Lemons Market

download Lemons Market

of 63

Transcript of Lemons Market

  • 7/30/2019 Lemons Market

    1/63

    2005, Southwestern

    Slides by Pamela L. Hall

    Western Washington University

    AsymmetricInformation

    Chapter 23

  • 7/30/2019 Lemons Market

    2/63

    2

    Introduction

    Managers (insiders) of firms can increase their profit by taking actionsbased on insider information (information that is not available to public)

    If insiders obtain positive (negative) information about a company, theybuy (sell) the companys stock with expectation that stocks price will rise

    (fall) when positive (negative) information is publicly announced

    Such insider trading of securities is illegal However, incorporating information not known by all agents in market pricing is

    generally legal

    When selling a commodity, agents are not legally required to provide fulldisclosure of information on a commodity

    Previously, we generally implicitly assumed or explicitly stated symmetryin market information as a characteristic of market structure

    Assumed all agents had costless access to this information

    Symmetry existed with both buyers and sellers having the same marketinformation

    For example, one of the explicit characteristics of perfect competition is agents perfect

    knowledge

  • 7/30/2019 Lemons Market

    3/63

    3

    Introduction

    In general, market information is costly, and this cost may vary betweenbuyers and sellers

    Resulting in asymmetric information held by agents

    One set of agents may be more knowledgeable about a commodity than anotherset

    Information cost may vary among agents as a result of differences ineducation and experience about commodity

    Examples include A firm possessing limited information about a potential workers abilities

    A used car buyer not having complete repair and maintenance history on an auto

    An insurance company not knowing risky behavior of a potential insurer

    When commodities are homogeneous and their characteristics arereadily available

    Cost of determining these characteristics is small

    Assumption of market symmetry would generally hold

    For example, symmetric information generally holds for commodity futures market

    Where, except for delivery dates, all futures contracts on same commodity haveidentical characteristics

  • 7/30/2019 Lemons Market

    4/63

    4

    Introduction

    In contrast, asymmetric information will generallyexist for heterogeneous commodities withcharacteristics that are costly to determine

    An example is the vehicle market Condition of a vehicle is difficult to determine without costly

    testing

    Heterogeneous nature of used vehicles prevents a generaldetermination of a vehicles condition based on examination of other

    like vehicles

    A major consequence of asymmetric information ispossible disappearance of markets

    Which result in an inefficient allocation of resources

  • 7/30/2019 Lemons Market

    5/63

    5

    Introduction

    Aim in this chapter is to demonstrate how missing marketsand associated efficiency losses result in presence ofasymmetric information Asymmetry in information generates two types of outcomes

    Adverse selection

    Where one agents decision depends on unobservable characteristics that

    adversely affect other agents

    Use used-automobile market to illustrate missing market and resultingmarket inefficiencies

    We discuss mechanisms of signaling and screening as second-best Pareto-efficient mechanisms for addressing these inefficiencies

    Moral hazard A contract is signed among agents with one agent being dependent on

    unobservable actions of other agents

    Using a principal-agent model, we derive inefficient level of precaution takenby agents

    Evaluate mechanisms (such as coinsurance) designed to addressinefficiencies

  • 7/30/2019 Lemons Market

    6/63

    6

    Introduction

    Asymmetric information is relatively new area for applied economic analysis In 1970 George A. Akerlof was first to address problems and solutions associated with adverse

    selection

    Knowledge of moral hazard has been around since advent of insurance in 18th century

    However, only recently have applied economists investigated ramifications of moral hazardon economic efficiency

    Asymmetric information in a market can result in market inefficiencies If information concerning characteristics of a commodity is not freely available, inefficient

    allocations may result

    One type of asymmetric information is called adverse selection (also called hiddeninformation)

    An informed agents decision depends on unobservable characteristics that adversely affect

    uninformed agents

    Classic example is market for used cars

    Assume used cars can be grouped by quality into two groups

    Within each group, used cars are homogeneous and are associated with a single price

    Comparing vehicles between groups, they are heterogeneous in quality and thus are not valued by identicalprices

    In a free (symmetric) information case, two heterogeneous groups of commodities (used cars) would haveseparate markets with associated prices p1 and p2

  • 7/30/2019 Lemons Market

    7/637

    Lemons Market

    Generally, sellers of a used car know vehicles history Can determine its market price at zero or very minimal cost

    In contrast, buyers do not have this knowledge

    Cost of determining information for each group of used cars is prohibitive

    Without information, buyers may base their market price determination on

    average quality of used cars available Asymmetry in information results in buyers only willing to pay up to

    average price of used cars available, p At average price sellers would be willing to supply only

    QS = qj(pj)

    pj p

    qj(pj) is supply of used cars in group j

    Above-average used cars, associated with pj > p, will not be offered for sale

    Sellers would be unwilling to supply their cars for less than vehicles market value

  • 7/30/2019 Lemons Market

    8/638

    Lemons Market

    Buyers realize above-average used cars will not enter market at average price So average quality of used cars offered in market is less than average quality of used

    cars available

    They will adjust downward their willingness-to-pay for used cars offered in themarket

    Only sellers who value their cars below this new lower price will supply vehicles

    Average quality of used cars offered in market will once again decline

    Ttonnement process will continue until only lowest-quality group of used carsare offered and sold in market

    When only lowest-quality group is offered for sale, any asymmetry in informationvanishes

    With symmetric information, buyers and sellers expected prices match and onlya market for lowest-quality group exists

    Missing markets for other groups of used cars represent market failure

    These lowest-quality cars are popularly referred to as lemons

    Market failure associated with adverse selection is called the lemons problem

  • 7/30/2019 Lemons Market

    9/639

    Lemons Market

    In Figure 23.1, lemons problem is illustrated for two quality groups ofused vehicles, reliable cars, , and lemons,

    Curves S and S are supply curves for lemons and reliable cars,respectively

    Supply curve for reliable cars is above lemons curve

    Indicates sellers of reliable cars are only willing to supply these higher-valuedvehicles at prices above the lemon

    Demand curves for lemons and reliable cars are represented by D and D,respectively

    Buyers are willing to pay a higher price for reliable compared with lemons So reliables demand curve is above lemons demand curve

    Given free information, market is able to discriminate between these twotypes of cars

    So market-clearing prices exist for both reliables and lemons markets Equilibrium price and quality for reliables are p and

    * and for lemons p and *

  • 7/30/2019 Lemons Market

    10/6310

    Figure 23.1 Lemons problem

  • 7/30/2019 Lemons Market

    11/6311

    Lemons Market

    Asymmetric information in form of adverse selectionprevents buyers from freely distinguishing reliable cars fromlemons Buyers may know proportion of automobiles that are reliable and

    lemons

    But are unable to distinguish quality of a given automobile

    Overall market demand, QD, facing sellers will be horizontalsum of lemons and reliables demand curves

    Total supply of cars, QS, is horizontal sum of lemons and

    reliables supply curves Resulting equilibrium price and quantity are p' and Q'

    Loss in ability of market to distinguish between reliables and lemons Results in number of lemons offered on market increasing from * to S

    ' andnumber of reliables declining from * to S

    '

  • 7/30/2019 Lemons Market

    12/6312

    Lemons Market

    Demand for lemons decreases from * to D' and demand for reliablesincreases from * to D'

    Imbalance within markets will result in some buyers who expect toreceive a reliable car instead receiving a lemon

    As buyers realize ratio of reliables to lemons is declining in market, they will

    adjust their expected quality downward Participation in number of buyers wanting a reliable car will decline as

    expectation of obtaining a reliable car in market decreases

    Resulting downward shift in demand curve further drives reliable cars out ofmarket

    Further erodes demand for reliable cars

    Ttonnement process will continue until buyers only expect lemons to besupplied, so their market demand curve is D

    Such a market will then supply * automobiles at a price of p*, and amissing market will exist for reliable cars

    Market is unable to allocate both supply of reliables and lemons efficiently to

    buyers It is unable to price discriminate across quality differences

  • 7/30/2019 Lemons Market

    13/6313

    Lemons Market

    An efficient allocation would result in quality discrimination Buyers would have market choice of purchasing either reliable cars or lemons

    Without market ability to quality discriminate, some buyers may by chance purchase a reliablecar

    But these may not be buyers with highest willingness-to-pay

    Failure of market to allocate commodities based on willingness-to-pay results in an inefficient allocation

    Cause of this missing market and inefficient allocation of resources is an externality betweensellers of reliable cars and lemons

    As illustrated in Figure 23.1, as number of sellers offering lemons increases

    Buyers expectations regarding quality of vehicles in market is affected

    Price buyers are willing to pay declines Adversely affects sellers of reliable cars by preventing them from selling their vehicles and improving efficiency

    Externality between sellers for reliable cars and lemons has distributional implications

    Owners of lemons may receive more than their automobile is worth and owners of reliable cars less

    Buyers possessing limited information generally benefit sellers of lemon products

  • 7/30/2019 Lemons Market

    14/6314

    Lemons Market

    Problem of adverse selection exists in other markets For example, in insurance market buyers of insurance know more about

    their general health than any insurance company

    Unhealthy consumers are more likely to buy insurance Because healthy consumers will find cost of insurance too high

    Ttonnement process will continue until only unhealthy consumers purchase insurance

    Will make selling insurance unprofitable

    Another example is labor market

    Workers potential productivity is unobservable by a hiring firm

    But workers themselves know their productive capabilities Ttonnement process will result in only less-productive workers being hired

    Market failure resulting from adverse selection explains Why a new automobile declines in value once it is driven off lot

    Why insurance is so high for a previously uninsured driver or a person withno medical history

    Why salaries start low with a potential for frequent raises once a person is

    hired

  • 7/30/2019 Lemons Market

    15/6315

    Second-Best Mechanism Designs

    U.S. health care costs are nearly double that of other nations andoutpace inflation

    Firms and workers are faced with rising premiums and cutbacks in coverage

    A national health insurance program can avoid inefficiencies of adverseselection in health care

    By making purchase of insurance compulsory Unhealthy citizens benefit from insurance premiums below their expected health

    costs

    Healthy citizens can purchase insurance at lower rates Such a government policy is called cross-subsidization

    Healthy consumers pay a portion of health care for unhealthy consumers

    One justification in favor of Medicare for elderly By providing insurance for all elderly, adverse selection is eliminated

    However, without knowing agents private information, obtaining Pareto-optimalallocation is not possible

    Acquiring such information is costly

    So only a constrained or second-best Pareto optimum can be obtained

  • 7/30/2019 Lemons Market

    16/6316

    Second-Best Mechanism Designs

    In general, insurance companies can avoid adverse selection by offeringgroup health insurance plans at places of employment

    Called poolingboth healthy and unhealthy consumers are pooled together

    Insurance premiums are based on average cost of health care Adverse selection is eliminated by requiring all employees to participate

    Government agencies can improve functioning of markets by providingfree information or requiring product information prior to sale

    Many government agencies currently provide information useful for makingmarket decisions

    Examples include U.S. State Department cautioning tourists about visiting aparticular region, USDA publishing situations and outlooks for agricultural

    commodities

    An example of requiring product information is FDAs requirement for

    food labeling on processed foods

  • 7/30/2019 Lemons Market

    17/6317

    Signaling Both buyers and sellers can potentially benefit from creating markets

    that were missing due to adverse selection

    Provides incentives for developing market mechanisms to mitigatemarket failure associated with adverse selection

    Signaling

    Mechanisms that transfer information from informed agent to uninformedagent

    Naive signal on part of a buyer

    Asking sellers quality of a commodityfor example, asking a used cardealer condition of a car

    Cost of such a signal could be high if signal is inaccurate and commodity ispurchased

    An example of a particularly weak signal

    Where cost of providing a signal is the same for all sellers regardless of quality oftheir product

    Appearance can be another weak signal

  • 7/30/2019 Lemons Market

    18/6318

    Signaling For a strong signal, a signal must have an associated lower cost for

    sellers offering relatively high-quality commodities

    Compared with cost for sellers offering poor-quality commodities

    Examples of strong signals used by firms are reputation and standardization Firms offering higher-quality commodities have an advantage over other firms in

    establishing a reputation for quality

    For example, construction subcontractors can provide a signal for qualityconstruction by developing a list of satisfied customers

    One problem with reputation as a signaling device

    Delay associated with establishing a reputation

    Problem may be partially avoided By supplementing reputation with guarantees and warranties as explicit signals of

    product quality

    For example, in 1980s, as a counter to Japanese auto manufacturers reputation

    for producing quality cars

    U.S. manufacturers offered extended 100,000-mile warranties as a signal ofimproved quality

  • 7/30/2019 Lemons Market

    19/63

    19

    Signaling Such signals are useful in cases where buyers lack information on

    quality of some commodity that they do not purchase on a regular basis

    For regularly purchased commodities that vary in quality

    Firms will attempt to standardize commodities they are offering to signal quality For example, a fruit and vegetable wholesaler will attempt to always offer same quality

    of produce

    Through standardization, sellers send a strong signal that buyers canexpect a quality product from them

    Some firms advertise such standardization as a market signal

    In general, a signaling mechanism will be employed by informed agents

    Agents are not always the seller

    Agent could be an antique dealer purchasing items for his shop Through experience, dealer will have a greater knowledge about market than sellers

    A reputable dealer could employ signaling mechanisms to separate him fromunreputable dealers

  • 7/30/2019 Lemons Market

    20/63

    20

    Signaling Concept of signals was first developed by Michael Spence

    in a labor market context A strong signal of a persons labor productivity is education

    Education generally improves a persons productivity However, even if it did not, it is still a strong signal of productivity

    Any admission requirements to a university or college will only result inhigher-quality individuals entering the institution

    Quality in quality out is signal sent to employers

    Consumers, firms, and government agencies have also used gender,race, color, religion, and national origin as signals for labor productivity

    But these signals, besides being illegal in U.S., are generally weak Exceptions are when insurance companies target insurance rates by such

    characteristics as age and gender

    Some segments of society may feel use of such discriminatory signalsis morally wrong and thus should always be illegal

  • 7/30/2019 Lemons Market

    21/63

    21

    Signaling Economic theory does not pass judgment on morality of

    signals But it does provide a framework for determining economic

    consequences of restricting such signals

    Theory would indicate that a government restriction on one signal would

    result in firms adopting related signaling mechanisms to maintain profits

    For used car market, reliable car dealers will be able to offersignals For instance, in form of warranties

    At a lower cost than lemon dealers, as illustrated in Figure 23.2 Lower warranty cost will result in lemon dealers being unable to compete in

    offering warranties

    Thus, only reliable dealers offer warranties

  • 7/30/2019 Lemons Market

    22/63

    22

    Figure 23.2 Signaling

  • 7/30/2019 Lemons Market

    23/63

    23

    Signaling Through these signals market for used vehicles can

    now be separated into two markets

    Lemons and reliables Market equilibrium for lemons is Pareto efficient by

    corresponding to free-information equilibrium (p*, *) Market supply and demand curves for lemons did not shift

    Introduction of a signal for reliable cars established a separatemarket for lemons

    Market supply curve for reliable cars shifts up from S to S' Represents increased cost associated with offering warranties

    As a result of supply shift, equilibrium quantity of reliable cars isbelow free-information quantity of*

    Equilibrium price of p' is above free-information price of p*

    Results in a deadweight loss area of CAB

  • 7/30/2019 Lemons Market

    24/63

    24

    Signaling Such a market equilibrium is called a separating equilibrium

    It segments pooled market for lemons and reliables into two markets

    However, this is only a second-best Pareto-efficientoutcome

    Because in markets with free information, sellers do not incur extraexpense of signals

    Deadweight loss of removing inefficiency Cost of removing externality

    Both producer and consumer surplus loss

    Proportion of costs paid by buyers and sellers depends onrelative elasticities of supply and demand for reliable cars In long run, as elasticity of supply becomes more elastic

    Larger proportion of signal cost is passed on to buyers

  • 7/30/2019 Lemons Market

    25/63

    25

    Screening

    Top three techniques to prevent used car scams Have a mechanic inspect vehicle

    Run a Vehicle History Report

    Will reveal if vehicle was flooded, rebuilt, salvaged, stolen, or totaled

    Never sign anything stating as is, no warranty

    Obtain at least a 30-day warranty Symmetric information associated with free information results in a

    Pareto-efficient allocation

    Pareto preferred to an allocation with signals

    However, signals can be a second-best Pareto-efficient outcome if they

    result in a separating equilibrium, which improves efficiency Not all signals do this

    Weak signals resulting in a pooling equilibrium

    Signals of different quality sellers cannot be differentiated

    Do not separate markets so market efficiency is not improved

    Buyers may attempt to distinguish or screen various commodities offered

  • 7/30/2019 Lemons Market

    26/63

    26

    Screening

    Screening exists when a buyer employs a mechanism for sortingcommodities offered by sellers

    Examples of screening are

    Buyer having a used car inspected prior to purchase

    Employer offering internships prior to employment

    In general, screening is employed by uninformed agent Can be either buyer or seller

    For example, price discrimination, discussed in Chapter 13, is a form ofscreening

    Seller does not have information on buyers willingness-to-pay for

    commodity By screening buyers based on their characteristics, sellers can create

    separate markets and practice price discrimination

  • 7/30/2019 Lemons Market

    27/63

    27

    Screening

    In some cases, buyers rely on another firm orconsumer (third parties) for screening

    For example A consumer may acquire her dentist, house painter, doctor, or

    maid through a recommendation from another consumer Or a firm may screen commodities and sell information to

    potential buyers

    Magazine Consumer Reports is in the business of screeningcommodities

    Major third parties for screening are governmentagencies providing market information

  • 7/30/2019 Lemons Market

    28/63

    28

    Screening

    Consider used car market Potential buyers may screen vehicles by having them inspected

    As illustrated in Figure 23.3, cost of screening will shift demand for bothlemons and reliable cars downward

    From D to D' for lemons market and from D to D' for reliable market

    Resulting separating-equilibrium prices, p' and p', are lower than free-information equilibrium prices, p* and p*

    Separating-equilibrium quantities, ' and ', are lower than free-informationequilibrium quantities, * and *

    Cost of screening is sum of deadweight losses in lemons market (shaded area CAB)and reliable market (shaded area DEF)

    Both signaling and screening have potential for reducing asymmetricinformation and yielding a second-best Pareto-efficient outcome

    Cost of reducing asymmetric-information externality

    Cost of signals or screening may offset any market efficiency gains They may or may not improve social welfare

  • 7/30/2019 Lemons Market

    29/63

    29

    Figure 23.3 Screening

  • 7/30/2019 Lemons Market

    30/63

    30

    Principal-Agent Models

    Concept of moral hazard Developed from study of insurance market

    An insurer has no control over policyholder not taking precautions toward reducingprobability of an insured event from occurring

    Term moral hazard (also called hidden actions) is derived from condition thata policyholder may take wrong (immoral) action by not taking proper precautions

    For example, an auto insurance firm has no control over hidden action of apolicyholder leaving car keys in an unlocked car

    Moral hazard lasts over life of some established agreement

    Moral hazard may result if purchase of a commodity establishes future returns orutility of an agent being dependent on actions of another agent

    Moral hazard is not restricted to issuance of insurance It generally exists whenever one agent (principal) depends on another agent (agent)

    to undertake some actions

    If agents actions are hidden from principal, asymmetric information is present Market inefficiencies may result

  • 7/30/2019 Lemons Market

    31/63

    31

    Principal-Agent Models

    In general, contracts establishing such dependenceare designed to mitigate potential moral hazardproblems

    Problems in designing contracts result from principal-

    agent problem Examples include

    Owners of a firm who are unable to observe a managers work ethic

    Instructors inability to observe how hard a student is actually

    studying

    In these examples, agents have ability to hide actions Uninformed principal wants to provide informed agent with efficient

    incentives for fulfilling contract

    Pareto Efficienc ith No Moral

  • 7/30/2019 Lemons Market

    32/63

    32

    Pareto Efficiency with No Moral

    Hazard

    As an illustration of no moral hazard, assume agents face an expected lossassociated with some event

    Examples are losses from fire damage to their business or an auto accident

    Without any insurance, consumers face full cost of some negative event, whichreduces their welfare

    Can mitigate negative impact by taking precaution

    An increase in level of precaution can both reduce likelihood of event occurring andmagnitude of loss when event does occur

    An objective of a consumer is to determine optimal level of precaution, P

    Assume total cost of precaution at first increases at a decreasing rate and thenincreases at an increasing rate with level of precaution (Figure 23.4)

    A basic level of precaution offers a great deal of protection with little increases in cost

    Examples are driving with traffic instead of against it, locking your car when shopping At basic level of precaution, precaution costs are increasing but at a decreasing rate

    At some point an additional level of precaution will result in costs increasing at an increasingrate

    Figure 23 4 Total and marginal

  • 7/30/2019 Lemons Market

    33/63

    33

    Figure 23.4 Total and marginal

    cost curves for precaution

    Pareto Efficiency with No Moral

  • 7/30/2019 Lemons Market

    34/63

    34

    Pareto Efficiency with No Moral

    Hazard

    If TC(P) is total cost function for precaution Then TC'(P) > 0 and at first TC"(P) < 0 and at some precaution level TC"(P) > 0

    For example, at first a great deal of fire protection can be purchased with a smallinvestment in a smoke detector

    For additional protection, fire extinguishers can be purchased at a higher cost per unit

    Followed by a sprinkler system at an even higher cost per unit

    Associated with a given level of precaution is an expected loss Expected loss is probability of event occurring times total loss

    Objective of a consumer is to determine efficient level of precaution thatminimizes overall cost (sum of expected losses and cost of precaution)

    F.O.C. is

    TC'(P) = -EL'(P) TC'(P) is marginal cost, MC(P)

    -EL'(P) is marginal benefit of precaution, MB(P)

    Marginal benefit is reduction in expected losses associated with an increase in precaution

    Pareto Efficiency with No Moral

  • 7/30/2019 Lemons Market

    35/63

    35

    Pareto Efficiency with No Moral

    Hazard

    EL'(P) < 0, so marginal benefit, -EL'(P), is positive (Figure 23.5) Optimal level of precaution, P*

    Where marginal cost equals marginal benefit

    If marginal benefit is greater than marginal cost An increase in precaution would reduce EL(P) more than increase in TC(P)

    So overall costs fall

    If marginal benefit is less than marginal cost A decrease in precaution would reduce TC(P) by more than increase in EL

    So overall cost will fall

    Optimal level of precaution is illustrated in Figure 23.6

    Positively sloping marginal precaution-cost curve represents assumption of increasingper-unit precaution cost

    Negatively sloping marginal precaution-benefit curve represents assumption ofdecreasing reduction in expected loss as precaution increases

    At P*, where marginal benefit equals marginal cost

    Overall costs are minimized

    To left (right) of P*, marginal benefit is greater (less) than marginal cost

    Consumer has an incentive to increase (decrease) precaution

  • 7/30/2019 Lemons Market

    36/63

    36

    Figure 23.5 Expected losses

    Fi 23 6 P t ffi i t ti

  • 7/30/2019 Lemons Market

    37/63

    37

    Figure 23.6 Pareto-efficient precautionlevel with no moral hazard

    Insurance Market with No Moral

  • 7/30/2019 Lemons Market

    38/63

    38

    Insurance Market with No Moral

    Hazard

    As discussed in Chapter 18, a risk-averse agent will not voluntarily takeon additional risk

    Will seek out opportunities for avoiding risk

    Insurance allows an agent to shift risk of a negative event onto anotheragent (an insurance company)

    In event of a loss, such as a flood, an insurance company compensatesagent for loss

    Assume contract (policy) between principal (insurance company) andagent (consumer) is actuarially fair insurance

    If consumer can purchase insurance covering full expected loss for a given

    level of precaution Consumer no longer suffers a loss from a negative event, EL = 0

    However, consumer must pay premium, which, for actuarially fair insurance,is equal to EL

    Assuming no moral hazard, insurance company will want to design a policy whereexpected payout varies by level of precaution a consumer takes

    Insurance Market with No Moral

  • 7/30/2019 Lemons Market

    39/63

    39

    Insurance Market with No Moral

    Hazard Premiums would be higher for a low level of precaution by a consumer

    Decline as level of precaution increases

    Let A(P) represent insurance premium, so A'(P) < 0

    A"(P) > 0

    Consumer is still faced with problem of determining optimal level of precaution thatminimizes overall cost of taking precaution and now paying insurance premium

    F.O.C. is

    TC'(P) = -A'(P)

    Consumer equates marginal precaution cost, TC'(P), to marginal precaution benefit, -A'(P)

    Marginal precaution benefit is additional savings in premium costs from an additional increase in

    precaution

    As illustrated in Figure 23.6, with no moral hazard and actuarially fair insurance

    Results in same level of precaution as in no-insurance case

    In general, assuming agents gain some utility from having an insurance company assumerisk (assuming agents are risk averse)

    Then P*, with insurance, is a Pareto-efficient level of precaution

  • 7/30/2019 Lemons Market

    40/63

    40

    Insurance and Moral Hazard

    Unfortunately, Pareto-efficient level of precaution is generally notpossible

    Hidden level of precaution by consumers makes cost of designing aninsurance policy where premiums are based on every level ofprecaution prohibitive

    In extreme case of moral hazard, where insurance company cannot atall determine level of precaution

    Insurance premium would not be a function of consumers precaution level

    Assuming insurance company sets premium at Pareto-efficient level ofprecaution, P*, consumers objective is

    Optimal solution is for consumer to not take any precaution, P = 0

    Zero level of precaution increases risk of negative event occurring Results in insurance company having to pay higher-than-expected claims

    This is root of terminology moral hazard for insurance company (principal)

  • 7/30/2019 Lemons Market

    41/63

    41

    Insurance and Moral Hazard

    Unless insurance company can design policies that provideincentives for consumers to take precaution Ttonnement process will result in no insurance company able to

    pay all its claims from revenue generated by premiums

    Inefficiency of zero precaution associated with moral hazard is

    represented by deadweight loss, area ABC, in Figure 23.6 Ttonnement process toward an equilibrium can also result in

    instances where agents are overinsured

    For example, due to falling property values or a failing business, anagent may realize that level of insurance is more than property is worth

    If this information is hidden from insurance company (adverse selection) Hidden action of not taking any precautions to prevent fire or even

    causing business to burn down can increase returns

    For this reason, in fire investigations owners are always possiblesuspects

  • 7/30/2019 Lemons Market

    42/63

    42

    Coinsurance Deadweight loss associated with moral hazard can be

    reduced by inducing consumers to take some precaution

    One type of inducement, employed by many healthinsurance companies, is coinsurance

    Require consumer to pay some percentage of cost, so insurancecompany pays less than 100% of loss

    Actual percentage paid varies, but a common rate is for an insurancecompany to pay 80% and consumers to pay remaining 20%

    As percentage of loss a consumer pays increases, less risk is shifted toinsurance company and consumer is more willing to take precaution

    Consumers will tend to seek lower-cost treatments rather than alternativehigher-cost treatments

  • 7/30/2019 Lemons Market

    43/63

    43

    Coinsurance If, for example, consumer pays 20% of cost along with a fixed

    premium A, then consumers objective is

    F.O.C. is

    =0.2EL'(P) = TC'(P)

    As illustrated in Figure 23.7, marginal benefit curve tiltsdownward and intersects marginal cost curve at second-bestPareto-efficient equilibrium level of precaution PO > 0

    Deadweight loss is reduced from area ABC to DEC Only when moral hazard can be eliminated will a Pareto-

    efficient solution P* exist

  • 7/30/2019 Lemons Market

    44/63

    44

    Figure 23.7 Coinsurance

  • 7/30/2019 Lemons Market

    45/63

    45

    Deductibles

    Writing insurance policies with deductibles is another option insurancecompanies employ for increasing agents precaution level

    Require agents to incur all loss up to some dollar limit

    For example, if an auto insurance policy has a $500 deductible provision

    First $500 in damages is paid by car owner, and insurance company pays anyremaining damages

    Generally, the higher the deductible, the lower will be the insurance premiums

    Insurance companies will incorporate deductibles into their policieswhen agents basic level of precaution is so low that insurance

    companies cannot earn normal profits

    For example, without some deductible for auto insurance, our roadwayscould take on a bumper-car atmosphere

    Resulting in dramatic insurance premium increases with few if any consumerswilling to be insured

  • 7/30/2019 Lemons Market

    46/63

    46

    Deductibles

    With deductible provision, optimal level of precaution for a consumer isdetermined by

    DA is level of deductible

    Maximum cost a consumer will incur is deductible DA

    However, if overall cost of precaution plus expected losses is less than DA Consumer can lower his cost below DA

    F.O.C. for minimizing cost is

    TC'(P) = -EL'(P)

    If DA > min[TC(P) + EL(P)], yielding optimal level of precaution P* (Figure 23.6)

    If DA < min[TC(P) + EL(P)], a zero level of precaution, P* = 0, is optimal level With DA as lowest possible level of cost

    Expenditures on precaution will not result in any additional benefits

  • 7/30/2019 Lemons Market

    47/63

    47

    Deductibles

    Deductibles allow consumers to insure against large losses But be responsible for any relatively small expected losses below deductible

    Reduces deadweight loss associated with moral hazard

    As DA increases, deadweight loss is reduced, as consumers will likelychoose no-insurance level of precaution, P*

    Consumers who are more willing to take risk will self-insure by seekinghigher insurance deductibles

    However, with increases in DA, risk-averse consumers are worse off since theyare less able to shift this risk to another agent (insurer)

    Other options available to insurance companies for increasing agents

    precaution level are

    Combinations of coinsurance and deductibles

    Subsidizing preventive care

    Health insurance policies will generally Have both deductibles and coinsurance provisions

    May also offer preventive care such as annual physical examinations and routine blood

    tests at reduced cost

    Employer and Employee

  • 7/30/2019 Lemons Market

    48/63

    48

    Employer and Employee

    Relations Moral hazard exists whenever asymmetric information in theform of hidden actions is prevalent in a principal-agent

    agreement For example, moral hazard can exist between an employer

    (principal) and an employee (agent)

    Unless an employer can constantly monitor productivity of employees Employees can engage in leisure while working (shirking) by reducing their

    level of effort

    For example, employees surfing the Net has become a major form of

    shirking

    Asymmetric information on level of employees productivitycreates inefficiencies

    An objective of employers is to design contracts that provideemployee incentives directed at improving productivity and

    reducing shirking

    Pareto Efficiency with No Moral

  • 7/30/2019 Lemons Market

    49/63

    49

    Pareto Efficiency with No Moral

    Hazard Major incentive for employees effort is

    compensation they receive for supplying their labor,in form of wage income

    Assuming symmetric information (no moral hazard)

    Can determine Pareto-efficient level of employee effort,E*

    By considering employers objective function and an employeesparticipation constraint

    No moral hazard implies that an employer canobserve an employees level of effort

    Assume employer determines labor contract and

    employee can then either accept or reject contract

    Pareto Efficiency with No Moral

  • 7/30/2019 Lemons Market

    50/63

    50

    Pareto Efficiency with No Moral

    Hazard An employer is concerned with productivity of an employee

    Denoted by production function q = f(E)

    q is some output level

    Given a per-unit output price of p and wage rate based on anemployees effort w(E)

    Employers objective is maximizing profit from this employee

    Employee has a cost of increasing effort in form of total opportunity costfrom lost shirking, TCE(E)

    Let MCE(E) represent marginal cost of effort So MCE(E) = TCE(E)/E

    In general, as illustrated in Figure 23.8, this marginalopportunity cost is U-shaped

    Figure 23 8 Employees marginal

  • 7/30/2019 Lemons Market

    51/63

    51

    Figure 23.8 Employee s marginal

    opportunity cost of effort

    Pareto Efficiency with No Moral

  • 7/30/2019 Lemons Market

    52/63

    52

    Pareto Efficiency with No Moral

    Hazard Marginal cost of effort may at first decline

    For very low levels of effort (to left of EM), additional effort results inmarginal cost of effort declining

    Spending so much time shirking, a little additional effort results in lowermarginal opportunity cost

    At relatively higher effort levels (to right of EM), any additional effortraises this marginal opportunity cost

    Employees payoff for E level of effort is

    Difference in wage income, w(E)E, and total opportunity cost, TCE(E)

    w(E)E TCE(E)

    Instead of working for this particular employer, employee could beengaged in other activities

    Being employed by another employer, being self-employed, or beingimmersed in total leisure

    Pareto Efficiency with No Moral

  • 7/30/2019 Lemons Market

    53/63

    53

    Pareto Efficiency with No Moral

    Hazard Assume next-highest payoff from these alternatives is U

    Employee will be willing to work for an employer if payoff is at least asgreat as U

    Specifically, if w(E)E TCE(E) U

    U is reservation-utility level, and equation is participation constraint

    Employer must pay at least level U if he expects to hire employee Employers objective is then

    Subject to w(E)E TCE(E) = U

    Constraint is an equality because if w(E)E - TCE(E) > U Employer could lower wages and still hire employee

    Pareto Efficiency with No Moral

  • 7/30/2019 Lemons Market

    54/63

    54

    Pareto Efficiency with No Moral

    Hazard Substituting constraint into objective function yields

    F.O.C. is MRPE = MCE

    For profit maximization, employer will equate marginalrevenue product of an employees effort, MRPE To employees marginal opportunity cost of effort, MCE

    Solving this F.O.C. for E results in Pareto-efficient level of

    employee effort, E* Illustrated in Figure 23.9, where MRPE is equated to MCE

    Figure 23 9 Pareto-efficient level of

  • 7/30/2019 Lemons Market

    55/63

    55

    Figure 23.9 Pareto-efficient level of

    effort for a risk-averse employee

    Pareto Efficiency with No Moral

  • 7/30/2019 Lemons Market

    56/63

    56

    Pareto Efficiency with No Moral

    Hazard Compensation scheme necessary for obtaining employeeeffort level E*

    Where level of compensation just equals reservation-utility level plusemployees cost of effort

    w(E)E = U + TCE(E)

    If employer is risk neutral and employee risk averse, employer willfully insure employee against any wage risk

    Employer will offer a fixed wage rate, w* = w(E*)

    Optimal contract when effort is observable Specifies Pareto-efficient effort level E*

    Fully insures a risk-averse employee against income losses

    When employee is also risk neutral, insurance is not necessary

    Any compensation scheme where wages are a function of profits, withw()E = U + TCE() will be efficient

  • 7/30/2019 Lemons Market

    57/63

    57

    Inefficiency with Moral Hazard

    In many cases, cost of monitoring effort prohibits constantlyobserving an employees level of effort For example, an employer is generally unable to observe a night

    clerk at a convenience store or a truck driver for a furniture company

    When effort is not observable, Pareto-efficient effort levelcomes in conflict with result of full insurance Only method for increasing employee effort is relating wages to

    firms profit

    Random nature of profit results in employee assuming some uninsuredrisk

    Such conflicts create inefficiencies unless employee is risk neutral

    A risk-neutral employee is only concerned with expected profit

    Would not be concerned with any random nature of profit

    Indifferent with taking uncertain profit in place of a certain wage

  • 7/30/2019 Lemons Market

    58/63

    58

    Inefficiency with Moral Hazard

    In contrast, when an employee is risk-averse Increased share of profit relative to a certain

    wage does affect employee

    Incentives for increased effort are directlyassociated with an employees cost of increasedrisk

    Results in an additional constraint on employer

    Employer not only maximizes profit subject to participationconstraint

    w(E)E TCE(E) U

    But also is subject to an incentive-compatibility constraint

    Must offer a compensation scheme that gives an

    employee an incentive to choose required effort level

    I ffi i i h M l H d

  • 7/30/2019 Lemons Market

    59/63

    59

    Inefficiency with Moral Hazard

    When employer can directly observe employeesefforts

    Employees will put forth required level of effortregardless of their desire

    In contrast, when effort is not directly observable Employees can shirk by not putting forth required level of

    effort To avoid such shirking, employers must offer a compensation

    scheme to induce employee to offer E* units of effort Determined by setting employees payoff associated with E* at least

    as great as payoff for any other level of effort

    w(E*)E* TCE(E*) w(E)(E) TCE(E)

    For all levels of effort E

    At any wage below this constraint, employee will shirk

    I ffi i i h M l H d

  • 7/30/2019 Lemons Market

    60/63

    60

    Inefficiency with Moral Hazard

    In the extreme case, not considering this incentive-compatibility constraint

    Results in an employee seeking an effort level independent of his wages

    Employee would minimize his total effort Optimal solution is for employee to totally shirk and not exert any effort

    Analogous to zero level of precaution associated with insurance

    Illustrated in Figure 23.6

    Unless employer can design contracts that provide incentives for employees to choose effort

    Ttonnement process will result in a zero level of effort

    Inefficiency of E = 0 associated with moral hazard is represented by deadweightloss, area ABC in Figure 23.9

    Designing employment contracts with compensation mechanisms that take intoconsideration this incentive-compatibility constraint will provide incentives foremployees to increase their work efforts

    Will reduce inefficiency associated with wages not directly linked with level of effort

    However, such contracts will be second-best Pareto-efficient allocations Still result in risk-averse employee not being fully insured

    Only with symmetric information associated with no hidden action on part ofagent (employee) will a Pareto-efficient allocation exist

    R id l Cl i

  • 7/30/2019 Lemons Market

    61/63

    61

    Residual Claimant Large poultry enterprises use residual claimant production contracts with

    independent farmers to raise chickens

    By having farmers assume risk of raising chickens

    Farmers will have incentives to take necessary effort to prevent disease and otherpossible adverse effects on chickens

    USDA Economic Research Service estimates 52% of approximately

    50,000 farms with poultry or egg production in 1995 reported use ofproduction contracts

    Value of poultry and eggs produced under such contracts accounted for 85%of total value of all poultry and egg production

    Farmers without contracts tended to be either large owner-integrated

    operations or independents providing poultry and poultry products tolocal markets

    In poultry contracting, employees are residual claimant to output

    An example of a second-best Pareto-efficient compensation schemeincorporating incentive compatibility

    R id l Cl i

  • 7/30/2019 Lemons Market

    62/63

    62

    Residual Claimant A residual claimant is an agent (farmer) who

    receives payoff from output after any fees are paidto a principal (poultry enterprise)

    An employee will maximize payoff by

    Equating marginal revenue product of employees effort toemployees marginal opportunity cost of effort

    Examples of residual claimant contracts are franchises andemployee buyouts

    Fast-food enterprises are a typical example of franchising

    Owner of a fast-food establishment pays parent company afixed fee for right to operate (franchise)

    Employees become residual claimant

    Compensation is now dependent on profits of firm minus lumpsum payment to owners

    R id l Cl i t

  • 7/30/2019 Lemons Market

    63/63

    Residual Claimant

    Specifically, employees objective is to maximize consumersurplus plus economic rent minus franchise fee

    F.O.C. is

    MRPE = MCE

    Although marginal benefit equals marginal cost, risk-averseemployees are not able to fully insure against losses Results in a second-best Pareto-efficient allocation

    Such residual claimant contracts are very popular when employees areable to take precautions and reduce possible losses in profits at a lowercost than owners