Lee Davis CMR Version

download Lee Davis CMR Version

of 28

Transcript of Lee Davis CMR Version

  • 8/6/2019 Lee Davis CMR Version

    1/28

  • 8/6/2019 Lee Davis CMR Version

    2/28

    I would like to thank the Danish Social Sciences Research Council for supporting the research behind

    this article. An earlier version of this article was presented at the DRUID (Danish Research Unit for

    Industrial Dynamics) Conference held in Copenhagen, Denmark, in June 2005. I am also grateful to

    Jens Frslev Christensen for pointing out some fruitful lines of inquiry and to Jerome D. Davis,

    Merete L. Drewsen, and two anonymous referees for reading through previous drafts and offering

    valuable comments for improvement.

    Licensing Strategies

    of the New IntellectualProperty Vendors

    Lee Davis

    CALIFORNIA MANAGEMENT REVIEW VOL. 50, NO. 2 WINTER 2008 CMR.BERKELEY.EDU6

    Agrowing number of firms are specializing solely in the generation

    and licensing of intellectual property (IP). These intellectual

    property vendors are not traditional suppliers, since they do not

    engage in production or sales. Their business model is based on

    licensing out the rights to their inventions to other firms, who further develop

    the inventions commercially. Three examples provide a glimpse into the world

    they inhabit:

    Orbital Corporation of Perth, Australia, invented an environmentally

    friendly fuel injection system for 2-stroke engines in the 1970s. For nearly

    four decades, it has existed mainly by earning license fees. While the

    invention has not been commercialized in its original target market (the

    major automakers), Orbital identified new buyers, such as the manufac-

    turers of marine and recreation vehicles, and has now morphed into a

    corporation that provides research, design, development, and testing

    services to many of the worlds powertrain producers, regulatory authori-

    ties, and research institutions.1

    ARM (Advanced RISC Machines) Holdings Plc, founded by twelve

    Cambridge University engineers in 1990, invented the RISC chip,

    which enables computer hardware to interpret and carry out softwarecommands. ARM, which calls itself a purely intellectual property licensing

  • 8/6/2019 Lee Davis CMR Version

    3/28

    company, has broadly and successfully licensed its IP so as to establish the

    basis for an international standard.2

    Virginia-based NTP Inc. leveraged its IP by suing Canadas Research in

    Motion Inc. (RIM), manufacturer of the popular BlackBerry wireless

    communication devices, for patent infringement. RIM, threatened with a

    court-ordered shutdown of its operations in the U.S., home to more than

    3 million BlackBerry users, finally settled the case in 2006 by paying NTP

    $612.5 million.3

    This article investigates the special characteristics and choices of these IP

    vendors. How do they create value from their inventions? What problems arise,

    and how do they address them?

    As David Teece observed in 1998, firms are increasingly jostling for posi-

    tion in markets for know-how. A new dynamic to competition and competitive

    advantage has emerged, characterized by a rapid growth in arrangements for the

    exchange of new products or services (particularly in high-tech industries),

    including R&D joint ventures, licensing, and R&D contracting.4 As the costs ofR&D soar, cooperation is becoming more central to successful global business

    strategies.5 However, while there is a large literature on firms licensing choices,6

    and considerable anecdotal evidence about individual IP vendors, there has as

    yet been no systematic investigation of the licensing strategies they pursue.

    Several scholars touch on key features of firms that specialize in markets

    for ideas. Andrew B. Hargadon discusses how some companies, with access to

    a variety of industries, can serve as knowledge brokers, recognizing the value

    of an idea from one sector and transferring it to a firm in another sector in the

    form of a novel, innovative solution.7 Ashish Arora, Andrea Fosfuri, and Alfonso

    Gambardella describe how markets for tech-

    nology can increase the strategy space for

    innovating firms, giving them the choice

    between producing the knowledge internally,

    acquiring it from external sources, or licensing

    out their own knowledge to other firms.8

    Joshua Gans and Scott Stern consider the challenges faced by small, start-up

    technology entrepreneurs who seek to profit from innovation through either the

    product market, or the market for ideas. Some of the latter are pure ideas facto-

    ries, commercially developing their inventions through partnerships with

    downstream players.9

    In all of this work, however, the strategies of IP vendors are analyzed

    in the context of the broader array of strategic choices available to innovating

    firms. Here, we investigate what makes IP providers unique, in order to con-tribute a new perspective to this ongoing theoretical discussion on the dynamics

    of markets for ideas in three manners. First, we shift the focus of analysis that is

    characteristic of virtually all studies on technology licensing, from the choices

    confronting the buyers of intellectual property to the choices confronting the

    sellers. For this reason, we have chosen to work with the term IP vendor,

    rather than vaguer concepts like ideas factories or invention factories.10

    Licensing Strategies of the New Intellectual Property Vendors

    CALIFORNIA MANAGEMENT REVIEW VOL.50,NO.2 WINTER 2008 CMR.BERKELEY.EDU 7

    Lee N. Davis is an Associate Professor at theDepartment of Innovation and Organizational

    Economics, Copenhagen Business School,

    Denmark.

  • 8/6/2019 Lee Davis CMR Version

    4/28

    Second, we are not interested in why firms choose between licensing, internal-

    ization, and hybrid organizational forms,11but rather in how they use licensing

    for strategic advantage. The factors that drive firms to license out proprietary

    technology, and the role played by technology in corporate strategy, have as yet

    only been sparsely investigated.12 Third, since IP vendors do not engage in pro-duction, sales, or distribution, the problems associated with capturing value from

    their inventions alone become especially acute. This article presents a frame-

    work outlining four strategies that can be utilized by these creative and enter-

    prising firms.

    Several recent trends have contributed to a fertile growth environment

    for IP vendors. First, many large companies have found it necessary to cut costs

    by reducing R&D staff and in-house laboratory capabilities. This creates an

    increased need to acquire intellectual property developed by other firms, par-

    ticularly in science-based industries.13 Related to this has been the movement

    towards greater specialization, forcing companies to define where their core

    competencies lie and to find external partners for non-core technologies.

    14

    Third, the patent system has been standardized and strengthened internation-

    ally, driven by the more pro-patent attitude of politicians and the courts in the

    industrialized countries, especially the United States.15 This has led to a prolifera-

    tion of patent applications and the increasingly strategic use of patents and

    licenses by firms to win competitive advantage.16

    Economists have traditionally viewed licensing and other forms of coop-

    eration with some skepticism. The key early economic studies examined the

    reasons for the high transaction costs associated with technology licenses due

    to the complexity of the subject matter to be transferred, along with the risks

    attributable to small numbers bargaining, asymmetric information, the uncer-

    tainties of innovation, and the difficulties of contracting for knowledge given

    its public good characteristics.17 In his seminal 1986 article on how firmsprofit from their investments in R&D, Teece argues that in weak appropriability

    regimes, it is often the owners of specialized complementary assets that earn the

    lions share of the profits, not the original inventor. Only firms in strong appro-

    priability regimes should contract for access.18

    Other scholars view cooperation more positively.19 Work has explored

    how problems associated with licensing can be dealt with through the design of

    the contract.20 According to Arora, Fosfuri, and Gambardella, not only can mar-

    kets for technology facilitate efforts by the individual firm to make more efficient

    use of its resources, they can potentially also lead to substantial industry-wide

    economies of specialization.21 Arora and Robert Merges investigate the relation-

    ship between the strength of intellectual property rights and firm boundaries.

    They contend that small technology specialist suppliers that possess important

    new information valuable to the potential buyer, and have strong patent protec-

    tion, enjoy increased bargaining power in contractual negotiations with larger

    firms. Thus specialized suppliers with strong firm capabilities in innovation

    should be encouraged to invest in them.22

    Licensing Strategies of the New Intellectual Property Vendors

    UNIVERSITY OF CALIFORNIA, BERKELEY VOL. 50,NO.2 WINTER 2008 CMR.BERKELEY.EDU8

  • 8/6/2019 Lee Davis CMR Version

    5/28

    Capturing Value from IP in the Market for Ideas

    Markets for ideas, as mentioned earlier, are characterized by numerous

    imperfections, rendering idea tradability difficult. One of the most important

    potential contractual hazards faced by an IP vendor is that the buyer mightappropriate part of the value of its proprietary knowledge without paying for

    it.23 To interest a potential buyer, the inventor must reveal enough information

    to convince the buyer of the value of the IP. However, once the buyer possesses

    this information, it no longer needs to pay a fee to gain access to it. The buyer

    might, perhaps, use this knowledge to invent around the vendors patents. Not

    only would the IP vendor lose the opportunity to earn license fees, it might also

    create a competitor.

    These appropriability hazards can be illustrated by the story of Robert

    Kearns, who invented and patented the intermittent windshield wiper in the

    1960s. Unable to commercialize this invention on his own, Kearns presented the

    idea to Ford Motor Company, disclosing to senior engineers not only the operat-

    ing principles, but also the functionality of his invention. Ford ultimately

    rejected Kearns license proposal. Shortly thereafter, Ford began to feature a

    similar technology in its automobiles. Other automakers followed suit in the

    U.S. and Europe. Kearns sued them all for patent infringement. For over twenty

    years, neither Ford nor the other automakers paid Kearns any royalties. Finally,

    in the 1990s, the courts successfully upheld his patents, enabling him to extract

    a portion of the economic returns for himself.24

    However, knowledge is not necessarily a public good. Most knowledge

    is context specific. This represents another source of market imperfections: the

    costs of transferring the technology from licensor to licensee. Generally speak-

    ing, the more codified and observable in use the knowledge is, the lower the

    costs of its transfer.25

    The receiving companys R&D lab must be able to assimi-late and exploit the information in a productive way.26 One common problem is

    the not invented here syndrome. The licensees R&D, production, and market-

    ing staff may not be interested in further developing the invention, since it is

    externally sourced and does not necessarily fit into their own plans or match

    their own competences. While the risk of imitation may be less for more com-

    plex inventions than for codifiable ones, it may be necessary to supplement the

    conventional license agreement with provisions covering the transfer of more

    sophisticated know-how or other forms of knowledge sharing.

    A third source of market imperfections is market and technical uncer-

    tainty. Market demand may change. The buyers demand for the invention in

    relation to its own technologies may change. The invention may not work prop-

    erly after the buyer has assumed the rights. New technologies may emerge that

    make the invention outdated.

    Fourth, a range of agency problems can arise. The licensor has developed

    the invention and possesses the relevant experience; the would-be licensee

    lacks information needed to evaluate the expected pay-offs. An IP vendor may

    find that its licensee, contrary to expectations, is unable to work the invention

    Licensing Strategies of the New Intellectual Property Vendors

    CALIFORNIA MANAGEMENT REVIEW VOL.50,NO.2 WINTER 2008 CMR.BERKELEY.EDU 9

  • 8/6/2019 Lee Davis CMR Version

    6/28

    effectively or fashion a successful marketing strategy. Alternatively, the licensee

    might try to create value from the invention in a way not agreeable to the IP

    vendor,27 possibly acquiring the rights not in order to commercialize the inven-

    tion, but to prevent another firm from doing so.28

    Finally, firms face the potential hazards associated with transaction-spe-

    cific assets and small numbers bargaining.29 The potential number of both buyers

    and sellers of a new proprietary technology will typically be limited. Buyers con-

    sidering trading with IP providers may fear being subjected to a hold-up situa-

    tion. Once the buyer has sunk the costs of developing an innovation based on

    the vendors patent, the vendor might use its bargaining power to set the price

    of its invention so high that the buyer incurs a loss on its initial investment. In

    particular, buyers may hesitate to trade with IP vendors that are the sole suppli-

    ers on the market.

    A Tale of Two Vendors

    While the sources of market imperfections described above render idea

    tradability difficult for all IP vendors, it is often possible to find workable solu-

    tions, either as part of the license contract or in some other manner. This can

    be illustrated by the strategies pursued by the two prominent IP vendors briefly

    introduced above: Orbital Corporation and ARM Holdings Ltd.

    Orbital Corporation, founded in 1970, initially patented an orbital

    engine (somewhat similar to the radial engine). However, it soon abandoned

    this, pursuing instead a novel fuel injection technology that was both environ-

    mentally friendly and cost-efficient. The company licensed out the rights to

    this technology, and a stream of related inventions, on a non-exclusive basis to

    major automakers and engine manufacturers. Orbital charged very high royal-

    ties to ensure that the licensees took the technology seriouslyand to enhance

    its own earnings.

    By 1990, Orbital had generated so much royalty income on its test

    engines and license contracts that it became the largest company in Western

    Australia in terms of market capitalization, and it was hailed as the best

    performer on the Australian stock market. Orbital also found new outlets for its

    inventions in engines for motorcycles, motorboats, and lawnmowers, and it now

    offers a range of consultant services. In the fiscal year ending June 2007, Orbital

    earned $15.2 million in revenues, mainly from its license agreements along with

    prototype and component manufacturing.30

    ARM Holdings Ltd., which generates revenue by widely licensing its RISC

    chip designs to semiconductor companies, has pursued quite a different strategy.Whenever ARM grants a license, it tries to build a reciprocal relationship with

    the licensee, giving ARM insights into the licensees process technology and

    access to new knowledge about emerging applications. This helps ARM design

    chips that best fit its partners future technologies and application needs. The

    more end applications that can be serviced by an ARM chip, the more both ARM

    and its partners can earn. ARMs licensees add their own application-specific

    Licensing Strategies of the New Intellectual Property Vendors

    UNIVERSITY OF CALIFORNIA, BERKELEY VOL. 50,NO.2 WINTER 2008 CMR.BERKELEY.EDU10

  • 8/6/2019 Lee Davis CMR Version

    7/28

    technology to the ARM chip designs, manufacture the chips in their wafer fabri-

    cation plants, and sell them to Original Equipment Manufacturers like Nokia or

    Hewlett Packard.

    As a result, the ARM design is now used in a vast range of consumer and

    industry products, from mobile phones to personal organizers to digital cameras.

    By 2001, the company had achieved a market share of 77% of the embedded

    RISC processor market and was accepted by industry leaders as the de facto global

    standard. In January 2007, the company won the European Business of the Year

    award.31

    Each company faced the sources of market imperfections described in the

    previous section but addressed them differently. To deal with appropriability

    hazards, for example, Orbital took out hundreds of patents. Its policy of liberal

    licensing, high license fees, and tight control over its intellectual property rights

    secured a continuous income stream. It was mainly up to the buyer to absorb

    the technology into its own development and production activities.

    Like Orbital Corporation, ARM made extensive use of patents, thoroughlyprotecting its basic invention. However, ARM allowed its buyers to custom tailor

    its chips to their needs. In so doing, ARM ran the risk that its buyers might imi-

    tate its technology. However, by underlining that reciprocal knowledge sharing

    was in the interests of both parties, ARM aligned their incentives, creating strong

    alliances.

    ARM thereby also reduced the costs of technology transfer. Buyers were

    encouraged to learn as much as possible about how the ARM design could work

    for them. ARM benefited from its buyers experiences with the chip, spurring

    ARM to improve chip performance. Orbital seems to have been plagued by the

    not invented here syndrome. The scientists and engineers who worked for

    the automobile manufacturers were themselves experimenting with a variety

    of new technologies. Why should they favor Orbitals process?

    The inventions pioneered by both Orbital and ARM faced considerable

    problems of technical and market uncertainty. Orbitals primary approach was

    to improve the technical efficiency and reliability of the fuel injection process,

    while leaving the question of eventual market uncertainty up to the automobile

    manufacturers. ARM tried to reduce both types of uncertainties, by engaging

    buyers directly in the continuing development process, finding out what they

    wanted specifically, and learning how to fulfill these needs.

    A crucial factor for Orbital concerned the systemic nature of technologies

    in vertically integrated, capital-intensive industries like automobiles.32 No matter

    how good an invention is, it will only be valuable to potential buyers if it can

    be integrated into this larger system. Orbitals fuel injection process, while tech-

    nically and environmentally attractive, involved revamping existing engine

    technology. Car dealers and insurance agents would have to learn about it.

    Mechanics would have to be trained in its repair. A faulty engine leading to a

    rash of consumer lawsuits could be enormously costly. The automobile manu-

    facturers had not been able to observe Orbitals development process. Contract-

    ing with such an external agent could put them at considerable cost and risk.

    Licensing Strategies of the New Intellectual Property Vendors

    CALIFORNIA MANAGEMENT REVIEW VOL.50,NO. 2 WINTER 2008 CMR.BERKELEY.EDU 11

  • 8/6/2019 Lee Davis CMR Version

    8/28

    ARM, by contrast, worked in semiconductors, a cumulative systems technol-

    ogy, where new products are closely linked technically with previous innova-

    tions (and may as a result infringe previous patents).33 The parties ensure

    mutual compatibility by extensive knowledge sharing and cross-licensing,

    reducing information asymmetries and thus costs related to adverse selectionand moral hazard.

    Finally, potential hazards associated with small numbers bargaining

    played out differently for the two companies. Orbital Corporation was the sole

    supplier of its fuel injection process. Because of its many patents, it effectively

    sealed off the area of technology to any other supplier, let alone the automobile

    companies. Empirical studies have shown that the greater the degree of asset

    specificity in transactions governing automobile components (and thus the

    higher the expected appropriable quasi-rents), the greater the tendency towards

    the vertical integration.34 The automobile manufacturers might well have felt

    vulnerable to hold up. ARM, the sole supplier of the RISC chip, also operated

    in an industry where the risk of hold-up can be acute. However, by engaging itsbuyers in mutually beneficial arrangements, it acted directly to ameliorate these

    fears.

    Towards a Framework for Analysis

    While ARM and Orbital devised quite different strategies to capture rent

    from their license agreements, other approaches may be employed. Consider,

    for example, the story of NTP, the third case briefly mentioned in the introduc-

    tion. NTP obtained five patents on inventions in e-mail systems with wireless

    networks, but did not develop the technology itself. Some time later, Research in

    Motion (RIM) realized that its already developed and commercialized Blackberry

    devices could not function without access to NTPs technology. RIM claimed ithad no idea it was infringing NTPs patents and questioned their validity. How-

    ever, faced with an injunction that would have closed its U.S. BlackBerry ser-

    vice, RIM settled out of court.

    NTP, like both Orbital and ARM, patented its technology to secure appro-

    priability. Like ARM, it also worked in a cumulative systems technology. How-

    ever, it did not engage in knowledge exchange. Nor did NTP make any effort to

    reduce the costs of technology transfer or ameliorate the technical and market

    uncertainties connected with its invention. All RIM wanted to do was to con-

    tinue to produce BlackBerries. Thus NTP used its blocking patent position simply

    to extract rents. Subsequently, NTP has filed new patent infringement lawsuits

    against the four biggest wireless carriers in the U.S.Alternatively, consider the experiences of the early Genentech. In 1978,

    its researchers won a prize competition sponsored by Eli Lilly to successfully

    synthesize the human insulin gene. Genentech applied for a patent on the

    invention and entered into an exclusive license agreement with Eli Lilly for its

    further development.35 In this case, appropriability hazards were not really an

    issue, since the two sides had agreed on the division of the property rights.

    Licensing Strategies of the New Intellectual Property Vendors

    UNIVERSITY OF CALIFORNIA, BERKELEY VOL. 50,NO.2 WINTER 2008 CMR.BERKELEY.EDU12

  • 8/6/2019 Lee Davis CMR Version

    9/28

    Problems related to the costs of technology transfer and asymmetric information

    were also more manageable, since the IP vendors invention was early on tai-

    lored to the buyers needs. While Genentech faced some technical uncertainty in

    developing the gene, Eli Lilly could help in finding a solution. The potential for

    hold-up, however, clearly existed.

    To generalize from the above cases, in the license negotiation process, the

    IP vendor and the would-be licensee strive to reach a contractual arrangement

    that can effectively deal with these sources of market imperfections. Moreover,

    as Oliver Hart has observed in his work on contractual governance,36 the ex post

    allocation of power (or control) in the contractthe position of each party if the

    other party does not performmatters as well. At different times, both vendor

    and buyer will invest in the IP being traded. Both attempt to minimize their

    financial exposure inherent in such investments, and maximize their future

    returns. Both operate under the constraints imposed by the characteristics of

    the technology concerned.

    Based on the literature on firm appropriability choices and economictheories of organization (here the theory of incomplete contracts), along with

    anecdotal evidence of the experiences of IP vendors in practice, we suggest that

    vendor strategies can be differentiated along two main dimensions. The first

    concerns the nature of the contractual relations; the second concerns the degree

    of cumulativeness in the technology to be traded.

    Stand Alone Licensing or Licensing Plus?

    In IP markets, the would-be buyer must be confident that its ex post

    investments in products, services, or processes arising from its purchasing the

    rights to an IP vendors invention will not lead to financial exposure due to the

    sellers bad faith. The IP vendor, for its part, must be assured that it can procure

    sufficient returns to cover the ex ante costs of its initial investments in the inven-

    tion. These mutual interests can give rise to a range of agreements, from

    straightforward licensing to complicated contractual relationships.

    In transaction costs economics, it is recognized that many problems can

    be associated with contracting for complex, unpredictable products, such as

    those involving research and development. Such contracts must be incomplete

    because it is difficult for the parties to think through and plan for any eventual

    contingencies that might arise, and to find a common language to guide the

    negotiation process. And even if the parties can overcome these problems, it can

    be very difficult to draw up the contract so that it can be effectively enforced by

    an outside authority.37 However, if both parties have an interest in increasing the

    returns from the invention, both will also be motivated to make the transactionas efficient as possible. Hostages or hostage-like mechanisms, where one

    firm offers a valuable asset to another that will be forfeit if the agreement is not

    honored, may be employed to align their incentives. The buyer can require the

    seller to post a cash bond, invest in specific capital, make bilateral investments,

    and the like.38 ARMs use of reciprocal knowledge sharing can be seen as an

    exchange of hostages involving highly specific assets. The willingness of both

    Licensing Strategies of the New Intellectual Property Vendors

    CALIFORNIA MANAGEMENT REVIEW VOL.50,NO. 2 WINTER 2008 CMR.BERKELEY.EDU 13

  • 8/6/2019 Lee Davis CMR Version

    10/28

    ARM and its licensing partners to reveal knowledge to each other suggests that

    both valued the continuation of the relationship and did not want it to fail.

    As Peter Smith Ring and Andrew Van de Ven have pointed out, for trans-

    actions characterized not only by a high degree of risk (with moderate to high

    asset specificity), but also by a high degree of trust, relational contracting can

    provide an efficient solution.39 In such contracts, the terms of exchange are

    uncertain, open, and incomplete, and the parties enjoy close social relations.

    According to Jeffrey Dyer and Harbir Singh, strong partnerships of this type can

    create relational rents, supernormal profits that can only be generated through

    the joint idiosyncratic contributions of the two parties.40 This work on relational

    contracting and relational rents, which builds as well on insights from the

    knowledge-based and competence-based views of the firm, allows us to add a

    strategic perspective to the efficiency perspective of economic theories of

    organization, enabling us to link governance structure with the IP licensors

    strategic choices.

    Against this background, we suggest that IP vendors can employ twomain approaches to licensing. In the first, the stand-alone licensing agreement,

    the license serves primarily to specify the legal basis for the transfer of rights and

    enable the IP vendor to earn royalties (or other forms of compensation like lump

    sum payments). The license fees can then finance the vendors ongoing inven-

    tive activities.

    In the second type of agreement, licensing plus, the vendor uses the

    license as a means not only to extract royalties, but also to support the longer-

    term relationship with the buyer. The license agreement can be supplemented

    by contracts covering other aspects of R&D collaboration and/or equity

    exchange. The inventive process is tailored to the evolving requirements of

    both parties. Scientists and engineers who work for such vendors must be will-

    ing to adjust their own research agendas to what buyers find important.

    Among the case studies explored above, Orbital Corporation and NTP

    seem to have viewed the license mainly as a means to earn royalties. ARM

    Holdings and the early Genentech, by contrast, employed a licensing plus

    approach.

    The Degree of Technological Cumulativeness

    The second critical dimension of the IP providers licensing choice con-

    cerns the degree to which its research activities are mutually dependent on the

    innovative activities of other market players. If an innovation gives rise to a

    stream of interlinked improvement innovations, or lays the basis for improve-

    ments in related areas, the technology may be characterized as cumulative.41

    In technological regimes of high cumulativeness, such as computers, semicon-

    ductors, electronic equipmentand, increasingly, biotechnologymanufactur-

    ers typically hold the patent rights to technologies to which other companies

    working in related technologies must be able to have access in order to continue

    with their own product development activities. The two parties, by cross-licens-

    ing their patent rights, avoid the possibility of mutually blocking patents. The

    Licensing Strategies of the New Intellectual Property Vendors

    UNIVERSITY OF CALIFORNIA, BERKELEY VOL. 50,NO.2 WINTER 2008 CMR.BERKELEY.EDU14

  • 8/6/2019 Lee Davis CMR Version

    11/28

    license primarily confers the right to utilize someone elses technology without

    being sued for patent infringement.42

    Technological regimes of lower cumulativeness, like the pharmaceutical

    industry, have exhibited a different dynamic.43 Traditionally, after a pharmaceu-

    tical company had successfully developed one drug, it basically started all over

    again to search for promising new molecules. With the revolution in biotech-

    nology, these conditions are changing, enabling companies to search more effi-

    ciently for new molecules, focusing on specific segments of the search space.44

    However, the pharmaceutical companies have continued to specialize in par-

    ticular therapeutic areas. They can either develop the needed inputs to their

    production process themselves, or contract with an external agent. When a

    pharmaceutical corporation enters into a license agreement with an external

    R&D supplier, the typical division of labor is for the supplier to conduct the ini-

    tial screening up to Clinical Phase III, when the testing process becomes much

    more expensive. The vendor then contracts with a pharmaceutical company for

    the inventions further commercial development.

    45

    This distinction between technologies of low and high cumulativeness

    echoes the distinction made in the literature on firm patenting strategies

    between the use of patents to block to fence and block to play.46 In the

    fence strategy, a firm patents not only its core invention, but also numerous

    substitutes, generating a protective layer around this core, blocking rivals from

    imitating it. This strategy is leveraged mainly in technological regimes of low

    cumulativeness.47 Here, the IP vendor typically grants the licensee the right to

    use its invention as an input into the licensees own production process, linking

    the two parties in a vertical buyer-supplier partnership. Depending on the

    invention, the vendor may need to possess one or a few patents (as exemplified

    by Robert Kearns, with his intermittent windshield wiper) or many hundreds

    (as illustrated by Orbital Corporation).

    By contrast, the play strategy is frequently employed in technological

    regimes of high cumulativeness. Patents serve as bargaining chips, enabling

    the orderly division of rights among producers of complementary technologies

    where there is some technical relationship between the two inventions. Access

    to the one is necessary if the other is to be enjoyed. Often such licenses must be

    negotiated among many different producers (as shown by ARM Holdings). How-

    ever, even a small firm can block to play if it possesses the patent rights to

    technologies to which another firm must have access.48

    As regards the degree of technological cumulativeness, Orbital Corpora-

    tion has a great deal in common with the early Genentech, since they worked

    as suppliers in markets characterized by relatively low cumulativeness. Thetechnologies offered by ARM and NTP are characterized by relatively high

    cumulativeness.

    Licensing Strategies of the New Intellectual Property Vendors

    CALIFORNIA MANAGEMENT REVIEW VOL.50,NO. 2 WINTER 2008 CMR.BERKELEY.EDU 15

  • 8/6/2019 Lee Davis CMR Version

    12/28

    IP Vendors Licensing Strategies:A Suggested Typology

    Using these two dimensions to create a typology, we suggest that IP ven-

    dors can pursue four different strategies:

    the independentstrategy (stand-alone licensing/technologies of low cumu-lativeness),

    the complementorstrategy (stand-alone licensing/technologies of high

    cumulativeness),

    the directedstrategy (licensing plus/technologies of low cumulativeness),

    and

    the reciprocal knowledge-sharing strategy (licensing plus/technologies of

    high cumulativeness).

    Figure 1 shows the main drivers of the four strategies, and examples of

    IP vendors that have implemented them. Orbitals approach to licensing can be

    classified in this typology as the independentstrategy, NTP as the complementor

    strategy, the early Genentech as the directedstrategy, and ARM as the reciprocal

    knowledge-sharing strategy.

    The Independent Strategy(Stand-Alone Licensing/Technologies of Low Cumulativeness)

    IP vendors that pursue this strategy, like Orbital Corporation, develop a

    new product or process to the point where they can demonstrate its potential

    commercial value, and then license it out. Ultra-Scan of Amherst, New York,

    also adopted this approach. Ultra-Scan introduced the worlds first ultrasonic

    fingerprint scanner in 1996. It holds an extensive portfolio of patents on its tech-

    niques utilizing ultrasound in reading, matching and identifying fingerprints.

    The technology can be widely applied in uses ranging from airport security sys-tems and fraud protection to biometric smart cards and online account access.49

    The independentlicensing strategy can be illustrated by a time line (see

    Figure 2), where t represents the time at which an action is undertaken. It

    should be emphasized that Figure 2 and the other time lines (Figures 3-5,

    below) are diagrammatic. Thus the term t does not represent year 1, or any

    other absolute figure, but provides a way of indicating the relative chronology of

    the strategic moves of the respective parties.

    The vendor invests in its invention at t=1, and patents it at t=2. Often,

    such vendors can amass large patent portfolios covering different aspects of the

    invention (patents on related products, processes, and uses), enabling a block

    to fence strategy. The vendor then seeks to license out the invention. If another

    firm is interested in using the invention as an input to its own development

    program, they enter into a license agreement. Because the technology is of low

    cumulativeness, the prospective buyer can choose not to license, attempting

    instead to invent around the vendors patent(s) (t=3).

    As can be seen, the prospective buyer does not commit resources until

    t=4, when the two parties sign a simple licensing contract. Such a contract can

    Licensing Strategies of the New Intellectual Property Vendors

    UNIVERSITY OF CALIFORNIA, BERKELEY VOL. 50,NO.2 WINTER 2008 CMR.BERKELEY.EDU16

  • 8/6/2019 Lee Davis CMR Version

    13/28

    include the background IP, the IP to be shared (including a specification of

    components), the transfer of the license, sublicensing rights, lump sum and/or

    royalty payments, secrecy, termination of licensing rights, and (future) dispute

    resolution. The vendor continues to perform independent R&D; the buyer may

    Licensing Strategies of the New Intellectual Property Vendors

    CALIFORNIA MANAGEMENT REVIEW VOL.50,NO. 2 WINTER 2008 CMR.BERKELEY.EDU 17

    FIGURE 1. A Suggested Typology of IP Vendors

    Nature of the

    Contractual

    Agreement

    Degree of

    Technological

    Cumulativeness

    Stand-Alone Licensing Licensing-Plus

    Low The Independent Strategy

    Main Drivers

    The license provides the legal basis

    for the transfer of rights, enabling the

    IP vendor to earn royalties (or other

    compensation).

    Patents to prevent imitation

    Block to fence (if large patentportfolio)

    Examples of Companies

    Orbital Corporation

    Robert Kearns

    Ultra-Scan

    Jerome Lemelson

    The DirectedStrategy

    Main Drivers

    The license is part of a larger pack-

    age of cooperative R&D agreements

    between vendor and buyer.

    Patents to prevent imitation

    Block to fence (if large patent

    portfolio)

    Examples of Companies

    Mojave Aerospace Ventures

    Orbital Corporations collaboration

    with Jaguar

    Ultra-Scans collaboration with

    US Biometrics Corp

    The early Genentech

    NeuroSearch

    High The ComplementorStrategy

    Main Drivers

    The license provides the legal basis

    for the transfer of rights, enabling theIP vendor to earn royalties (or other

    compensation).

    Patents as bargaining chips

    Non-trolls:Block to play

    Trolls: Block to force compensation

    Examples of Companies

    Systemonic and other young

    university spin-offs in cumulative

    technologies

    NTP

    Eolas

    MercExchange

    The Reciprocal

    Knowledge-SharingStrategy

    Main Drivers

    The license is part of a larger pack-age of cooperative R&D agreements

    between vendor and buyer.

    Patents as bargaining chips

    Block to play

    Examples of Companies

    ARM

    Cambridge Display Technologies

    CombiMatrix and Benitec

    Qualcomm

  • 8/6/2019 Lee Davis CMR Version

    14/28

    or may not develop the technology commercially (t=5). If the buyer goes ahead

    with commercialization, it must commit further resources, risking major finan-

    cial exposure if the technology fails. If the contract is later terminated (t=6), both

    parties lose their contract-specific investments.

    This strategy may also be leveraged by the so-called patent trolls, com-

    panies that patent potentially valuable inventions and then wait until another

    firm develops a technology that infringes its patents. The troll then brings suit,

    demanding license fees or some other compensation. An example is Jerome

    Lemelsons invention of a toy race car track including vertical loops. Lemelson

    later claimed that Mattel Inc.s Hot Wheels toy car racing system violated his

    patent. In 1989, a U.S. federal jury ordered Mattel to compensate Lemelson for

    patent infringement.50

    The Complementor Strategy(Stand-Alone Licensing/Technologies of High Cumulativeness)

    In this case (see Figure 3), the vendor develops an invention (t=1) thatis complementary to the prospective buyers technology (if unbeknownst to

    the buyer) and patents it (t=2). In the meantime, this prospective buyer has

    been investing in the complementary technology (t=2), patenting its inventions,

    engaging in cross-licensing agreements with other producers (t=3) (block to

    play), and, possibly, commercializing the technology (t=4). The vendor may

    or may not be interested in cross-licensing. At some point, the buyer becomes

    Licensing Strategies of the New Intellectual Property Vendors

    UNIVERSITY OF CALIFORNIA, BERKELEY VOL. 50,NO.2 WINTER 2008 CMR.BERKELEY.EDU18

    IP

    Vendor

    Prospective

    Buyer

    Invests in

    invention

    Patents

    invention(s)

    (if large patent

    portfolio, block

    to fence)

    t=0 t=1 t=2 t=4

    Ifprospective

    buyer decides

    to license,

    enters into

    license

    contract with

    buyer

    Decides whether

    to license or

    i nvent around

    vendors

    patent(s)

    t=5

    Either develops

    the technologycommercially

    (incurring major

    financial

    exposure)

    or does not

    If decides to

    license

    enters into

    license

    contract

    with vendor

    Continues

    own R&D

    t=3

    License either

    continued or

    terminated

    License either

    continued or

    terminated

    Seeks to

    license out

    invention

    t=6

    FIGURE 2. Time Line One:The Independent Strategy

  • 8/6/2019 Lee Davis CMR Version

    15/28

    aware that the vendors patent covers an invention to which it musthave access

    if it is to continue with its own development and production activitiesperhaps

    when the vendor approaches it and asks for a license (t=5). The buyer realizes

    it faces major financial exposure by notdealing with the vendor. It enters into

    a license agreement or compensates the vendor in some other way (t=6). After

    settling with the vendor, the buyer continues with its R&D and manufacturing

    agenda (t=7).

    In this case, the IP provider leverages its patent(s) to create value because

    other firms working in the area of the patented technology cannot proceed

    without licensing. This is different from Strategy 1, where the buyer may or may

    not decide to license.

    IP vendors that pursue the complementorlicensing strategy typically work

    in the areas of software and electronics. Many are small, entrepreneurial ven-

    tures, including university spin-offs. Systemonic, a wireless chip company,

    provides a good illustration. The company was founded in 1999 by Gerhard

    Fettweis, professor of mobile telecommunications at the Technical University of

    Dresden. Fettweis was an expert in digital signal processors (DSPs), a special chip

    critical to communications applications. Systemonic later licensed its intellectual

    property to the large telecommunications and consumer electronics

    companies.51

    This category also includes numerous patent trolls. If the vendor is a

    troll, t=5 may well take the form of a lawsuit, threatening the producer of the

    Licensing Strategies of the New Intellectual Property Vendors

    CALIFORNIA MANAGEMENT REVIEW VOL.50,NO. 2 WINTER 2008 CMR.BERKELEY.EDU 19

    FIGURE 3. Time Line Two:The ComplementorStrategy

    Invests ininvention

    complemen-tary to thebuyerstechnology

    Patentsinvention(s);non-trolls:block to play

    t=0 t=2 t=3 t=4

    Asks buyer to

    license the rightsto the inventionorpay othercompensation

    t=5

    Realizes it facesmajor financialexposure bynot

    dealing with thevendor. Licensesthe rights to theinvention or givesthe vendor othercompensation

    Licenses out theinvention orreceives othercompensation

    t=7

    Develops (and possiblycommercializes)invention(s)

    t=6t=1

    Invests intechnologycomplemen-tary to thevendors

    invention

    Continueswith R&D andmanufacturingagenda

    Patents invention(s)

    (block to play);engages in cross-licensing with otherproducers ofcomplementarytechnologies

    IP

    Vendor

    Prospective

    Buyer

  • 8/6/2019 Lee Davis CMR Version

    16/28

    complementary technology with an injunction, forbidding it to sell the technol-

    ogy until the courts can decide if patent infringement has occurred. The buyer

    has no choice but to reach agreement with the trollunless the costs of settle-ment are greater than the costs of revamping its entire business.

    Recent instances of trolls in action include Eolas, which won $520 million

    from Microsoft after a jury found that certain aspects of Microsofts Internet

    Explorer browser had infringed Eolas patent on a method for displaying

    browser plug-ins.52 Similarly, MercExchange, a small online vendor with three

    patents related to the process of online auctions and shopping, sued eBay for

    patent infringement. An important reason why such trolls have been able to

    flourish concerns the poor quality of the patents concerned, where examiners

    have not insisted on high enough standards defining two key criteria of

    patentability, novelty and non-obviousness.53

    The Directed Strategy(Licensing Plus/Technologies of Low Cumulativeness)

    Here, the IP firm invests in an invention (t=1) and patents it (t=2), as

    illustrated in Figure 4, employing a block to fence approach if it possesses a

    sufficiently large patent portfolio. At t=3, vendor and buyer enter into a contract

    that includes the license as well as other R&D agreements. The vendor continues

    Licensing Strategies of the New Intellectual Property Vendors

    UNIVERSITY OF CALIFORNIA, BERKELEY VOL. 50,NO.2 WINTER 2008 CMR.BERKELEY.EDU20

    FIGURE 4. Time Line Three:The DirectedStrategy

    Invests ininvention

    Patentsinvention(s)(if large patentportfolio,block to fence)

    t=0 t=1 t=2 t=3

    Enters set ofcontracts that:include bothlicense plus jointR&D contractwith milestones,etc.*

    t=4

    Furtherdevelopment

    t=5

    Success orfailure inachievingmilestones

    Reviewsresults

    t=6

    Either developsthe technologycommercially(incurring majorfinancialexposure) ordoes not

    Investmentssupportingvendorsfurtherdevelopment

    t=7

    Contractualrelationshipeithercontinued orterminated.Possiblynewlicenses anddevelopmentcontracts

    Enters set of contracts that:include both license plus

    joint R&D contract withmilestones, etc.

    Contractualrelationship

    eithercontinued orterminated.Possiblynewlicenses anddevelopmentcontracts

    IP

    Vendor

    Prospective

    Buyer

    *These can include possible equity purchase of IP vendor shares, establishment of management committees, etc.

  • 8/6/2019 Lee Davis CMR Version

    17/28

    to devote resources to developing the invention (t=4). Contractual milestones

    indicate whether the arrangement is proceeding satisfactorily (t=5). The buyer

    either develops the technology commercially (incurring financial exposure), or

    does not (perhaps waiting for a resolution of technical or market uncertainty)

    (t=6). The parties may also expand their contractual relationship. If the originalagreement is discontinued (t=7), the parties lose their contract-specific invest-

    ments, but can go their separate ways.

    This approach can be illustrated by the California-based Mojave Aero-

    space Ventures (MAV), which won the Ansari X prize for the development of

    a reusable rocket to carry passengers to the edge of the earths atmosphere and

    back. In 2004, MAV and Sir Richard Bransons new company, Virgin Galactic,

    entered into a licensing and joint venture agreement to develop a commercially

    viable suborbital spacecraft, launching a new era of space tourism.54 The directed

    strategy may also be pursued by independentvendors (Strategy 1) interested in a

    more relational contract. For example, in May 1992, Orbital announced that it

    would develop a high performance, two-stroke V6 engine in cooperation withthe British carmaker Jaguar. In May 2005, Ultra-Scan announced the formation

    of a joint venture with the computer security company US Biometrics Corp., to

    further elaborate Ultra-Scans fingerprinting technology to provide health pro-

    fessionals with secure access to hospital computer workstations.55

    Strategy 3 is particularly suitable for small biotech IP vendors. For exam-

    ple, in December 2003, the Danish biotechnology firm NeuroSearch and the

    British pharmaceutical corporation GlaxoSmithKline (GSK), announced a five-

    year research and development alliance covering a number of programs on the

    treatment of diseases of the central nervous system, and ion channel drug dis-

    covery and development. GSK obtained access to new drug candidates in Neu-

    roSearchs pipeline, and the option to license them. NeuroSearch received EUR

    82 billion in guaranteed payments (in the form of upfront payments and sharesto be issued to GSK). NeuroSearch could receive further milestone payments

    based on the successful development of its drug candidates, and royalties on

    sales of successfully launched compounds. If GSK did not exercise its license

    options, NeuroSearch would be free to further develop the drugs as they wished.

    In November 2006, the two companies agreed to expand the scope of this agree-

    ment (t=7).

    Since drug discovery programs sometimes run into problems concerning

    safety or lack of efficacy, it may be necessary to discontinue the cooperation. A

    case in point is NeuroSearchs development contract in December 2000 with the

    Spanish pharmaceutical company Grupo Ferrer for a drug targeted to treat anxi-

    ety (NS 2710). NeuroSearchs early clinical trials had indicated that the drug

    might cause skin rashes. Grupo Ferrer completed a clinical safety study, confirm-

    ing that there was a serious problem with skin rashes. As a result, the two com-

    panies decided not to continue, terminating the contract (t=6).56

    Licensing Strategies of the New Intellectual Property Vendors

    CALIFORNIA MANAGEMENT REVIEW VOL.50,NO. 2 WINTER 2008 CMR.BERKELEY.EDU 21

  • 8/6/2019 Lee Davis CMR Version

    18/28

    The Reciprocal Knowledge-Sharing Strategy(Licensing Plus/Technologies of High Cumulativeness)

    Finally, in the reciprocal knowledge-sharing strategy, as illustrated by ARM

    Holdings, the inventor enters into a complex licensing and product development

    agreement with several or many market participants. These can potentially

    include suppliers, competitors, and customers. The vendor develops and patents

    the invention at t=1 (see Figure 5) and searches for potential partners with

    whom to cross-license at t=2. In the meantime, the would-be buyer has been

    developing and patenting a complementary technology. Both parties use patents

    to block to play. The goal is the rapid diffusion of the technology. Both enter

    into a cross-licensing contract or contracts, supplemented by other forms of R&Dcollaboration, at t=3. Both invest in the further elaboration of their technologies

    (t=4), both incur major financial exposure in relation to the joint effort, and

    both engage in extensive mutual feedback (t=5). Moving along the time line to

    t=8, reciprocal knowledge-sharing enables further cross-licensing and continu-

    ous improvements to the technology.

    Licensing Strategies of the New Intellectual Property Vendors

    UNIVERSITY OF CALIFORNIA, BERKELEY VOL. 50,NO.2 WINTER 2008 CMR.BERKELEY.EDU22

    FIGURE 5. Time Line Four: The Reciprocal Knowledge-SharingStrategy

    Develops and patentsinvention(s) complemen-tary to the buyersinvention (block to play)

    t=0 t=1 t=2 t=3

    Enterscross-licensing/R&Dcontracts

    Enterscross-licensing/R&Dcontract

    t=4

    Invests in furtherreciprocalinnovation,incurring majorfinancialexposure

    t=5

    Provides newideas/receivesfeedback

    t=6

    Invests inimprovements

    t=7

    Furtherfeedback

    Contractualrelationshipcontinued,expandedor contested

    t=8

    Invests in furtherreciprocal

    innovation,incurring majorfinancialexposure

    Invests inimprovements

    Provides newideas/receivesfeedback

    Furtherfeedback

    Contractualrelationshipcontinued,expandedor contested

    Searches forpotentialpartners forcross-licensee(s)

    Invests in andpatents invention(s)complementary tothe vendorsinvention(block to play)engages in cross-

    licensing with otherproducers ofcomplementarytechnologies

    IP

    Vendor

    Prospective

    Buyer

  • 8/6/2019 Lee Davis CMR Version

    19/28

    A second instance of this approach is Cambridge Display Technologies

    (CDT), launched in 1992 as a Cambridge University spin-off. CDT specializes in

    the innovation of light-emitting polymers, which can be applied in a variety of

    products, including calculators, cellular phones, and laptop computer screen

    displays. The company soon became the global leader in this technology. How-ever, when CDT tried to manufacture and market products incorporating its

    technology, it nearly went bankrupt. As a result, CDT changed its business

    model, entering into licensing and co-development and manufacturing deals

    with established companies such as Philips Electronics, Seiko-Epson, Hoechst,

    and DuPont. CDTs partners could then apply their complementary skills to the

    technology to develop specific products for their own markets.57

    While these examples are from the electronics industry, reciprocal knowl-

    edge-sharing agreements are also increasingly seen in biotechnology, in areas

    where webs of interlocking technologies necessitate complex forms of contract-

    ing. For example, in February 2005, the Australian biotech company Benitec,

    Ltd., a leading RNA interference (virus-destroying) therapeutics company, andthe CombiMatrix Group, a Seattle-based biotechnology company specializing in

    electrochemical manufacturing, signed a broad cross-licensing and collaboration

    agreement. Benitec received the right to use certain therapeutic agents against

    viral diseases, along with genetic treatments for HIV, developed by CombiMatrix.

    In return, Benitec granted CombiMatrix the license rights to its IP portfolio of

    ten issued and sixty pending patents covering the treatment or prevention of

    illnesses caused when human beings are exposed to biological, chemical,

    radioactive, and other weapons. Other collaborative projects were included

    in the deal.58

    Strategy 4 agreements are often continued and expandedbut they may

    also be violently contested in huge legal battles if the parties fall out. Consider

    the story of Qualcomm, founded in 1985 in San Diego, California by sevenindustry veterans. Four years later, Qualcomm introduced its basic Code Division

    Multiple Access (CDMA) technology for wireless and data products. Qualcomms

    current licensing program enables third parties to design, manufacture, and sell

    products based on this technology. By 2007, over 130 telecommunications

    equipment manufacturers around the world had cross-licensed the rights to

    the companys essential CDMA patents.59

    However, extensive cross-licensing agreements provide no guarantee

    of continued successor of harmonious relationships between the parties. For

    example, Qualcomms CDMA technology was initially used in all Nokia cell

    phones. However, Nokia then sought a reduction in the license fees it was pay-

    ing. In 2005, Qualcomm filed a patent infringement suit against Nokia. In 2007,

    Nokia hit back, filing its own infringement suit against Qualcomm. Both asked

    the U.S. International Trade Commission to ban the import of the other com-

    panys products.60

    Licensing Strategies of the New Intellectual Property Vendors

    CALIFORNIA MANAGEMENT REVIEW VOL.50,NO. 2 WINTER 2008 CMR.BERKELEY.EDU 23

  • 8/6/2019 Lee Davis CMR Version

    20/28

    Implications and Conclusion

    Managers of IP vendors can use this typology to guide them in deciding

    what licensing strategy would be best for them. Does it make more sense to use

    the license to extract royalties, or to see it more as a building block in establish-ing in a longer-term relationship with the licensee? Managerial choices are also

    constrained by the nature of the technology (the degree of cumulativeness).

    Success will depend on how effectively managers deal with the five sources of

    market imperfections described earlier (appropriability hazards, the costs of tech-

    nology transfer, market and technical uncertainty, agency problems, and small

    numbers bargaining) through the contractual agreement(s)and at what cost.

    For example, managers that pursue the independent strategy (Strategy

    1) can reduce appropriability hazards by securing tight proprietary control.

    However, this approach will also raise the costs the licensee must bear in inte-

    grating the vendors technology into its own production. Technical and market

    uncertainty may well be high, with a risk of incurring the not invented here

    syndrome. The buyer might also hesitate to trade given the possibility of oppor-

    tunistic vendor behavior due to non-observability of the vendors inventive

    process, and small numbers bargaining. Such vendors preserve their indepen-

    dence but run the risk that no one will further develop the invention. The ven-

    dor can help to reduce these costs by being willing to share information with

    the buyer about its product development and test procedures and its own under-

    standing of the market, and/or organizational arrangements such as personnel

    exchanges, giving the would-be buyer direct access to its operations.

    Managers of complementor patent trolls (Strategy 2) stand to hit the jack-

    pot if they succeed. However, if no one infringes their patent, or if their patent

    infringement suit fails, they get nothing, not even license royalties. Ironically,

    there may even be costs to winning. Recently, NTP was itself sued by a softwaredeveloper who claims that he did much of the work behind NTPs patents, and

    so claimed to deserve a share of the RIM settlement.61

    Managers of vendors that employ the directed strategy (Strategy 3) can

    reduce appropriability hazards by using patents to specify the division of prop-

    erty rights with the buyer in the broader product development process. Vendor

    and buyer share the costs related to technical uncertainty and technology trans-

    fer. Because the license supports a continuing relationship, agency costs are rela-

    tively low. However, if the relationship breaks down, the vendor will incur high

    transaction costs in switching to an alternative buyer. Hostage-like arrange-

    ments such as bilateral investments, along with personnel exchanges, might

    decrease these hazards.

    The reciprocal knowledge-sharing strategy (Strategy 4) offers the greatest

    potential to reduce all five sources of market imperfections, since vendor and

    buyer will be closely cooperating throughout the development process, aligning

    their incentives. The parties can observe each others behavior relatively easily.

    However, managers of Strategy 4 (and Strategy 3) vendors also risk being locked

    into outdated technologies to the degree that their customers miss emerging

    Licensing Strategies of the New Intellectual Property Vendors

    UNIVERSITY OF CALIFORNIA, BERKELEY VOL. 50,NO.2 WINTER 2008 CMR.BERKELEY.EDU24

  • 8/6/2019 Lee Davis CMR Version

    21/28

    market opportunities.62 Where the technology succeeds, they risk costly lawsuits

    and damages if the parties fall out.

    The nature of the IP vendors investment at t=1 can vary. This investment

    might be substantial (as in biotech) or minimal (as in toy race car tracks). The

    specificity of the property rights being licensed may be clear or somewhat fuzzy.

    Many patents, for example, lack a demonstration of prior knowledge. In some

    areas, particularly software, patents are relatively non-specific as to the inven-

    tions design and specification. This can create problems for licensing contracts

    and fertile conditions for patent trolls.

    The number of patents required for successful vending can be phenome-

    nal. By 2007, for example, Qualcomms patent portfolio included some 6,100

    United States patents and patent applications for CDMA and related technolo-

    gies. Such patenting costs can seem exorbitant. Yet without an impregnable

    patent position, the vendors bargaining stance will be too weak.

    Since the typology used here is at the level of the individual license trans-

    action, and not the firm, vendors may also pursue two or more different licens-ing strategies, depending on the characteristics of the invention concerned. Thus

    Orbital Corporation and Ultra-Scan, as described above, have pursued both inde-

    pendent and directed approaches to licensing. Some vendors have moved out of

    our framework altogether. Genentech now engages in production and commer-

    cialization, as well as inventioneven licensing in inventions from its own IP

    vendors. Systemonic became a semiconductor manufacturer.

    An alternative to trading with an IP vendor is to acquire it. As emphasized

    by transaction cost economists, for transactions with high levels of asset speci-

    ficity, frequency, and uncertainty (IP vendors inventions typically rank high on

    all three counts), the most efficient governance structure should be internaliza-

    tion. Further benefits of internalization include reducing the risk of imitation,

    and the costs of technology transfer. Philips, for example, exercised this option

    when it bought Systemonic in 2003.63

    IP vendors can provide an efficient way for society to expand the sum

    total of inventions available for commercial exploitation, reaping the benefits

    of increased specialization. Yet it might also mean that valuable ideas are not

    effectively exploited. Orbital Corporation, for example, has earned handsomely

    from its investments in IP. However, because the environmentally friendly fuel

    injection system was never actually used commercially by the major automak-

    ers, an important societal benefit may have been lost. Instead of using non-

    exclusive licensing to maximize royalty earnings, Orbital could have entered into

    an exclusive license agreement with a single automobile manufacturer. How-

    ever, Orbital may have rejected this approach precisely because it wished to con-tinue to be an independent IP vendor. Ironically, its insistence on non-exclusive

    licenses might have ensured that no automobile manufacturer would ultimately

    be interested, since no one could earn the high rents made possible by an exclu-

    sive license.

    Managers can effectively deal with lurking patent trolls by searching

    patent databases in the area of their technological trajectory early on. If they

    Licensing Strategies of the New Intellectual Property Vendors

    CALIFORNIA MANAGEMENT REVIEW VOL.50,NO. 2 WINTER 2008 CMR.BERKELEY.EDU 25

  • 8/6/2019 Lee Davis CMR Version

    22/28

    unmask a troll, they can try to invent around its patents before their investment

    costs have been sunk. Possibly this enhanced risk of discovery might even

    encourage trolls to move to one of the relational boxes in the matrixin

    which case, they would cease to be trolls.64

    As with any model, which by definition must simplify to identify the

    essence of a strategy, the typology used here is not absolute. Some strategies do

    not easily fit into a given category. The pharmaceutical industry, for example,

    has traditionally specialized in discrete technologies (technologies of low cumu-

    lativeness). With the recent developments in biotechnology, however, cross-

    licensing deals have become more prevalent. Thus the Dutch biotechnology

    company Crucell N.V. and the pharmaceutical giant Merck & Co. signed a cross-

    licensing agreement giving Merck access to several of Crucells inventions in

    vaccine technology, and giving Crucell access to Mercks large-scale manufactur-

    ing technology for vaccines.65 This arguably represents a hybrid of Strategies 3

    and 4.

    Most IP vendors start out on the left side of our matrix. However, rela-tional rents can only be earned by vendors on the right hand side. Many of the

    IP vendors discussed above, including ARM and Cambridge Display Technolo-

    gies, began as university spin-offs, and their very early licensing strategies fall

    under Strategy 2. As they grew in size and experience, they moved towards

    more ambitious goals (Strategy 4). Had they become stuck in the comple-

    mentor strategy, they might never have achieved their full potential. Relational

    rents, nevertheless, depend on the continued strength of the relationship. As

    our Qualcomm case demonstrates, extensive cross-licensing agreements can

    also lead to considerable acrimony and efforts on the part of both companies

    to extract rents via lawsuits.

    Finally, managers of IP vendors must understand that while they face

    some risk of financial exposure after contracting for the commercial develop-

    ment of their inventions, the real risk is faced by the buyer. After signing the

    contract, the relationship between the two parties becomes asymmetrical. The

    vendor continues to earn license fees, even if the invention is not developed

    commercially. However, the buyer needs to be assured, as far as possible, that

    its future investments will not be compromised due to vendor opportunism or

    other uncertainties.

    Notes

    1. See , accessed on October 15, 2007; Andre Morkel and Kelvin

    Willoughby, Orbital Engine Corporation, teaching case, 1992. The company changed its

    name to Orbital Corporation in October 2004.2. In addition to RISC chips, ARMs product offering currently includes processors, physical IP,

    cache and SoC designs, application-specific standard products (ASSPs), and related software

    and development tools. Its technology is used in digital applications ranging from wireless,

    networking, and consumer entertainment solutions to imaging, automotive, security, and

    storage devices. See , accessed on October 15, 2007; Eleanor OKeeffe,

    ARM Holdings Plc., teaching case, INSEAD-EAC, Singapore, 2002.

    3. RIM agreed to pay even though the U.S. Patent and Trademark Office, in a preliminary

    ruling, had found all five of NTPs patents invalid. Nor did NTP provide e-mail service or

    Licensing Strategies of the New Intellectual Property Vendors

    UNIVERSITY OF CALIFORNIA, BERKELEY VOL. 50,NO.2 WINTER 2008 CMR.BERKELEY.EDU26

  • 8/6/2019 Lee Davis CMR Version

    23/28

    compete with RIM. See Keith E. Maskus, Reforming U.S. Patent Policy: Getting the Incen-

    tives Right, Council on Foreign Relations Report, CSR No. 19, November 2006, p. 5.

    4. David J. Teece. Capturing Value from Knowledge Assets: The New Economy, Markets for

    Know-How, and Intangible Assets, California Management Review, 40/3 (Spring 1998): 55-79.

    5. Andrew B. Hargadon, Firms as Knowledge Brokers: Lessons in Pursuing Continuous Inno-

    vation, California Management Review, 40/3 (Spring 1998): 209-227.6. See, for example, Ulrich Lichtenthaler, The Drivers of Technology Licensing: An Industry

    Comparison, California Management Review, 49/4 (Summer 2007): 67-89; Ashish Arora and

    Andrea Fosfuri, Licensing the Market for Technology, Journal of Economic Behavior & Organi-

    zation, 52/2 (October 2003): 277-295; Bernard Guilhon, Raja Attia, and Roland Rizoulieres,

    Markets for Technology and Firms Strategies: The Case of the Semiconductor Industry,

    International Journal of Technology Management, 27/2-3 (2004): 123-142; Tamara Nanayakkara,

    Negotiating Technology Licensing Agreements, International Trade Forum, 4 (2002): 13. A

    wide variety of license arrangements may be negotiated. Some licenses are restricted to

    particular markets, for example. Some contain provisions that obligate the licensee to share

    information regarding any improvements made in the licensed technology, often free of

    charge.

    7. Hargadon, op. cit.

    8. Ashish Arora, Andrea Fosfuri, and Alfonso Gambardella, Markets for Technology and Their

    Implications for Corporate Strategy, Industrial and Corporate Change, 10/2 (June 2001): 419-

    451.9. Joshua S. Gans and Scott Stern, The Product Market and the Market for Ideas: Commer-

    cialization Strategies for Technology Entrepreneurs, Research Policy, 32/2 (February 2003):

    333-350. It might be noted that the concept market for ideas is not new; it was used over

    thirty years ago by Ronald H. Coase, in The Economics of the First Amendment: The Mar-

    ket for Goods and the Market for Ideas,American Economic Review, 64/2 (1974): 384-391.

    However, Coase was analyzing the economics of the First Amendment of the U.S. constitu-

    tion, not the tradability of ideas among firms.

    10. The term invention factories was coined by Hargadon, op. cit.

    11. See for example Arora, Fosfuri, and Gambardella, op. cit.; Oliver Williamson, The Economic

    Institutions of Capitalism (New York, NY: The Free Press, 1985); Oliver Williamson, Compara-

    tive Economic Organization: The Analysis of Discrete Structural Alternatives, Administrative

    Science Quarterly, 36/2 (June 1991): 269-296; Kwaku Atuahene-Gima, Inward Technology

    Licensing as an Alternative to Internal R&D in New Product Development: A Conceptual

    Framework, The Journal of Product Innovation Management, 9/2 (June 1992): 156-167; Toru

    Yoshikawa, Technology Development and Acquisition Strategy, International Journal of

    Technology, 25/6-7 (2003): 666-674.

    12. Lichtenthaler, op. cit.

    13. Alvin K. Klevorick, Richard C. Levin, Richard R. Nelson, and Sidney G. Winter, On the

    Sources and Significance of Inter-Industry Differences in Technological Opportunities,

    Research Policy, 24/2 (March 1995): 185-205.

    14. Dorothy Leonard-Barton, Core Capabilities and Core Rigidities: A Paradox in Managing

    New Product Development, Strategic Management Journal, 13/5 (Summer 1992): 111-125.

    15. See, for example, Adam B. Jaffe and Josh Lerner, Innovation and its Discontents (Princeton, NJ:

    Princeton University Press, 2004); Carlos A. Primo Braga, Trade-Related Intellectual Prop-

    erty Issues: The Uruguay Round Agreement and Its Economic Implications, in Will Martin

    and L. Alan Winters, ed., The Uruguay Round and the Developing Economies, World Bank

    Discussion Papers, Washington, D.C., 1995, pp. 381-411.

    16. See, for example, Peter C. Grindley and David J. Teece, Managing Intellectual Capital:

    Licensing and Cross-Licensing in Semiconductors and Electronics, California Management

    Review, 39/2 (Winter 1997): 8-41; Kevin G. Rivette and David Kline, Rembrandts in the Attic:

    Unlocking the Hidden Value of Patents (Boston, MA: Harvard University Press, 2000).17. Farok Contractor, International Technology Licensing: Compensation, Costs, and Negotiation (Lex-

    ington, MA: Lexington Books, 1981); Richard Caves, H. Crookel, and J.P. Killing, The

    Imperfect Market for Technology Licensing, Oxford Bulletin of Economics and Statistics, 45/3

    (1983): 249-267.

    18. David J. Teece, Profiting from Technological Innovation: Implications for Integration, Col-

    laboration, Licensing and Public Policy, Research Policy, 15/6 (1986): 285-305.

    19. John Hagedoorn, Sharing Intellectual Property RightsAn Exploratory Study of Joint

    Patenting Amongst Companies, Industrial and Corporate Change, 12/5 (October 2003): 1035-

    Licensing Strategies of the New Intellectual Property Vendors

    CALIFORNIA MANAGEMENT REVIEW VOL.50,NO. 2 WINTER 2008 CMR.BERKELEY.EDU 27

  • 8/6/2019 Lee Davis CMR Version

    24/28

    1050; Holger Kollmer and Michael Dowling, Licensing as a Commercialization Strategy for

    New Technology-Based Firms, Research Policy, 33/8 (2004): 1141-1151; Klevorick et al., op.

    cit. Teece himself, in his 1998 contribution [op. cit.], argues that when firms compete in

    markets for know-how, there can be advantages to R&D collaborations (though he empha-

    sizes that idea tradability is still difficult).

    20. See for example, Ashish Arora, Licensing Tacit Knowledge: Intellectual Property Rights andthe Market of Know-How, Economics of Innovation and New Technology, 4 (1995): 41-79; Jay

    Pil Choi, Technology Transfer with Moral Hazard, International Journal of Industrial Organi-

    zation, 19/1-2 (January 2000): 241-267; Bruce A. Larson and Margot Anderson, Technol-

    ogy Transfer, Licensing Contracts, and Incentives for Further Innovation, American Journal

    of Agricultural Economics, 76/3 (August 1994): 547-556; Ines Macho-Stadler, Xavier Martinez-

    Giralt, and David Perez-Castrillo, The Role of Information in Licensing Contract Design,

    Research Policy, 25 (1996): 43-57.

    21. Arora, Fosfuri, and Gambardella, op. cit.

    22. Ashish Arora and Robert P. Merges, Specialized Supply Firms, Property Rights and Firm

    Boundaries, Industrial and Corporate Change, 13/3 (2004): 451-475.

    23. Gary P. Pisano, The R&D Boundaries of the Firm: An Empirical Analysis,Administrative

    Science Quarterly, 35/1 (March 1990): 153-176. This conundrum was first explored by Ken-

    neth A. Arrow, Economic Welfare and the Allocation of Resources for Invention, in Uni-

    versities-National Bureau of Economic Research, The Rate and Direction of Inventive Activity:

    Economic and Social Factors, Conference No. 13 (Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press1962).

    24. Gans and Stern, op. cit. While Kearns is often seen as the victim here, he in fact could have

    done much more to position himself more favorably in relation to Ford and the other auto-

    makers, saving himself (and everyone else) the stress of decades of lawsuits. See Jerome

    Davis and Lee Davis, The Mad Max Puzzle: Positioning and the Lone Inventor, in Lars

    Fuglsang, ed., Innovation and the Creative Process (London: Edward Elgar, 2007).

    25. Teece (1998), op. cit.

    26. Wesley M. Cohen and Daniel A. Levinthal, Innovation and Learning: The Two Faces of

    R&D, Economic Journal, 99/397 (1989): 569-596. Information may also be sticky, to the

    degree that it is costly to transfer from one place to another. See Eric Von Hippel, Sticky

    Information and the Locus of Problem Solving: Implications for Innovation,Management

    Science, 40/4 (April 1994): 429-439.

    27. Klaus Kultti and Thomas Takalo, T. Hold-Ups and Asymmetric Information in a Technology

    Transfer: The Micronas Case, Journal of Technology Transfer, 27/3 (June 2002): 233-243.

    28. Thursby has analyzed the risk that a licensee might shelve an invention by a university

    researcher, and what contractual solutions exist. This logic can readily be extended to IP

    firms. See Marie Thursby, Shirking, Sharing Risk, and Shelving: The Role of University

    License Contracts, Paper presented to the Summer Conference of the Danish Research Unit for

    Industrial Dynamics, Copenhagen, June 27-29, 2005. Available via the DRUID homepage,

    .

    29. See Williamson (1985) and (1991), op. cit.

    30. The automakers had to pay 30-40 Australian dollars per engine, as opposed to the industry

    rate of about 1 Australian dollar. See Morkel and Willoughby, op. cit. For recent develop-

    ments, see , accessed on October 15, 2007.

    31. OKeeffe, op. cit.; Maija Palmer, Arm Bolstered by Royalty Revenues, Financial Times, April

    20, 2006, p. 21; , accessed on October 15, 2007.

    32. J. Stanley Metcalfe and Michael Gibbons, Technology, Variety, and Organization: A System-

    atic Perspective on the Competitive Process, in R.S. Rosenbloom and R.A. Burgelman,

    Research on Technological Innovation, Management, and Policy (London: 1989), pp. 153-173;

    Nathan Rosenberg, Why Technology Forecasts often Fail, The Futurist, 29/4 (July/August

    1995): 16-21.33. Grindley and Teece, op. cit.; James E. Bessen, Holdup and Licensing of Cumulative Innova-

    tions with Private Information, Economics Letters, 82/3 (March 2004): 321-326.

    34. Kirk Monteverde and David J. Teece, Appropriable Rents and Quasi-Vertical Integration,

    Journal of Law and Economics, 25/2 (October 1982): 321-328. This was demonstrated empiri-

    cally by Klein et al. in their analysis of General Motors decision to buy out Fisher Body in

    the 1920s. Benjamin Klein, Robert G. Crawford, and Armen A. Alchian, Vertical Integra-

    tion, Appropriable Rents, and the Competitive Contracting Process, Journal of Law and

    Economics, 21/2 (October 1978): 297-326.

    Licensing Strategies of the New Intellectual Property Vendors

    UNIVERSITY OF CALIFORNIA, BERKELEY VOL. 50,NO.2 WINTER 2008 CMR.BERKELEY.EDU28

  • 8/6/2019 Lee Davis CMR Version

    25/28

    35. Gans and Stern, op. cit.

    36. Oliver Hart, Firms, Contracts, and Financial Structure (Oxford: Clarendon Press, 1995).

    37. Williamson, op. cit.

    38. See P.H. Rubin,Managing Business Transactions (New York, NY: The Free Press, 1990).

    39. Peter Smith Ring and Andrew Y. Van de Ven, Structuring Cooperative Relationships

    between Organizations, Strategic Management Journal, 13/7 (October 1992): 483-498.40. Jeffrey H. Dyer and Harbir Singh, The Relational View: Cooperative Strategy and Sources of

    Interorganizational Competitive Advantage,Academy of Management Review, 23/4 (October

    1998): 660-679.

    41. Suzanne Scotchmer, Standing on the Shoulders of Giants: Cumulative Research and the

    Patent Law, Journal of Economic Perspectives, 5/1 (Winter 1991): 29-41; Stefano Breschi,

    Franco Malerba and Luigi Orsenigo, Technological Regimes and Schumpeterian Patterns of

    Innovation, Economic Journal, 110/463 (April 2000): 388-410; Robert P. Merges and Richard

    R. Nelson, On Limiting or Encouraging Rivalry in Technical Progress: The Effect of Patent

    Scope Decisions, Journal of Economic Behavior and Organization, 25/1 (September 1994): 1-24.

    42. Royalty payments are adjusted to reflect the overall contributions of the different parties to

    the agreement. See Grindley and Teece, op. cit.

    43. Franco Malerba and Luigi Orsenigo, Innovation and Market Structure in the Dynamics of

    the Pharmaceutical Industry and Biotechnology: Towards a History-Friendly Model, Indus-

    trial and Corporate Change, 11/4 (August 2002): 667-703.

    44. Biotech firms may experience difficulties in contracting for access to specific research tools.Some scholars have expressed concerns that this situation has led to an anti-commons

    problem. See especially Rebecca S. Eisenberg, Bargaining Over the Transfer of Proprietary

    Research Tools: Is this Market Failing or Emerging? in Rochelle C. Dreyfuss, Diane L. Zim-

    merman, and Harry First, Expanding the Boundaries of Intellectual Property (Oxford: Oxford

    University Press, 2001), pp. 223-249. Other scholars find only limited evidence of an anti-

    commons problem in practice, though problems of hold-up may well exist between particu-

    lar buyers and sellers. See John P. Walsh, Ashish Arora, and Wesley M. Cohen, Research

    Tool Patenting and Licensing and Biomedical Innovation, in W.M. Cohen and S.A. Merrill,

    eds., Patents in the Knowledge-Based Economy (Washington, D.C. National Academies Press,

    2003).

    45. In Phase I clinical trials, the new drug or treatment is tested on a small group of people (20-

    80) for the first time to evaluate its safety, determine the safe dosage, and see what side

    effects exist. In Phase II, it is given to a larger group (100-300), and in Phase III, to an even

    larger group (1,000-3,000) to further evaluate its safety and effectiveness. See , accessed on October 15, 2007.

    46. See especially Wesley M. Cohen, Richard R. Nelson, and John P. Walsh, Protecting their

    Intellectual Assets: Appropriability Conditions and Why U.S. Manufacturing Firms Patent

    (or Not), NBER Working Paper, Cambridge, MA, 2000; Wesley Cohen, Akira Goto, Akiya

    Nagata, Richard R. Nelson, and John P. Walsh, R&D Spillovers, Patents and the Incentives

    to Innovate in Japan and the United States, Research Policy, 31/8-9 (December 2002): 1349-

    1367.

    47. Malerba and Orsenigo, op. cit.

    48. Grindley and Teece, op. cit.

    49. Fred O. Williams, Amherst, N.Y-Based Ultra-Scan Considers IPO, Knight Ridder Tribune

    Business News, October 4, 2002, p. 1; , accessed on October 15, 2007.

    50. Sarah Chapin Columbia and Stacy L. Blasberg, Beware Patent Trolls, Risk Management

    Magazine, 53/4 (April 2006): 22-27. All in all, Lemelson received 562 U.S. patents on tech-

    nologies ranging from automated manufacturing systems to bar code readers, video cameras,

    and facsimile machines. Beginning in the 1970s, he brought patent infringement suits

    against numerous major U.S. corporations including General Motors, IBM, General Electric,

    and Zenith, reportedly reaping hundreds of millions of dollars in royalties and court awards.See also William F. Heinze and Harry Goldstein, Dead Patents Walking, IEEE Spectrum,

    39/5 (May 2002): 52-54.

    51. Katherine Campbell, A Chip Spun off the US Block: Venture Capital: Katharine Campbell

    Looks at a German Universitys Pioneering Spin-Off, Financial Times, December 7, 2000,

    p. 18.

    52. See Patricia S. Abril and Robert Plant, The Patent Holders Dilemma: Buy, Sell, or Troll?

    Communications of the ACM, 50/1 (January 2007): 37-44.

    53. Jaffe and Lerner, op. cit.

    Licensing Strategies of the New Intellectual Property Vendors

    CALIFORNIA MANAGEMENT REVIEW VOL.50,NO. 2 WINTER 2008 CMR.BERKELEY.EDU 29

  • 8/6/2019 Lee Davis CMR Version

    26/28

    54. MAV also made an agreement with Scaled Composites, which had been central to the devel-

    opment of the craft, to utilize the technology to build new spaceships to carry passengers

    into space. One small step for space tourism . . . , The Economist, December 18, 2004,

    pp. 141-142, , accessed on October 15, 2007.

    55. See , accessed on October 15, 2007.

    56. These details are based on press releases from the companies concerned. For further infor-mation, see , accessed on October 15, 2007.

    57. Arora, Fosfuri, and Gambardella, op. cit.; , accessed on October 15,

    2007.

    58. CombiMatrix and Benitec Enter Cross-Licensing and Collaboration Agreement, Nanotech-

    wire, February 22, 2005, available at ,

    accessed on October 8, 2007. See also and

    .

    59. Arora, Fosfuri and Gambardella, op. cit.; , accessed on October 17,

    2007.

    60. See Nancy Gohring, Qualcomm Files Patent Infringement Suit Against Nokia, IDG News

    Service, November 7, 2005, available at , accessed on

    October 17, 2007; Mark Halper, Nokia vs. Qualcomm, Fortune, December 25, 2006, pp. 23-

    24; Nokia Hits Back at Qualcomm in Patent Row, Computer Business Review, May 25, 2007,

    available at , accessed on October 17, 1007; Telecoms:

    Industry Update, Datamonitor, 6/10 (October 2007): 217-218.61. Arik Hesseldahl, NTP: A Taste of Its Own Medicine, Business Week Online, November 8,

    2006, p. 29. Subsequently, the U.S. Patent and Trademark Office has rejected all five patents

    that formed the basis of NTPs case against RIM. NTP is appealing the ruling.

    62. See Clayton M. Christensen, The Innovators Dilemma (Cambridge, MA: Harvard Business

    School Press, 1997).

    63. Alternately, they may make their own acquisitions. In November 2006, for example, Qual-

    comm bought nPhase LLC, which provides machine-to-machine solutions, helping to rein-

    force Qualcomms position in this market. ,

    accessed on October 15, 2007.

    64. There are also indications that patent trolls are facing a more precarious existence. While

    RIM felt compelled to settle, another would-be troll, MercExchange, was less successful in

    its suit against eBay. In 2006, the U.S. Supreme Court reversed a lower courts ruling sup-

    porting MercExchange and tightened the standards for granting injunctions made at the

    behest of patent trolls. William R. Overend, Patent Injunctions after eBay: The Bidding is

    Open on Who Really Benefits, The Corporate Counselor21/3 (August 2006): 1-2, 7-8.

    65. Merck & Co., Inc. and Crucell Sign Cross-Licensing Agreement on Vaccine Production and

    Technology,Marketwire, December 27, 2006. Available at

    , accessed October 8, 2007.

    Licensing Strategies of the New Intellectual Property Vendors

    UNIVERSITY OF CALIFORNIA, BERKELEY VOL. 50,NO.2 WINTER 2008 CMR.BERKELEY.EDU30

  • 8/6/2019 Lee Davis CMR Version

    27/28

  • 8/6/2019 Lee Davis CMR Version

    28/28