Migration in Response to Civil Conflict: Evidence from the Border of ...

35
Migration in Response to Civil Conflict: Evidence from the Border of the American Civil War Shari Eli University of Toronto and NBER Laura Salisbury York University and NBER Allison Shertzer University of Pittsburgh and NBER February 2016 Abstract This paper documents a migration response to the American Civil War. We compare men who served in the Confederate Army with their men who served in the Union army in the border state of Kentucky, which contributed significant numbers of soldiers to both armies. To create the dataset, we collected the universe of existing Union and Confederate enlistees from Kentucky and matched men to their pre- and post-war occupations and place of residence using the 1860 and 1880 censuses. Our findings show that Confederate soldiers were positively selected from the Kentucky population prior to the onset of the conflict. We demonstrate strikingly dierent postwar migration patterns between Union and Confederate veterans, and we argue that this is driven by geographic dierences in the social returns to having served on each side. Our results suggest that the decision to serve on the Union or Confederate side created lasting social divisions between otherwise similar men, and that these divisions had real economic consequences. This is an extremely preliminary and incomplete draft. Please do not cite. 1

Transcript of Migration in Response to Civil Conflict: Evidence from the Border of ...

Page 1: Migration in Response to Civil Conflict: Evidence from the Border of ...

Migration in Response to Civil Conflict: Evidence from the Border

of the American Civil War

Shari Eli

University of Toronto and NBER

Laura Salisbury

York University and NBER

Allison Shertzer

University of Pittsburgh and NBER

February 2016

Abstract

This paper documents a migration response to the American Civil War. We compare menwho served in the Confederate Army with their men who served in the Union army in the borderstate of Kentucky, which contributed significant numbers of soldiers to both armies. To createthe dataset, we collected the universe of existing Union and Confederate enlistees from Kentuckyand matched men to their pre- and post-war occupations and place of residence using the 1860and 1880 censuses. Our findings show that Confederate soldiers were positively selected fromthe Kentucky population prior to the onset of the conflict. We demonstrate strikingly di↵erentpostwar migration patterns between Union and Confederate veterans, and we argue that this isdriven by geographic di↵erences in the social returns to having served on each side. Our resultssuggest that the decision to serve on the Union or Confederate side created lasting social divisionsbetween otherwise similar men, and that these divisions had real economic consequences.

⇤This is an extremely preliminary and incomplete draft. Please do not cite.

1

Page 2: Migration in Response to Civil Conflict: Evidence from the Border of ...

1 Introduction

More than half of the nations around the world have faced armed conflicts or civil wars during

the last fifty years. Recent literature has shown that civil war is linked to low per capita incomes

and slow economic growth.1 While the economic development literature on civil war has increased

substantially in the last decade, little is known about the long-term economic e↵ects of armed

internal conflict. Moreover, the consequences for individual soldiers of serving on opposing sides of

a civil conflict are not well studied. War creates victors and losers, and social divisions between

veterans from opposing sides may lead to persistent inequality and lack of economic integration

among regions of a country. In this paper, we consider the American Civil War (1861 - 1865) and

compare the post-war migration decisions of men who selected into the Confederate Army with

their counterparts on the Union side. We focus our analysis on the border state of Kentucky, which

contributed numerous soldiers to both armies.

The literature on the consequences of civil conflict focuses on the e↵ects of exposure to war

rather than the e↵ects of participating on a winning or losing side. In particular, this literature

explores the economic consequences of destruction of physical infrastructure, the e↵ects of exposure

to violence and disease on later human capital acquisition, and the e↵ects of conflict on institutional

development.2 The American Civil War provides a unique context for studying the outcomes of

winners and losers in armed civil conflicts. The economic and human costs associated with this

war were staggering: hundreds of thousands of men died in the war, and the war imposed billions

of (1860) dollars in direct economic costs (Goldin and Lewis 1975). Moreover, su�cient time has

passed to observe the later life outcomes of Civil War veterans, which stands in contrast to modern

civil conflicts.

We focus on documenting a migration response to the Civil War. Economists typically model

migration as an investment: individuals migrate in order to maximize their expected lifetime earn-

ings net of mobility costs. In the case of civil conflict, animosity between former combatants may

generate migrations which would never have happened for economic reasons in the absence of the

conflict. In other words, by imposing social costs on participants, civil conflict leads to “ine�cient”

migration behavior. This is yet another potential cost associated with civil war. On the other

1See Blattman and Miguel (2010) for a review of recent literature.2Miguel and Roland (2011) measure the e↵ect of exposure to bombing during the Vietnam war on human capital

attainment; Bundervoet et al (2009) look at the e↵ect of exposure to conflict in Burundi on child health; Blattman andAnnan (2010) measure the e↵ects of being conscripted into military service in Uganda on human capital attainmentand income in later life. For a more complete survey of this literature, see Blattman and Miguel (2010).

2

Page 3: Migration in Response to Civil Conflict: Evidence from the Border of ...

hand, conditional on a civil conflict having occurred, migration may reduce prolonged exposure to

enemy combatants, and may thus limit ongoing violence. In any case, migration responses have

important potential implications about the lasting impacts of civil war.

In the case of the American Civil War, migration responses are di�cult to meausure. For one

thing, most combatants from opposing sides didn’t live anywhere near one another. Most Union

soldiers came from the North, and most Confederate soldiers came from the South. Looking at

aggregate census data, it appears that the fraction of southern-born individuals living outside the

South declined during the years after the Civil War (see figure 1), which suggests that migration

from South to North might have slowed or reversed after the war. However, it is di�cult to draw

causal inferences from this picture. Border states like Kentucky are much more useful in this regard,

as soldiers from the Union and Confederate armies came from similar localities, which creates more

scope for a measurable migration response.

We construct a longitudinal database of Union and Confederate recruits from Kentucky. We do

this by matching Union and Confederate military records from Kentucky regiments to the census of

1860, and then linking recruits forward to the census of 1880. This allows us to measure and control

for selection into each army on the basis of observable socioeconomic status. We are also able to

observe recruits’ county of residence prior to enlistment, which allows us to infer whether recruits

were living in places where Union or Confederate status would have been more socially rewarded.

Thus, we can determine whether or not Union recruits were “pushed” out of counties that were

more socially aligned with the Confederacy, and whether or not they were “pulled” toward counties

that were more socially aligned with the Union. The longitudinal nature of our database allows us

to deal with concerns about di↵erent migration behavior being driven by di↵erences in skill and

not by social rewards or penalties from military service. For example, suppose that Union recruits

are systematically less skilled, and that they are more likely to leave counties more sympathetic

to the Confederacy. In principle, this could happen because counties more sympathetic to the

Confederacy also have higher returns to skill. As such, the ability to observe ex ante characteristics

of recruits – especially things like occupational attainment and wealth – is a major advantage of

our research design.

We find that Union and Confederate recruits from Kentucky displayed very di↵erent migration

behavior after the Civil War. We measure social alignment to the Confederacy using 1860 election

returns, as well as the prevalence of slavery. We find that Union veterans from more “Confederate”

counties were significantly more likely to migrate, and this cannot be explained by di↵erence in

3

Page 4: Migration in Response to Civil Conflict: Evidence from the Border of ...

average skill. Moreover, conditional on migrating, Union veterans were more likely to opt for places

more sympathetic to the Union. We also find that Union and Confederate migrants were di↵erently

selected in terms of skill, in a way that is consistent with social rewards or penalties from military

service disproportionately a↵ecting skilled workers.

This paper is organized in the following way: Section 2 provides a background on Union and

Confederate soldiers as well as a review of the literature on the economic and social costs and

outcomes of the Civil War. Section 3 provides a discussion of data gathered; Section 4 explains the

empirical strategy; Section 5 presents and then discusses our results; and Section 6 concludes.

2 Historical Background

The Civil War began on April 12, 1861 when Confederate ships attacked the Union Army at Fort

Sumter, South Carolina and ended on April 9, 1865 when Robert E. Lee surrendered at Appomattox

Courthouse in Virginia. Approximately 2.2 million men served on the side of the Union (North)

and 1.1 million men served for the Confederacy (South).

2.1 Kentucky during the War

During the Civil War, Kentucky – a border and slave state – did not declare secession from the

Union. As in other border states, pro-Confederate and pro-Union supporters lived alongside each

other (both Union President Abraham Lincoln and Confederate President Je↵erson Davis were

born in Kentucky). Tobacco, whiskey, snu↵ and flour produced in Kentucky were exported to

the South and Europe via the Ohio and Mississippi rivers and to the North by rail. Therefore,

Kentucky’s economy relied on markets in the Union and the Confederacy. In addition, though

most Kentuckians owned no slaves, others were heavily involved in the profitable exportation of

slaves to the Deep South. Therefore, since allegiance of Kentuckians was divided for economic and

geographic reasons, the state legislature attempted to remain neutral for the first year of the conflict.

Remaining neutral, however, proved impossible when the Confederate army invaded the state in

the fall of 1861. While the state legislature remained o�cially loyal to the Union side throughout

the war, there was considerable support for both sides throughout the state. In the end, up to

100,000 Kentuckians served for the Union side and up to 40,000 served on the Confederate side

(Marshall 2010).

4

Page 5: Migration in Response to Civil Conflict: Evidence from the Border of ...

2.2 Aftermath of the Civil War

The literature on the costs of the war is substantial, and “costs” have been defined in di↵erent

ways. Goldin and Lewis (1975) estimate the direct and indirect cost of the Civil War to the North

and the South using aggregate data. Specifically, they estimate a consumption stream that would

have occurred in the absence of the war and compare it to the stream that did occur. They find

that the cost was very large for the entire country, but it was greater in the South. Social scientists

have proposed a host of reasons why the South lagged behind the North by nearly any economic

measure for a century after the conflict ended, beyond recovering from these losses. Scholars have

highlighted low levels of human capital, relatively high fertility rates, over-reliance on cotton, and

political institutions as factors that led to stalled economic development in the U.S. South (Wright

1986; Margo 1990; Naidu 2012; Sokolo↵ and Engerman 2000).

Wright (1986) considers the reasons for stalled southern economic growth in the post-war era

and argues that the “separateness” of the South is what led to its slower development. In particular,

Wright (1986) posits that the South, so heavily and solely invested cotton agriculture, su↵ered upon

the emancipation of slaves, which were financial assets to wealthy southerners.3 While there were

other potential avenues of economic growth in the South, such as the mining of coal deposits or

raising hogs, Wright (1986) argues that the South was so heavily invested in cotton agriculture that

a switch to investment in other sectors was too costly for individuals and thus didn’t occur. Margo

(1990) argues that poor white and black children in the South were undereducated (i.e. required

to attend fewer days of school per year than richer white children) in an e↵ort by school boards

to prevent children from seeking employment in the North upon reaching adulthood and instead

maintain a large workforce in cotton agriculture. Lack of migration to the North resulted in the

lack of convergence in real wages between the South and other sections of the country (Rosenbloom

1990).

In general, the literature on the economic consequences of the Civil War emphasizes the experi-

ence of the southern U.S. Much less is written about the consequences of the war in border regions,

where individual communities contributed troops to both sides. In border states, the “civil” na-

ture of the Civil War is most apparent, and post-war social conflicts between people aligned with

opposing sides may have had profound economic consequences. This study will contribute to the

historical literature on the American Civil War by o↵ering new insight into the experience of border

3There is a substantial literature on economic viability of slavery and whether slavery would have ended due tothe lack of profitability in the South. See Conrad and Meyer (1958), Goldin (1976), and Fogel and Engerman (1974).

5

Page 6: Migration in Response to Civil Conflict: Evidence from the Border of ...

areas.

2.3 Outcomes of Union Army Veterans

There is a large literature on the post-Civil War outcomes of Union Army veterans. This literature

typically does not focus on the consequences of military service, but rather uses Union army veterans

as a representative sample of the northern male population for which high quality longitudinal data

are available. Costa (1995, 1997) has used Union army veterans to study the impact of pension

income on retirement and living arrangements; Eli (2015) has used this group to study income

e↵ects on health; Salisbury (2014) uses Union Army widows to measure the e↵ect of a transfer with

a marriage penalty on the rate of remarriage. One study that explicitly measures the impact of

the war on veterans is Costa and Kahn (2008), which looks at how unit cohesion a↵ects later life

outcomes, including migration behavior.

3 Data

Our dataset consists of linked military and census records. We describe the data from each source,

and the procedure by which records are linked, sequentially.

3.1 Military Records

We begin with a collection of military records from the genealogical website fold3.com. The data

we have collected are essentially indexes to compiled service records, which consist of muster rolls

and other documents collected from the War Department and the Treasury Department. These

records existed for both Union and Confederate soldiers; however, they are likely more complete

for Union soldiers The indexes to these record collections contain the recruit’s regiment, full name,

and (in some cases) age at enlistment. These indexes are extracted in their entirety for Kentucky,

with 107,589 entries on the Union side and 50,304 entries on the Confederate side.

Table 1 contains an illustration of the nature of the data extracted from these indexes. An

obvious complication with using these indexes is that it is not clear when multiple entries refer to

the same person. The first three entries in table 1 are men from the 3rd Union Cavalry named

John Ewbanks, John Ubanks, and John Ebanks, respectively. The 4th entry is a man from the

55th Union Infantry, who is also named John Ewbanks. These names are all phonetic variants of

one another, and could easily refer to the same person. Soldiers frequently re-enlisted in multiple

6

Page 7: Migration in Response to Civil Conflict: Evidence from the Border of ...

units, and if their names were spelled di↵erently on di↵erent muster rolls or were duplicated for

some other reason, they could easily appear in this index multiple times.

This poses a challenge for establishing the coverage of these records. In particular, estimating

the coverage of these indexes will depend on assumptions that we make about which records are

duplicates. In the top panel of table 1, we illustrate the least conservative grouping, in which

we assume that phonetically identical names from the same regiment are the same person. In

the example in table 1, this reduces the number of unique soldiers from 10 to 7. In the entire

sample, this reduces the number of unique soldiers to 78,257 Union and 37,917 Confederate, for a

total of 116,174 recruits from Kentucky (see table 2 for relevant statistics).4 Another possibility is

to assume that all Union or Confederate soldiers with phonetically identical names are the same

person, as illustrated in panel B of table 1; this reduces the number of soldiers in table 1 to 5,

and it reduces the number of records in the complete sample to 64,309 (44,976 Union and 19,333

Confederate).

How do these sample sizes compare with the likely number of military recruits from Kentucky?

The best estimate (quoted in Marshall 2010) is that 90,000 to 100,000 Kentuckians enlisted on the

Union side, while only 25,000 to 40,000 enlisted on the Confederate side. This suggests that our

grouping in panel A of table 1 is likely to be the most accurate. It also suggests that men from

Kentucky enlisted at a higher rate than the national average.5

The military indexes give us very little information other than the name of the recruit and the

side on which he enlisted. Therefore, we need to match these indexes to other records in order

to characterize these enlistees and their outcomes. A di�culty with using this data source is that

the only information we can use to match military indexes to other records is first and last name.

Although many enlistment records contain the recruit’s age, this is substantially more common in

Union records: more than 80% of Union records contain the recruit’s age at enlistment, while only

about 15% of Confederate records contain this information. Accordingly, we cannot use age at

enlistment to match records without introducing severe systematic di↵erences in the accuracy of

4These groupings are formed by creating NYIIS codes for both first and last names and grouping by these codes.When only first initials are given, they are grouped with full first names containing the same first initial.

5Conventional figures for Civil War enlistment among whites are approximately 2,000,000 from the North and800,000 from the South. In 1860, there were approximately 2.1 million while men ages 10-45 residing in the Southand 6 million while men in the same age range residing in the North. These age ranges are based on data fromthe Union Army database (Fogel 2000), in which 99% of recruits were born between 1817 and 1847. The slightlyexpanded age range is intended to allow for measurement error in the reporting of age in the 1860 census. This impliesthat 33% of northern men in this age range enlisted, while 40% of southern men in this age range existed. Therewere approximately 275,000 white men in this age range residing in Kentucky in 1860. So, if enlistment patternsin Kentucky were similar to enlistment patterns elsewhere, this would imply that somewhere between 90,000 and110,000 men from Kentucky enlisted in total, which is less than the actual enlistment of 115,000-140,000.

7

Page 8: Migration in Response to Civil Conflict: Evidence from the Border of ...

matches by Union or Confederate status. Furthermore, we cannot be sure how many individuals

each unique name entry covers. Importantly, some names appear on both Union and Confederate

rosters. To construct our list of names to match to census and death records, we group names by

phonetic first and last name group, defined using NYIIS codes (Atack and Bateman 1992), and

military side, i.e. Union or Confederate. We restrict to phonetic name groups that are uniquely

identifiable as Union or Confederate, and we treat each phonetic group as a single individual. We

also omit name groups that only include first initials, as we do not have su�cient information from

these initials to accurately link our observations to other records.6 As an example, see panel C

of table 1, in which only two of the five unique phonetic name groups listed would be included in

our sample. As seen in table 2, this leaves us with 49,180 unique phonetic name groups to match,

38,318 of which are Union and 10,862 of which are Confederate.

3.2 Matches to 1860 census

We match our sample of unique Union and Confederate names to the census of 1860 using records

available from ancestry.com via the NBER. Again, our challenge is that the only linkable information

we have from military data is the soldier?s name. So, to facilitate matching to the census, we impose

certain restrictions on our target sample of census records. First, because our sample of recruits

comes from regiments of white males, we limit our search to white males in the census. A sample

of Union Army veterans indicates that 99% of Union recruits were born between 1817 and 1847

(Fogel 2000). Assuming a similar age range in the Confederate army, and allowing for some error

in the reporting of ages, we further restrict our search of the 1860 census to men born between

1815 and 1850. Finally, we restrict the geographic area in which we search for these soldiers.

We impose these restrictions on our target sample in order to minimize error in matching. An

unrestricted match to the 1860 census based on name alone would yield many potential matches,

most of which would be incorrect. Using information about the prior probability that recruits have

other characteristics can improve the accuracy of our matches. Take, for example, residential loca-

tion. Given that our recruits enlisted in Kentucky regiments, it is overwhelmingly likely that they

resided in Kentucky at the time of enlistment, which occurred between 1861 and 1865. Companies

6This restriction reduces the number of Confederate recruits relative to Union recruits, since almost 20% ofConfederate records list only a first initial, while very few Union recruits list only a first initial. This can be seenin table 2. We find that, in our Confederate sample of names, the regiment that the soldier enlisted in explainsabout 12% of the variation in whether or not a full first name is reported, and we do not find evidence that thesocioeconomic status of the soldier’s surname is related to the probability of reporting a full first name. As such, webelieve that reporting only a first initial reflects record keeping practices of individual regiments or companies ratherthan systematic socioeconomic di↵erences.

8

Page 9: Migration in Response to Civil Conflict: Evidence from the Border of ...

were typically organized locally, and regiments were named after the state that enlistees were from.

So, we believe it is fair to assume that recruits were more likely to reside in Kentucky in 1860 than

elsewhere; as such, matches residing in Kentucky are more likely to be correct than matches residing

elsewhere. We perform two versions of our matching procedure: one in which we match military

records to white men ages 10-45 residing in Kentucky (275,999 records in target sample), and one

in which we match our military records to white men ages 10-45 residing in states surrounding

Kentucky (3,610,482 records in target sample).7 We match names by searching for exact phonetic

first name and surname matches between the military records and the target census sample, then

by comparing the similarity of the first and last names using the jaro-winkler algorithm (Ruggles

et al 2010). We discard matches with a string similarity score of less than 0.9.

Table 3 contains information on matching rates using both approaches. Not surprisingly, match-

ing to an expanded geographic area increases the fraction of military records matched to at least

one census record, from around 43% to 66%. However, it decreases the fraction of records that are

matched uniquely to the target sample, from around 25% to 18%. Moreover, it appears that the

matches made exclusively to Kentucky are more accurate. Recall that we have information on ages

for most of the Union recruits in our sample. While we do not perform matches to the census using

this information, we can use it to check the accuracy of our results. Specifically, for individuals

with an age of enlistment recorded on their military record, we can estimate

Agemil

= �0 + �1Age1860 + u

If a match is correct, the age on the military record (Agemil

) should be essentially the same as

the age in the census record (Age1860). So, a sample of correct matches should yield an estimated

intercept close to zero and a slope close to one. In the bottom panel of table 3, we estimate this

regression equation under two specifications: (i) using only records that uniquely matched to the

1860 census; and (ii) using all matched records, weighting multiple matches by 1/N , where N

is the number of census records that match the military record in question. We estimate these

specifications for three samples: (i) a sample matched to all states surrounding Kentucky; (ii) a

sample matched to Kentucky only; (iii) and a sample matched to Missouri only, as a sort of placebo

test.

The first four columns of panel B of table 3 indicate that using unique matches between military

7These states are: Kentucky, Tennessee, Missouri, Illinois, Indiana, Ohio, Virginia, Arkansas, Mississippi, Al-abama, Georgia, North Carolina, and South Carolina.

9

Page 10: Migration in Response to Civil Conflict: Evidence from the Border of ...

records and the 1860 census introduces less error than using weighted multiple matches. And,

these results indicate that matching to Kentucky only is more accurate than matching to all states

bordering Kentucky. Restricting the target sample to Kentucky will cause us to miss (or erroneously

match) recruits who migrated to Kentucky subsequent to 1860. However, it appears that expanding

the target sample introduces enough false matches that we are better o↵ with the restriction. The

last two columns of the table indicate that matches to Missouri alone are extremely inaccurate,

which gives us further confidence that our matches to Kentucky are of a high quality.8

3.3 Matches to 1880 census

We match our recruits from the 1860 census to the 1880 100% census sample (NAPP). Here,

we make use of the demographic information we obtain from the 1860 census when matching our

records. We search the entire 1880 census for records that exactly match our 1860 census records on

the following dimensions: birth place, phonetic first and last name codes, sex, and race. We restrict

birth year in 1880 census to be no more than three years before or after birth year in the 1860

census. Finally, we discard matches in which the index measuring the similarity of names across

census records (using the jaro-winkler algorithm) is less than 0.9. These procedures approximately

follow Ruggles et al (2010). Using this procedure, we are able to uniquely match 30% of our Union

soldiers and 29% of our Confederate soldiers. This match rate compares favorably to other studies

that perform automated record linkages (Ferrie 1996; Ruggles et al 2010; Abramitzky et al 2012).

4 Empirical Approach

We are interested in understanding how service in the military a↵ected locational choices after the

Civil War. We typically model migration as an investment, which maximizes a person’s expected

lifetime earnings. Importantly, we usually think of migration as welfare maximizing: if people

migrate in response to regional wage di↵erentials, they are e↵ectively sorting themselves into regions

where labour is relatively productive. Moreover, if people migrate to regions that complement their

individual skill profiles, as much of the existing research on migrant selection contends, they are

8This “check” on the accuracy of our matches is necessarily driven by Union recruits, as they comprise theoverwhelming majority of records with age information. However, we have no reason to believe that Confederaterecruits were less likely to come from Kentucky than Union recruits. When we match to all states surroundingKentucky, we end up finding a greater fraction of Confederate matches in Kentucky than Union matches: 30% of ourConfederate matches reside in Kentucky, whereas 26.5% of our Union matches live in Kentucky. So, we are confidentthat restricting our target sample to Kentucky improves match accuracy overall.

10

Page 11: Migration in Response to Civil Conflict: Evidence from the Border of ...

sorting into the regions in which they are individually most productive. In the case of civil conflict,

migration may occur for other reasons. In particular, animosity among combatants may generate

migrations which would never have happened for economic reasons in the absence of the conflict.

As such, this represents an additional “cost” imposed by civil war.

Our aim with this paper is to measure the degree to which conflict among recruits from opposing

sides generated a migration response after the Civil War. To cast this in economic terms, we can

think of a person i’s earnings in county c (Yic

) depending on both individual ability (Aic

) and

“social capital” (Sic

), both of which are person and location specific. A person will choose to locate

in the county that maximizes Y (Aic

, Sic

) net of migration costs; if this is the person’s home county,

he will choose not to migrate. Our hypothesis is that the Civil War a↵ected Sic

. In particular, in

counties more sympathetic to the North, Sic

should have fallen for Confederate recruits and risen

for Union recruits; in counties more sympathetic to the South, Sic

should have fallen for Union

recruits and risen for Confederate recruits. This will a↵ect observed migration behavior in two key

ways: (1) Recruits who have experienced a reduction in Sic

in their home county should be more

likely to migrate; (2) Migrant recruits should be more likely to select a destination in which Sic

has

increased for recruits from their side.

We use two county-level indicators to infer relative “social capital” to Union and Confederate

recruits after the war: (1) the county’s share of the presidential vote going to Stephen A. Douglas

– the Democratic candidate – in the 1860 election; (2) the fraction of the county’s population that

was enslaved in 1860. As we will show in the next section, both are strong predictors of military

side. Conditional on other characteristics, a 10 percentage point increase in vote share to Douglas

generates a 6 percentage point increase in the probability of serving in the Confederate army, and

a 10 percentage point increase in the fraction enslaved generates a 6.5 percentage point increase

in the probability of joining the Confederate army; this is significant at the 1% level. So, we will

use both of these indicators to proxy for a county’s degree of social alignment with the South.

We then test whether the propensity to leave a county depends di↵erently on these indicators for

Union and Confederate recruits. We also test whether migrants from Union and Confederate sides

sorted di↵erentially into places more sympathetic to the South, measured as Douglas vote share

or fraction enslaved in 1860 for intrastate migrants, and region of residence in 1880 for interstate

migrants.

To determine whether Union recruits were more likely to leave more “Confederate” counties,

11

Page 12: Migration in Response to Civil Conflict: Evidence from the Border of ...

we estimate the following equation by OLS:

Mij,1880 = ↵+ �1Uij

+ �2Sj,1860 + �3Uij

⇥ Sj,1860 + �X

i,1860 + �j

+ uij

(1)

Here, Mij

is an indicator equal to one if person i from county j had migrated by 1880; Uij

is equal

to 1 if this person served in the Union army; Sj,1860 is an indicator of sympathy for the Confederacy

in county j in 1860; Xi,1860 is a matrix of individual characteristics observed in 1860, including age

and birthplace fixed e↵ects; �j

is an 1860 county fixed e↵ect. We expect to find �3 > 0.

A complication with this approach is that Union and Confederate recruits are drawn from

systematically di↵erent parts of the skill distribution: Confederate recruits are more skilled on

average. So, we may find that Union recruits are more likely to leave “Confederate” counties if these

counties are more complementary to skilled individuals. In other words, di↵erences in migration

propensities may work through di↵erences in individual skill and not di↵erences in social capital. We

show that migrants from counties more sympathetic to the Confederacy are not negatively selected

on 1860 socioeconomic status, and that our results are robust to controlling for interactions between

ex ante socioeconomic status and our indicators of social alignment with the South. While Union

and Confederate recruits may also be selected on unobservable skill, it is unlikely that counties

more aligned with the South will systematically favor workers with unobservable skills but not

observable ones. Thus, we argue that it is unlikely that di↵erences in skill between Union and

Confederate recruits can explain these results.

To determine whether Union recruits were more likely to sort into less “Confederate” counties,

we estimate the following, using a sample of internal migrants within Kentucky:

Sik,1860 = ↵+ �U

ijk

+ �Xi,1860 + �

j

+ uij

(2)

Here, Sik,1860 is an indicator of social alignment with the South in county k, where person i is

residing in 1880; and Uijk

is an indicator equal to one if person i who migrated from county j to

county k between 1860 and 1880 served in the Union army. The remaining variables are defined as

above. Here, we expect to find � < 0. We also estimate regressions with indicators for residence in

each region in 1880, using a sample of interstate migrants. We predict that enlistees on the Union

side should be more likely to move north than enlistees on the Confederate side.

Again, this is complicated by systematic di↵erences in skill between Union and Confederate

recruits. Because we are able to control for ex ante occupational attainment and family wealth, we

12

Page 13: Migration in Response to Civil Conflict: Evidence from the Border of ...

can rule out the hypothesis that di↵erences in locational choices are entirely driven by observable

skill. One specific concern is that Union veterans were eligible to acquire land under the Homestead

Act of 1862, while Confederate veterans were excluded until 1867. So, Union veterans may have

disproportionately migrated to areas with better land, since they had the first opportunity to do so.

To argue that this does not explain our regional location results, we control for 1880 farm value per

acre and the rate of farm ownership, which are the characteristics that are available at the county

level in 1880. If we still estimate a significant �, this means that regional locational di↵erences

cannot be explained by regional di↵erences in land quality.

It is likely that social and individual capital interact in determining a person’s earnings. For

instance, occupations higher in the skill distribution – such as managers and o�cials – may benefit

more from social capital that occupations that are lower in the skill distribution – like common

laborers. Thus, Union and Confederate migrants from di↵erent counties may be di↵erently selected

in terms of occupational status or wealth. We test this explicitly by estimating the following

regressions separately for Union and Confederate veterans:

Mij,1880 = ↵+ �1Yi,1860 + �2Yi,1860 ⇥ S

j,1860 + �Xi,1860 + �

j

+ uij

(3)

Yi,1880 = ↵+ �1Mij,1880 + �2Mij,1880 ⇥ S

j,1860 + �3Yi,1860 + �Xi,1860 + �

j

(4)

Yi

denotes log occupational earnings, which is the only available measure of skill in both 1860 and

1880. In equation (3), the parameter �2 captures the selectivity of migrants from counties with

higher S. In particular, if �2 > 0, this means that migrants from counties with larger S are more

positively selected than migrants from counties with lower S. If �2,Union

> �2,Confed.

, this means

that Union migrants from counties more aligned with the Confederacy are more positively selected

than Confederate migrants from these counties. This is what we would expect if S a↵ects the

earnings of skilled individuals more than the earnings of unskilled individuals. In equation (4), �2

captures a di↵erential return to migration for migrants from counties with higher S. If Union and

Confederate recruits are di↵erently selected out of Confederate counties on unobservable skills, we

should expect to see a larger return to migration for Union recruits from counties with large S.

Lastly, we are concerned that our results may be driven by pre-existing social divisions, and

not by the experience of military service itself. If this is the case, then we should see similar

di↵erences in migration behavior among the younger brothers of Union and Confederate recruits

from Kentucky. We explicitly test this with our linked data by estimating our main specifications

13

Page 14: Migration in Response to Civil Conflict: Evidence from the Border of ...

on a sample of younger brothers.

5 Results

We present preliminary results using our sample of soldiers’ names that are matched uniquely to

Kentucky in 1860 (12,440 individuals). We are able to uniquely match 3,553 of these men to the

census of 1880. We use only these samples in the results that follow.

5.1 Characteristics of Soldiers in 1860

Figure 2 illustrates the geographic distribution of Union and Confederate soldiers within Kentucky.

Darker counties contain more enlistees, as a percentage of the total number of enlistees on each

side. The distribution of soldiers on both sides is relatively dispersed: the largest share to be

contained in a single county is 6% for Union soldiers and 4% for Confederate soldiers. Still, there

are certain systematic di↵erences in the location of soldiers who ultimately enlist on each side.

There is a concentration of Union recruits in coal-producing areas of the state, specifically in

the lower portion of the eastern mountains and coalfields, and in the western coalfields. There are

concentrations of Confederate enlistees from the northeastern agricultural (“Bluegrass”) region and

around the Mississippi Plateau in the southwest portion of the state, which is also an agricultural

region. There is also a concentration of Confederates in the eastern part of the state along the

border with Virginia. It is, however, notable that there are many overlapping or adjacent areas of

Union and Confederate concentration.

In table 4, we compare average characteristics of Union and Confederate soldiers. The first

column contains mean values of each variable for Union soldiers, the second columns contains means

for Confederates, and the third column contains means for all white men in Kentucky between the

ages of 10 and 45. The fourth column contains results from an OLS regression of an indicator for

Union status on all characteristics together. As a group, soldiers were younger and less likely to

be married than the general population, which is not surprising. They were also more likely to be

native to Kentucky or native to the United States.

Comparing Union and Confederate soldiers, a number of di↵erences are apparent. On average,

Union soldiers were older, more likely to be married, and less likely to live with a parent. Figure 3

additionally shows the age distribution for soldiers from both sides. There are more Union soldiers

in their 30s and 40s in 1860; however, there are also more Union soldiers in their early teens. This

14

Page 15: Migration in Response to Civil Conflict: Evidence from the Border of ...

likely indicates that enlistment near the end of the war was more skewed toward the Union side than

enlistment at the beginning of the war By the end of the war, both armies were enlisting soldiers who

were much older and younger than were enlistees at the beginning of the war, when most soldiers

were in their early 20s. Table 4 also indicates large di↵erences in nativity. Confederate enlistees

were much more likely to be born in Kentucky or in the South generally (including Kentucky).

Union soldiers were much more likely to be born in the Northeast, Midwest, or abroad.

Evidence also points to di↵erential selection of Confederate soldiers on socioeconomic charac-

teristics. Confederate soldiers systematically came from counties with more slaves, greater value

of property per family, and more people employed in agriculture. While we do not have data on

the individual wealth of everyone in our sample, we find that Confederate soldiers typically had

surnames that were associated with greater value of real estate and more white collar employment

in 1850. These findings are consistent with men who had greater ties to slavery being more likely to

join the Confederate army. We also find significant di↵erences in voting patterns. Men who joined

the Confederate army tended to live in counties with a greater vote share going to the Democratic

Party in the 1860 presidential election; Conversely, Union soldiers came from counties more likely

to vote for John Bell, an alternative candidate from the Constitutional Union party who opposed

the westward expansion of slavery.

5.2 Outcomes for Soldiers in 1880

Table 5 contains additional summary statistics for our sample of soldiers who are matched to the

1880 census. This table includes average outcomes in 1880, as well as average 1860 characteristics

that we have only collected for this sample. These are largely consistent with table 4, in that they

point to Confederate recruits being of higher socioeconomic status ex ante. The table also points

to systematic di↵erences in locational outcomes for Union and Confederate soldiers. We discuss

these di↵erences in detail below.

5.2.1 Migration Propensity

From table 5, we can see that roughly 70% of our sample still resided in Kentucky as of 1880;

however, approximately 50% of our sample had moved between counties by 1880. This is true of

both Union and Confederate veterans. In table 6, we estimate OLS regressions of an indicator

for having moved between counties (columns 1-4) or states (columns 5-8) on an indicator for

having served in the Union army, as well as other individual characteristics and 1860 county fixed

15

Page 16: Migration in Response to Civil Conflict: Evidence from the Border of ...

e↵ects. We find no evidence that Union recruits were more likely to migrate than their Confederate

counterparts. We find some evidence that migrants were positively selected in terms of occupational

attainment but negatively selected in terms of family wealth. As farmers typically owned a large

number of assets but had a relatively low occupational income score, this likely indicates that

landowning farmers were unlikely to move, relative to semi skilled or skilled workers.

In table 7, we estimate the impact of home county vote share to Douglas and the home county

incidence of slavery on the propensity to migrate among Union and Confederate recruits. We find

that Union recruits are significantly more likely that Confederate recruits to leave counties with a

larger vote share going to Douglas in the 1860 presidential election. To address concerns that this is

driven by county-level di↵erences in the return to skill, we include indicators for occupational class

and interactions between these indicators and Douglas vote share in column (2). This has very

little impact on our results; moreover, we do not find evidence that migrants from counties with a

greater Douglas vote share are negatively selected on skill, which would be a necessary condition

for skill di↵erences among Union and Confederate recruits to explain our results. In column (3),

we proxy observable skill with log family wealth in 1860, and we find similar results. In columns

(4)-(6), we use the 1860 fraction enslaved to measure social alignment with the South, and we find

broadly similar results.

5.2.2 Migration Destination

In figure 4, we map the locations of interstate migrants from the Union and Confederate army

in 1880. There appear to be clear locational di↵erences: Union recruits are more likely to move

north, and Confederate recruits are more likely to move south and west. In table 8, we estimate

di↵erences in locational choices of interstate migrants by military side. We regression indicators for

having moved to the South, Northeast, Midwest and West on an indicator for having served in the

Union army, as well as other 1860 characteristics including age, birthplace and county of residence

fixed e↵ects. We find that Union recruits were significantly more likely to migrate to the Midwest,

and less likely to migrate to the South or the West. This is conditional on ex ante occupational

attainment, literacy, and family wealth, so di↵erences in destination regions cannot be explained

by di↵erences in observable skill. This is consistent with recruits moving to areas of the country

where the social returns to their military service are highest.9

9As the West was sparsely populated, it migration to the West should have been associated with a smaller “penalty”for serving on the Confederate side.

16

Page 17: Migration in Response to Civil Conflict: Evidence from the Border of ...

As mentioned above, a concern is that these results are not driven by regional di↵erences in the

social returns to military service, but by the Homestead Act of 1862. Because Confederate veterans

were excluded until 1867, they may have been excluded from acquiring the best available land, if

this land was claimed first. If the best land was in the Midwest, this might generate our results.

To address this concern, we control for two salient 1880 county characteristics: average farm value

per acre, and the ownership rate in agriculture. If di↵erences in destination region are totally

explained by the fact that Union recruits could access better quality land, then including these

controls should wipe out any systematic regional di↵erences in location by military side. While this

does substantially reduce the e↵ect of being in the Union army on the probability of living in the

South in 1880, it does not substantially alter the e↵ect on the probability of living in the Midwest

or West.

In table 9, we estimate di↵erences in locational choices of intrastate migrants in Kentucky. We

find that intrastate migrants from the Union side migrated to counties with a smaller Douglas vote

share in 1860, and with a lower incidence of slavery in 1860. Again, this is is robust to controlling

for ex ante observable skill.

5.2.3 Migrant Selection

In tables 10 and 11, we explore di↵erences in the selection of migrants from the Union and Confed-

erate side. We believe that it is likely that social and individual capital are complementary: strong

social networks have a larger e↵ect on the earnings of skilled workers than unskilled workers. Thus,

we should expect to see social alignment with the Confederacy a↵ecting the migration decisions

of skilled and unskilled workers di↵erently. In table 10, we look at di↵erences in the selection of

migrants overall. We regress an indicator for having migrated between 1860 and 1880 on measures

of observable skill in 1860 separately for Union and Confederate recruits, and we test whether or

not our coe�cients of interest are significantly di↵erent for Union and Confederate recruits. We

find some evidence that migrants from the Union side were more positively selected than movers

from the Confederate side. In particular, being from the top two tiers of the skill distribution (white

collar or skilled blue collar) strongly predicts migration among Union veterans; however, this is not

the case for Confederate veterans. The di↵erence in the e↵ect of white collar status on migration

between samples is significant at the 5% level. This is consistent with what we believe about the

complementarity between social capital and skill. As a rule, Kentucky became less sympathetic to

the North and more sympathetic to the South after the Civil War. So, we should expect Union

17

Page 18: Migration in Response to Civil Conflict: Evidence from the Border of ...

“leavers” to be disproportionately more skilled if the social penalty they faced after the war mostly

a↵ected skilled workers. Importantly, this finding remains if we classify “migrants” as interstate

migrants only.

In table 11, we estimate equations (3) and (4). In the top panel, we look at whether or not

Union recruits from more “Confederate” counties were more positively selected than Confederate

recruits from “Confederate” counties, in terms of ex ante observable skill and unobservable skill

(measured as occupational attainment in 1880, conditional on occupational attainment in 1860).

We find evidence that this is the case. We also find some evidence that the return to migration was

greater for Union recruits than Confederate recruits. In the bottom panel, we look at di↵erences in

the selection of migrants from counties with a higher incidence of slavery. Here, we find that Union

migrants from counties with more prevalent slavery are more positively selected than Confederate

migrants in terms of family wealth, but not occupational attainment. Similarly, we do not find that

Union migrants from counties with more slaves attained a higher occupational status in 1880 than

Confederate migrants from these counties. However, given the close association between slavery

and agriculture, we are a bit concerned about how the low placement of farmers in our occupational

ranking is a↵ecting these estimates.

We should also note that Union recruits may have been more positively selected in predomi-

nantly Confederate counties: perhaps skilled men were more likely to “go against the grain.” We

test whether or not Union recruits were more skilled ex ante (measured by occupational attainment

and family wealth) when they came from counties more aligned with the Confederacy. We do not

find any evidence that this is the case. However, we will grant that they may have been selected

on unobservables, which may contribute to their di↵erent occupational outcomes in 1880.

5.2.4 Brothers of Civil War Recruits

We ave argued that social penalties associated with serving on the Union or Confederate side

generated a migration response after the Civil War. However, it is possible that these social divisions

existed before the war, and we would have observed the same migration behavior in the absence of

the conflict. To test this conjecture – and the conjecture that recruits were punished or rewarded

for “ideology” rather than military service explicitly – we estimate our baseline specifications using

a sample of younger brothers of Union and Confederate veterans. If men who did not fight in the

war (but are from families that sided with one army or the other) behave similarly to combatants,

this suggests that the experience of actually serving on one side or the other is not so important.

18

Page 19: Migration in Response to Civil Conflict: Evidence from the Border of ...

We present these results in table 12. While some of the patterns we observe for recruits hold true

for their younger brothers, many others do not. This suggests to us that military service on one

side or the other was an important determinant of migration behavior.

6 Conclusion

Our results suggest that social divisions among Union and Confederate sides following the Civil

War had large e↵ects on migration behavior. We measure a county’s social alignment with the

Confederacy – which increases the relative return to having served in the Confederate army – by

the vote share the Stephen A. Douglas in the 1860 presidential election, and the fraction of the

population that was enslaved in 1860. We document systematically di↵erent migration behavior

among Union and Confederate veterans, which depends on the ex ante social alignment of their

county of origin with the Confederacy. Our results suggest that recruits migrated as a consequence

of social divisions created by the war.

References

[1] Abramitzky, Ran, Leah Platt Boustan, and Katherine Eriksson (2012). “Europe’s Tired, Poor,Huddled Masses: Self-Selection and Economic Outcomes in the Age of Mass Migration.” Amer-ican Economic Review. 102(5): 1832-1856.

[2] Annan, Jeannie and Christopher Blattman (2010). “The Consequences of Child Soldiering.”Review of Economics and Statistics. 92(4): 882-898.

[3] Atack, Jeremay and Fred Bateman (1992). “Matchmaker, Matchmaker, Make Me a Match:A General Personal Computer-Based Matching Program for Historical Research” HistoricalMethods. 25(2):53-65.

[4] Beard, Charles A. The Rise of American Civilization. New York: The Macmillan Company,1927.

[5] Blattman, Christopher, and Edward Miguel. “Civil War.” Journal of Economic Literature,48(1): 3- 57, 2010.

[6] Bleakley, Hoyt, Louis Cain, and Joseph Ferrie. “Amidst Poverty and Prejudice: Black andIrish Civil War Veterans,” in Institutions, Innovation, and Industrialization: Essays in Eco-nomic History and Development, Avner Greif, Lynne Keisling, John V.C. Nye (eds.), 2014.(Festschrift volume for Joel Mokyr.)

[7] Bundervoet, Tom, Philip Verwimp, and Richard Akresh (2006). “Health and Civil War inRural Burundi.” Journal of Human Resources. 44(2): 536-563.

19

Page 20: Migration in Response to Civil Conflict: Evidence from the Border of ...

[8] Cain, Louis P. and Sok Chul Hong. “Survival in 19th Century Cities: The Larger the City, theSmaller Your Chances,” Explorations in Economic History, October 2009.

[9] Cohran, Thomas C. “Did the Civil War Retard Industrialization?” Mississippi Valley Histor-ical Review, XLVIII (September 1961), 197-210.

[10] Collins, William J. and Marianne H. Wanamaker (2014). “Selection and Economic Gains in theGreat Migration of African Americans: New Evidence from Linked Census Data.” AmericanEconomic Journal: Applied Economics. 6(1): 220-252.

[11] Clubb, Jerome M., William H. Flanigan, and Nancy H. Zingale. Electoral Data for Countiesin the United States: Presidential and Congressional Races, 1840-1972. ICPSR08611-v1. AnnArbor, MI: Inter-university Consortium for Political and Social Research [distributor], 2006-11-13. doi:10.3886/ICPSR08611.v1

[12] Conrad, Alfred H. and John R. Meyer. “The Economics of Slavery in the Ante Bellum South.”The Journal of Political Economy, 66(2): 95-130. April 1958.

[13] Costa, Dora L. “Pensions and Retirement: Evidence from Union Army Veterans.” QuarterlyJournal of Economics. May 1995, 110(2): 297-320.

[14] Costa, Dora L. “Displacing the Family: Union Army Pensions and Elderly Living Arrange-ments.” Journal of Political Economy. December 1997, 105(6): 1269-1292.

[15] Costa, Dora L, and Matthew Kahn. Heroes and Cowards: The Social Face of War. 2008.Princeton University Press.

[16] Eli, Shari J. (2015). “Income E↵ects on Health: Evidence from Union Army Pensions.” Journalof Economic History. 75(2): 448-478.

[17] Engerman, Stanley. “Slavery as an Obstacle to Economic Growth in the United States: A PanelDiscussion,” with Alfred H. Conrad and others. Chapter 2 in Paul Finkelman, ed., Articles onAmerican Slavery, Volume 10, Economics, Industrialization, Urbanization and Slavery, NewYork: Garland Press, 1989: 28-70.

[18] Ferrie, Joseph P. (1996). “A New Sample of Americans Linked from the 1850 Public Use MicroSample of the Federal Census of Population to the 1860 Federal Census Manuscript Schedules.”Historical Methods. 29: 141- 156.

[19] Fogel, Robert W. (2000). Public Use Tape on the Aging of Veterans of the Union Army:Military, Pension, and Medical Records, 1860-1940, Version M-5. Center for Population Eco-nomics, University of Chicago Graduate School of Business, and Department of Economics,Brigham Young University.

[20] Fogel, Robert and Stanley Engerman. Time on the Cross: The Economics of American NegroSlavery. New York: W.W. Norton and Company. 1974.

[21] Goldin, Claudia and Frank Lewis. “The Economic Cost of the American Civil War: Estimatesand Implications,” Journal of Economic History. June 1975 35: 299-326.

[22] Goldin, Claudia and Frank Lewis. “The Post-Bellum Recovery of the South and the Cost ofthe Civil War: A Comment,” Journal of Economic History. June 1978 38: 487-92.

20

Page 21: Migration in Response to Civil Conflict: Evidence from the Border of ...

[23] Goldin, Claudia. Urban Slavery in the American South, 1820 to 1860: A Quantitative History.Chicago, IL: University of Chicago Press.

[24] Haines, Michael R., and Inter-university Consortium for Political and Social Research (2010).Historical, Demographic, Economic, and Social Data: The United States, 1790-2002 [Computerfile]. ICPSR02896-v3. Ann Arbor, MI: Inter-university Consortium for Political and SocialResearch [distributor], 2010-05-21. doi:10.3886/ICPSR02896

[25] Harrison, Lowell H. (1975). The Civil War in Kentucky. Lexington: The University Press ofKentucky.

[26] Margo, Robert. Race and Schooling in the South, 1880-1950: An Economic History, NBERMonograph Series on Long-Term Factors in Economic Development. Chicago: University ofChicago Press, 1990. Pp. vii, 164.

[27] Marshall, Ann. Creating a Confederate Kentucky: The Lost Cause and Civil War Memory ina Border State. Chapel Hill: University of North Carolina Press, 2010.

[28] Miguel, Edward and Gerard Roland (2011). “The Long-Run Impact of Bombing in Vietnam.”Journal of Development Economics. 96(1): 1-15.

[29] Naidu, Suresh. “Su↵rage, Schooling, and Sorting in the Post-Bellum U.S. South.” WorkingPaper, 2012.

[30] Rosenbloom, Joshua. “One Market or Many? Labor Market Integration in the Late Nineteenth-Century United States.” Journal of Economic History, 50 (March 1990): 85-108

[31] Ruggles, Steven J., Trent Alexander, Katie Genadek, Ronald Goeken, Matthew B. Schroeder,and Matthew Sobek. Integrated Public Use Microdata Series: Version 5.0 [Machine-readabledatabase]. Minneapolis: University of Minnesota, 2010.

[32] Salisbury, Laura. “Women’s Income and Marriage Markets in the United States: Evidencefrom Civil War Pensions,” NBER Working Paper No. 20201, June 2014.

[33] Salsbury, Stephen. “The E↵ect of the Civil War on American Industrial Development,” inRalph Andreano, ed, The Economic Impact of the American Civil War. New York: SchenkmanPublishing Co., 1967.

[34] Sokolo↵, Kenneth and Stanley Engerman. “Institutions, Factor Endowments, and Paths ofDevelopment in the New World.” Journal of Economic Perspectives, 14(3): 217-232, Summer2000.

[35] Wright, Gavin. Old South, New South: Revolutions in the Southern Economy Since the CivilWar, Baton Rouge: Louisiana State Press, 1986.

21

Page 22: Migration in Response to Civil Conflict: Evidence from the Border of ...

7 Tables and Figures

Table 1: Military Data: Example

Side Regiment Name

Union 3rd Cavalry John EwbanksUnion 3rd Cavalry John UbanksUnion 3rd Cavalry John EbanksUnion 55th Infantry John EwbanksUnion 1st Cavalry Jefferson Eubanks

Confederate Kirkpatrick's Battalion John J EwbankConfederate Kirkpatrick's Battalion J J EubankConfederate 10th Infantry Napolean EwbanksConfederate 12th Cavalry Napolean EubanksConfederate 19th Infantry F Eubanks

Union 3rd Cavalry John EwbanksUnion 3rd Cavalry John UbanksUnion 3rd Cavalry John EbanksUnion 55th Infantry John EwbanksUnion 1st Cavalry Jefferson Eubanks

Confederate Kirkpatrick's Battalion John J EwbankConfederate Kirkpatrick's Battalion J J EubankConfederate 10th Infantry Napolean EwbanksConfederate 12th Cavalry Napolean EubanksConfederate 19th Infantry F Eubanks

Union 3rd Cavalry John EwbanksUnion 3rd Cavalry John UbanksUnion 3rd Cavalry John EbanksUnion 55th Infantry John EwbanksUnion 1st Cavalry Jefferson Eubanks

Confederate Kirkpatrick's Battalion John J EwbankConfederate Kirkpatrick's Battalion J J EubankConfederate 10th Infantry Napolean EwbanksConfederate 12th Cavalry Napolean EubanksConfederate 19th Infantry F Eubanks

Panel A: phonetic name + regiment groups

Panel B: phonetic name + union/confederate groups

Panel C: names included in final sample

22

Page 23: Migration in Response to Civil Conflict: Evidence from the Border of ...

Table 2: Military Data: Statistics

Union Confederate Total

Total # Records 107,589 50,304 157,893 % of total 68.1% 31.9% 100%# unique phonetic last name + phonetic first name + regiment groups 78,257 37,917 116,174# unique phonetic last + phonetic first + union/confederate groups 44,976 19,333 64,309# groups with only first initials available 129 3,578 3,707 % of groups with only first initials available 0.3% 18.5% 5.8%# unique phonetic last + phonetic first + union/confederate groups, excl groups with only first initials, identifiable as union/confederate only 38,318 10,862 49,180

% of total 77.9% 22.1% 100%

Note: about 75% of phonetic name groups contain unique entries.

23

Page 24: Migration in Response to Civil Conflict: Evidence from the Border of ...

Table 3: Matches between Military Data and 1860 Census: Statistics

Union Confederate Union Confederate

# military records matched at least once to census 25,461 7,103 - 16,472 4,588 -Mean # matches per military record (of matched) 11.86 9.00 *** 2.12 1.81 ***# unique matches to census 6,503 2,008 - 9,529 2,911 -% of military records matched to at least one census 66.4% 65.4% ** 43.0% 42.2%Conventional match rate 17.0% 18.5% *** 24.9% 26.8% ***% of matches living in Kentukcy 26.5% 29.5% *** - - -

Sample:Unique Weighted Unique Weighted Unique Weighted

Coefficient on Military Age 0.501 0.214 0.632 0.474 0.051 0.048Constant 10.3 18.0 7.0 11.4 22.3 22.5R-squared 0.185 0.027 0.294 0.135 0.001 0.001Observations 5,944 302,022 9,391 35,393 4,323 28,299

Panel A. Linkage Rates to Census by Target Sample

Matched to all states near KY Matched to KY

Matched to all states near KY Matched to KY Matched to MO (placebo)

Panel B. Test of Accuracy of Matched Records

24

Page 25: Migration in Response to Civil Conflict: Evidence from the Border of ...

Table 4: Characteristics of Union and Confederate Soldiers, 1860

OLS Regresion

Union Confederate

All men 10-45 in Kentucky,

1860 Dependent variable = 1 if Union

Age 22.398 22.031 ** 23.895 -0.002**(0.001)

Married 0.319 0.270 *** 0.370 0.019(0.015)

Household head 0.302 0.251 *** 0.371 0.020(0.019)

Lives with parent 0.442 0.481 *** 0.385 -0.013(0.011)

Born Kentucky 0.749 0.820 *** 0.722

Born south (incl. Kentucky) 0.863 0.933 *** 0.834

Born northeast 0.018 0.010 *** 0.021 0.100***(0.026)

Born midwest 0.043 0.023 *** 0.038 0.081***(0.026)

Immigrant 0.077 0.034 *** 0.106 0.153***(0.021)

County % agricultural 0.754 0.788 *** 0.766 0.041(0.088)

County % urban 0.090 0.081 0.117 -0.254**(0.112)

County % slave 0.148 0.189 *** 0.176 -0.650***(0.226)

County % free black 0.008 0.009 0.009 1.229(1.765)

Property per family ($1000) 3.873 4.909 *** 4.576 0.002(0.012)

County ag value per acre 18.524 22.072 22.403 -0.001(0.002)

County mean farm size 2.371 2.315 2.210 0.010(0.019)

County churches per 100 people 0.193 0.187 0.187 0.249*(0.143)

County value per church 2.233 2.234 2.675 0.004(0.008)

Vote share: Bell 0.454 0.419 *** 0.451

Vote share: Douglas 0.357 0.441 *** 0.353 -0.597***(0.101)

Vote share: Breckenridge 0.178 0.134 *** 0.186 -0.189(0.133)

Presidental voter turnout 0.667 0.699 *** 0.671 -0.161(0.182)

Surname: mean prop., 1850 ($1000) 1.240 1.739 *** 1.503 -0.002***(0.000)

Surname: % white collar, 1850 0.057 0.066 *** 0.065 -0.058(0.053)

Surname: % farmer, 1850 0.627 0.625 0.623 -0.002(0.025)

Surname: % laborer, 1850 0.064 0.061 0.062

Constant 1.204***(0.161)

Observations 9,529 2,911 275,999 10,346R-squared 0.094

Mean Comparison

Note: Stars next to mean comparison refer to significance of coefficient on 1860 characteristic in a univariate regression of union status on that characteristic. For county-level characteristics, standard errors are clustered at county level. Regression in final column also clusters standard errors by county.

25

Page 26: Migration in Response to Civil Conflict: Evidence from the Border of ...

Table 5: Summary Statistics of Linked 1860-1880 Census Data

Union Confederate Union Confederate1880 Characteristics

Age 42.136 41.951 2,743 810Married 0.886 0.864 * 2,743 810# Children in household 3.490 3.207 *** 2,743 810Lives in Kentucky 0.697 0.719 2,743 810Lives elsewhere in south 0.061 0.093 *** 2,743 810Lives in northeast 0.022 0.010 ** 2,743 810Lives in midwest 0.210 0.157 *** 2,743 810Lives in west 0.010 0.021 ** 2,743 810White collar 0.081 0.121 *** 2,743 810Semi-skilled 0.109 0.100 2,743 810Farmer 0.647 0.654 2,743 810Laborer 0.137 0.096 *** 2,743 810No occupation 0.026 0.028 2,743 810

1860 CharacteristicsFamily wealth ($1000) 2.109 6.074 *** 2,716 798Household head 0.309 0.279 2,743 810Married 0.320 0.289 * 2,743 810Literate 0.901 0.935 *** 2,726 797Parent white collar 0.049 0.088 *** 1,260 397Parent semil-skilled 0.091 0.078 1,260 397Parent farmer 0.710 0.733 1,260 397Parent laborer 0.052 0.040 1,260 397Parent no occupation 0.098 0.060 ** 1,260 397White collar 0.045 0.068 * 1,483 413Semi-skilled 0.117 0.092 1,483 413Farmer 0.409 0.448 1,483 413Laborer 0.251 0.225 1,483 413No occupation 0.179 0.167 1,483 413

Mean Sample size

26

Page 27: Migration in Response to Civil Conflict: Evidence from the Border of ...

Table 6: Determinants of Migration between 1860 and 1880

(1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6) (7) (8)Dependent variable

Union 0.005 0.014 0.023 -0.011 -0.005 -0.005 0.013 -0.007(0.020) (0.021) (0.026) (0.021) (0.017) (0.018) (0.023) (0.019)

Log family wealth, 1860 -0.054*** -0.048*** -0.003 -0.012(0.013) (0.010) (0.012) (0.009)

Literate, 1860 0.024 -0.003 0.029 0.023(0.033) (0.031) (0.029) (0.028)

Log occupational score, 1860 0.096*** 0.057**(0.029) (0.026)

White collar, 1860 0.077 0.070(0.047) (0.043)

Semi skilled, 1860 0.114*** 0.033(0.040) (0.036)

Farmer, 1860 0.002 -0.002(0.026) (0.023)

Unskilled blue collar, 1860 0.042 0.061(0.068) (0.061)

No occupation, 1860 0.040 0.055**(0.029) (0.026)

Age & Birthplace FE's Y Y Y Y Y Y Y Y1860 county FE's N Y Y Y N Y Y Y

Observations 3,693 3,693 2,415 3,513 3,693 3,693 2,415 3,513R-squared 0.043 0.100 0.158 0.137 0.102 0.152 0.205 0.161

Moved counties between 1860 & 1880 Moved states between 1860 & 1880

Table 7: Impact of County Characteristics on Migration Propensity

(1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6)Dependent variable:Social indicator

Union -0.089* -0.079* -0.091* -0.031 -0.028 -0.071**(0.046) (0.047) (0.047) (0.036) (0.036) (0.036)

Union X Social indicator, 1860 0.247** 0.226** 0.186* 0.249 0.242 0.347**(0.098) (0.098) (0.100) (0.160) (0.160) (0.166)

White collar, 1860 0.039 0.153*(0.094) (0.079)

Semi skilled, 1860 0.146* 0.170**(0.082) (0.067)

Farmer, 1860 -0.022 0.049(0.053) (0.039)

Unskilled blue collar, 1860 -0.090 0.080(0.131) (0.116)

No occupation, 1860 0.048 0.079*(0.050) (0.041)

White collar X Social indicator, 1860 0.114 -0.405(0.242) (0.354)

Semi skilled X Social indicator, 1860 -0.057 -0.181(0.231) (0.300)

Farmer X Social indicator, 1860 0.108 -0.166(0.114) (0.198)

Unskilled blue collar X Social indicator, 1860 0.450 -0.195(0.357) (0.560)

No occupation X Social indicator, 1860 0.048 -0.048(0.108) (0.192)

Log family wealth, 1860 -0.039* -0.079***(0.022) (0.018)

Log family wealth X Social indicator, 1860 -0.031 0.142**(0.052) (0.070)

Observations 3,693 3,693 3,514 3,693 3,693 3,514R-squared 0.102 0.108 0.134 0.101 0.107 0.135

1860 Douglas vote share 1860 % enslavedMoved counties, 1860-80

27

Page 28: Migration in Response to Civil Conflict: Evidence from the Border of ...

Table 8: Locational Choices of Interstate Migrants

(1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6) (7) (8)Dependent variable:

Union -0.098*** -0.027 -0.004 -0.024 0.148*** 0.103*** -0.048*** -0.054***(0.034) (0.029) (0.018) (0.017) (0.039) (0.037) (0.018) (0.017)

Family wealth, 1860 0.005 0.027 -0.052 -0.072** -0.044 -0.065 0.089*** 0.110***(0.065) (0.054) (0.034) (0.033) (0.073) (0.071) (0.033) (0.033)

Literate, 1860 -0.001 0.006 -0.030 -0.033 0.045 0.038 -0.012 -0.010(0.057) (0.048) (0.030) (0.029) (0.065) (0.062) (0.030) (0.029)

White collar, 1860 -0.031 -0.025 0.002 0.003 0.035 0.029 -0.010 -0.011(0.041) (0.034) (0.021) (0.020) (0.046) (0.044) (0.021) (0.021)

Semi-skilled, 1860 0.093 0.089 0.087* 0.090** -0.176* -0.174* -0.003 -0.006(0.085) (0.071) (0.045) (0.042) (0.097) (0.092) (0.044) (0.043)

Farmer, 1860 -0.058 -0.024 -0.011 -0.017 0.060 0.037 0.006 0.002(0.045) (0.038) (0.023) (0.023) (0.051) (0.049) (0.023) (0.023)

Unskilled blue collar, 1860 -0.001 0.004 0.001 -0.002 -0.009 -0.012 0.007 0.008(0.016) (0.013) (0.008) (0.008) (0.018) (0.017) (0.008) (0.008)

No occupation, 1860 0.017 -0.008 -0.064** -0.057** 0.077 0.092 -0.031 -0.029(0.054) (0.045) (0.028) (0.027) (0.061) (0.058) (0.028) (0.027)

County log farm value per acre, 1880 -0.255*** 0.081*** 0.163*** 0.005(0.014) (0.008) (0.018) (0.009)

County % farms owned, 1880 -1.408*** 0.187*** 0.833*** 0.381***(0.099) (0.059) (0.128) (0.060)

Observations 1,053 1,050 1,053 1,050 1,053 1,050 1,053 1,050R-squared 0.287 0.508 0.425 0.481 0.276 0.344 0.147 0.188

Migrated to:

Note: All regressions contain age, birthplace and 1860 county fixed effects. Sample consists of interstate migrants.

South Northeast Midwest West

Table 9: Locational Choices of Intrastate Migrants

(1) (2) (3) (4)

Dependent variable:

Union -0.044** -0.036* -0.023** -0.020*(0.018) (0.019) (0.011) (0.011)

Family wealth, 1860 0.055** -0.001(0.025) (0.016)

Literate, 1860 0.009 0.016***(0.010) (0.006)

White collar, 1860 -0.043 0.010(0.055) (0.035)

Semi-skilled, 1860 -0.073** -0.014(0.032) (0.022)

Farmer, 1860 -0.006 0.003(0.021) (0.014)

Unskilled blue collar, 1860 0.021 -0.007(0.053) (0.040)

No occupation, 1860 0.007 0.014(0.023) (0.015)

Observations 787 727 787 727R-squared 0.432 0.453 0.418 0.446

1860 vote share to Douglas in 1880 county of residence

1860 % enslaved in 1880 county of residence

Note: All regressions contain age, birthplace, and 1860 county fixed effects. Sample consists of internal migrants in Kentucky

28

Page 29: Migration in Response to Civil Conflict: Evidence from the Border of ...

Table 10: Selection of Union and Confederate Migrants

(1) (2) (3) (4)Dependent variable:Sample: Union Confederate p (u=c) Union Confederate p (u=c)

Family wealth 1860 -0.039** -0.060*** 0.472 -0.047*** -0.041** 0.772(0.018) (0.023) (0.013) (0.018)

Literate 1860 0.010 -0.000 0.920 -0.010 -0.031 0.817(0.036) (0.091) (0.034) (0.081)

Log occupational score 1860 0.093*** 0.055 0.611(0.034) (0.064)

White collar, 1860 0.124** -0.102 0.048(0.058) (0.097)

Semi skilled, 1860 0.121*** 0.023 0.379(0.045) (0.101)

Farmer, 1860 0.014 -0.047 0.338(0.030) (0.056)

Unskilled blue collar, 1860 0.019 0.174 0.407(0.076) (0.168)

No occupation, 1860 0.027 0.035 0.917(0.033) (0.064)

Observations 1,862 553 2,716 797R-squared 0.172 0.370 0.147 0.302

Moved counties, 1860-1880

Note: All regressions contain birthplace and 1860 county fixed effects.

29

Page 30: Migration in Response to Civil Conflict: Evidence from the Border of ...

Table 11: Evidence of Di↵erential Migrant Selection by County

(1) (2) (3) (4)Dependent variableSample Union Confederate p(u=c) Union Confederate p(u=c)

Log occupation score, 1860 X Douglas vote share, 1860 0.178 -0.609** 0.029(0.175) (0.309)

Log family wealth, 1860 X Douglas vote share, 1860 0.144 -0.046 0.206(0.094) (0.115)

Moved counties X Douglas vote share, 1860 0.245*** -0.133 0.055(0.089) (0.183)

Moved counties 0.037** -0.005 0.347(0.018) (0.042)

Log occupational score, 1860 0.095*** 0.087 0.913 0.287*** 0.389*** 0.06(0.035) (0.066) (0.025) (0.050)

Log family wealth, 1860 -0.037** -0.055** 0.532 0.038*** 0.018 0.352(0.018) (0.023) (0.013) (0.018)

Observations 1,862 553 1,816 539R-squared 0.173 0.376 0.262 0.454

Log occupation score, 1860 X % Slave, 1860 -0.339 0.191 0.686(0.275) (0.465)

Log family wealth, 1860 X % Slave, 1860 0.292** 0.022 0.196(0.127) (0.164)

Moved counties X % Slave, 1860 -0.310** 0.230 0.077(0.154) (0.275)

Moved counties 0.028 -0.024 0.216(0.018) (0.040)

Log occupational score, 1860 0.098*** 0.045 0.498 0.288*** 0.391*** 0.057(0.034) (0.069) (0.025) (0.050)

Log family wealth, 1860 -0.049*** -0.062** 0.711 0.040*** 0.018 0.317(0.018) (0.028) (0.013) (0.018)

Observations 1,862 553 1,816 539R-squared 0.175 0.370 0.260 0.454

Migrated counties Log occupational score, 1880

30

Page 31: Migration in Response to Civil Conflict: Evidence from the Border of ...

Table 12: Migration Behavior of Brothers of Civil War Recruits

(1) (2) (3) (4)

Dependent variableDouglas vote

share % Slave

Union brother 0.034 0.025 -0.044* 0.014(0.028) (0.028) (0.025) (0.014)

Union brother X Douglas vote share, 1860 -0.044(0.124)

Union brother X % Slave, 1860 0.345(0.222)

Observations 2,195 2,195 524 518R-squared 0.140 0.141 0.366 0.415

Dependent variableSample Union Confederate p(u=c) Union Confederate p(u=c)

Moved counties 0.032 0.035 0.948 0.025 0.039 0.791(0.021) (0.052) (0.021) (0.049)

Moved counties X Douglas vote share, 1860 0.210** 0.064 0.146(0.101) (0.207)

Moved counties X % Slave, 1860 -0.194 0.138 0.438(0.192) (0.398)

Observations 1,613 416 1,613 416R-squared 0.245 0.371 0.244 0.371

Moved counties

Note: Sample includes younger brothers (ages 0-9 in 1860) of Union and Veteran recruits

Destination county:

Log occupational score, 1880

31

Page 32: Migration in Response to Civil Conflict: Evidence from the Border of ...

Figure 1: Changes in Distribution of Southern Born, 1850-1890

−2−1

01

2Pe

rcen

tage

poi

nts

1860 1870 1880 1890Year

Living in Northeast Living in MidwestLiving in South Living in West

Change in % of Southern Born MenFrom Last Census Year

®

Source: Haines & ICPSR (2010).

32

Page 33: Migration in Response to Civil Conflict: Evidence from the Border of ...

Figure 2: Geographic Distribution of Union and Confederate Soldiers, 1860

33

Page 34: Migration in Response to Civil Conflict: Evidence from the Border of ...

Figure 3: Age Distribution of Union and Confederate Soldiers, 1860

0.0

2.0

4.0

6.0

8D

ensi

ty

10 20 30 40 50Age

Union Confederate

Age Distribution of Union and Confederate Recruits, 1860

®

34

Page 35: Migration in Response to Civil Conflict: Evidence from the Border of ...

Figure 4: Distribution of Migrant Union and Confederate Veterans, 1880

35