Is Macroeconomics hard? -- Brad DeLong

download Is Macroeconomics hard? -- Brad DeLong

of 8

Transcript of Is Macroeconomics hard? -- Brad DeLong

  • 8/11/2019 Is Macroeconomics hard? -- Brad DeLong

    1/8

    June 28, 2010

    Is Macroeconomics Hard?

    Is Macroeconomics Hard?

    "Math is hard," said Malibu Barbie, famously--and a ton of criticism came down on her for the

    implicit message that her auditors should go off and do other, easier, things instead and leave

    the math to the trained professionals. Is macroeconomics hard in this sense? I confess that I do

    not think so. I think that macro is pretty easy...[1]

    Let's go back in time almost two centuries, to the days when--first after the end of the

    Napoleonic Wars and then in 1825-6--the nascent intellectual community of economists

    confronted the question of whether the circular flow of economic activity as mediated by the

    market system could break down and the economy become afflicted by a "general glut" of

    commodities.

    There was no question that there could be a "glut" of particular commodities. An example may

    make this clear:

    Suppose--this is Berkeley, after all--that households decide that they want to spend less than

    they have been spending on electricity to power large-screen video and audio entertainment

    systems and more on yoga lessons to seek inner peace. The immediate consequence--within

    the "market day," as late-nineteenth century British economist Alfred Marshall would have put

    it--of this shift in preferences is excess demand for yoga instructors and excess supply of

    electric power. Prices of electricity (and of large-screen TVs, and of audio systems) fall as

    unsold inventories pile up in stores and as generators spin down and stand idle. Yogainstructors, by contrast, find themselves overscheduled, working ten-hour days, and stressed

    out--and find the prices they can charge for their lessons going through the roof. Workers in

    electric power distribution and in video and audio production and sales find that they must either

    accept lower wages or find themselves out on the street without jobs.

  • 8/11/2019 Is Macroeconomics hard? -- Brad DeLong

    2/8

    Over time the market system provides individuals with changing incentives that resolve the

    excess-supply excess-demand disequilibrium and restore the economy to equilibrium balance.

    Seeing the fortunes to be earned by teaching yoga, more young people learn to properly regulate

    their svadisthana chakra and teach others to do so. Seeing unemployment and stagnant wages

    in electrical engineering, fewer people major in EECS. The supply of yoga instructors grows. Thesupply of electrical engineers shrinks. Wages of yoga instructors fall back towards normal.

    Wages of electrical engineers rise. And balanced equilibrium is restored.

    Thus we understand how there can be a glut of a particular commodity--in this case, electric

    power. And we understand that it is matched by an excess demand for another commodity--in

    this case, yoga instructor services to properly align your svadisthana chakra.

    But can there be a general glut, a glut of everything?

    Some economists early in the nineteenth century said yes--and that the economy was

    experiencing one, and that the fact that such "general gluts" could manifest themselves was a

    problem with the market system that economists needed to figure out how to solve. Thomas

    Robert Malthus was the most prominent of those who protested. He agreed that the

    then-fashionable economic theory said that a glut in one market had to be balanced by a surplus

    of excess demand in another. But, he said, so much the worse for economic theory:

    Malthus on Ricardo: [A]ccording to [Ricardo's]... theory of profits... the master manufacturers would have been in a

    state of the most extraordinary prosperity, and the rapid accumulation of their capitals would soon have employed

    all the workmen that could have been found. But, instead of this, we hear of glutted markets, falling prices, and

    cotton goods selling at Kamschatka lower than the costs of production. It may be said, perhaps, that the cotton

    trade happens to be glutted and it is a tenet of the new doctrine on profits and demand, that if one trade be

    overstocked with capital, it is a certain sign that some other trade is understocked. But where, I would ask, is there

    any considerable trade that is confessedly under-stocked, and where high profits have been long pleading in vain

    for additional capital? The [Napoleonic] war has now been at an end above four years and though the removal of

    capital generally occasions some partial loss, yet it is seldom long in taking place, if it be tempted to remove by

    great demand and high profits but if it be only discouraged from proceeding in its accustomed course by falling

    profits, while the profits in all other trades, owing to general low prices, are falling at the same time, though not

    perhaps precisely in the same degree, it is highly probable that its motions will be slow and hesitating...

    http://www.google.com/url?q=http%3A%2F%2Foll.libertyfund.org%2F%3Foption%3Dcom_staticxt%26staticfile%3Dshow.php%253Ftitle%3D114%26chapter%3D38404%26layout%3Dhtml%26Itemid%3D27&sa=D&sntz=1&usg=AFQjCNF7e2R-GRIAAWXKIqtiw6NUuU13xg
  • 8/11/2019 Is Macroeconomics hard? -- Brad DeLong

    3/8

    Jean-Baptiste Say defended the theory. He wrote to Malthus claiming that theory was sound, and

    that the idea of a "general glut" was logically inconceivable:

    Letters to Mr. Malthus: I shall not attempt, Sir, to add... in pointing out the just and ingenious observations in your

    book the undertaking would be too laborious.... [And] I should be sorry to annoy either you or the public with dull

    and unprofitable disputes. But, I regret to say, that I find in your doctrines some fundamental principles which...

    would occasion a retrograde movement in a science of which your extensive information and great talents are so

    well calculated to assist the progress.... What is the cause of the general glut of all the markets in the world, to

    which merchandize is incessantly carried to be sold at a loss?... Since the time of Adam Smith, political

    economists have agreed that we do not in reality buy the objects we consume, with the money or circulating coin

    which we pay for them. We must in the first place have bought this money itself by the sale of productions of our

    own. To the proprietor of the mines whence this money is obtained, it is a production with which he purchases

    such commodities as he may have occasion for.... From these premises I had drawn a conclusion... that if certain

    goods remain unsold, it is because other goods are not produced and that it is production alone which opens

    markets to produce.... [W]henever there is a glut, a superabundance, [an excess supply] of several sorts ofmerchandize, it is because other articles [in excess demand] are not produced in sufficient quantities... if those

    who produce the latter could provide more... the former would then find the vent which they required.... You, on the

    contrary, assert that there may be a superabundance of goods of all sorts at once and you adduce several facts in

    favour of your opinion. M. Sismondi had already opposed my doctrine...

    As the young John Stuart Mill put it, the core of the argument of Say, Ricard, and their school

    was that:

    There can never, it is said, be a want of buyers for all commodities because whoever offers a commodity for sale,

    desires to obtain a commodity in exchange for it, and is therefore a buyer by the mere fact of his being a seller. The

    sellers and the buyers, for all commodities taken together, must, by the metaphysical necessity of the case, be an

    exact equipoise to each other and if there be more sellers than buyers of one thing, there must be more buyers

    than sellers for another...

    Thus a general glut was as impossible as a square circle or a solid gas.

    Yet Say changed his mind. By 1829, in his analysis of the British financial panic and recession of

    1825-6, Jean-Baptiste Say was writing that there could indeed be such a thing as a general glut

    http://www.google.com/url?q=http%3A%2F%2Foll.libertyfund.org%2Findex.php%3Foption%3Dcom_staticxt%26staticfile%3Dshow.php%253Ftitle%3D1795%26layout%3Dhtml%23chapter_99253&sa=D&sntz=1&usg=AFQjCNEmrmFFW7Gqnw4hI-viU8zBeFBjnw
  • 8/11/2019 Is Macroeconomics hard? -- Brad DeLong

    4/8

    of commodities after all: "every type of merchandise had sunk below its costs of production, a

    multitude of workers were without work. Many bankruptcies were declared..."

    The general glut, Say wrote in 1829, had been triggered by a panicked financial flight to quality

    which had led the Bank of England to shrink its liabilities:

    The Bank [of England], legally obliged to redeem its banknotes in specie... [t]o limit its losses... forced the return of

    its banknotes, and ceased to put new notes into circulation. It was then obliged to cease to discount commercial

    bills. Provincial banks were in consequence obliged to follow the same course, and commerce found itself

    deprived at a stroke of the advances on which it had counted, be it to create new businesses, or to give a lease of

    life to the old. As the bills that businessmen had discounted came to maturity, they were obliged to meet them, and

    finding no more advances from the bankers, each was forced to use up all the resources at his disposal. They

    sold goods for half what they had cost. Business assets could not be sold at any price. As every type of

    merchandise had sunk below its costs of production, a multitude of workers were without work. Many bankruptcies

    were declared among merchants and among bankers, who having placed more bills in circulation than their

    personal wealth could cover, could no longer find guarantees to cover their issues beyond the undertakings of

    individuals, many of whom had themselves become bankrupt...

    What was going on?

    The answer was nailed by John Stuart Mill in that same year.

    Mill's explanation: there was indeed a "general glut" of newly-produced commodities for sale and

    of workers to hire. But it was also the case that the excess supply of goods, services, and labor

    was balanced by an excess demand elsewhere in the economy. The excess demand was an

    excess demand not for any newly-produced commodity, but instead an excess demand for

    financial assets, for "money":

    Although he who sells, really sells only to buy, he needs not buy at the same moment when he sells... there may

    be, at some given time, a very general inclination to sell with as little delay as possible, accompanied with an

    equally general inclination to defer all purchases as long as possible.... In order to render the argument for the

    impossibility of an excess of all commodities applicable... money must itself be considered as a commodity....

  • 8/11/2019 Is Macroeconomics hard? -- Brad DeLong

    5/8

  • 8/11/2019 Is Macroeconomics hard? -- Brad DeLong

    6/8

    outsidemoney and some inside money are AAA assets) and not of bonds (some of

    which are AAA assets, but not all). You fix a depression by restoring market

    confidence and so shrinking demand for AAA assets and by increasing the supply of

    AAA assets. Eliminating the excess demand for high-quality assets is eliminated will

    bring the goods and labor markets out of excess supply and back into balance.

    From the perspective of this Malthus-Say-Mill framework Keynes's General Theory is a not

    entirely consistent mixture of (1), (2), and (3)...

    Note that these financial market excess demands can have any of a wide variety of causes:

    episodes of irrational panic, the restoration of realistic expectations after a period of irrational

    exuberance, bad news about future profits and technology, bad news about the solvency of

    government or of private corporations, bad government policy that inappropriately shrinks asset

    stocks, et cetera. Nevertheless, in this Malthus-Say-Mill framework it seems as if there is always

    or almost always something that the government can do to affect asset supplies and demands

    that promises a welfare improvement over, say, waiting for prolonged nominal deflation to raise

    the real stock of liquid money, of bonds, or of high-quality AAA assets. Monetary policy open

    market operations swap AAA bonds for money. Quantitative easing that raises expected inflation

    diminishes demand for money and for AAA assets by taxing them. Non-standard monetary policy

    interventions swap risky bonds for AAA bonds or money. Fiscal policy affects both demand for

    goods and labor and the supply of AAA assets--as long as fiscal policy does not crack the statusof government debt as AAA and diminish rather than increasing the supply of AAA assets.

    Government guarantees transform risky bonds into AAA assets. Et cetera...

    And then there are, of course, those who never read their John Stuart Mill of 1829, and who

    never noticed that Jean-Baptiste Say in 1829 had retracted his 1803 claim that a general glut is

    impossible. They continue claim that a depression is not an economic disequilibrium that can be

    cured by proper government policy at all--but rather an economic equilibrium that can only be

    made even less pleasant by government intervention. Think of Karl Marx, Friedrich Hayek,Ludwig von Mises, Andrew Mellon, Robert Lucas, et cetera.

  • 8/11/2019 Is Macroeconomics hard? -- Brad DeLong

    7/8

    This fraction maintains that in a depression there is no excess supply of goods and labor in any

    meaningful sense. But, instead, they say:

    goods and labor markets are in balance--no government policy to raise employment

    and production is welfare-increasing--it is just that technological regress has lowered

    the productivity of labor, and employment is low because real wages are low and

    workers would rather be unemployed or

    goods and labor markets are in balance---no government policy to raise employment

    and production is welfare-increasing--it is just that workers have an increased taste

    for leisure that has raised their reservation wage, and employment is low because

    real wages are high and businesses would rather not hire or

    goods and labor markets are in balance---no government policy to raise employment

    and production is welfare-increasing--it is just that previous overinvestment has given

    us a capital stock that is too large and misallocated, and employment is low because

    workers cannot quickly be redeployed into jobs in the consumption goods sector or

    goods and labor markets are in balance---no government policy to raise employment

    and production is welfare-increasing--it is just that workers have mistaken nominal

    shocks for real shocks, and think that real wages are lower than they are because

    they misperceive the price level.

    It is pretty clear that they are wrong. Indeed, John Stuart Mill and Jean-Baptiste Say back in 1829

    had pretty clear and convincing arguments that this no-disequilibrium fraction is wrong. And Mill's

    and Say's arguments have not become less clear and convincing in the past 180 years.

    I like this Malthus-Say-Mill framework. I think that this framework allows me to at least

    characterize every position on our current macroeconomic dilemmas that I have heard--like, for

    example, that the advocates of austerity are convinced that further debt issue by the U.S.

    government will crack the U.S. Treasury bond's status as a safe asset and thus increase, not

    decrease, the excess demand for AAA assets and increase, not decrease, the excess supply of

    recently-produced commodities and labor.

    And it is not rocket science.

  • 8/11/2019 Is Macroeconomics hard? -- Brad DeLong

    8/8

    But it is, however, cutting-edge economics--cutting edge for 1829, that is.

    [1] People who, along with me, took Olivier Blanchard's Economics 2410b course in spring 1983

    will note how closely this tracks what Olivier was trying to teach us in the three classes--the

    week and a half--he spent on Lloyd Metzler's "Wealth, Savings, and the Rate of Interest." (The

    only distinction Metzler is missing that I think is needed is the distinction between safe and risky

    bonds.) And, of course, Edmond Malinvaud's Theory of Unemployment Reconsidered