure,” and “new equip-ment.” Thus, considering the relatively short time-to-

call together with the stated uses of funds, it seemshighly plausible that most convertible issuers wereconsidering the possible need to fund future invest-ment options when raising capital for current activities.

Post-Call Investment Activity. Having looked atcorporate statements of intent and the timing of convertible calls, the next step in my study was toexamine both actual investment and further financ-ing activity around the time of the convertible bondcalls. For each of the 289 companies in my sample,I collected annual data from Standard & Poor’s 

Industrial Compustat files on capital expenditures (acategory which represents the funds used for addi-tions to the company’s property, plant, and equip-ment, but excludes amounts arising from acquiredcompanies). My data collection began five yearsbefore the convertible call (year -5) and ended four

 years after the year of the call (year +4). For each of the 10 years (year 0 counts as the year of the call) andfor all 289 companies, I calculated (1) the level of capital expenditures as a percentage of total assetsand (2) (for nine of the ten years) the change incapital expenditures as a percentage of total assetsfrom the prior year. Then I performed the same

calculations for a control sample of companies in thesame four-digit industrial classification.

 As shown in Table 3 (see columns 2 and 3),companies that call their convertibles show some-

 what higher levels of capital expenditures than their

FIGURE 1FREQUENCY DISTRIBUTION OF TIME TO

CALL (NUMBER OF YEARSBETWEEN ISSUE ANDCALL) FOR 286 CALLEDCONVERTIBLE BONDS,1971-1990

21. These companies also tended to be among the larger firms in theirindustries; however, I think that the more useful comparison is that betweenconvertible issuers and issuers of straight bonds in the same industry. Other studies(e.g., Essig (1991)) have shown that across industries small firms tend to have the

greatest proportion of convertible securities. This fact is also consistent with thesequential-financing hypothesis since issue costs are more important for smallerissues, and issue size should be correlated with firm size.

   F  r  e  q  u  e  n  c  y

 Time to Call (Years)

30

40

20

10

0

50

1 5 9 13 17 21 25

Companies that call their convertibles show somewhat higher levels of capital 

expenditures than their industry competitors in the years leading up to the call, but 

sharply higher levels in the years following the call. By far the largest changes in 

capital expenditures are reported in the year of the call and the year 

immediatelyfollowing.

Page 12: Morgan Stanley Article7 MCI

7/30/2019 Morgan Stanley Article7 MCI

http://slidepdf.com/reader/full/morgan-stanley-article7-mci 12/16

18 JOURNAL OF APPLIED CORPORATE FINANCE

industry competitors in the years leading up to thecall, but sharply higher levels in the years following

the call. Moreover, as can be seen most clearly incolumn 6,  by far the largest changes in capitalexpenditures are reported in the year of the call(3.4%) and the year immediately following (5.0%).(MCI’s increases in capital expenditures were 40.9%and 25.8% in the year of and the year following thecall of its first convertible issue in 1983.) As shownin column 7, the industry-matched control firms alsoshow their largest increases in years 0 and 1 (al-though the increases were only 1.5% and 1.6%).(And, to return to the MCI example, the capitalspending of other telecommunications firms changedby –1.1% and 0.6% in 1983 and 1984.) Increased

investment by competitors is not surprising since theprofitability of investment options for firms withinindustries should be correlated. That is, when one oilcompany decides to undertake a major expansion,the same factors are likely to drive other oil compa-nies to do the same. But even so, both the levels of 

capital expenditures, and their rates of growth, aresignificantly higher for the companies that force

conversion of their convertibles.Financing activity. Using the same Compustat source for the same sample of 289 firms, I nextcalculated the amount of funds received from (1)thesale of common and preferred stock, (2) the issu-ance of long-term debt, and (3) total sources—eachas a percentage of total assets—over the same ten-

 year period. As shown in Table 4, long-term debt,common and preferred stock, and total fundingsources all experience significant increases duringthe year of the call. For example, as shown in Panel

 A, the average increase in long-term debt for con- vertible-calling firms was 6.66% of total assets (as

compared to less than 1% for the industry matchedsample). And, as shown in Panel B, the increase incommon and preferred stock in year 0 also is about6%, which reflects mainly the conversion of thecalled convertibles into stock.22 But then in year 1,the percentage of equity drops sharply (by about

 TABLE 3 MEAN AND MEDIAN CAPITAL EXPENDITURES AND CHANGES IN CAPITAL EXPENDITURES (LEVELS ANDCHANGES SCALED BY TOTAL ASSETS FOR YEAR –1) FOR YEARS RELATIVE TO THE CALL OF CONVERTIBLEDEBT BY 289 FIRMS DURING THE PERIOD 1971 THROUGH 1990*

Capital Expenditures/Total Assets (%) Changes in Capital Expenditures/Total Assets (%)

Conversion Industry Conversion Industry  Sample Match Sample Match    Two-sample Test p-values

 Year Mean/Median Mean/Median N(Sample) N(Match) Mean/Median Mean/Median t-test Wilcoxon (1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6) (7) (8) (9)

-5 5.0/3.7 4.7/4.0 227 228

-4 5.8/4.2 5.1/4.5 241 233 1.0a/0.5a 0.4a/0.4a 0.0967 0.2106

-3 6.8/5.8 5.7/4.8 245 241 0.8a/0.4a 0.5a/0.4a 0.4285 0.6412

-2 7.6/6.4 6.6/5.7 264 253 0.8a/0.7a 0.8a/0.6b 0.9377 0.9618

-1 9.2/7.1 7.8/6.2 276 268 1.3a/0.6a 0.8a/0.4a 0.1720 0.4009

0 13.4/8.8 9.5/7.2 273 268 3.4 /1.3 1.5 /0.5 0.0023 0.0019

1 18.3/11.6 11.5/8.1 261 268 5.0c/1.8a 1.6 /0.5 0.0001 0.0001

2 18.8/12.4 12.7/9.5 252 268 1.0b/0.9 0.3a/0.2 0.5132 0.0274

3 20.5/12.5 13.4/9.6 238 257 1.8c/0.9 –0.1b/0.2 0.0929 0.0138

4 23.2/12.2 14.6/9.7 224 249 1.3b/0.5b 0.7/0.2 0.5033 0.5719

*Tests reported in columns 6 and 7 (and indicated by the letters a, b, and c as described below) are paired mean and median tests comparing year-zero changes withthe changes in other years. Thus, for example, the 3.4 mean value reported in column 6, year 0 is significantly different from the other mean values of that columnin all years. The tests reported in columns 8 and 9 are the indicated two-sample tests comparing the sample and matching mean changes and distributions of changesfor each year. Thus, for example, both the means and distributions differ in years 0 and 1 between the conversion sample (column 6) and the industry matches (column 7).a. indicates significance at the 0.01 level.b. indicates significance at the 0.05 level.c. indicates significance at the 0.10 level.

22. I inferred this from the following procedure: Using the fractions of outstanding shares into which the bonds are convertible (about 14%), as reportedin Singh, Cowan, and Nayar (1991), and the equity capitalization and total asset

means from Table 3, I estimate that shares added through conversions on averagerepresent 5.5% of assets. See A.K. Singh, A.R. Cowan, and N. Nayar, “UnderwrittenCalls of Convertible Bonds,” Journal of Financial Economics 29 (1991), 173-196.

Page 13: Morgan Stanley Article7 MCI

7/30/2019 Morgan Stanley Article7 MCI

http://slidepdf.com/reader/full/morgan-stanley-article7-mci 13/16

19 VOLUME 13 NUMBER 1 SPRING 2000

 TABLE 4 MEAN AND MEDIAN ISSUANCES OF LONG-TERM DEBT, COMMON AND PREFERRED, AND TOTAL SOURCESOF FUNDS (LEVELS AND CHANGES SCALED BY TOTAL ASSETS FOR YEAR -1) FOR YEARS RELATIVE TO THECALL OF CONVERTIBLE DEBT BY 289 FIRMS DURING THE PERIOD 1971 THROUGH 1990*

Financing Activity Level/Total Assets (%) Changes in Financing Activity/Total Assets (%)

Conversion Industry Conversion Industry  Sample Match Sample Match    Two-sample Test p-values

 Year Mean/Median Mean/Median N(Sample) N(Match) Mean/Median Mean/Median t-test Wilcoxon (1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6) (7) (8) (9)

PANEL A: ISSUANCES OF LONG-TERM DEBT

-5 4.4/2.6 3.6/1.3 195 224

-4 5.0/2.8 3.9/1.6 205 229 0.8a/0.0a 0.7 /0.0 0.8398 0.3640

-3 7.5/4.9 3.4/1.8 214 233 2.7b/0.5 –0.3c/0.0 0.0003 0.0012c

-2 7.9/5.6 3.2/1.9 220 241 0.5a/0.0a  –0.2a/0.0 0.4828 0.5194b

-1 8.9/5.0 4.3/2.3 230 253 1.3b/0.8a 0.4 /0.0 0.3020 0.1939c

0 15.5/9.0 4.9/2.3 243 268 6.6 /1.6 0.9 /0.0 0.0001 0.0004

1 21.0/8.6 7.2/3.0 229 268 5.4 /0.0 1.9c/0.0 0.1410 0.2694

2 18.1/8.5 6.7/2.6 225 268 –2.3a/0.0a  –1.5b/0.0 0.7622 0.6488c

3 20.9/7.6 9.0/2.8 219 257 2.3b/0.0a 0.6 /0.0 0.4578 0.9114

4 22.4/9.1 9.6/3.2 207 250 0.2b/0.0 1.1 /0.0 0.7038 0.7552

PANEL B: ISSUANCES OF COMMON AND PREFERRED

-5 0.9/0.1 0.3/0.0 200 224

-4 1.4/0.1 0.6/0.0 212 229 0.4a/0.0a 0.2 /0.0 0.5335 0.3864

-3 1.7/0.2 0.6/0.0 219 233 0.3a/0.0a 0.0c/0.0 a 0.4362 0.0072

-2 1.8/0.2 0.6/0.0 227 241 0.0a/0.0a 0.1 /0.0 0.7142 0.2078

-1 2.4/0.5 0.7/0.0 238 253 0.6a/0.0a 0.0b/0.0 a 0.2119 0.0071

0 9.4/5.4 0.9/0.1 250 268 6.7 /3.5 0.2 /0.0 0.0001 0.0001

1 5.4/0.5 0.6/0.1 239 268 –4.0a/–2.4a  –0.3b/0.0a 0.0002 0.0001

2 3.5/0.2 0.6/0.1 232 268 –1.8a/0.0 –0.2 /0.0 a 0.1662 0.00373 4.1/0.3 0.9/0.0 220 257 0.7a/0.0a 0.1 /0.0 0.5740 0.8634

4 3.8/0.2 0.7/0.0 206 250 –0.6a/0.0 0.0 /0.0 b 0.6038 0.3575

PANEL C: TOTAL SOURCES OF FUNDS

-5 13.1/11.2 14.1/11.6 210 224

-4 15.4/12.7 16.0/12.6 219 228 2.4a/1.3a 2.2b/1.7a 0.8455 0.5159

-3 19.4/15.4 16.3/14.4 219 231 4.2a/3.1a 1.8b/1.7a 0.0180 0.0127

-2 22.8/18.5 18.3/17.2 212 236 4.0a/3.3a 1.8b/2.2a 0.0748 0.0773

-1 27.4/21.9 21.9/19.9 208 240 4.7a/2.8a 2.3 /2.8c 0.1112 0.7692

0 43.0/34.3 29.1/22.6 212 252 16.1 /12.4 7.3 /3.0 0.0043 0.0001

1 47.6/33.4 31.0/24.4 185 244 3.3a/–1.4a 4.3 /1.8c 0.7505 0.0012

2 48.1/36.7 32.9/26.1 169 221 1.8a/2.2a 0.4a/1.9a 0.6850 0.5429

3 52.9/36.9 38.7/29.4 150 200 5.0a/0.8a 3.8 /2.9 0.7025 0.25854 60.2/38.9 40.5/32.8 129 186 7.4 /2.8a 4.0 /2.2 0.4198 0.7757

*Tests reported in columns 6 and 7 (and indicated by the letters a, b, and c as described below) are paired mean and median tests comparing year-zero changes withthe changes in other years. Thus, for example, the 6.6 mean value reported in column 6, year 0 of Panel A is significantly different from the other mean values of thatcolumn and Panel in all years except year 1. The tests reported in columns 8 and 9 are the indicated two-sample tests comparing the sample and matching mean changesand distributions of changes for each year. Thus, for example, both the means and distributions differ in year 0 of Panel A between the conversion sample (column6) and the industry matches (column 7).a. indicates significance at the 0.01 levelb. indicates significance at the 0.05 levelc. indicates significance at the 0.10 level

Long-term debt, common and preferred stock, and total funding sources all 

experience significant increases during the year of the call. Debt is clearly the

preferred instrument for financing after convertible bond calls.

Page 14: Morgan Stanley Article7 MCI

7/30/2019 Morgan Stanley Article7 MCI

http://slidepdf.com/reader/full/morgan-stanley-article7-mci 14/16

20 JOURNAL OF APPLIED CORPORATE FINANCE

4%)—and the reason for this sudden drop willshortly become clear.

In the final part of my study, I also collected datafrom Investment Dealer’s Digest (which reports allissues of public securities by corporations) on thefinancing activity of a somewhat larger sample of 365convertible-calling companies around the time of the call. Of the 365 firms, 110 obtained new financingduring the year prior to the call, while 144 raised new capital the year after the call, a significant increase of 

31%. Moreover, of the 144 firms with new post-callfinancings, 86 issued only debt, 28 only equity, andseven only preferred—while 23 issued some combi-nation of debt and either preferred or equity. Thus,debt is clearly the preferred instrument for financingafter convertible bond calls.23

 Another way to capture the relative importanceof debt in post-call financing is to examine leverageratios (LTD/Equity), which reflect private as well aspublic debt. As a result of conversion, there aresignificant reductions in leverage ratios by the endof year 0, the mean and median leverage ratios are0.63 and 0.36, as compared with 0.94 and 0.47 at the

end of the preceding year. But at the end of year 1,the mean and median leverage ratios have risensignificantly to 0.81 and 0.39. Moreover, by the endof year 2, mean and median leverage are 1.00 and0.43, which are indistinguishable from their values at

 year end -1. (And the same result is obtained using

total debt rather than long-term debt in measuringthe leverage ratio.) This rapid increase in leverageratios after the call explains the sharp drop incommon and preferred in year 1.

In summary, Figure 2 illustrates the changes inboth capital expenditures and funding sources of the289 companies over the 10-year period surroundingtheir conversions. As shown in the figure, both thelevel of investment and total sources of outsidefunding experience notable increases in the year of 

the call and the year after. Nevertheless, equity funding, after rising sharply in the year of conver-sion, declines sharply in the next two years ascompanies follow with new debt (or convertible)issues.

CONCLUSION

In the “new economy,” a rapidly growingproportion of corporate value appears to derive notfrom the profits generated by companies’ currentactivities, but from their real investment options thatmay prove worth pursuing, but may not. For com-

panies whose value consists in large part of realoptions (and Internet and biotech stocks are likely tofall into this category), convertible bonds may offerthe ideal financing match (as long as the coupon ratecan be kept low enough) because of the matchingfinancial option that they provide.

FIGURE 2MEAN CAPITALEXPENDITURES AND NEW 

FINANCING (SCALED BY  ASSETS IN YEAR –1) FOR  YEARS RELATIVE TO THECALL OF CONVERTIBLEDEBT BY 289 FIRMS,1971-1990

23. Further, these estimates of the relative number of firms with new debtfinancings are likely biased down by the omission of private financings by theDigest.

Common and Preferred

Capital ExpendituresLong-term Debt

Total Sources

   D  o   l   l  a  r  s   /   A  s  s  e   t  s   (   Y  e  a  r –

   1   )

 Years Relative to Convertible Call 

0.4

0.3

0.2

0.1

0.0

0.5

0.6

0.7

 –5 –4 –3 –2 –1 0 1 2 3 4

Page 15: Morgan Stanley Article7 MCI

7/30/2019 Morgan Stanley Article7 MCI

http://slidepdf.com/reader/full/morgan-stanley-article7-mci 15/16

21 VOLUME 13 NUMBER 1 SPRING 2000

In this paper, I propose that corporations useconvertible debt as a key element in a financingstrategy that aims not only to fund current activities,

but to enable them to “exercise” their real options by giving them access to low-cost capital should theoptions turn out to be valuable. In this sense,convertibles can be seen as the most cost-effectivesolution to a sequential financing problem—that is,how to fund not only today’s activities, but alsotomorrow’s opportunities. According to my analysis,the sequential financing approach is designed tocontrol an overinvestment incentive that can arise if financing is provided before an investment option’smaturity (i.e., before an investment opportunity materializes). The key considerations in my analysisare new issue costs (which include the “informationcosts” associated with selling underpriced securities)and the degree of uncertainty about the profitability of the firm’s real investment options. The higher thenew issue costs, and the greater the degree of uncertainty about the size and timing of the firm’sfuture capital requirements, the more effective areconvertibles both in controlling the overinvestmentproblem and minimizing costs associated with rais-ing capital in the future.

 As my analysis also shows, the critical featureof convertibles is the call provision that, provided

the stock price is “in the money,” effectively en-ables managers to force conversion of the bondsinto equity. As option pricing theory suggests, the

 value of this call option increases directly withincreases in uncertainty about both the eventual

 value and the maturity date of the real option. If and when the investment opportunity does materi-alize, exercise of the call feature gives the firm aninfusion of new equity that enables it to carry outits new investment and financing plan unencum-bered by the debt issue.

Because my analysis suggests the convertiblefeature is the key to solving a sequential-financingproblem, my study examines the investment andfinancing activities of 289 companies around thetime their convertible bonds are called and con-

 verted. Such companies made significant increasesin capital expenditures (as compared to those by anindustry-matched control group) starting in the yearof the call and extending through three years after.These companies also showed increased financingactivity following the call, mainly new long-termdebt that is issued in the year of the call. These new issues of debt, which are often themselves convert-ible into equity, suggest that financing the exerciseof real investment options is an important consider-ation in the design of convertible bonds.

DAVID MAYERS

holds the Philip L. Boyd Chair in Finance at the A. Gary AndersonGraduate School of Management at the University of California,Riverside.

For companies whose value consists in large part of real options (and Internet and 

 biotech stocks are likely to fall into this category), convertible bonds may offer the

ideal financing match because of the matching financial option they provide.

Page 16: Morgan Stanley Article7 MCI

7/30/2019 Morgan Stanley Article7 MCI

http://slidepdf.com/reader/full/morgan-stanley-article7-mci 16/16

Journal of Applied Corporate Finance  (ISSN 1078-1196 [print], ISSN1745-6622 [online]) is published quarterly on behalf of Morgan Stanley byBlackwell Publishing, with offices at 350 Main Street, Malden, MA 02148,

USA, and PO Box 1354, 9600 Garsington Road, Oxford OX4 2XG, UK. CallUS: (800) 835-6770, UK: +44 1865 778315; fax US: (781) 388-8232, UK:+44 1865 471775, or e-mail: [email protected].

Information For Subscribers For new orders, renewals, sample copy re-quests, claims, changes of address, and all other subscription correspon-dence, please contact the Customer Service Department at your nearestBlackwell office.

Subscription Rates for Volume 17 (four issues) Institutional Premium

Rate* The Americas† $330, Rest of World £201; Commercial Company Pre-

mium Rate, The Americas $440, Rest of World £268; Individual Rate, TheAmericas $95, Rest of World £70, Ð105‡; Students**, The Americas $50,Rest of World £28, Ð42.

*Includes print plus premium online access to the current and all availablebackfiles. Print and online-only rates are also available (see below).

†Customers in Canada should add 7% GST or provide evidence of entitlementto exemption ‡Customers in the UK should add VAT at 5%; customers in the EU should alsoadd VAT at 5%, or provide a VAT registration number or evidence of entitle-ment to exemption

** Students must present a copy of their student ID card to receive this

rate.

For more information about Blackwell Publishing journals, including online ac-cess information, terms and conditions, and other pricing options, please visitwww.blackwellpublishing.com or contact our customer service department,tel: (800) 835-6770 or +44 1865 778315 (UK office).

Back Issues Back issues are available from the publisher at the current single-issue rate.

Mailing Journal of Applied Corporate Finance is mailed Standard Rate. Mail-ing to rest of world by DHL Smart & Global Mail. Canadian mail is sent byCanadian publications mail agreement number 40573520. Postmaster Send all address changes to Journal of Applied Corporate Finance, BlackwellPublishing Inc., Journals Subscription Department, 350 Main St., Malden, MA02148-5020.

Journal of Applied Corporate Finance is available online through Synergy,Blackwell’s online journal service which allows you to:• Browse tables of contents and abstracts from over 290 professional,

science, social science, and medical journals• Create your own Personal Homepage from which you can access your

personal subscriptions, set up e-mail table of contents alerts and runsaved searches

• Perform detailed searches across our database of titles and save thesearch criteria for future use

• Link to and from bibliographic databases such as ISI.Sign up for free today at http://www.blackwell-synergy.com.

Disclaimer The Publisher, Morgan Stanley, its affiliates, and the Editor cannotbe held responsible for errors or any consequences arising from the use of

information contained in this journal. The views and opinions expressed in this journal do not necessarily represent those of the Publisher, Morgan Stanley,its affiliates, and Editor, neither does the publication of advertisements con-stitute any endorsement by the Publisher, Morgan Stanley, its affiliates, andEditor of the products advertised. No person should purchase or sell any

security or asset in reliance on any information in this journal.

Morgan Stanley is a full service financial services company active in the securi-ties, investment management and credit services businesses. Morgan Stanleymay have and may seek to have business relationships with any person orcompany named in this journal.

Copyright © 2004 Morgan Stanley. All rights reserved. No part of this publi-cation may be reproduced, stored or transmitted in whole or part in any formor by any means without the prior permission in writing from the copyright

holder. Authorization to photocopy items for internal or personal use or for theinternal or personal use of specific clients is granted by the copyright holderfor libraries and other users of the Copyright Clearance Center (CCC), 222Rosewood Drive, Danvers, MA 01923, USA (www.copyright.com), providedthe appropriate fee is paid directly to the CCC. This consent does not extendto other kinds of copying, such as copying for general distribution for advertis-ing or promotional purposes, for creating new collective works or for resale.Institutions with a paid subscription to this journal may make photocopies forteaching purposes and academic course-packs free of charge provided suchcopies are not resold. For all other permissions inquiries, including requeststo republish material in another work, please contact the Journals Rights and

Permissions Coordinator, Blackwell Publishing, 9600 Garsington Road, OxfordOX4 2DQ. E-mail: [email protected].