LernerTirole standars SCIENCE.pdf

download LernerTirole standars SCIENCE.pdf

of 2

Transcript of LernerTirole standars SCIENCE.pdf

  • 8/10/2019 LernerTirole standars SCIENCE.pdf

    1/228 FEBRUARY 2014 VOL 343 SCIENCE www.sciencemag.org972

    POLICYFORUM

    Technological standards are ubiqui-

    tous, whether they allow consumers to

    communicate seamlessly across wire-

    less networks or manufacturers to procure

    goods across complex global supply chains.

    These standardsshaped by standard-setting

    organizations (SSOs) and participating engi-

    neers, academics, lawyers, and executives

    in turn shape how new technologies evolve,

    specifying rules for how standard-compliant

    products must work and interact with other

    components. This standardization process is

    under tremendous stress. Many disputes roil-

    ing courts and administrative bodies around

    the worldsuch as those involving Apple,

    Google, Microsoft, and Samsungconcerncommitments made during the standardiza-

    tion process and the ways that firms have

    sought to game the system. We explore why

    the system is breaking down and propose a

    way in which standard setting could be rede-

    signed to address these problems.

    Standardization assures users that they

    will not be stuck with an orphan technology

    largely incompatible with other systems and

    used by few others. Instead, users will benefit

    from network externalities, where the tech-

    nologys value depends on the number of oth-

    ers using the technology. This boosts demandfor new technology, which provides research-

    ers with incentives to innovate.

    Standard-setting organizations play three

    roles in this process. First, engineers iden-

    tify alternative avenues to solve a given tech-

    nological challenge. Second, in cases where

    there are conflicting technologies where none

    is evidently superior, the SSO will frequently

    coordinate on one approach. This winnowing

    down of alternatives is important because it

    greatly simplifies the choices of manufactur-

    ers and consumers.

    Finally, because stakes are high for firms

    participating in the standardization process,SSOs seek to regulate the behavior of mem-

    bers. Particular concerns are ensuring that

    firms disclose relevant patents, so as to pro-

    vide adequate information to other parties in

    the standard-setting process, and agree not to

    price licenses to their patents too aggressively,

    so as to enable broader

    adoption of the technol-

    ogy. But SSOs are limited in

    this regulatory role, because

    technology owners can seek

    another SSO if rules are too

    onerous.

    The intellectual property

    (IP) embodied in standards

    has two essential charac-

    teristics, which can lead to

    unfortunate outcomes. First,

    in many cases, new tech-

    nologies tend to be covered

    by a wide array of patents

    issued to the different firmsthat contribute components

    to the technology. In this

    patent thicket, if each pat-

    ent owner sets the revenue-

    maximizing price for its pat-

    ent licenses without considering the fact that

    other patent owners benefit from wider diffu-

    sion, the resulting price is likely to be far too

    high. Economists term this royalty stack-

    ing.

    Second, in many cases, there are multiple

    routes to solving a given technological prob-

    lem. Each one of these may be equally viable,but often an SSO will choose only one avenue.

    After the decision is made, however, any pat-

    ent needed to practice the standard becomes

    a standard-essential patent (SEP), and the

    patent owner can ask for a high royalty even

    when other patents could have offered compa-

    rable value, had the technology been morphed

    differently. SSOs must therefore regulate

    licensing of the patents chosen to be part of

    the standard. SSOs typically eschew any dis-

    cussion of price before the establishment of

    the standard. This reluctance largely reflects

    fear of antitrust authorities: Any price discus-

    sions might lead to charges of collusive andanticompetitive behavior, as the SSO could

    blackmail patentees to accept low prices in

    exchange for inclusion into the standard.

    To restrain firms from taking advan-

    tage of the essentiality of their patents that

    was acquired only from being included in a

    standard, SSOs commonly require firms to

    commit in advance to license their patents

    on fair, reasonable, and nondiscriminatory

    (FRAND) terms. But FRAND commitments

    are ambiguous; what exactly is fair and rea-

    sonable? This is determi

    not by the SSO itself, bu

    a court years after the st

    dard is established. Perc

    tions of patent value can

    fer widely when one lo

    before or after the dispu

    Ambiguities associated w

    FRAND commitments h

    resulted in dozens of exp

    sive litigations (1, 2).

    Even in the absence o

    legal dispute, the FRAN

    requirement has not wor

    well. Consider the

    uncommon case where pticipants in an SSO est

    lish a patent pool to join

    license key patents cove

    by the standard. Many po

    simply divide royalties

    proportion to the number of patents that e

    firm has contributed to the pool. Such

    rules may reflect that patents initially

    ferent in their importance are made equa

    essential by standardization. The process t

    over-rewards minor innovations at the expe

    of major ones. In these settings, selection

    patents for the standard (and pool) canhighly contentious. SSOs may include eit

    too many or too few patents in the standar

    Structured Price Commitments

    We propose an alternative approach, wh

    we term structured price commitments.

    suggest that SSOs follow this sequence:

    1. During a discovery phase, part

    explore which technology combinations

    technically viable (as is done now by SSO

    This engineering phase makes no refere

    to prices at which patents would be licens

    2. Before the standard is finalized (a

    unlike todays practice), there is a receduring which firms commit to a price

    at which they will grant nondiscriminat

    licenses to their patents. Firms make co

    mitments to the maximum price (and m

    restrictive terms) that they would cha

    before the patent is included in the standa

    3. Participants choose the standard, w

    out discussing prices, as is currently done

    4. Finally, some or all of the participa

    may form a patent pool after the standar

    set, again following todays practice.

    A Better Route to Tech Standards

    INTELLECTUAL PROPERTY

    Josh Lerner1* and Jean Tirole2

    Prestandard price commitments, as well as

    government intervention, may help patent

    licensing and standard setting.

    1Harvard Business School, Boston, MA 02163, USA. 2Tou-

    louse School of Economics and Institute for Advanced Studyin Toulouse, 31000 Toulouse, France. *Author for corre-

    spondence. [email protected]

    Published by AAAS

    http://www.sciencemag.org/http://www.sciencemag.org/
  • 8/10/2019 LernerTirole standars SCIENCE.pdf

    2/2www.sciencemag.org SCIENCE VOL 343 28 FEBRUARY 2014

    POLICYFORU

    Our theoretical analysis (3) looks at conse-

    quences of this modified standard-setting pro-

    cess. Initially, it might be thought that this pro-

    cess, too, might lead to a variety of opportu-

    nistic behaviors. For instance, a patent-holder

    might set a high price cap in order to achieve

    a stronger bargaining stance when it comes todividing profits from the eventual patent pool

    formed around the standard. Such behavior

    might lead to excessively high licensing rates

    and too little technology adoption. Despite

    the possibility of such gaming, our analy-

    sis shows that structured price commitments

    achieve the desired competitive bench-

    mark, with license prices the same as would

    prevail if there were no network externali-

    ties and, thus, no need for a standard, which

    would free users to adopt whatever mixture of

    technology they wished. This provides a rea-

    sonable balance between incentives for tech-nology innovation and diffusion.

    How can price caps selected before stan-

    dard-setting work? Intuitively, when patents

    are fairly interchangeable with each other

    before selection of the standard, the require-

    ment to commit to a cap forces patent own-

    ers to choose a lower price than they would

    afterwards, so as to get their patent included

    in the standard. Otherwise, the SSO would

    choose a more affordable option. And when

    patents are complementary rather than inter-

    changeable, setting ones price away from its

    competitive level leads to a loss of profit: For

    instance, if a patent owner opts for a low pricecap, other owners will be less willing to give

    him or her a large share of the proceeds of any

    patent pool that may form.

    Such commitments lower the amount that

    ultimately will need to be paid to license the

    key patents to implement the standard, and

    also better match the rewards to innovations

    (royalties) with their contributions.

    We do not suggest abandoning FRAND.

    SSOs may make mistakes, and important

    patents may escape attention at the time the

    standard is promulgated. However vague and

    limited, FRAND still imposes some ex post

    constraints on licensing terms. Thus, we view

    structured price commitments as a comple-

    ment, not a substitute, to FRAND.

    Can Regulation Work?The idea that patent owners might commit

    to prices before standard-setting is not new;

    both academics and policy-makers [e.g., (4)]

    have mentioned that possibility. Furthermore,

    this policy has been tested by some SSOs (see

    text box). Yet there has been little adoption by

    SSOs in general.

    One issue is that economists had no

    framework for thinking about price commit-

    ments. There was no way to predict, even at a

    theoretical level, what would happen if such

    commitments were mandated. The theoreti-

    cal analysis comforts us about the normativeimpact of commitments (should we expect

    a good outcome from this new institution?).

    But thus far, it does not explain why SSOs

    which, rightly or wrongly, tried them, failed

    to appeal to IP owners and set a new stan-

    dard for the standard-setting process.

    Consistent with historical examples, our

    model highlights that patent owners prefer

    to go to an SSO that does not constrain their

    freedom to license patents as they see fit.

    Competition between SSOs, which we term

    forum shopping, allows IP owners to find

    more complacent SSOs that do not put such

    pressure on their prices. Owners of equallyimportant, standard-relevant patents will

    always opt for a lenient (commitment-free)

    SSO. Only in specific circumstances will pat-

    ent owners be attracted by such requirements,

    e.g., when owners of clearly essential patents

    fear that an SSO will include a number of

    more minor patents, with whose owners they

    will have to share the pie equally.

    The corollary is that without a govern-

    ment mandate and/or purchasing prefer-

    ences, SSOs are unlikely to opt for the right

    answer and demand price commitments

    Nevertheless, the suggestion that price com

    mitments be mandated has problems: I

    could be infeasible or, if feasible, the regula

    tion might do more harm than good.

    Concerning feasibility, the rule can be

    implemented where public procuremen

    is sizable, such as telecommunications. I

    would suffice to require suppliers to con

    form to compliant standards enacted

    by SSOs requir ing price commitments

    Furthermore, antitrust authorities and courts

    already involved in regulating standard

    setting through reviews and litigation, could

    favor compliant standards and discourage

    noncompliant ones.

    As for unintended consequences of reg

    ulation, the requirement is simply to com

    mit to a price cap. If practice does not work

    according to theory (only experimentation

    can tell), the hazard is that IP owners will se

    too high a cap. But it cannot be worse than

    the current policy, which is formally an infinite price cap. The combination of a cap with

    FRAND cannot be worse than only FRAND

    So this is rather low-risk.

    In recent years, antitrust authoritie

    have wakened to the importance of stan

    dardization and the way in which firms can

    manipulate this process (5). Now, the chal

    lenge is to create rules that will ensure tha

    standards can effectively promote transla

    tion of scientific and technological insight

    into new products and economic growth

    Requiring price commitments is theoreti

    cally appealing, rather risk-free, and worthexperimenting with.

    References and Notes 1. Lemley and Shapiro (2) suggest that these disputes be

    settled via arbitration, making adjudication more expedi

    ent, better informed, and overall more consistent. 2. M. A. Lemley, C. Shapiro, Berkeley Technol. Law J.28,

    1135 (2013). 3. J. Lerner, J. Tirole, Standard-essential patents (Work-

    ing paper no. 19664, National Bureau of EconomicResearch, Cambridge, MA, 2013).

    4. D. P. Majoras, Recognizing the procompetitive potentia

    of royalty discussions in standard setting, Standardiza-tion and the Law, Stanford University, 23 September

    2005; www.ftc.gov/sites/default/files/documents/public_statements/recognizing-procompetitive-potentia

    royalty-discussions-standard-setting/050923stanford.pdf.

    5. National Academy of Sciences,Patent Challenges for

    Standard-Setting in the Global Economy: Lessons From

    Information and Communications Technology(National

    Academy Press, Washington, DC, 2013). 6. T.O. Barnett, Business Review Letter: VITA, Antitrust

    Division, U.S. Department of Justice, 30 October 2006. 7. J. L. Contreras,Jurimetrics53, 163 (2013).

    Acknowledgment:J.T. is a member of Industrial EconomicsInstitute, which receives funds from Microsoft, Orange, andQualcomm.

    The international trade association VITA, which develops standards that govern modular embeddedcomputer systems in such products as advanced avionics devices and complex medical instruments,became frustrated when owners of patents that were essential to implementing one of their new standardsdemanded a higher royalty rate than anticipated after being deemed standard-essential. As a result, VITAproposed a new policy, which the U.S. Department of Justices Antitrust Division approved in October2006 (6). VITA demanded that members declare the highest royalty rates and most restrictive terms underwhich they would license these patents for implementation of the given standard. In response to thiscontroversial policy, Motorola launched a campaign to decertify VITA as an SSO recognized by the

    American National Standards Institute, an effort that ultimately proved unsuccessful. Although VITA endedup moving forward with its standardization process, it was not a spectacular success (7). Similarly, theInstitute of Electrical and Electronics Engineers and the European Telecommunications Standards Instituteencountered stiff resistance and, in the end, had to make price commitments optional. Even if pricecommitment requirements lead to a good outcome, we cannot expect SSOs to mandate them bythemselves or expect patent holders to cooperate with standard bodies that mandate such commitments.

    10.1126/science.124643PHOTOCREDIT:HARLANDQUARRINGTON/WIKIMEDIACOMMONS

    Published by AAAS