INTRODUCTION Dictators, Democrats, and...

40
1 INTRODUCTION Dictators, Democrats, and Government Performance for African Development Book manuscript by A. Carl LeVan, American University As de-colonization neared its end in the 1950’s, a wave of optimism swept across Sub-Saharan Africa. In Nigeria, the jewel of Britain’s African colonies, citizens anxiously embraced the promise of political sovereignty. At his inauguration as governor-general in 1960, Nigeria’s great nationalist, Nnamdi Azikiwe, recited a poem by the African-American author Langston Hughes, called “Youth,” which begins, “We have tomorrow bright before us like a flame/Yesterday a night-gone thing a sun-down name.” Hughes sat in the audience with thousands of Nigerians, all welcoming a new dawn. 1 The incoming government promised massive investment in education and socio-economic development. Voters had peacefully exercised their rights at the polls, foreign investment was pouring in, and the economy was expanding. When a new political generation gathered in the capital half a century later to commemorate that momentous day, militants detonated two bombs near President Goodluck Jonathan, killing a dozen people. Only minutes before, Jonathan had cautiously reflected on Nigeria’s previous five decades, declaring, “There is certainly much to celebrate: our freedom, our strength, our unity and our resilience.” One newspaper called the 2010 bombing “perhaps one of the most unfortunate incidents in the 50 years of Nigerias post-independence history.” 2 Another Nigerian commentary bluntly asked, “Has Nigeria achieved the greatness it was clamoring for at independence? Or is Nigeria a fool at fifty?” 3 1 “Zik Becomes His Excellency,” West Africa, 19 November 1960, p. 1299. 2 Abba Gana Shettima, “Nigeria: Abuja Bomb Blasts – Agony of a Confused Nation,” Daily Trust, 8 October 2010. 3 Lawan Yakubu, “A Requiem for Nigeria?” Daily Trust, 8 October 2010.

Transcript of INTRODUCTION Dictators, Democrats, and...

1

INTRODUCTION

Dictators, Democrats, and Government Performance for African Development

Book manuscript by

A. Carl LeVan, American University

As de-colonization neared its end in the 1950’s, a wave of optimism swept across Sub-Saharan

Africa. In Nigeria, the jewel of Britain’s African colonies, citizens anxiously embraced the

promise of political sovereignty. At his inauguration as governor-general in 1960, Nigeria’s great

nationalist, Nnamdi Azikiwe, recited a poem by the African-American author Langston Hughes,

called “Youth,” which begins, “We have tomorrow bright before us like a flame/Yesterday a

night-gone thing a sun-down name.” Hughes sat in the audience with thousands of Nigerians, all

welcoming a new dawn.1 The incoming government promised massive investment in education

and socio-economic development. Voters had peacefully exercised their rights at the polls,

foreign investment was pouring in, and the economy was expanding.

When a new political generation gathered in the capital half a century later to

commemorate that momentous day, militants detonated two bombs near President Goodluck

Jonathan, killing a dozen people. Only minutes before, Jonathan had cautiously reflected on

Nigeria’s previous five decades, declaring, “There is certainly much to celebrate: our freedom,

our strength, our unity and our resilience.” One newspaper called the 2010 bombing “perhaps

one of the most unfortunate incidents in the 50 years of Nigeria’s post-independence history.”2

Another Nigerian commentary bluntly asked, “Has Nigeria achieved the greatness it was

clamoring for at independence? Or is Nigeria a fool at fifty?”3

1 “Zik Becomes His Excellency,” West Africa, 19 November 1960, p. 1299.

2 Abba Gana Shettima, “Nigeria: Abuja Bomb Blasts – Agony of a Confused Nation,” Daily Trust, 8 October 2010.

3 Lawan Yakubu, “A Requiem for Nigeria?” Daily Trust, 8 October 2010.

2

The answers offered in this book will disappoint the cynics and surprise the optimists. It

is true that the United Nations counts Nigeria among the world’s most underdeveloped nations,

where approximately 90 percent of the population lives on less than $2 per day and the average

life expectancy is less than forty-eight years. Economic growth since the transition to democracy

in 1999 masks significant governance failures, including increases in economic inequality and

extreme poverty (United Nations Development Programme 2009). The country has little to show

for the estimated US$300 billion it has earned from oil exports since the 1970s. When

Transparency International, a global non-governmental organization that monitors corruption,

ranked Nigeria just ahead of low achievers such as Zimbabwe and Mauritania in a 2010 report,

an editorial in one of Nigeria’s leading newspapers lamented, “The fight against corruption has

remained a problematic one, with sloganeering by successive governments and very little else to

show for it.”4

But President Jonathan’s reflections on the 50th

anniversary of independence were not

unfounded. After all, Nigeria survived one of Africa’s most brutal civil wars and five military

coups. It emerged from this violence to become an important regional and global leader in

peacekeeping and diplomacy. The youth literacy rate stands at 87 percent, up from 65 percent in

1985. In the early years after independence, only 5 percent of the nation’s children were enrolled

in primary school; enrollment rates now reach 100 percent in some parts of the country. In

contrast to the high inflation that crippled Nigeria’s booming oil economy in the 1970s and the

subsequent borrowing that funneled export income into interest payments, consumers today face

more predictable prices and the government has rid itself of almost all foreign debt.

Nigeria record seems to validate the claim that development comes through good public

policy. Increased literacy and school enrollment owe much to policies instituted in the 1970s,

4 Editorial, “The Transparency International Corruption Report,” Daily Trust, 1 November 2010.

3

when the federal government called education the “greatest investment that a nation can make

for the development of its economic, political, sociological and human resources.”5 Federal

budget deficits and inflation became less volatile after a reform-minded public finance team

renegotiated or paid off the country’s debts in 2006. Nigeria’s many failings must be viewed

alongside developmental successes that punctuate its post-colonial history.

The question that drives this book is: what factors affect the Nigerian government’s

ability to formulate policies conducive to development? Polices are binding decisions about

public resources, and good government performance means that policy outputs serve a greater

common good over the long term. Comparative studies often blame ethnic diversity, foreign

debt, authoritarianism, or an economy dependent on natural resource exploitation for policy

failures in the developing world. Research on Africa very often adds colonial legacies to this list.

Nigeria possesses many of the qualities associated with policy failure, including a string of

dictatorships, high foreign debt, tremendous ethnic diversity, and a robust oil economy. While

these characteristics are certainly relevant to understanding Nigeria, none of them fully explain

variations in government performance.

Drawing on a historical study of Nigeria since independence, I argue that the structure of

the policy-making process explains variation in government performance better than other

variables. I use the concept of “veto players” to capture this underlying structure, identifying

political actors operating in both formal and informal political settings with the leverage to block

policy change and extract concessions. Using qualitative and quantitative data gathered during

extensive field research, I then empirically link Nigeria’s veto players to patterns in government

performance from 1960 to 2007. Focusing on policies which the development literature

associates with long term economic development, I distinguish between national collective

5 Editorial, “Hard Road for Education,” West Africa, May 21, 1979, p. 871.

4

goods, non-excludable public policies that inherently benefit the country on the whole, and local

collective goods that are more particularistic and might be targeted to specific communities or

interests.

Even after taking into account intervening variables for dictatorship, debt, and oil

revenue, I show that the number of veto players systematically explains Nigerian government

performance in these two broad categories of public policy. But the number of veto players has

differential effects, which leads to an important insight: conditions which impair the delivery of

national collective goods also tend to improve the delivery of local collective goods. Nigeria, like

many African countries, therefore faces what I refer to as a “Madisonian dilemma,” since it has

to balance contradictory effects implicit in the structure of the policy process. Resolving this

dilemma remains a perennial challenge due to cultural and demographic pressures to make the

policy process representative. For example, Nigeria has arguably complicated matters by

adopting some institutions to explicitly represent identities and others intended to transcend

them.

The approach here differs from many single country studies, since it does not attempt to

explain maldistribution or patronage other than what is reported in aggregate national-level

figures. Similarly, it does not attempt to document the quality of governance or changes in the

level of corruption. I instead focus on how the underlying structure of the policy process affects

the government’s ability to deliver policy benefits consumed at different levels. Government

performance in these terms refers to policy outputs directly linked to government decisions, such

as hiring more instructors to teach in public schools. Following Baum and Lake (2003), it also

includes more indirect policy outcomes. After all, even if the government is not a direct provider

of the goods and services in question, it still regulates them and monitors performance. By

5

conceptually organizing regimes based on centers of power, my causal explanation transcends

blunt distinctions between democracy and dictatorship, and contributes to emerging literatures on

authoritarian institutions, political development, and ethnic politics. Veto player analysis

therefore offers a new way of thinking about the causes of suboptimal government performance

in Africa and beyond.

GOVERNMENT PERFORMANCE IN THE LITERATURE

In order to situate this book’s central argument about veto player theory in a proper context, it is

important to review four standard explanations for poor government performance in Africa. Each

of these explanations faces limitations. I begin with a discussion of modernization theory, which

argues that economic and social progress lead to democratization. This theory has experienced a

revival over the last decade, although the persistence of illiberal regimes in a surprising number

of countries across the developing world has kept the debate over modernization theory’s

explanatory value alive. A second, common explanation attributes performance failures to the

relative wealth of the state. Governments with little income have weak capacity due to few

resources to enact good public policies, while governments with substantial revenue from natural

resources perform poorly because citizens lack political leverage to hold government

accountable. In this construction, Africa’s poor countries are doomed either way. A third

explanation blames ethnic diversity for breeding parochialism and clientelism, outcomes that

distort the distribution of resources and ultimately undermine long-term economic growth.

Finally, there is the bad leadership explanation. Political commentators, casual observers, and

scholars often attribute governance successes or failures to leaders’ personal qualities. There is

reason to be skeptical of this formulation. As Tanzania’s first president, Julius Nyerere, said in

1968, “Leadership cannot replace democracy” (Nyerere 1973). This blunt assessment of

6

leadership as process still rings true, affirming the possibilities of comparative politics by

emphasizing the need to understand the systemic factors that impact decision making by

individuals. “For policies to be effective,” writes a leading Nigerian political scientist, “the

process through which they are made and executed has to be rational, sequential and

deliberative” (Jega 2007, 105).

The Regime Type Explanation: Does Democracy Deliver?

When European colonial powers withdrew from Africa in the 1950’s, many Africans hoped that

independence would lead to political development and economic self-sufficiency. The developed

world promised assistance to ease the transition from colonialism to independence, and the new

nationalist governments enjoyed enormous popular support. Decolonization coincided with

democratization. Nationalist movements in Kenya, Tanzania, and elsewhere were reborn as

political parties, and citizens embraced new forms of political participation as the franchise

quickly expanded. By the end of the 1960s though, a number of African countries, including in

Nigeria and Ghana, had experienced violent coups and had fallen prey to a cycle of instability

and corruption. Continuing violence sowed doubts about the possibility for true democracy.

Events in the developing world, including the Cold War and ambiguous outcome of the Third

Wave of democratization, further clouded the picture in Africa.

Support for illiberal politics in the name of stability and prosperity remains common in

Africa. Rwanda middle class often rationalizes away President Paul Kagame’s poor human rights

record, saying “it’s necessary to have a little repression here to keep the lid on” in order to obtain

economic development (Kinzer 2007, 23-6). Similarly, President Yoweri Museveni in Uganda

has tightened his grip on power between in Uganda by suppressing civil society and harassing

opposition. As the country’s combined score for political and civil rights by the non-

7

governmental organization Freedom House dropped from eleven to nine (out of fourteen), the

economy grew at a rate of 5.7 percent. This presents the question, does democracy deliver? Is the

existence of a democratic government linked to positive performance outcomes?

Research on the linkages between regime type and government performance has its

origins in modernization theory. Early cross-national studies noted a correlation between

development and democracy—certain socioeconomic conditions led to particular political

outcomes (Lipset 1959; Deutsch 1961). Modernization theorists argued that democratization

occurs when an educated middle class develops an expectation of political influence and a

willingness to exercise political moderation. Samuel Huntington led a group of scholars who

took the argument one step further, arguing that building a middle class and achieving economic

growth in the developing world would require limiting popular participation in the short term

until political institutions consolidated. In his view, limits on democracy were a necessary and

temporary sacrifice to achieve long-term economic growth and contain communism (Huntington

1968).

“Bureaucratic authoritarian” models of development from Latin American seemed to

confirm the claim. Military regimes governed by unelected technocrats adopted politically

unpopular but economically rational public policies conducive to growth (O’'Donnell 1973;

Collier 1979). Chile emerged as a favorite example, where the dictator Augusto Pinochet

recruited American economists to liberalize the economy. Growth in East Asia also seemed to

confirm democracy’s disadvantages, as governments maintained high growth rates through

corporatism (Wade 1992) and “soft authoritarianism” (Johnson 1987, 136-164).

This reasoning had strong appeal in Africa. In 1979, reflecting on progress made under

his military government, Olusegun Obasanjo defended dictatorship’s ability to promote growth

8

through sound public policies. He credited his outgoing government with a fourteen-fold

increase in economic output, the establishment of free primary education, and reduced inflation.6

General Ibrahim Babangida, four years into his dictatorship in 1989, similarly praised the

Nigerian military’s contribution to stability and progress. He claimed credit for rescuing the

nation from the “serious economic crisis arising from the mismanagement of the political era.”7

Some scholars even acknowledge that, for all their flaws, these military regimes contributed

positively to the country’s development (Iwayemi 1979, 47-72; Ohiorhenuan 1988, 141-162).

One of Babangida’s civilian governors (who later went on to chair the political party still ruling

today), praises the government of the late 1980s for its policies on rural development, economic

liberalization, and infrastructure expansion. Drawing a comparison to U.S. President Barack

Obama, he says, Babangida ran a “task oriented” cabinet full of experts.8

Democratization since the 1990s has challenged modernization’s causal claims in both

directions. First, affirming a famous critique by Rustow (1970), contemporary examples across

Latin America and Africa suggest there are no socioeconomic preconditions for democracy

(Wood 2000; Lindberg 2006). Democratic transitions can occur at any point in a country’s

development, although democracy is more likely to survive the farther along a country is on the

development continuum (Przeworski et al. 2000). Second, a thriving post-democratization

literature explores the unexpected persistence of hybrid regimes nestled somewhere between

dictatorship and democracy (Levitsky and Way 2010; Zinecker 2009). Breaking with

modernization’s linear philosophy, which sees illiberal polities as moving inexorably toward

democracy, this new research explores the possibility of authoritarian consolidation – not just

6 “A Budget for Civilian Rule,” West Africa, 19 April 1979, pp. 613 – 618.

7 Address by General Imbrahim Babangida on the Occasion of the Inauguration of the Armed Forces Consultative

Assembly (Government Monograph), 5 June 1989. 8 Interview with Okwesilieze Nwodo, March 8, 2010. Abuja.

9

stalled democratization (Brownlee 2007; Tripp 2010). The North African revolutions of 2011

notwithstanding, Freedom House classifies a third of the world’s 194 countries as only “partly

free.” As if taking a cue from Aristotle, who explains in The Politics that tyrants extend their

rule by giving the appearance of limited royal authority, these intermediate regimes mask

oppression in a veneer of freedom. With great skill, a surprising number of governments thus

manage to formally hold elections while suppressing competition and popular participation

(Schedler 2006; Bunce and Wolchik 2010).

In terms of the impact of democracy on policy performance, a robust literature on

governance and growth generally concludes that democracies perform better than autocracies.

But there are important layers of nuance. For example, dictators may invest in productive

economic policies when they do not fear for their future. Relative political stability and

institutional longevity extend the time horizon with which rulers judge the political benefits (or

costs) of public policies. To borrow Mancur Olson’s famous analogy, these regimes may behave

as “stationary” rather than “roving” bandits and are thus able to promote long-term growth by

enforcing contracts (Olson 2000), protecting property rights (Clague et al. 1997), and investing

in social policies such as education and health care (Glaeser et al. 2004). Theoretical models also

claim that oligarchs may adopt policies to enhance productivity because they can efficiently

overcome organizational obstacles and face potentially greater potential returns on investments

(Gorodinichenko and Grygorenko 2008). Countless articles document the link between natural

resources and corruption, but dictators with revenue streams from natural resources also face less

political uncertainty, and this can create incentives to pursue productive policies (Boix 2003).

Democracy’s defenders continue to argue that political freedom and competition deliver

clear benefits through several mechanisms. Democracy resolves the problem of short-term, self-

10

interested thinking by politicians by creating an institutional incentive for leaders to supply the

type of good governance that voters demand. This arrangement is meant to bind the short-term

interests of politicians to the long-term economic and political development of the nation (North

and Weingast 1989). Democracy also addresses the succession problem that plagues all autocrats

from Mubarak to Mugabe. An institutionalized, recurring method of leadership selection

eliminates a certain degree of uncertainty about the future (Brownlee 2002; Hirschman 1970).

Finally, democracy’s defenders argue that by creating a credible threat of replacement,

democracy incentivizes politicians to provide public goods and resist “temptations for politically

opportunistic behavior that is economically damaging” (Alence 2004). Even poor democracies

face electoral pressures to provide services such as education that benefit society as a whole

(Brown and Hunter 1999; Halperin et al. 2010).

Extensive cross-national research concludes that citizens of democratic countries live

longer, happier, and healthier lives (Halperin et al. 2010; Przeworski et al. 2000). Precisely how

democracy leads to these outcomes remains a subject of considerable debate. Democracy may

directly alter governmental spending priorities. Studies from newly democratized Latin

American countries report shifts from government consumption to social welfare (Ames 1987;

Looney and Frederiksen 1987), as well as increases in the absolute amount of resources devoted

to social services (Brown and Hunter 2004). Research from Africa shows that democracy leads

to increased spending on education (Stasavage 2005a) and access to education (Stasavage

2005b). On a global level, the evidence is more mixed: democratic and authoritarian regimes

typically fund social services (such as pension and welfare) at comparable levels (Mulligan et al.

2004).

11

However, democracy’s most important effects on policy performance may actually be

indirect. A broad range of studies refute modernization theory’s claims about the developmental

advantages of dictatorship, but they also fail to find a specific causal link between democracy

and economic growth (Feng 2003; Bueno de Mesquita et al. 2001; Mainwaring and Perez-Linan

2003; Norris 2008). A recent meta-analysis of the democracy-development link reviewing 483

sets of statistical results from 84 studies concludes that democracy’s direct impact on

government performance is indeterminate and that its primary benefits are indirect

(Doucouliagos and Ulubasoglu 2008). This is reinforced by studies showing that democracies are

more likely to promote human capital formation by investing in health care and education. The

effects of such policies are indirect in that the benefits become clear over time, as the labor force

becomes healthier, better educated, and more productive (Schultz 1999; Baldacci et al. 2008).

But the direct and indirect benefits of democracy are both predicated on the existence of

viable political competition. This caveat possibly explains the ambiguous effects of African

experiments with democracy in the 1990s (Olivier de Sardan 1999; van de Walle 2001). Without

competition, party turnover, and a broader political environment of freedom and transparency,

governments lack the accountability. This has complicated assessments of African democracy

because democratic institutions seem to coexist with corruption, inflation, and economic

mismanagement. Notwithstanding the significant economic development in a number of African

countries, Lewis (2008) for example points to the problematic phenomenon in Africa today of

“growth without prosperity.” Governance decisions generate wealth and improve

macroeconomic performance, but the poor are ignored and disempowered.

A disadvantage of focusing on regime type (democracy versus dictatorship) is that it

glosses over important variations among democracies and dictatorships, both in terms of how

12

they govern and in terms of how they perform. For every Zimbabwe or Cameroon, where

authoritarianism has led to economic catastrophe, there is a Uganda or Rwanda, where illiberal

regimes have created laudable development. For every Ghana, where democracy has contributed

to economic gains, there is a Benin, where democracy reigns but the population remains

destitute. Perhaps the most comprehensive multi-country study of African development to date

concludes that regime type was less important to explaining growth than over-regulation, war,

short-sighted policy making, or distribution of resources along ethno-regional lines. Combining

cross-national analyses with country case studies, the authors argue that countries can overcome

unfavorable structural conditions such as landlocked geography or exploitative colonial pasts by

adopting growth-enhancing policies (Ndulu et al. 2008). In addition, bracketing the question of

whether countries are democratizing or not allows us to focus on other factors and types of

institutional which affect the policy making environment.

State Wealth: Poor States, Poor Performance?

Another common set of explanations for government performance focus on levels of government

income. In one version, scholars argue that governments with little income have less capacity

and fewer resources to direct toward good public policies (Przeworski et al. 2000). Countries are

developmentally poor because the state is poor and spending largely depends on revenue (Please

1967). Moreover, revenue fluctuations from global commodity price changes adversely impact

African public policy spending (Ekpo 1996). Exposure to exogenous economic conditions is a

perennial issue for Africa’s largely undiversified economies (Ake 1996). Another version of the

economic argument blames surplus rather than scarcity for government performance failures. In

particular, governments that receive a great deal of income from natural resources tend to

perform poorly. Resource-rich countries have low levels of taxation, and this deprives citizens

13

of a powerful source of leverage they can use to hold government accountable (Jensen and

Wantchekon 2004; Ulfelder 2007). In the long run, this so-called resource curse weakens state

capacity as public officials see politics primarily as a redistributive game (Karl 1997; Robinson

et al. 2006).

Together, these two sides of the economic coin suggest that African countries are at risk

when the state is too rich or too poor. Africa’s economies are susceptible to exogenous shocks,

and natural resource revenue has fueled violence, corruption, and clientelism. Mineral-rich

countries like Angola and the Democratic Republic of the Congo are mired in corruption and

patronage, while revenue-poor countries such as Benin and Togo cannot afford to make the

human capital investments necessary for economic growth. These challenges remain prevalent

today, and they lie at the center of “poor state, poor performance” explanations.

Subsequent chapters will examine the political circumstances that contribute to the

economic problems facing African governments. Recent oil discoveries in several African

countries point to an urgent need to rethink the resource curse hypothesis since extraction will

have begun after democratic transitions (unlike dictatorships which benefitted from oil

discoveries in the 1970s). Ghana for example expects to earn $400 million from its first year of

oil production in 2011, boosting economic growth from an already respectable 5 percent to

nearly 12 percent.9 Since countries which have a record of human capital investment appear to be

better equipped to absorb such income and technology shocks (Kurtz and Brooks 2011), Ghana’s

democracy just might manage to turn the curse into a blessing.

Nigeria offers an especially useful case study in this regard, since Nigeria has fallen into

both categories at various points in its history—it has suffered from both too little and too much

income. Since oil exports took off in 1970, the country has earned an estimated US$300 billion

9 Will Connors, “Ghana is set to Start Pumping Oil,” Wall Street Journal 15 December 2010.

14

dollars in oil revenue. In considering the effects of a sudden influx of dollars, most studies have

focused on how Nigeria’s oil booms undermined governance by enabling corruption and creating

economic distortions (Ikein et al. 2008; Ahmad Khan 1994). There’s little reason to question this

relationship, but it is important to acknowledge that increased revenues impact other aspects of

performance as well. For example, the initial rise of oil revenues into Nigeria in the early 1970s

also prompted huge investments in education and infrastructure (Odetola 1982; Onyejekwe

1981).

The problem for Nigeria really came when subsequent governments encountered reduced

oil revenues (Asiodu 2000, 7-10). Faced with the daunting task of collecting taxes in a poor

country with weak property rights and political instability, governments instead cut social

spending and, like many African countries, borrowed liberally from abroad. Across the

continent, African debts to foreign creditors accumulated at an astonishing pace during the 1970s

and 80s. In the early 1980s, Africa’s foreign debt to export ratio increased more than fivefold. By

the end of the 1990s, the average African country was spending 15 percent of all export earnings

paying off debts (DeLancey 2001, 117). These loans had helped stabilize recalcitrant dictators,

but the long-term costs were passed on to fragile new democratic governments during the Third

Wave of democratization. When Nigeria transitioned to democracy in 1999, it had more debt in

absolute dollars than any other country in Africa, 15 percent of the continent’s total. For 17

years, creditors provided generous loans to a succession of Nigerian dictators, oblivious to the

damage it was doing to political reformers (Chevillard 2001).

Africa’s debts affected government performance by diverting scarce revenue into loan

repayments rather than human capital and infrastructure investments (Tordoff 2002), which

undermined economic growth (Pattillo et al. 2004; Mohamed 2005). Without the debt burden,

15

some models predict that growth in thirty-five African countries would have been as much as 50

percent higher (Fosu 1999). But like the relationship between development and democracy, the

relationship between debt and government performance is complex. With regard to growth, the

amount of debt is clearly significant, since modest loans invested productively tend to actually

stimulate growth (Ayadi and Ayadi 2008; Moore and Thomas 2010). In terms of diverting

money from the social sector, there is some evidence that anticipated future debt rather than the

actual payments may be to blame for adverse effects on government policy (Fosu 2007). Debt

thus influences policy priorities, but it offers only a partial explanation for performance. We can

better understanding how revenue and spending impact policy performance by including an era

when neither oil nor debt significantly shaped Nigeria’s policy planning environment. My

findings suggest that the structure of the policy making had a more systematic impact on

government performance than these two other factors.

Ethnicity Explanations: Primordialism and Parochialism

A third account blames social heterogeneity for poor policy performance and a broad range of

other outcomes summarized in an influential literature review by Chandra (2009). At the far end

of the spectrum, ethnicity is seen as the root of civil war—and the conflicts in Yugoslavia and

Rwanda would seem to bear this out. Scholars in this tradition argue that people reflexively turn

to primordial identities in moments of uncertainty or tension and allow these emotional

attachments to spur violence. Even when ethnic identity does not lead to war, some scholars see

diversity as a threat to political stability and democratic consolidation; this operates on

assumptions about the willingness of incumbent elites to permanently exclude some groups.

Finally, several studies link diversity to poor government performance across different types of

public policies.

16

At the most basic level, social heterogeneity is seen as a possible impediment to

collective action. Compelling empirical research shows that ethnic fractionalization contributes

to low growth, low school enrollment, and federal budget deficits (Easterly and Levine 1997,

1203-50). Coordinating interests across socially diverse constituencies is simply more difficult

due to mistrust or memories of marginalization among ethnic groups. And even if they do not

harbor hard feelings that inspire retaliation, it can still be difficult to communicate across

constituencies with different cultural values. Corruption increases and the quality of policy

making declines for similar reasons (Alesina et al. 2003, 155-94). Tests in 130 countries using

the broad concept of “social diversity,” which incorporates multiple expressions of ethnicity,

arrive at similar conclusions about economic performance (Okediji 2011).

Recent groundbreaking micro-level research complements these large-N studies by

offering an explanation for how diversity can undermine public policy. “Ethnically homogeneous

communities have an advantage in providing public goods because ethnic groups possess both

norms and networks that facilitate the sanctioning of community members who fail to contribute

to collective endeavors” (Habyarimana et al. 2007, 722). Other scholars link ethnicity to

distributional distortions. Without other meaningful political cleavages based on ideology or

class, ethnicity breeds the kind of mistrust conducive patronage. This argument is especially

compelling with regard to Africa because colonial authorities purposefully exacerbated ethnic

tensions among ethnic groups in order to divide and conquer. Both the direct and indirect forms

of colonial rule favored some groups over others in order to maximize imperial efficiency and

minimize costs (Mamdani 1996).

Nigeria’s governance failures could therefore be rooted in its diversity. After all, the

north is largely Muslim, the south is largely Christian, and hundreds of languages (5 percent of

17

the world’s total) are spoken in Nigeria’s 400-square-mile territory. This hyper-diversity could

conceivably create countless possibilities for primordialism and parochialism. The British

famously adopted a sympathetic view towards the Hausa and Fulani in the north, which

undermined national integration and generated lasting resentments. This tension climaxed with a

brutal civil war from 1967 to 1970 which killed more than a million people. Simply put, scholars

writing in this tradition argue, quite reasonably, that politicians will serve their own ethno-

regional communities at the expense of others. This ethnic patrimonialism depends on access to

the so-called “national cake,” the figurative and literal resource wealth controlled by the center.

Nnoli for example blames ethnicity for Nigeria’s failure to allocate these resources, for intra-

group bourgeois competition, and for religious conflict (Nnoli 1995). A core problem in

governing ethnically diverse countries is limiting politicians’ ability or incentive to serve their

own ethno-religious communities at the expense of others. This has been described as a problem

of “prebendalism” (Joseph 1991), the sense of entitlement that a subset of Nigerians have to the

revenues of the state when members of their ethnic or kinship circle are in office.

Nigerians discuss this diversity through the discourse of the “national question.” For

ordinary citizens, this involves reconciling your identity as a citizen of the modern state with

your ethnic and cultural affinities (Amuwo, Agbaje and others 2000; Suberu 2001). Successive

governments experimented with various solutions since the 1950s, including building strong

regional governments, imposing ethnic quotas on the bureaucracy and the military, and arranging

power sharing agreements among the various ethnic groups.

I argue that the standard view of ethnicity overestimates the likelihood that diversity will

undermine government performance (Fish and Brooks 2004; Collier 2003). As noted, even in

ethnically divided societies, a government’s performance record significantly shapes citizens’

18

voting preferences (Gibson and Long 2009; Bratton and Kimenyi 2008). Patronage politics

remain common, but voters increasingly seem to weigh those benefits against other objectives,

including more programmatic national policies (Wantchekon 2003). The political salience of

ethnicity is conditional on a range of factors. Ethnicity must be actively politicized through

particular historical processes or identifiable institutions such as electoral systems (Posner 2005).

But ethnicity is no more likely to be activated than other types of identity, even though it is

relatively more visible. It simply does not have the sort of unique causal status often ascribed to

it in the literature (Chandra 2009).

By focusing on a single country over time, the research design of this book, as described

in Chapters 2 and 3, provides a dependable way to measure the impact of ethnic diversity on

government performance because the outcomes vary but the number of ethnic groups in Nigeria

does not. Ethnic salience in Nigeria fluctuates depending on changes in the political and social

incentives for self-identification. Surveys shortly after the 1999 democratic transition showed

Nigerians having stronger ethnic self-identification than almost any other Africans

(Afrobarometer 2002). Since then, ethnic and religious self-identification has varied locally over

time (Lewis 2007). Clearly, ethnic heterogeneity alone cannot explain the vicissitudes of

government performance. I argue that Nigeria’s political differences between north and south

remain the most important and that institutional consolidation depends upon balancing or

transcending these regional cleavages. This was dramatically illustrated in 2010, when a

president from the north, Umaru Yar’Adua, died in office and a succession battle erupted

because vice president Goodluck Jonathan came from the south. Jonathan eventually became

president, and I claim in the book’s conclusion that his re-election the following year constitutes

a historic turning point because it suggests that Nigerians are joining other African voters who

19

increasingly value policy performance over ethnicity when evaluating politicians (Bratton et al.

2011; Ferree 2011).

Leadership

The last explanation for government performance commonly invoked by scholars, officials, and

casual observers is the quality of leadership. Ideas about the centrality of a leader’s personal

characteristics arose during the anti-colonial struggles that featured towering personalities such

as Jomo Kenyatta in Kenya, Léopold Sédar Senghor in Senegal, and Kwame Nkrumah in Ghana.

Patrick Chabal refers to “failure of leadership” as the standard explanation for Africa’s post-

colonial disappointments (Chabal 2009, 118), and it emerged again following Africa’s re-

democratization in the 1990s. “The effective study of leadership is enjoying a period of

resurgence across the globe,” wrote Joseph Ayee in an assessment of Ghana’s leadership since

the 1993 transition to democracy. Leadership entails formulating a vision for the future,

developing a rational strategy for realizing that vision, and enlisting the support of political

actors who can help. Politics is based on a “leader-follower” relationship that is purposeful,

interactive, and capable of causation (Ayee 2007, 166). Kwame Boafo-Arthur, drawing on the

work of former British prime minister, Tony Blair, the World Bank, and the New Partnership for

Africa’s Development, argues that there is a recent convergence of views about the importance

of good leadership in mobilizing economic resources, limiting political failures, and adopting

good policies (Boafo-Arthur 2007). “Leadership, in other words, is an essential element in the

process of nation-building,” concludes one diagnosis of post-colonialism. “The history of

nation-states and civilizations have clear [sic] shown that well-focused, transparent, and

visionary leaders have played strategic roles…above all, changing the destiny of their countries”

(Abubakar 2004, 154).

20

In this view, good governance requires leaders like Plato’s philosopher-king, possessed

of noble virtue. When Chukwuma Nzeogu began discretely planning Nigeria’s first coup in late

1965, he and his co-conspirators blamed selfish politicians and weak leadership for “moving the

nation steadily but surely into self-destruction.” They dreamed that military discipline would

lead the country into social revolution, or at least unify a nation that democracy had divided

(Obasanjo 2004, 82). There is a long history in Africa of idolizing, indeed fetishizing, the “strong

and enlightened visionaries at the helm” in Asia’s fast-developing nations (Tsikata 2007, 82).

Praise for selfless personal character routinely leads to romanticizing of Asia’s soft

authoritarianism. Kwaku Tsikata writes that what distinguishes the Asian success stories from

many African cases is “strong and enlightened visionaries at the helm” who provided the sort of

“developmental leadership” (Tsikata 2007, 82). Ayee also attributes Africa’s stalled

development to a lack of “transformational” leadership of the kind that benefitted the Asian

dragons (Ayee 2007, 165). Along the same lines, Nigeria’s former dictator Yakubu Gowon says,

“I wish we had the fortune of Singapore’s or Malaysia’s leadership. . . . When one got to know

them and see how they [were] doing things, that was what we wanted to achieve.”10

A senior

Nigerian senator comments, “When you have a very energetic and visionary president, things

change. And Nigeria has not been blessed with one so far. If you look at Asian countries, there

comes a time when a president comes and changes everything.” Speaking in 2010, during the

most dramatic constitutional leadership crisis since the 1999 transition, he said “Nigeria has a

bright future, provided that we are lucky to have the right leadership. Just like in America or any

other country, you see that the fortunes of those countries change when they have good

leadership.”11

10

Interview with General Yakubu Gowon, Abuja, March 16, 2010. 11

Interview with Senator Abiola Ajimobi, Ibadan, March 15, 2010.

21

Scholars blame Nigeria’s flawed leaders for a variety of developmental problems,

including widespread corruption (Balogun 2009; Aluko 2009). One of Nigeria’s leading political

scientists and the current chair of the electoral commission, Attahiru Jega, links the country’s

“crisis of leadership” to ethnic tensions and “political brinkmanship.” Transparency,

accountability, and good governance all originate in “the mind-set of the leaders,” he says, while

“democracy-inclined” civil society strives to exercise political control (Jega 2007). “There is a

near consensus that almost all of Nigeria’s problems are traceable to poor leadership,” says

another scholar. “In no sphere of life is this debacle being more universally felt than the

economy. . . . Policy uncertainty, executive arbitrariness, unsustainable expansionary spending

and wastage are the defining characteristics of what could pass for monetary and fiscal policies”

(Tukur 2004, 244). Joseph’s classic work on the short-lived Second Republic argues that

democracy collapsed due to bad leadership rather than any inherent institutional flaws (Joseph

1987, 129). An analyst of the current Fourth Republic writes, “Most politicians, statesmen and

business leaders have not been practicing the politics of virtue.” Nigeria’s leaders therefore need

to display loyalty, respect, fairness, compassion, and self-discipline. This “hero in history”

model builds from counterfactuals, arguing that issues and events would have been different

without the influence and power of individual leaders possessed of strong character (Dike 2003).

Capturing the cultural mood on the question of national stewardship, one of Nigeria’s

most famous authors, Chinua Achebe, writes, “The trouble with Nigeria is simply and squarely a

problem of leadership.” Studies of African governance frequently refer to this quote from The

Trouble with Nigeria (Achebe 1983, 1). For example, an introductory chapter to the 2010

edition of Democratization in Africa says it “sums up the opinion of many contemporary

Africans about the underlying cause of their perennial national crises of bad governance and

22

underdevelopment” (Prempeh 2010, 22). Achebe, however, puts this conclusion in important

contexts. First, he says, “It is totally false to suggest, as we are apt to do, that Nigerians are

fundamentally different from any other people in the world” (Achebe 1983). This is important

because it responds to claims of African exceptionalism. Political science spent much of the last

decade revisiting debates over area studies, methodology, and positivism with surprising

contentiousness.12

Second, Achebe probes his compatriots to think about deeper explanations

and alternatives, writing, “Nigerians are corrupt because the system under which they live today

makes corruption easy and profitable…They will cease to be corrupt when corruption is made

difficult and inconvenient” (Achebe 1983, 38). In this new formulation, enlightened citizens are

more important than enlightened leaders. When some of Nigeria’s reformers argued in the late

1990s that their best hope lay in the hands of the brutal dictator, Sani Abacha, a dissident colonel

offered a stringent critique: “To continue to predicate the future of this country on the existence

of one man, I think will be very dangerous. What happens when the man is gone?”13

A new generation of political thinkers now links the quality of leaders to the political

processes that chooses them. Suggesting that Achebe’s oft-used quotation represented post-

colonial hero worship and Weberian ideas of charismatic authority, Osaghae says that

democratization taught Africans one thing: “The best form of leadership was that restrained by

institutional checks” (Osaghae 2010, 420). Liberian President and Nobel Peace Prize Laureate

Ellen Sirleaf Johnson similarly concludes, “Good leadership is only partly about the individual

people in leadership positions. Much more important is how these leaders are chosen and how

they are held accountable by citizens” (Radelet 2010, 5).

12

See for example the symposium, “Perestroika in Political Science: Past, Present, and Future,” PS: Political

Science and Politics 43, 4 (October 2010), 725 – 754. 13

Danlami Nmodu, “What if He is No More?” TELL, 23 February 1998, p. 20.

23

Clearly, leadership matters for something. Coming to power in 1994 after 27 years in

prison, Nelson Mandela’s willingness to protect the rights and property of South Africa’s white

minority was a monumental act of forgiveness which also helped preserve the country’s engines

of growth. And as Seymour Martin Lipset reminds us of George Washington, nothing

exemplifies “self-sacrificing heroism” like the former general’s willingness to gracefully return

to private life after the Revolutionary War and then do so again after serving two terms as

president. England’s stunned King George commented that this made Washington “the greatest

character of the age” (Lipset 1998, 24). James Madison himself asked, during the Virginia

Convention, “Is there no virtue among us? If there be not, we are in a wretched situation. No

theoretical checks—no form of government can render us secure.”14

But the danger of embracing leadership is that it ignores institutions, social forces, and

other types of post-colonial African agency. By resigning history to randomness, it falsely

separates a leader’s decisions from the social reality and political systems in which they are

made. Like structural determinism, the leadership explanation asks citizens to accept governance

failures as the result of forces beyond their control. African nationalists in fact discarded

colonial constitutions with surprising swiftness following independence. And while many post-

colonial policies had failed by the 70s, evidence increasingly demonstrates that excessive

voluntarism is too stochastic to account for empirical patterns of government performance in the

decades since then. African agency operates within a finite universe of opportunity constraints,

Africans are not locked fatalistically into path dependency in which neither politicians nor

citizens have control over their destiny (Alence 2004; Ndulu et al. 2008). James Madison, whose

ideas inspire the theoretical argument of this book, understood the dangers of relying on political

14

James Madison, “Judicial Power,” Virginia Convention Speech, June 12, 1788. Ketcham (2006) highlights these

contrasting views in his introduction to Selected Writings of James Madison.

24

will and placing hope in individual leaders. “A nation of philosophers is as little to be expected

as the philosophical race of kings wished for by Plato,” he writes in “Federalist Number 49.” An

enduring, hard reality, he writes elsewhere in the Federalist Papers, is that “enlightened

statesmen will not always be at the helm.” Governance always entails confrontations among

hostile factions, and “it is in vain to say that enlightened statesmen will be able to adjust to these

clashing interests, and render them subservient to the public good.”15

AN ALTERNATIVE EXPLANATION

Madison argues that the causes of factions, which include above all the unequal distribution of

property, cannot be removed. Therefore, “controlling the effects” of factions is among the

principal tasks of government. “Each department should have a will of its own,” he explains in

the Federalist Papers, famously arguing that “ambition must be made to counter ambition.”16

Starting in the 1990s, political scientists have used this central insight as the basis for developing

veto player theory. Yet Madison’s foundational legacy is largely taken for granted and the

literature rarely mentions him. In one sense, this is unsurprising because veto player theory is

intended to operate in a comparative framework and overt references to Madison could be

misinterpreted as narrowing its scope to just the American experience. In a broader sense

though, veto player theory and even comparative politics more generally, have unpaid debts to

Madison (Samuels and Shugart 2010).

George Tsebelis makes the contemporary case for veto players as a comparative tool,

arguing that conventional categories such as presidential/parliamentary, unicameral/bicameral, or

majoritarian/proportional often defy clear demarcation. For example, despite innumerable

national differences, this theory allows meaningful comparisons between political executives in

15

Federalist No. 10. 16

Federalist No. 51.

25

Peru and France who, without formal institutional authority, often exercise effective vetoes over

policy. Policy making is therefore better understood in terms of a continuum reflecting the

number and type of divided interests. These veto players are thus “individual or collective actors

whose agreement is required for a change of the status quo” (Tsebelis 1995).

His work has spawned dozens of studies over the last fifteen years that have tested or

extend this framework in various ways. With a few notable exceptions,17

virtually all of this

research has focused on developed countries. “It may be that there is much less faith in

institutional approaches among those who do not work on developing countries,” explains a

recent literature review on veto players, which is unfortunate in light of the theory’s “proven

use” (Hallerberg 2010, 35). While veto player theory has formed the basis of a highly integrated

niche literature on the developed world, it has been less convenient to apply in regions where key

concepts are difficult to measure and quantify. Despite an appreciation for the idea that veto

players are more than numbers on a chart, that they represent some underlying social contract

concerning the distribution of political authority, operationalizing this idea remains a challenge.

Most veto player studies are also limited by their focus on explaining policy stability

rather than change (Konig et al. 2010; Gelbach and Malesky 2010). This focus is unnecessarily

narrow, since some literature does link veto players to other types of outcomes. If veto players

can extract policy concessions, then their impact should be seen in their ability to demand

targetable policy outputs that function as side payments to political allies – in addition to their

ability to block policy change (Cox and McCubbins 2001; Lyne 2008). Indeed, one study

looking at institutional actors in seventy-eight countries found that as the number of “veto

points” increases, governments embark on more costly “white elephant” projects that benefit

narrow constituencies (Henisz and Zelner 2006). Research on African power-sharing agreements

17

See for example Cheesman and Tendi (2010) and MacIntyre (2001).

26

suggests that veto players may also impact the likelihood of renewed political violence

(Cheeseman and Tendi 2010). The literature explores how veto players limit opportunities for

selfish behavior, but typically through the lens of policy stability. Scholars try to gauge the

extent of veto players’ “commitment” or “resoluteness” when it comes to maintaining the status

quo (Haggard and McCubbins 2001). Accountability is framed as a safeguard against impetuous

policy shifts driven by a small number of cohesive political actors.

Madison, however, recognizing the risks of making policy too difficult to change and

argued for a strong, but bicameral, legislature. The division of the legislature was intended as a

form of horizontal monitoring—separate and sovereign authorities to create checks and balances

within and across government. Though he was no populist, Madison at the same time feared that

inadequate control of delegated authority would disenfranchise the poor majority or enable the

executive to spend recklessly. He appreciated the importance of accountability with a vertical

dimension as well. In contemporary veto players literature, these ideas are represented in the

form of strong unions, independent judiciaries, or influential militaries who shape policy choice

(Tsebelis 2002; Andrews and Montinola 2004). In this book I bring such actors close to the heart

of veto player theory. An analysis rooted in these foundational principles advances the study of

Africa, where nationalists won their freedom in the 1960s, where social movements were

surprisingly effective building capacity for vertical accountability in the 1980s, and where

restraining executive authority stands out as perhaps the central problem of institutional

consolidation today (Barkan 2009; Diamond and Plattner 2010). I build upon veto player theory

by integrating the social bases of authority into the analysis of elite behavior. I find that the

number of veto players does not only impact policy stability, the usual focus of veto player

studies, it also has differential effects on local and nationally-oriented public policy outputs.

27

Since most veto player studies also focus on developed democracies, this book also aims

to contribute to emerging comparative scholarship about authoritarianism. This research, which

now complements democratization as a significant field of inquiry, strives to disaggregate

authoritarian regimes in order to understand how they govern. By examining alternative bases of

accountability, policy control, and civic participation, this “analytic authoritarian” literature has

exposed how seemingly different regimes face surprisingly similar pressures to represent societal

interests. For example, twenty-nine years into his tenure as president of the Ivory Coast, Félix

Houphouët-Boigny asserted, “There is no number two, three or four...In Côte d’Ivoire there is

only a number one: that’s me and I don’t share my decisions” (Meredith 2006, 379). In my view,

the analytic authoritarian literature questions this excessive bravado. It explores how political

institutions such as legislatures or mass political parties can and do constrain dictators (Wright

2008; Brownlee 2007; Frantz and Ezrow 2011). Autocrats govern through a variety of collective

decision-making mechanisms, challenging the myth of the “solitary autocrat” (Gandhi 2008).

Repression has its limits. Autocrats face real “audience costs,” the political risks of coercion

compared to cooptation (Weeks 2008). Burkina Faso’s dictator, for example, has survived

several waves of mass protests since coming to power in 1987 by employing strategies of

conciliation rather than coercion.18

Unlike much of the democratization literature, which uses a

wide array of ideal types to analyze illiberal regimes, veto player theory supports a comparative

analysis by conceptualizing political authority on a continuum.

There is a pressing need to understand authoritarianism better because two decades after

the “Third Wave” of democratization reached Africa’s shores, democracies across the continent

are in a precarious condition and illiberal politics retain a significant allure. The Economist

Intelligence Unit declared in 2010 that “Democracy is in retreat. The dominant pattern in all

18

Adam Nossiter, “In Burkina Faso, Leader Keeps Cool Under Fire,” New York Times, 10 May 2011.

28

regions over the past two years has been backsliding on previously attained progress” In Sub-

Saharan Africa, democratization “is grinding to a halt and in some cases is being reversed”

(Economist Intelligence Unit 2010, 2). Freedom House reported similarly discouraging findings

in 2011 when it announced that freedom on a global level had declined for the fifth consecutive

year.

Surveys carried out by Afrobarometer show that, since the project began in 1999, demand

for democracy has increased across Africa and majorities reject alternatives to democracy

(understood as one-man rule, one-party rule, or military rule). Still, fewer than half (47 percent)

of respondents in 2008 indicated a demand for democracy, with significant variation across

countries. More alarmingly, among the twenty most politically liberal countries in Africa,

nowhere do a majority of respondents see democracy as consolidated—and in several cases a

majority describe a consolidation of autocracy (Bratton and Mattes 2009). Citizens also express

strong doubts about the quality of democracy. Vertical accountability and government

responsiveness are low, indicating a deficiency in “extending the link between citizens and

government beyond regular elections and formal constitutional protections to the day-to-day

realm of policy-making and implementation” (Logan and Mattes 2010, 11). And even in

countries where citizens clearly do prefer democracy (such as Nigeria), impatience with its

ability to deliver on desired policies creates a restlessness which coup plotters have historically

exploited.

Evidence suggests that Nigerians still clearly prefer democracy, but their commitment to

the democratic process is weak. According to Afrobarometer surveys, there has been decline in

“patience with democracy” since 2000, due to the government’s performance record. In 2005,

nearly 40 percent of Nigerians said that they would “consider other political options” if

29

democratic performance does not improve (Afrobarometer 2006). Even before the corrupt

elections of 2007, polls revealed growing cynicism about democracy. And after the elections,

less than one-third of those interviewed were either “fairly satisfied” or “very satisfied” with the

way democracy works in Nigeria. Nigeria’s youthful population, roughly half of whom had

never lived under a democracy at the time of the transition, expressed frustration. One retired

military colonel who had risked his life to move the democratic transition forward in Nigeria

complained in 2004, “This democracy that we have made so many sacrifices to bring about and

invested so much hope in, has not delivered the expected dividends….This system has not

promoted good governance.”19

For his generation, such sentiments evoke memories of the period

before the 1983 coup, a surprisingly popular regime change that ushered in sixteen dark years of

dictatorship. Olusegun Obasanjo, who stepped aside in 1979 to allow a democratic transition,

perhaps best expressed the nation’s enigmatic attitude toward democracy. Commenting after a

1985 coup that ordinary citizens are more concerned with the substance of government than its

form, he said “[Nigerians] are interested in the ability to deliver, the ability to perform, rather

than the means by which the government is brought about.”20

The Structure of the Book

During the 1990s, a new dictator sent Obasanjo to prison, where the retired general changed his

mind about democracy. After he was released, Obasanjo ran for office and became the first

democratically elected president following the 1999 transition. During his eight years in office,

he clashed continually with the National Assembly which tried to impeach him numerous times,

oversaw two flawed elections, and witnessed the rise of Islamic law in the north and new violent

rebellions in the south. He also increased social spending, oversaw economic reforms, paid off

19

Abubakar Umar, “Why I am Angry,” Vanguard, 5 April 2004, pp. 38-39. 20

“Obasanjo Breaks His Silence,” West Africa, August 12, 1985, p. 1667; excerpts in West Africa, August 19, 1985.

30

the country’s foreign debts, and restored Nigeria’s international reputation. What does this

decidedly mixed record teach us about the factors that determine government performance? This

book digs beneath the standard political and cultural formulations to understand the underlying

dynamics that guide policy making.

The first chapter uses veto player theory to develop an alternative explanation for

government performance. I detail the criteria for identifying and enumerating veto players. In my

formulation, political actors possess veto authority when they possess motives to challenge the

status quo, the organizational means to internally coordinate preferences, and they demonstrably

block policy in one major area such as federal budgets or constitutional reform. I argue that the

conditions which increase policy stability and credibility also make it more difficult for political

actors to coordinate their interests. This should impact policies with non-excludable benefits at

the national level since it is more difficult for veto players to agree that their interests are better

served by these broad, collective policies. The number of veto players should also theoretically

impact the overall levels of more particularistic goods since each actor can use its leverage to

demand excludable benefits. Throughout the book I describe these two distinct policy outcomes

as national collective goods and local collective goods, respectively.

In Chapter 2, I count the number of veto players in each Nigerian regime between

independence in 1960 and the end of President Olusegun Obasanjo’s second term in 2007.

Anecdotes from interviews with primary sources vividly illustrate why regimes with more veto

players face bargaining problems. I explain how veto authority develops, sometimes from the top

down and sometimes from the ground up. I pay special attention to policy actors who have

gained power since Nigeria’s 1999 transition, the country’s longest experience with democracy

since independence. I argue that violent agitation for Islamic law in the north and militant

31

demands for control over oil resources in the south stem from efforts to maintain a federal

bargain between two distinct geopolitical regions. This analysis roots macro-level political

leverage in geography, culture, and history, and it explores the endogenous factors that shape

institutions.

In Chapter 3, I define government performance, specify different methods of measuring

performance, and perform two sets of statistical tests. Building on the theory of public goods and

relevant critiques, I elaborate on the distinctions between local and national collective goods.

With respect to collective goods distributed on a national level, it is costly to exclude some

citizens from enjoying their benefits. I operationalize these variables with original empirical data

on budgetary policy, inflation, education, and judicial resolution of property rights cases. With

respect to collective goods distributed on a local level, it theoretically is possible to target

delivery and exclude some constituencies. I operationalize these variables with original data on

capital and recurrent spending and electricity provision. I draw upon speeches and government

documents to show that these performance indicators all reflect government policy priorities.

I then formulate twin hypotheses: A “coordination hypothesis” predicts that regimes with

additional veto players will face bargaining problems that impede the delivery of national-level

collective goods. A “logroll hypothesis” predicts that additional veto players will correspond

with greater overall levels of local collective goods Statistical tests with original data show that

additional veto players do increase coordination problems, but they also foster policy stability

and accountability. In a practical sense, having more veto players makes it more difficult to enact

policies at a national level because it is difficult for veto players to agree on broad, collective

policies. Regimes with the most veto players have larger budget deficits, higher inflation rates,

higher student/teacher ratios, and less efficient judicial resolution of property rights cases. But

32

having more veto players actually lowers the overall delivery level of local collective goods.

Tests show that these regimes are more likely to restrain capital and recurrent spending. This is

because each player has the leverage to demand favors but faces greater scrutiny from political

counterparts. I attribute these performance outcomes to the improved monitoring generated by

additional veto players. All of these results remain robust after including controls for the

conventional explanations for government performance. The evidence indicates that Nigeria

faces a “Madisonian dilemma,” where the conditions that foster accountability simultaneously

contribute to coordination problems.

To probe the comparative potential of the model beyond Nigeria, Chapter 4 investigates

the individual, collective, and institutional factors guiding the policy process in two other

African cases, Ghana and Zimbabwe. Rather than attempting to code veto players or establish

causal relationships, the chapter builds on “post-paradigmatic” research approaches (Lichbach

and Zukerman 2009). By focusing on discovery, explanation, and evidence, ontology and

understanding trump the parochialism that sometimes traps political science in paradigms.

Within discovery lies possible “core difficulties” that present barriers to the accumulation of

knowledge. Within explanation lies causality in a “middle range” which avoids universalistic

theoretical ambitions but still aims to account for a range of phenomena. And finally, within

evidence resides “stylized facts” which deepen understanding of established causal relationships

such as those I identify in Chapter 3. Where variables serve as evidence, here research looks to

prevent them from becoming “reified social facts” which overextend their applications beyond

the environment which gives them meaning. In this way, context and structure enrich theory

development and empirical testing. Tools such as case studies and narratives thus serve a variety

of roles within this broader post-foundational approach to political research (Lichbach 2009).

33

The narratives in Chapter 4 identify “analytical equivalents” and historical junctures

when the policy process expanded or contracted. The study of Ghana focuses on a period of

institutional consolidation in the 1980s when the country showed signs of breaking with post-

independence patterns of impetuous economic policy making. The Zimbabwe narrative traces the

path to the 2008 power-sharing agreement and identifies the sources of political reconfigurations

in economic liberalization, coalitions for institutional reform, and new electoral challenges. By

the time the country arrived at this critical historical juncture, elites had destroyed the institutions

capable of arbitrating among different political factions, and the regime was beholden to a

variety of independent-minded allies.

The final chapter, “Madison’s Model Unbound,” explains how this study adds to our

understanding of informal institutions, federalism, and authoritarian governance. Even during

regimes that formally limited states’ power, subnational actors sometimes constructed authority

from the ground up. Conversely, sometimes institutions designed to counterbalance interests fail

to exercise this power. I also identify factors that potentially limit the model’s generalizability.

For example, Nigeria differs from many countries in its minimal dependence on foreign aid and

its relatively unusual political equilibrium between the northern and southern regions at the heart

of its federal system. New actors such as militant movements demanding “resource control” in

the oil-rich Niger Delta and Islamic movements such as Boko Haram in the north are straining

the historical bargain at the core of Nigeria’s nationhood, which will be 100 years old in 2014.

There are positive signs that Nigeria’s political system is becoming more broadly

accessible and that its institutions are creating incentives for political organizing that cut across

this highly sensitive regional cleavage. When a succession crisis ensued following the death of

President Umaru Yar’Adua, a northerner, in 2010, the presidency unexpectedly shifted to a

34

southerner, Vice President Goodluck Jonathan. The resolution to the crisis demonstrated a

commitment to constitutional terms of separate sovereignty, public authority grounded in distinct

branches of government, and protecting national interests that cut across regional concerns.

Similarly, southerners rose to defend presidential term limits in 2006, even though a southern

politician stood to gain most immediately from constitutional modifications that would have

allowed him to stay in office. Madison claimed, “The safety and happiness of society are the

objects at which all political institutions aim, and to which all such institutions must be

sacrificed.” Nigerians strengthened their political institutions by defending them, and politicians

and civil society activists continue to fortify them in ways that demonstrate creativity and hope.

35

References

Abubakar, Dauda. 2004. "Leadership and the Challenges of Rebuilding a Nation." In Nigeria's

Struggle for Democracy and Good Governance: a Festscrift for Oyeleye Oyediran, ed. A.

Agbaje, L. Diamond and E. Onwudiwe. Ibadan: University of Ibadan Press.

Achebe, Chinua. 1983. The Trouble with Nigeria. New Hampshire and Oxford: Heinemann

Educational Publishers.

Afrobarometer. 2006. "Performance and Legitimacy in Nigeria's New Democracy."

———, ed. 2002. Afrobarometer Briefing Paper #1: Key Findings About Public Opinion in

Africa.

Ahmad Khan, Sarah. 1994. Nigeria: the Political Economy of Oil. Oxford: Oxford University

press.

Ake, Claude. 1996. Democracy and Development in Africa. Washington, D.C: Brookings

Institution.

Alence, Rod. 2004. "Political Institutions and Developmental Governance in Africa." Journal of

Modern African Studies 42 (2):163-87.

Aluko, Yetunde. 2009. "Corruption in Nigeria: Concept and Dimensions." In Anti-Corruption

Reforms in Nigeria Since 1999, ed. D. U. Enweremadu and E. E. Okafor. Ibadan: IFRA.

Ames, Barry. 1987. Political survival politicians and public policy in Latin America. Berkeley:

University of California Press.

Andrews, Josephine T., and Gabriella Montinola, R. 2004. "Veto Players and the Rule of Law in

Emerging Democracies." Comparative Political Studies 37 (1):55-87.

Ayadi, Folorunso, and Felix Ayadi. 2008. "The Impact of External Debt on Economic Growth: A

Comparative Study of Nigeria and South Africa." Journal of Sustainable Development in

Africa 10 (3):235-64.

Ayee, Joseph R.A. 2007. "A Decade of Political Leadership in Ghana, 1993-2004." In Ghana--

one decade of the liberal state, ed. K. Boafo-Arthur. New York: Zed Books.

Baldacci, Emanuele, Benedict Clements, Sanjeev Gupta, and Qiang Cui. 2008. "Social Spending,

Human Capital, and Growth in Developing Countries." World Development 36 (8):1317-

41.

Balogun, M.J. 2009. The Route to Power in Nigeria: A Dynamic Engagement Option for Current

and Aspiring Leaders. New York: Palgrave Macmillan.

Barkan, Joel D., ed. 2009. Legislative Power in Emerging African Democracies. Boulder and

London: Lynne Rienner.

Baum, Matthew A., and David Lake. 2003. "The Political Economy of Growth: Democracy and

Human Capital." American Journal of Political Science 47 (2):333-47.

Boafo-Arthur, Kwame. 2007. Ghana--one decade of the liberal state. New York: Zed Books.

Boix, Carles. 2003. Democracy and Redisitribution. Cambridge and New York: Cambridge

University Press.

Bratton, Michael, Ravi Bhavnani, and Tse-Hsin Chen. 2011. "Voting Intentions in Africa:

Ethnic, Economic, or Partisan?" Afrobarometer Working Paper 127.

Bratton, Michael, and Mwangi Kimenyi. 2008. "Voting in Kenya: Putting Ethnicity in

Perspective." Afrobarometer.

Bratton, Michael, and Robert Mattes. 2009. "Neither Consolidating Nor Fully Democratic: The

Evolution of African Political Regimes, 1999-2008." Afrobarometer.

36

Brown, David, and Wendy Hunter. 2004. "Democracy and Human Capital Formation: Education

Spending in Latin America, 1980 - 1997." Comparative Political Studies 37 (7):842-64.

Brown, David S., and Wendy Hunter. 1999. "Democracy and Social Spending in Latin America,

1980-1992." American Political Science Review 93 (4):779-90.

Brownlee, Jason. 2007. Authoritarianism in an Age of Democratization. Cambridge and New

York: Cambridge University Press.

Brownlee, Jason M. 2002. "Low Tide after the Third Wave: Exploring Politics Under

Authoritarianism." Comparative Politics 34 (4):477-98.

Bueno de Mesquita, Bruce, James D. Morrow, Randolph Siverson, and Alastair Smith. 2001.

"Political Competition and Economic Growth." Journal of Democracy 12 (1):57-72.

Bunce, Valerie, and Sharon Wolchik. 2010. "Defeating Dictators: Electoral Change and Stability

in Competitive Authoritarian Regimes." World Politics 62 (1):43-86.

Chabal, Patrick. 2009. Africa: The Politics of Suffering and Smiling. London and New York: Zed

Books.

Chandra, Kanchan. 2009. "Making Causal Claims about the Effects of Ethnicity." In

Comparative Politics: Rationality, Culture, and Structure, ed. M. Lichbach and A.

Zukerman. Cambridge and New York: Cambridge University Press.

Cheeseman, Nic, and Blessing-Miles Tendi. 2010. "Power-Sharing in Comparative Perspective:

the Dynamics of 'Unity Government' in Kenya and Zimbabwe." Journal of Modern

African Studies 48 (2):203-29.

Chevillard, Nicole. 2001. "Nigeria's External Debt: Evolution, Mix and Current Issues." In

Nigeria During the Abacha Years, 1993 - 1998, ed. D. C. Bach, Y. Lebeau and K.

Amuwo. Ibadan, Nigeria: Institut Francais de Recherche en Afrique.

Clague, Christopher, Philip Keefer, Stephen Knack, and Mancur Olson. 1997. "Democracy,

Autocracy, and the Institutions Supportive of Economic Growth." In Institutions and

Economic Development: Growth and Governance in Less-Developed and Post-Socialist

Countries, ed. C. Clague. Baltimore and London: Johns Hopkins University Press.

Collier, Paul. 2003. "Implications of Ethnic Diversity." ed. E. Nnadozie. Amsterdam, Boston,

London, New York: Academic Press.

Cox, Gary, and Mathew McCubbins. 2001. "The Institutional Determinants of Economic Policy

Outcomes." In Presidents, Parliaments, and Policy, ed. S. Haggard and M. McCubbins.

New York: Cambridge University Press.

DeLancey, Virginia. 2001. "The Economies of Africa." In Understanding Contemporary Africa,

ed. A. A. Gordon and D. L. Gordon. Boulder: Lynne Rienner.

Deutsch, Karl W. 1961. "Social Mobilization and Political Development." American Political

Science Review 55 (3):493-514.

Diamond, Larry Jay, and Marc F. Plattner, eds. 2010. Democratization in Africa : progress and

retreat. 2nd ed. Baltimore, Md.: Johns Hopkins University Press.

Dike, Victor E., ed. 2003. Nigeria and the Politics of Unreason: A Study of the Obasanjo

Regime. London: Adonis & Abbey Publishers Ltd.

Doucouliagos, Hristos, and Mehmet Ali Ulubasoglu. 2008. "Democracy and Economic Growth:

A Meta-Analysis." American Journal of Political Science 52 (1):61-83.

Economist Intelligence Unit. 2010. "Democracy Index 2010: Democracy in Retreat." London.

Ekpo, Akpan H. 1996. "Pattern of Public Expenditure in Nigeria: 1960 - 92." In Economic

Reform and Macroeconomic Management in Nigeria, ed. A. Ariyo. Ibadan: Centre for

Public-Private Cooperation.

37

Feng, Yi. 2003. Democracy, Governance, and Economic Performance: Theory and Evidence.

Cambridge, MA and London: The MIT Press.

Ferree, Karen. 2011. Framing the Race in South Africa: The Political Origins of Racial-Census

Elections. Cambridge and New York: Cambridge University Press.

Fish, M. Steven, and Robin S. Brooks. 2004. "Does Diversity Hurt Democracy?" Journal of

Democracy 15 (1):154-66.

Fosu, Augustin Kwasi. 1999. "The External Debt Burden and Economic Growth in the 1980s:

Evidence from sub-Saharan Africa." Canadian Journal of Development Studies 20

(2):307-18.

———. 2007. "Fiscal Allocation for Education in Sub-Saharan Africa: Implications of the

External Debt Service Constraint." World Development 35 (4):702-13.

Frantz, Erica, and Natasha Ezrow. 2011. The Politics of Dictatorship: Institutions and Outcomes

in Authoritarian Regimes. Boulder: Lynne Rienner.

Gandhi, Jennifer. 2008. Political Institutions Under Dictatorship. Cambridge and New York:

Cambridge University Press.

Gelbach, Scott, and Edmund Malesky. 2010. "The Contribution of Veto Players to Economic

Reform." Journal of Politics 72 (4):957-75.

Gibson, Clark C., and James D. Long. 2009. "The Presidential and Parliamentary Elections in

Kenya, December 2007." Electoral Studies 28:497-502.

Glaeser, Edward L., Rafael La Porta, Florencio Lopez-de-Silanes, and Andrei Shleifer. 2004.

"Do Institutions Cause Growth?" Journal of Economic Growth 9:271-303.

Gorodinichenko, Yuriy, and Yegor Grygorenko. 2008. "Are Oligarchs Productive? Theory and

Evidence." Journal of Comparative Economics 36 (1):17-42.

Habyarimana, James, Macartan Humphreys, Daniel Posner, and Jeremy M. Weinstein. 2007.

"Why Does Ethnic Diversity Undermine Public Goods Provision?" American Political

Science Review 101 (4):709-25.

Haggard, Stephan, and Mathew McCubbins, eds. 2001. Presidents, Parliaments, and Policy.

Cambridge and New York: Cambridge University Press.

Hallerberg, Mark. 2010. "Empirical Applications of Veto Player Analysis and Institutional

Effectiveness." In Reform Processes and Policy Change: Veto Players and Decision-

Making in Modern Democracies, ed. T. Konig, G. Tsebelis and M. Debus. New York:

Springer.

Halperin, Morton H., Joseph T. Siegle, and Michael M. Weinstein. 2010. The democracy

advantage : how democracies promote prosperity and peace. Rev. ed. New York:

Routledge.

Henisz, Witold, and Bennet Zelner. 2006. "Interest Groups, Veto Points, and Electricity

Infrastructure Deployment." International Organization 60 (Winter):263-86.

Hirschman, Albert O, ed. 1970. Exit, voice, and loyalty responses to decline in firms,

organizations, and states. Cambridge, Mass: Harvard University Press.

Ikein, Augustine A., D.S.P. Alamieyeseigha, and Steve Azaiki, eds. 2008. Oil, Democracy, and

the Promise of True Federalism in Nigeria. Lanham, MD: University Press of America.

Jega, Attahiru M. 2007. Democracy, Good Governance and Development in Nigeria. Ibadan:

Spectrum Publishers.

Jensen, Nathan, and Leonard Wantchekon. 2004. "Resource Wealth and Political Regimes in

Africa." Comparative Political Studies 37 (7):816-41.

38

Joseph, Richard A. 1987. Democracy and prebendal politics in Nigeria the rise and fall of the

Second Republic: Cambridge University Press.

Karl, Terry Lynn. 1997. The Paradox of Plenty Oil Booms and Petro-states. Berkeley:

University of California Press.

Ketcham, Ralph, ed. 2006. Selected Writings of James Madison. Indianapolis and Cambridge:

Hackett Publishing.

Konig, Thomas, George Tsebelis, and Marc Debus, eds. 2010. Reform Processes and Policy

Change: Veto Players and Decision-Making in Modern Democracies. New York:

Springer.

Kurtz, Marcus, and Sarah M. Brooks. 2011. "Conditioning the 'Resource Curse': Globalization,

Human Capital, and Growth in Oil-Rich Nations." Comparative Political Studies 44

(6):747-70.

Levitsky, Steven, and Lucan Way. 2010. Competitive Authoritarianism: Hybrid Regimes After

the Cold War. Cambridge and New York: Cambridge University Press.

Lewis, Peter M. 2007. "Identity, Institutions and Democracy in Nigeria." Afrobarometer.

———. 2008. "Growth without Prosperity in Africa." Journal of Democracy 19 (4):95-109.

Lichbach, Mark, and Alan Zukerman, eds. 2009. Comparative Politics: Rationality, Culture, and

Structure. Second ed. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

Lindberg, Staffan I., ed. 2006. Democracy and Elections in Africa. Baltimore: The Johns

Hopkins University Press.

Lipset, Seymour Martin. 1959. "Some Social Requisites of Democracy: Economic Development

and Political Legitimacy." American Political Science Review 53 (1):69-105.

———. 1998. "George Washington and the Founding of Democracy." Journal of Democracy 9

(4):24-38.

Logan, Carolyn, and Robert Mattes. 2010. "Democratizing the Measurement of Democratic

Quality: Public Attitude Data and the Evaluation of African Political Regimes."

Afrobarometer.

Looney, Robert E., and P.C. Frederiksen. 1987. "Consequences of Military and Civilian Rule in

Argentina: An Analysis of Central Government Budgetary Tradeoffs, 1961-1982." 20

(1):34-46.

Lyne, Mona. 2008. The Voter's Dilemma and Democratic Accountability: Latin America and

Beyond. University Park: Penn State University Press.

MacIntyre, Andrew. 2001. "Institutions and Institutions and Investors: The Politics of the

Financial Crisis in Southeast Asia." International Organization 55 (1):81-122.

Mainwaring, Scott, and Anibal Perez-Linan. 2003. "Level of Development and Democracy:

Latin American Exceptionalism, 1945-1996." Comparative Political Studies 36 (9):1031-

67.

Mamdani, Mahmood, ed. 1996. Citizen and subject contemporary Africa and the legacy of late

colonialism. Princeton, N.J: Princeton University Press.

Meredith, Martin. 2006. The Fate of Africa: a History of Fifty Years of Independence: Public

Affairs.

Mohamed, Mutasim Ahmed Abdelmawla. 2005. "The Impact of External Debts on Economic

Growth: An Empirical Assessment of the Sudan, 1978-2001." Eastern Africa Social

Science Research Review 21 (2):53-66.

Moore, Winston, and Chrystol Thomas. 2010. "A Meta-Analysis of the Relationship Between

Debt and Growth." International Journal of Development Issues 9 (3):214-25.

39

Mulligan, Casey B., Ricard Gil, and Xavier Sala-i-Martin. 2004. "Do Democracies Have

Different Public Policies than Nondemocracies?" Journal of Economic Perspectives 18

(1):51-74.

Ndulu, Benno J., Stephen A. O'Connell, Robert H. Bates, Paul Collier, and Chukwuma Soludo,

eds. 2008. The Political Economy of Economic Growth in Africa, 1960 - 2000. Vol. 1.

Cambridge and New York: Cambridge University Press.

Norris, Pippa. 2008. Driving Democracy: Do Power-Sharing Institutions Work? Cambridge and

New York: Cambridge University Press.

North, Douglass, and Barry Weingast. 1989. "Constitutions and Commitment: The Evolution of

Institutions Governing Public Choice in 17th Century England." Journal of Economic

History 49 (4).

Nyerere, Julius. 1973. "Freedom and Development." In Freedom and Development: a Selection

from Writings and Speeches, 1968-1973, ed. J. Nyerere. London: Oxford University

Press.

Obasanjo, Olusegun. 2004. Nzeogwu. Ibadan: Spectrum Books.

Okediji, Tade. 2011. "Social Fragmentation and Economic Growth: Evidence from Developing

Countries." Journal of Institutional Economics 7 (1):77-104.

Olivier de Sardan, J.P. 1999. "A Moral Economy of Corruption in Africa?" Journal of Modern

African Studies 37:25-52.

Olson, Mancur. 2000. Power and Prosperity: Outgrowing Communist and Capitalist

Dictatorships. New York: Basic Books.

Osaghae, Eghosa. 2010. "The Limits of Charismatic Authority and the Challenges of Leadership

in Nigeria." Journal of Contemporary African Studies 28 (4):407-22.

Pattillo, Catherine, Helene Poirson, and Luca Ricci. 2004. "What are the Channels Through

Which External Debt Affects Growth?" IMF Working Paper 4 (15).

Please, Stanley. 1967. "Saving Through Taxation - Reality or Mirage." Finance and

Development 4 (1):24-32.

Posner, Daniel N. 2005. Institutions and Ethnic Politics in Africa. Cambridge and New York:

Cambridge University Press.

Prempeh, Kwasi. 2010. "President's Untamed." In Democratization in Africa : Progress and

Retreat, ed. L. J. Diamond and M. F. Plattner. Baltimore, Md.: Johns Hopkins University

Press.

Przeworski, Adam, Michael E. Alvarez, Jose Antonio Cheibub, and Fernando Limongi, eds.

2000. Democracy and Development: Political Institutions and Material Well-being in the

World, 1950-1990. Cambridge and New York: Cambridge University Press.

Radelet, Steven. 2010. Emerging Africa: How 17 Countries Are Leading the Way. Washington,

DC: Center for Global Development.

Robinson, James A., Ragnar Torvik, and Thierry Verdier. 2006. "Political Foundations of the

Resource Curse." Journal of Development Economics 79 (2):447-68.

Rustow, Dankwart A. 1970. "Transitions to Democracy: Toward a Dynamic Model."

Comparative Politics 2 (3):337-63.

Samuels, David J., and Matthew S. Shugart. 2010. Presidents, Parties, and Prime Ministers:

How the Separation of Powers Affects Party Organization and Behavior. Cambridge:

Cambridge University Press.

Schedler, Andreas, ed. 2006. Electoral Authoritarianism: The Dynamics of Unfree Competition.

Boulder and London: Lynne Rienner.

40

Schultz, T. Paul. 1999. "Health and Schooling Investments in Africa." Journal of Economic

Perspectives 13 (3):67-88.

Stasavage, David. 2005a. "Democracy and Education Spending in Africa." American Journal of

Political Science 49 (2):343-58.

———. 2005b. "The Role of Democracy in Uganda's Move to Universal Primary Education."

Journal of Modern African Studies 43 (1):53-73.

Tordoff, William. 2002. Government and Politics in Africa. Bloomington: Indiana University

Press.

Tripp, Aili Mari. 2010. Museveni's Uganda : paradoxes of power in a hybrid regime. Boulder:

Lynne Rienner Publishers.

Tsebelis, George. 1995. "Decision Making in Political Systems: Veto Players in Presidentialism,

Parliamentarism, Multicameralism, and Multipartyism." British Journal of Political

Science 25 (3):289-325.

———. 2002. Veto Players: How Political Institutions Work. New York and Princeton: Russell

Sage Foundation with Princeton University Press.

Tsikata, G. Kwaku. 2007. "Challenges of Economic Growth in a Liberal Economy." ed. G. O. D.

o. t. L. State. Dakar: CODESRIA Books.

Tukur, Mahumd M. 2004. "Needed: Better Leadership." In Crafting the New Nigeria:

Confronting the Challenges, ed. R. I. Rotberg. Boulder and London: Lynne Rienner.

Ulfelder, Jay. 2007. "Natural-Resource Wealth and the Survival of Autocracy." Comparative

Political Studies 40 (8):995-1018.

United Nations Development Programme. 2009. "Hman Development Report, Nigeria 2008-

2009: Achieving Growth with Equity." Abuja: UNDP.

van de Walle, Nicolas. 2001. African Economies and the Politics of Permanent Crisis, 1979-

1999. Cambridge and New York: Cambridge University Press.

Wantchekon, Leonard. 2003. "Clientelism and Voting Behavior: A Field Experiment in Benin."

World Politics 55:399-422.

Weeks, Jessica L. 2008. "Autocratic Audience Costs: Regime Type and Signaling Resolve."

International Organization 62:35-64.

Wood, Elisabeth Jean. 2000. Forging Democracy from Below: Insurgent Transitions in South

Africa and El Salvador. Cambridge and New York: Cambridge University Press.

Wright, Joseph. 2008. "Do Authoritarian Institutions Constrain? How Legislatures Affect

Economic Growth and Investment." American Journal of Political Science 52 (2):322-43.

Zinecker, Heidrun. 2009. "Regime-Hybridity in Developing Countries: Achievements and

Limitations of New Research on Transitions." International Studies Review 11:302-31.