Interregional Trade and Transport Connectivity: An ...

24
1 Interregional Trade and Transport Connectivity: An Analysis of Spatial and Networks Dependence by Using a Spatial Econometric Flow Model at NUTS3 level Luisa Alamá-Sabater * Laura Márquez-Ramos * Celestino Suárez-Burguet * José Miguel Navarro-Azorín ** * Universitat Jaume I, Castellón, Spain ** Universidad Politécnica de Cartagena, Spain Abstract Recent research has analyzed whether existing transportation networks affect interregional trade in goods in a spatial econometric model approach (LeSage and Polasek, 2008; Alamá-Sabater et al, 2012). Nonetheless, to our knowledge, previous research within this approach does not deal with highly disaggregated regional trade data by disentangling the role of different types of transportation networks. This paper aims to cover this lack in the existing literature. In order to proxy for the transportation network structure, data for trade flows between Spanish provinces (NUTS3) 1 in the year 2007 are obtained, as well as data about the characteristics of logistics platforms existing in each region. Previously, Alamá-Sabater et al (2012) provided evidence about the role of the location of logistics platforms for satisfying existing demand for transport structure at NUTS2 spatial disaggregation level, as spatial and transportation networks dependence play a significant role on interregional trade flows. However, these authors only focused on the number and area of logistics platforms existing in each region to proxy for the logistics facilities in contiguous regions. The present paper uses a gravity model of trade as a basis to explain trade flows between Spanish intra-national regions in spatial approach terms, incorporating, in addition to the characteristics of each region, information on transportation networks. Additionally, it extends the procedure followed by LeSage and Polasek (2008) and Alamá-Sabater et al (2012) including weighting matrixes based on the logistics performance by typology (i.e. sea ports) to analyze and compare the role of transportation networks on trade of different sectors. Keywords: Spanish regions, interregional trade, logistics platforms. JEL classification: R12, R23, R48 Corresponding author: Luisa Alamá-Sabater, Department of Economics, Universitat Jaume I, Campus del Riu Sec, Castellon (12071), Spain. E-mail: [email protected] 1 NUTS is a French acronym for Nomenclature of Territorial Units for Statistics used by Eurostat. In this nomenclature NUTS1 refers to European Community Regions and NUTS2 to Basic Administrative Units, with NUTS3 reflecting smaller spatial units most similar to counties in the USA.

Transcript of Interregional Trade and Transport Connectivity: An ...

Page 1: Interregional Trade and Transport Connectivity: An ...

1

Interregional Trade and Transport Connectivity: An Analysis of Spatial and Networks

Dependence by Using a Spatial Econometric Flow Model at NUTS3 level

Luisa Alamá-Sabater*

Laura Márquez-Ramos*

Celestino Suárez-Burguet*

José Miguel Navarro-Azorín** *Universitat Jaume I, Castellón, Spain

** Universidad Politécnica de Cartagena, Spain

Abstract

Recent research has analyzed whether existing transportation networks affect interregional trade in

goods in a spatial econometric model approach (LeSage and Polasek, 2008; Alamá-Sabater et al,

2012). Nonetheless, to our knowledge, previous research within this approach does not deal with

highly disaggregated regional trade data by disentangling the role of different types of transportation

networks. This paper aims to cover this lack in the existing literature.

In order to proxy for the transportation network structure, data for trade flows between Spanish

provinces (NUTS3)1 in the year 2007 are obtained, as well as data about the characteristics of logistics

platforms existing in each region. Previously, Alamá-Sabater et al (2012) provided evidence about the

role of the location of logistics platforms for satisfying existing demand for transport structure at

NUTS2 spatial disaggregation level, as spatial and transportation networks dependence play a

significant role on interregional trade flows. However, these authors only focused on the number and

area of logistics platforms existing in each region to proxy for the logistics facilities in contiguous

regions.

The present paper uses a gravity model of trade as a basis to explain trade flows between Spanish

intra-national regions in spatial approach terms, incorporating, in addition to the characteristics of each

region, information on transportation networks. Additionally, it extends the procedure followed by

LeSage and Polasek (2008) and Alamá-Sabater et al (2012) including weighting matrixes based on

the logistics performance by typology (i.e. sea ports) to analyze and compare the role of transportation

networks on trade of different sectors.

Keywords: Spanish regions, interregional trade, logistics platforms.

JEL classification: R12, R23, R48

Corresponding author: Luisa Alamá-Sabater, Department of Economics, Universitat Jaume I,

Campus del Riu Sec, Castellon (12071), Spain. E-mail: [email protected]

1 NUTS is a French acronym for Nomenclature of Territorial Units for Statistics used by Eurostat. In this nomenclature NUTS1 refers to European Community Regions and NUTS2 to Basic Administrative Units, with NUTS3 reflecting smaller spatial units most similar to counties in the USA.

Page 2: Interregional Trade and Transport Connectivity: An ...

2

1. Introduction

This paper uses a gravity model of trade (Bergstrand, 1985 and 1989; Deardorff, 1995) as a basis to

explain trade flows between intra-national regions in spatial approach terms, incorporating, in addition

to the characteristics of each region, information on transport connectivity.

In previous research for highly disaggregated interregional United States trade, Hillberry and Hummels

(2008) shown that goods produced at a particular distance are not purchased because there is no

local demand for them, and then most shipments occur only between proximate location pairs, as

shipments are extremely localized. Two main reasons are provided. First, consumers would buy a

good produced at a distance if price became competitive with local alternatives (Eaton and Kortum,

2002; Melitz, 2003). Second, Hillberry and Hummels (2008)’ results support that regions specialize in

the production of different goods and vary in the mix of inputs they absorb. Transport connectivity

might play an important role in both explanations.

Transport connectivity has recently been considered in gravity studies of trade. In this sense, we can

distinguish two ways of defining connectivity (Márquez-Ramos et al, 2011). On the one hand,

connectivity in a narrow sense is limited to the physical properties of the transport network. On the

other hand, connectivity in a broad sense includes those factors related to the features of the services

and cooperation of transport operators, which are essential for the efficiency and effectiveness of the

transportation network. Márquez-Ramos et al (2011), as well as other authors who have considered

transport connectivity, address the concept in a narrow sense (Limao and Venables, 2001; Sanchez et

al, 2003; Clark et al, 2004; Micco and Serebrisky, 2004; Wilson et al, 2004), finding that transport

connectivity increases trade flows between trading partners. Nonetheless, these studies do not

consider the existence of spatial dependence among regions that, following Alamá-Sabater et al

(2012), is introduced in this paper to analyze the effect of transport connectivity in the broad sense.

Using a spatial autoregressive model, Alamá-Sabater et al (2012) analyzed the presence of spatial

autocorrelation effects on Spanish interregional trade flows, which has also been analyzed in LeSage

and Llano (2006). There are also working papers of the same authors in the public domain, where

spatial and network autocorrelation effects are also tested for Spain using sector specific flows from

the same trade database that we use in the present paper. Nonetheless, in addition to the traditional

connectivity concept defined by the geographical criteria which Lesage and Llano (2006) used, Alamá-

Sabater et al (2012) used a broad transport connectivity concept by considering the presence of

logistics platforms. In order to do so, these authors extended the procedure followed by LeSage and

Polasek (2008) to consider the actual connectivity structure of the road/rail network in Austria at

NUTS3, including weighting matrices based on logistics performance in neighboring regions. One

advantage of using this framework is that it allows nearby regions to enter into the determination of

spatial lags, with the weight assigned increasing directly with neighbors’ logistics performance.

Therefore, previous research has shown that spatial correlation exists in heavily broken down

geographical data (LeSage and Llano, 2006; LeSage and Polasek, 2008; Alamá-Sabater et al, 2012).

Nonetheless, LeSage and Polasek (2008) only considered the land (road/rail) transportation routes

that pass through Austrian regions, but they did not distinguished among them, and did not consider

Page 3: Interregional Trade and Transport Connectivity: An ...

3

sectorial disaggregation. Furthermore, these authors pointed out that an issue that could be of great

importance is that of accessibility (or what we call transport connectivity) and stated that “this could be

quite different for rail versus road networks. For the case of commodity flows under examination here,

an important factor would be the relative amounts of rail versus road transportation of commodities. In

many parts of the USA, where an extensive road network exists and commodities are transported

primarily by road with few natural barriers such as mountains, rivers, or lakes, the unmodified

approach to forming the spatial weight structure set forth in LeSage and Pace (2008) should work well.

Our empirical illustration involves rail and truck commodity flows between 35 regions in Austria where

mountains and other natural barriers as well as more limited road networks place limitations on

access” (LeSage and Polasek, 2008; pp.230-231).

This paper analyzes interregional trade flows in Spain. Spain exported 73% of its total exports to the

European Union (EU) in 2009 and 67% of its total imports came from the EU in the same period.2

However, that country is far from the centre of economic activity in Europe, isolated on its peninsula

with Portugal from the rest of the continent. There are only two major road and rail passages to France

and the rest of Europe through the Pyrenees (Hendaye/Irun and Cerbere/Portbou). In fact, the

Mediterranean Corridor, which connects the Iberian Peninsula to the rest of Europe, has been pre-

identified in the EU core network in the field of transport (EC, 2011).

In addition, the country is mountainous with average altitude standing at 610 meter. These conditions

make access to the main ports and connecting to the European network via France particularly

important to connect interregional and international trade flows. Therefore, as is the case of Austria in

LeSage and Polasek (2008), the effect of transport connectivity on interregional Spanish trade flows

could be quite different depending on the type of transportation network considered, and then different

typologies of logistics platforms are distinguished.3 Methodologically speaking, we disentangle the role

of sea ports by introducing their presence in neighboring regions, as well as we consider their relative

importance in weighting matrices.4

LeSage and Llano (2006) and Alamá-Sabater et al (2012) already accounted for spatial dependence

by using Spanish regions in a gravity framework, involving origin-destination flows. Additionally,

Alamá-Sabater et al (2012) took the analysis of different sectors a step further by following a spatial

pattern in accordance with the structure of territory and the type of economic sector. Although both

LeSage and Llano (2006) and Alamá-Sabater et al (2012) focused on Spanish regions and their

results revealed a spatial pattern, they also revealed the limitations of the level of territorial breakdown

chosen; Autonomous Communities (NUTS2), which are a too large basic unit and too heterogeneous

to be treated as a whole. It is therefore necessary to reduce the spatial level and consider a smaller

basic unit area, as LeSage and Polasek (2008) did for the case of Austria. In this paper, we reduce the

geographical scale to provincial level (NUTS3), and we do not only provide evidence regarding the

2 Source: Instituto Nacional de Estadística, INE. 3 The RELOG project (“Red Logística Española”) has for the first time compiled comprehensive data on the Spanish network of logistics platforms. Professor Celestino Suárez-Burguet led this project. 4 It is important to note that a number of sea ports concentrate the main flows of merchandise traffics in Spain. In particular, the most important sea ports in terms of sea traffic (tonnes) are Bahía de Algeciras, Valencia, Barcelona and Bilbao.

Page 4: Interregional Trade and Transport Connectivity: An ...

4

convenience of introducing spatial dependence in gravity models of trade when analyzing the role of

transport connectivity on regional and sectorial trade flows, but we also obtain unbiased sectorial

elasticities by logistics platform type which capture the magnitude of the impact of different types and

modes of transport connectivity on interregional trade flows.

Focusing on logistics platforms and disentangling them by typology is of great interest as if

intermodality is an issue and logistics platforms mainly connect international and interregional-inter-

modal flows, the most important logistics platforms will be those located in the coast; additionally,

when different sector specific trade flows are considered, such as is the case of the “oil product”, the

logistics platforms of interest would be related to refineries, airports, chemical clusters, etc, which

could be located at the other side of a railway or a pipeline.

The rest of the paper is organized as follows. Section two describes the spatial econometric flow

model and highlights the main hypotheses to be tested. Section three outlines the data and variables

used in the study. The empirical analysis is performed in section four and finally, section five contains

the conclusions and policy implications.

2. The model and main hypotheses

The purpose of flow models is to explain variation in the magnitude of flows between each origin-

destination (O-D) pair. The model introduced by LeSage and Pace (2008) is based on the type of

spatial auto-regressive models appearing in equation (1):

y = ρ�W�y + ρWy +ρ�W�y+∝ +βX + β�X� + γD + ε (1)

As in gravity models (Bergstrand, 1985 and 1989; Deardorff, 1995), X’s matrix captures the

characteristics of origin and destination regions that could influence bilateral trade, as well as the

distance between the main city in origin-destination regions (D). Each variable produces an n2 by 1

vector with the associated parameters at origin i, βo, and destination j, βd. The dependent variable

represents an n by n square matrix of interregional flows from each of the n origin regions to each of

the n destination regions, where each of the n columns of the flow matrix represents a different

destination and the n rows represent origins. As in LeSage and Pace (2008), the model matrices are

defined as �� = �� ⊗ �, �� = � ⊗ �� and �� = �� ⋅ ��.

W matrix represents an n by n spatial weight matrix based on a neighbor’s criteria as geographical

first-order contiguity. Non-zero values for elements i, j denote that zone i is a neighbor to zone j, and

zero values denote that zones i, j are not neighbors. The elements on the diagonal are zero to prevent

an observation from being defined as a neighbor to itself.

The spatial lag vector ��y would be constructed by averaging flows from neighbors to the origin

region, and parameter ρ1 would capture the magnitude of the impact of this type of neighboring

observation on the dependent variable. The spatial lag vector ��� would be constructed by averaging

flows from neighbors to the destination region, and parameter ρ2 would measure the impact and

significance of flows from origin to all neighbors of the destination region. Finally, the third spatial lag in

the model ��� is constructed using an average of all neighbors to both the origin and destination

regions. Estimating parameters ρ1, ρ2 and ρ3 provides an inference of the relative importance of the

three types of spatial dependence between the origin and destination regions.

Page 5: Interregional Trade and Transport Connectivity: An ...

In order to test whether incorporating transport connectivity information into the spatial structure of the

model results in substantial differences in the estimates, a first

based on first-order contiguous neighboring

Ww. Second, the model was estimated based on

conjunction with the restriction that only first

spatial lags. Finally, we disentangle the role of sea ports by introducing

regions, as well as we consider their

The three spatial matrices used in the present study are represented in Figure 1. Matrix

based dependence) captures the spatial relationship between trade of regions

D) and B, matrix Wd (destination

neighboring B (E and F), and matrix

neighboring A (C and D) and regions

Figure 1: Trade flows taken into account (

In relation to transport connectivity,

arise from Figure 1. On the one hand, a low quality of transport networks in one region compared to its

neighbors could be an incentive for firms to locate their activities in a region with better transport

connectivity (diversion effect). On the other hand,

an origin region to a destination region would create similar flows to

effect). Alamá-Sabater et al (2012) showed that the creation effec

using interregional trade data at NUTS

particular province (NUTS3) could benefit from its

effect is higher than the diversion effect

level of disaggregation of geographical data, the greater

creation effect outweighs the diversion effect), as it is difficult

unit could produce many goods without the help of the surrounding areas, as well as

small economic unit would not benefit

markets if it could not reach without crossing them

two different effects related to the fact that

5 Relative importance of each Spanish then if a region has an important sea port and share a border, the matrix element is near 1; otherwise, if they border one another but the sea port moves a reelement is near zero and if they do not border one another the matrix element is zero.6 When considering logistics platforms, it seems plausible for the trade creation effect to be higher than the trade diversion effect the higher the level of disaggregation as, for example, Gerona (NUTS3) benefits from transport infrastructures in Barcelona and Zaragoza to reach the market in Madrid.

In order to test whether incorporating transport connectivity information into the spatial structure of the

model results in substantial differences in the estimates, a first variant of the model w

neighboring regions to construct the weighting matrices

estimated based on a matrix W which considers transport connectivity in

conjunction with the restriction that only first-order neighbors are included in the formation of the

we disentangle the role of sea ports by introducing their presence in neighboring

their relative importance in weighting matrices.5

es used in the present study are represented in Figure 1. Matrix

based dependence) captures the spatial relationship between trade of regions neighboring

destination-based dependence) reflects trade between A and

, and matrix Ww (O-D-based dependence) considers trade between

regions neighboring B (E and F), the three matrixes

Trade flows taken into account (Wo, Wd, Ww, respectively).

In relation to transport connectivity, Alamá-Sabater et al (2012) stated that two opposite effects might

arise from Figure 1. On the one hand, a low quality of transport networks in one region compared to its

could be an incentive for firms to locate their activities in a region with better transport

on effect). On the other hand, it seems plausible that forces leading to flows from

an origin region to a destination region would create similar flows to neighboring destination

Sabater et al (2012) showed that the creation effect overcomes the diversion effect by

nterregional trade data at NUTS2. Therefore, the first hypothesis to be tested is whether

could benefit from its neighbors’ transport networks, and then the creation

than the diversion effect (H1). The second hypothesis to be tested is that

geographical data, the greater we expect the positive effect

the diversion effect), as it is difficult to imagine that a small spatial economic

unit could produce many goods without the help of the surrounding areas, as well as

not benefit from the transport networks of surrounding areas to reach

d not reach without crossing them (H2).6 The third hypothesis tests

related to the fact that most shipments occur only between very proximate location

Spanish sea port is calculated by using a 0-1 standardization measure, then if a region has an important sea port and share a border, the matrix element is near 1; otherwise, if they border one another but the sea port moves a relative low quantity of sea traffic, the matrix element is near zero and if they do not border one another the matrix element is zero.

When considering logistics platforms, it seems plausible for the trade creation effect to be higher than sion effect the higher the level of disaggregation as, for example, Gerona (NUTS3)

benefits from transport infrastructures in Barcelona and Zaragoza to reach the market in Madrid.

5

In order to test whether incorporating transport connectivity information into the spatial structure of the

he model was estimated

matrices Wo, Wd, and

which considers transport connectivity in

are included in the formation of the

their presence in neighboring

es used in the present study are represented in Figure 1. Matrix Wo (origin-

neighboring A (C and

reflects trade between A and regions

considers trade between regions

are n2*n2.

two opposite effects might

arise from Figure 1. On the one hand, a low quality of transport networks in one region compared to its

could be an incentive for firms to locate their activities in a region with better transport

it seems plausible that forces leading to flows from

destinations (creation

t overcomes the diversion effect by

the first hypothesis to be tested is whether a

, and then the creation

The second hypothesis to be tested is that the higher the

the positive effect to be (the

to imagine that a small spatial economic

unit could produce many goods without the help of the surrounding areas, as well as the fact that a

surrounding areas to reach

The third hypothesis tests the co-existence of

most shipments occur only between very proximate location

1 standardization measure, then if a region has an important sea port and share a border, the matrix element is near 1; otherwise,

lative low quantity of sea traffic, the matrix element is near zero and if they do not border one another the matrix element is zero.

When considering logistics platforms, it seems plausible for the trade creation effect to be higher than sion effect the higher the level of disaggregation as, for example, Gerona (NUTS3)

benefits from transport infrastructures in Barcelona and Zaragoza to reach the market in Madrid.

Page 6: Interregional Trade and Transport Connectivity: An ...

6

pairs. First, goods are more likely to be exported to a particular importing region when price becomes

competitive with local alternatives, as a good transportation connection network to surrounding regions

increases neighbors’ exports (origin-dependence). Second, a good transportation connection network

to surrounding regions might also be highly beneficial to satisfy the existing local industrial demand

and then to increase neighbors’ imports (destination-based dependence). The hypothesis stated by

Hillberry and Hummels (2008) with highly disaggregated trade data that variation in regional industrial

structure should help explain the pattern of bilateral shipments would be supported if destination-

dependence is found to be higher than origin-based dependence. Additionally, Spanish interregional

traders might find it easier to cooperate in destination than in origin, as the industrial structure forces

importers to cooperate in logistics to benefit in terms of trade costs to a higher extent than exporters

(H3). Hypothesis four states that first-order contiguity dependence may include a series of factors such

as cultural proximity, a shared history, and a perception of closeness and information costs rather than

acting exclusively as a proxy for transport connectivity. By estimating the two variants of equation (1),

the constructed from first-order contiguity relationships (first-order contiguity) and the model based on

transport connectivity considerations (connectivity), the effect of transport connectivity is isolated.

Therefore, coefficients ρ�, ρ and ρ�in the connectivity model (by different types of logistics platforms)

should be lower in magnitude than those obtained in the first-order contiguity model (H4), as the

connectivity model is a more accurate way to estimate the role of transport connectivity, understood in

the broad sense. Finally, we disentangle the role of sea ports on trade of different sectors, as if

intermodality is an issue and logistics platforms mainly connect international and interregional-inter-

modal flows, neighboring to logistics platforms located in the coast will play a significant role on

interregional trade flows (H5).

3. Data and variables

We generate a dataset with total commodity flows transported between 47 Spanish regions

(provinces)7 during the year 2007.8 As we are considering the interregional trade in the mainland and

the effect of trade with bordering regions, the Canary Islands and the Balearic Islands, Ceuta and

Melilla are not taken into account.9 The regions were based on the NUTS3 and the interregional trade

flow matrices were supplied by C-Interreg.10 We used 16 origin-destination matrices; one with total

trade flows in tonnes, while the others correspond to 15 branches of activity.11 We focus on extending

gravity equations and then consider a number of the characteristics of the origin and destination

regions. In order to construct the matrices Xo (origin) and Xd (destination), and following LeSage and

Polasek (2008), we used the log of the area, the log of population, the log of GDP per capita and the

7 See Figure A.1, in Appendix. 8 We have worked with 47 regions, so the weighting matrix is 2209 rows and 2209 columns (47x47). 9 Note that neither “ship-land” nor “plane-land” connections between the peninsula and the islands play a significant role to connect international and interregional-inter-modal flows, as there is not an important commodity trade flow between inner regions and the islands. Islands-peninsula logistics platform connections are used mainly for passengers transportation. 10 We are using “unrestricted” trade flows supplied by C-intereg project. This dataset is explained in Llano et al (2008), where a difference is made between “restricted” and “unrestricted” flows. 11 See Table A.1 in the Appendix.

Page 7: Interregional Trade and Transport Connectivity: An ...

7

log of unemployment in each region12 as explanatory variables. A vector of (logged) distances (km)

between the capitals of each O-D region was also included as an explanatory variable, along with an

intercept vector. We would expect area, population and GDP per capita to display a positive sign,

leading to higher levels of commodity flows (weights) in both the origin and destination regions. The

coefficient of unemployment is expected to present an ambiguous sign as this variable might be

reflecting sector-specific characteristics such as the degree of resources intensity and technological

innovation achievement, whereas the expected coefficient estimate on distance is ambiguous. First,

distance might be negative, indicating a decrease in commodity flows with distance and, second,

distance variable might be positive if Spanish provinces trade more, for example, with the largest

economic centers, which are not necessarily the nearest ones when a much disaggregated territorial

level is taken into account.

In order to explain the model and the dependent variable in equation (1), we generate an n2 by 1

vector by stacking the columns of the matrix. If we consider a model with 4 regions, the flow matrix

would be represented as in Table 1. Columns show the dyad label (4 origin regions x 4 destination

regions = 16), identifier (ID) of the origin region and ID of the destination region, y denotes the

dependent variable (exports) and X’s the explanatory variables (area, population, GDP per capita and

employment, together with geographical distance). Only four regions (Seville, Zaragoza, Barcelona

and Madrid) are considered in Table 1 for simplicity.

Table 1: Data organization

Dyad label

Region origin ID origin

Region destination

ID destination

Origin explanation variables

Destination explanation variables

Distances

Y X1 X2 X3 X1 X2 X3

1 Seville 1 Seville 1 y11 a11 a12 a13 b11 b12 b13 d11

2 Zaragoza 2 Seville 1 y21 a21 a22 a23 b11 b12 b13 d21

3 Barcelona 3 Seville 1 y31 a31 a32 a33 b11 b12 b13 d31

4 Madrid 4 Seville 1 y41 a41 a42 a43 b11 b12 b13 d41

5 Seville 1 Zaragoza 2 y12 a11 a12 a13 b21 b22 b23 d12

6 Zaragoza 2 Zaragoza 2 y22 a21 a22 a23 b21 b22 b23 d22

7 Barcelona 3 Zaragoza 2 y32 a31 a32 a33 b21 b22 b23 d32

8 Madrid 4 Zaragoza 2 y42 a41 a42 a43 b21 b22 b23 d42

9 Seville 1 Barcelona 3 y13 a11 a12 a13 b31 b32 b33 d13

10 Zaragoza 2 Barcelona 3 y23 a21 a22 a23 b31 b32 b33 d23

11 Barcelona 3 Barcelona 3 y33 a31 a32 a33 b31 b32 b33 d33

12 Madrid 4 Barcelona 3 y43 a41 a42 a43 b31 b32 b33 d43

13 Seville 1 Madrid 4 y14 a11 a12 a13 b41 b42 b43 d14

14 Zaragoza 2 Madrid 4 y24 a21 a22 a23 b41 b42 b43 d24

15 Barcelona 3 Madrid 4 y34 a31 a32 a33 b41 b42 b43 d34

16 Madrid 4 Madrid 4 y44 a41 a42 a43 b41 b42 b43 d44

12 The Spanish Statistical Institute (INE) is the data source of explanatory variables. Regarding the dependent variables, dates refer to 2007.

Page 8: Interregional Trade and Transport Connectivity: An ...

8

Alamá-Sabater et al (2012) constructed weighting matrices by using a geographical criterion

(contiguity-based model) and introducing the presence of logistics platforms (transport connectivity

model), i.e. the regions adjacent to A (origin) or B (destination) that also have logistics platforms. In

order to proxy the quality and level of logistics factors between O-D regions, they calculated a

connectivity index as a simple average of two dimension indices, these being the number and size of

logistics platforms.

Figure A.2 in Appendix presents an example to illustrate the accuracy difference regarding transport

connectivity on interregional trade flows between both the first-order contiguity and the connectivity

model. In the example, Zaragoza has eight neighbors (Huesca, Lleida, Tarragona, Teruel,

Guadalajara, Soria, La Rioja and Navarra) and, whereas in the contiguity model the eight regions

present equal weights (the geographical criteria are the same for all regions), in the connectivity model

the imposed filter weights the eight regions with the connectivity index defined above, and then three

regions present the highest weightings (Tarragona, Guadalajara and Navarra).

Following Alamá-Sabater et al (2012), Figures 2 and 3 show the number of logistics platforms and the

logistics surface area by Spanish province, respectively. Madrid, Barcelona, Zaragoza and Cadiz,

have the largest surface area of logistics platforms, mainly due to the presence of very large logistics

platforms in these regions (such as the Zaragoza Logistics Centre in the region of Aragon, the Madrid

Barajas centre in the Madrid region and the Port of Algeciras in Andalusia), which increase the

average size of platforms. Provinces such as Valence, in the Valencian Community, and a number of

provinces in Andalusia-Extremadura (Seville, Malaga, Granada and Badajoz13) also present a large

number of logistics platforms. In contrast, provinces in Extremadura, Castile La Mancha and Castile

and Leon show a real shortage of square meters devoted to logistics activities. The Balearic and

Canary Islands are also home to only a small number of large platforms linked to their ports. This

transport connectivity picture is in line with the international or supra-regional intermodal nodes

identified in PEIT (2005), which are located in the area of Madrid, the area of Barcelona/Catalonia, the

area of the Basque Country, and Valencia, Zaragoza, Algeciras and Seville, as well as with the main

national combined traffic corridors that are located on the Mediterranean Axis, the Central Corridor

(Asturias-Madrid, Basque Country-Madrid and from here to Andalusia) and the Ebro Axis. Traffic levels

are also significant in the Madrid-Levante Corridor.

Figure 2: Number of logistics platforms (by Spanish region in 2007).

13 The Madrid-Badajoz-Portugal axis is also a corridor of great importance.

Page 9: Interregional Trade and Transport Connectivity: An ...

9

Source: The RELOG project.

Figure 3: Logistics surface area (by Spanish region in 2007) as a percentage of total logistics surface

area in Spain.

Source: The RELOG project.

19

0

NUMBER OF LOGISTIC PLATFORMS

17.48

0

2007

LOGISTIC SURFACE AREA

Page 10: Interregional Trade and Transport Connectivity: An ...

10

In order to introduce logistics characteristics by modifying weighting matrixes in a spatial

autoregressive specification to proxy for transport connectivity, Alamá-Sabater et al (2012) calculated

a connectivity index as a simple average of the number and size of logistics platforms. Scores of every

dimension were derived as an index relative to the maximum and minimum achieved by both origin

and destination regions, based on the assumption that logistics play a comparable role in O-D. The

performance of the connectivity index took a value between 0 and 1 calculated according to equation

(2):

)minmax(

)min(

valueobservedvalueobserved

valueobservedvalueactualCI

−= (2)

According to this index, if regions i, j have good logistics infrastructure and share a border, the matrix

element is near 1; otherwise, if they border one another but the logistics infrastructure is poor, the

matrix element is near zero and if they do not border one another the matrix element is zero.

Nonetheless, a number of shortcomings should be mentioned related to the definition of what is

considered as “logistics platform”.

One possible definition of logistics activities is the process of planning, implementing, and controlling

the efficient, cost effective flow and storage of raw materials, in process inventory, finished goods and

related information flows from point of origin to point of consumption for the purpose of conforming to

customer requirements.14 According to this definition, under the RELOG project, logistics platforms are

locations where goods can be stored, transshipped between different means of transport and where

their journeys are organized. The facilities considered logistics platforms are: dry ports, logistics

platforms, logistics zones, centers for commodity exchanges, inter-modal centers, logistics centers,

transport centers, ports, loading terminals, centers for boarding located in airports and merchandize

terminals. Then, a number of questions arise. First, whether the “logistics platform” term includes “free

ports” or “free zones”, located in the ports. These areas are mainly connected to the activity of

international customs and are built mainly for promoting the international trade (not the interregional

one). Therefore, if the size and number of “logistics platform” include these areas, the situation of the

coastal regions, with large “maritime ports” and intense international trade in/out- flows, will be biased

compared to the inner regions. Second, whether the “logistics platform” term includes “stocking-

facilities” and then, whether they are owned by the firms producing the commodities (self-stocking-

facilities) or by “logistics operators”. And third, whether the “logistics platforms” term includes “oil-

chemical-gas” tanks strategically located around big airports, ports and refineries. Depending on the

answer to these questions, the effects captured by the model will be different, as well as the

interpretation of the results obtained in sectorial regressions.

Therefore, in the empirical analysis, we firstly run regressions by using highly disaggregated regional

trade data at NUTS3 with the same methodology as used in Alamá-Sabater et al (2012). Thus is, our

first variant of the model includes only first-order contiguity (contiguity-based model), whereas our

second variant of the model (transport connectivity model) reflects the logistics performance in

Spanish provinces by using surface and size of logistics platforms. Finally, logistics platforms by

typology are disentangled for a better understanding of the role of spatial and transportation networks

14 US Council of Supply Chain Management. Webpage: www.cscmp.org

Page 11: Interregional Trade and Transport Connectivity: An ...

11

dependence on interregional trade flows. Table A.2 in Appendix lists logistics platforms included

separately under every issue.

4. Empirical analysis

4.1. Descriptive analysis

First of all, we present a map of Spain showing regions containing the total trade flows, as export-trade

(Figure 4) and as import-trade (Figure 5). The areas where the most important trade flows are

concentrated are identified with darker colors (darker red colors reflect higher levels of flows, while

lighter red colors indicate lower flow levels). These maps represent total trade flows, so the analysis

should be carried out from a general point of view. According to our data, the Spanish regions with the

greatest outward and inward intensity are Barcelona, Madrid, Seville and Valencia.15

Figure 4: Spanish regions (NUTS3) by export intensity.16

Figure 5: Spanish regions (NUTS3) by import intensity.

15 Note that the maps on intensity of trade flows are measured in tonnes, therefore, they do not control for the value/volume relation of the flows. As a consequence, a number of regions could appear to be as very important trading regions, but they are not. 16 These maps are constructed by setting flows within regions to zero to emphasize interregional flows.

1.5e+08

720621

Total trade (tonnes) 2007

SPANISH PROVINCES (NUTS 3) BY EXPORT INTENSITY (OUTFLOWS)

Page 12: Interregional Trade and Transport Connectivity: An ...

12

Finally, Figure 6 shows the map of the connectivity index from equation (2) in the case of NUTS3.17

Examining the maps in Figures 4 and 5 in conjunction with that of the logistics network in Figure 6,

there appear to be more flows in origin and destination regions in the provinces where logistics

networks are more extensive than in provinces with less developed logistics networks.

In the Spanish case, a clear differentiation can be made between provinces in terms of logistics

performance and then, this descriptive test emphasizes the need of explicitly incorporating such prior

information into the spatial and networks dependence structure of a spatial econometric flow model

when analyzing trade flows, as it might result in substantial differences in the estimates and

inferences.

Figure 6: Spanish regions (NUTS3) - Connectivity index

17 The regions containing the highest logistics performance index values are dark red.

1.5e+08

4.5e+06

Total trade (tonnes) 2007

SPANISH PROVINCES (NUTS 3) BY IMPORT INTENSITY (INFLOWS)

Page 13: Interregional Trade and Transport Connectivity: An ...

13

4.2. Main results

In order to analyze the spatial dependence of interregional Spanish trade flows, we estimate equation

(1) by maximizing the log-likelihood function concentrated with respect to the parameters ρ1, ρ2 and

ρ3, and the parameters βi.

Our first variant of the model includes only first-order contiguity, whereas our second variant of the

model reflects the logistics performance in Spanish regions discussed in Section 3, as we employ a

matrix W which considers logistics performance in conjunction with the restriction that only first-order

neighbors are included in the formation of the spatial lags. This results in a direct relationship between

increased numbers of the nearest neighbors and the performance of the logistics segments that go on

to form the spatial lag variables. Full results are only presented for the transport connectivity model for

simplicity.18

Different columns in Table 2 present the results obtained when estimating equation (1) for total trade

and different activity branches (R1-R15). Column (1) shows that area, population and income display

the expected positive sign and are significant. The bigger surface, population and income are in a

region the higher trade flows. Unemployment is found to be not significant, whereas distance is

positive signed and significant.19 The positive sign found in the variables of area, population and

income, in conjunction with the positive sign found in distance variable might be pointing towards the

idea that provinces trade more with the largest economic centers, which are not necessarily the

nearest ones when a much disaggregated territorial level is taken into account. The negative sign for

distance variable found in sectors R4 (Textile and Clothing), R5 (Leather and Footwear Industry), R9

(Manufactures of Rubber and Plastic Products) and R12 (Manufactures of Machinery and Mechanical

18 The full results for the first-order contiguity model are available upon request from the authors. 19 Similar results are obtained for the first-order contiguity model.

Deviation from the mean[+]Deviation from the mean[-]

CONNECTIVITY INDEX

Page 14: Interregional Trade and Transport Connectivity: An ...

14

Equipment) seems to indicate a higher importance of interregional land (road/rail) transportation costs

in these sectors, as the higher the geographical distance, the lower trade, and as a consequence they

might be tending to locate nearer to the most important economic and geographical Spanish centers.

The variable of occupation/unemployment is found to be positive and significant in sectors R1

(Agriculture, Forestry and Fishing), R2 (Mining and Quarrying), R11 (Basic Metals and Fabricated

Metal Products), R14 (Manufactures of Transport Equipment) and R15 (Diverse Industries). This result

might be reflecting that these industries are intensive in labor, as a higher number of workers engaged

in these industries (higher occupation/lower unemployment), the higher production and exports.

With regard to the sectorial parameters which capture the magnitude of the impact of transport

connectivity on Spanish interregional trade flows (ρ1, ρ2 and ρ3), we find a positive and significant

effect of transport connectivity, understood in its broad sense, on total trade flows. Therefore, a

particular region benefits from its neighbors’ transportation networks, as the creation effect is higher

than the diversion effect and the spatial lags for the origin and destination (associated with parameters

ρ1 and ρ2) average of neighboring regions on the logistics network are positively associated with the

level of commodity flows (H1).

Page 15: Interregional Trade and Transport Connectivity: An ...

15

Table 2: Estimates from the transport connectivity spatial model Total

trade R1 R2 R3 R4 R5 R6 R7 R8 R9 R10 R11 R12 R13 R14 R15

Origin Area 0.73***

(4.16)

1.18***

(5.70)

0.32

(1.52)

0.42*

(1.91)

0.09

(0.94)

0.23***

(2.58)

0.42**

(2.33)

0.26

(1.55)

0.66***

(3.32)

0.33**

(2.12)

0.62***

(2.94)

0.84***

(4.18)

0.17

(1.46)

0.47***

(2.76)

0.26

(1.50)

0.57***

(3.83)

Origin

Population

1.25***

(11.34)

1.12***

(9.16)

1.05***

(8.40)

0.98***

(7.37)

0.49***

(8.59)

0.52***

(10.13)

0.87***

(8.14)

1.32***

(11.94)

1.25***

(10.27)

1.17***

(12.76)

1.39***

(10.68)

1.59***

(12.47)

0.21***

(3.27)

1.15***

(11.00)

0.93***

(8.80)

1.01***

(11.47)

Origin GDPpc 2.42***

(3.93)

4.20***

(5.72)

2.32***

(3.13)

2.02***

(2.62)

0.26

(0.73)

0.23

(0.70)

1.34**

(2.12)

2.39***

(4.01)

2.55***

(3.67)

1.35**

(2.45)

2.81***

(3.77)

4.97***

(6.91)

0.39

(0.95)

1.82***

(3.03)

2.16***

(3.50)

2.17***

(4.14)

Origin

Occupation

0.04

(0.74)

0.13**

(2.21)

0.11*

(1.81)

0.01

(0.21)

-0.02

(-0.61)

-0.03

(-1.12)

-0.007

(-0.13)

-0.02

(-0.45)

0.06

(0.97)

-0.05

(-1.19)

0.06

(0.99)

0.26***

(4.24)

0.02

(0.48)

0.03

(0.57)

0.09*

(1.68)

0.10**

(2.38)

Destination

Area

0.62***

(3.52)

1.22***

(5.75)

0.28

(1.32)

0.94***

(4.36)

0.11

(1.10)

0.12

(1.33)

0.44**

(2.40)

0.21

(1.22)

0.65***

(3.22)

0.31**

(2.00)

0.74***

(3.50)

0.40*

(1.93)

0.17

(1.50)

0.71***

(4.22)

0.22

(1.24)

0.32**

(2.16)

Destination

Population

0.76***

(7.33)

0.69***

(5.95)

0.66***

(5.49)

1.02***

(7.94)

0.47***

(8.25)

0.35***

(7.12)

0.43***

(4.31)

1.22***

(11.23)

1.16***

(9.32)

1.06***

(10.88)

0.95***

(7.20)

1.18***

(9.24)

0.37***

(5.78)

1.11***

(10.87)

0.96***

(8.98)

0.85***

(9.17)

Destination

GDPpc

1.76***

(2.90)

3.98***

(5.49)

1.66**

(2.22)

2.39***

(3.20)

0.13

(0.38)

0.23

(0.72)

0.47

(0.75)

2.78***

(4.64)

2.18***

(3.07)

1.49***

(2.71)

1.65**

(2.24)

4.30***

(5.98)

1.32***

(3.20)

3.34***

(5.62

2.87***

(4.62)

-0.002

(-0.005)

Destination

Occupation

0.01

(0.20)

0.20***

(3.35)

0.06

(0.99)

0.04

(0.69)

-0.05*

(-1.67)

-0.004

(-0.16)

-0.07

(-1.40)

-0.05

(-1.01)

-0.02

(-0.31)

-0.15***

(-2.90)

-0.01

(-0.12)

0.19***

(3.22)

0.06*

(1.68)

0.13***

(2.62)

0.07

(1.32)

-0.15***

(-3.06)

Distance 0.88***

(10.52)

0.60***

(5.78)

0.64***

(5.53)

0.63***

(5.94)

-0.13***

(-2.94)

-0.08**

(-2.03)

1.13

(1.46)

-0.03

(-0.39)

0.22**

(2.36)

-0.17**

(-2.44)

0.56***

(5.03)

0.19*

(1.96)

-0.17***

(-2.99)

-0.12

(-1.35)

0.009

(0.11)

-0.08

(-1.14)

Constant term -30.07***

(-8.12)

-21.65***

(-5.17)

-18.90***

(-4.36)

-25.99***

(-5.88)

-11.51***

(-5.49)

-12.13***

(-6.40)

-18.33***

(-4.88)

-16.38***

(-4.76)

-27.14***

(-6-64)

-21.09***

(-6.67)

-30.80***

(-7.00)

-16.54***

(-3.92)

-3.52

(-1.49)

-21.15***

(-6.16)

-10:86***

(-2.94)

-23.07***

(-7.43)

ρ1. Connectivity 0.22***

(5.75)

0.31***

(8.42)

0.26***

(7.17)

0.49***

(14.51)

-0.02

(-0.54)

-0.02

(-0.73)

0.24***

(6.41)

0.23***

(6.91)

0.18***

(4.87)

-0.08**

(-2.30)

0.22***

(5.69)

0.09**

(2.45)

0.08**

(2.47)

0.16***

(4.68)

0.27***

(8.46)

-0.07*

(-1.89)

ρ2. Connectivity 0.41***

(11.45)

0.41***

(12.13)

0.30***

(8.61)

0.42***

(11.56)

0.10***

(3.39)

0.12***

(4.16)

0.26***

(7.96)

0.22***

(6.62)

0.36***

(10.98)

0.22***

(6.70)

0.51***

(15.33)

0.41***

(12.64)

0.05

(1.35)

0.18***

(5.60)

0.31***

(9.98)

0.37***

(12.25)

ρ3. Connectivity 0.46***

(8.61)

0.33***

(6.91)

0.54***

(11.19)

-0.03

(-0.71)

0.05

(1.23)

0.18***

(4.30)

0.33***

(6.73)

-0.06

(-1.43)

0.19***

(4.05)

0.12***

(2.65)

0.23***

(4.88)

0.22***

(4.96)

0.25***

(4.72)

0.23***

(5.27)

-0.04

(-1.00)

0.16***

(3.54)

ρ1. First-order

contiguity

0.27***

(6.62)

0.32***

(8.07)

0.28***

(6.73)

0.51***

(14.30)

-0.01

(-0.17)

-0.05

(-1.19)

0.26***

(6.44)

0.30***

(7.92)

0.22***

(5.44)

-0.05

(-1.24)

0.23***

(5.52)

0.12***

(2.82)

0.04

(1.01)

0.19***

(4.69)

0.36***

(9.74)

-0.06

(-1.55)

Page 16: Interregional Trade and Transport Connectivity: An ...

16

ρ2. First-order

contiguity

0.42***

(11.91)

0.46***

(12.63)

0.32***

(7.94)

0.48***

(12.82)

0.14***

(3.52)

0.22***

(5.71)

0.31***

(8.06)

0.31***

(8.15)

0.41***

(11.48)

0.32***

(8.66)

0.61***

(17.30)

0.47***

(13.86)

0.11***

(2.71)

0.28***

(7.09)

0.39***

(10.85)

0.50***

(14.75)

ρ3. First-order

contiguity

0.53***

(9.14)

0.37***

(7.02)

0.69***

(11.92)

0.04

(0.887)

0.12*

(1.83)

0.36***

(5.04)

0.46***

(7.53)

-0.05

(-1.03)

0.22***

(4.14)

0.22***

(3.86)

0.31***

(5.62)

0.32***

(6.05)

0.44***

(5.85)

0.36***

(6.27))

-0.05

(-0.85)

0.31***

(5.02)

Notes: ***, **, * indicate significance at 1%, 5% and 10%, respectively. Z-statistics are given in brackets.

Page 17: Interregional Trade and Transport Connectivity: An ...

17

Overall, O-D-based dependence, i.e. that dependence considering trade between regions neighboring

origin and regions neighboring destination, is found to be of greater importance than origin-based and

destination-based dependence. If we compare these results with those obtained in Alamá-Sabater et

al (2012), they are in line with the expectation that the higher the level of disaggregation of

geographical data, the greater the positive effect of transport connectivity on interregional trade flows.

Therefore, we are able to provide empirical evidence supporting H2.

Furthermore, when different sectors are distinguished, three different patterns emerge. First, those

sectors for which origin-based dependence is the most important (R3: Food Industry and R7: Paper,

printing and Graphic Arts), where an origin region with a good transportation connection network to

surrounding regions benefits the most in terms of exports. Second, we find sectors for which

destination-based dependence is the most important (R1, R4, R8, R9, R10, R11, R14 and R15),

where a destination region with a good transportation connection network to surrounding regions

benefits the most in terms of trade. This result is in line with the hypothesis stated by Hillberry and

Hummels (2008) that variation in regional industrial structure should help explain the pattern of

bilateral shipments. Therefore, a good transportation connection network to surrounding regions is

highly beneficial to satisfy the existing local industrial demand (H3). Finally, we also find those sectors

for which O-D dependence is the most important (R2, R5, R6, R12 and R13). As previous research

which revealed a spatial pattern when analyzing interregional trade flows in Spain (Alamá-Sabater et

al, 2012), there is a consistent pattern of parameter ρ2 being of greater importance than ρ1,

suggesting that neighbors to the destination region in the analyzed logistics model represent the most

important determinant of higher levels of industrial commodity flows between O-D pairs. These results

differ of those obtained by LeSage and Polasek (2008) for the case of Austria, who find that ρ1 is

always larger than ρ2, pointing towards more importance assigned to the spatial lag involving

neighbors to the origin, relative to the destination region.

We also provide evidence supporting H4, as coefficients ρ1, ρ2 and ρ3 are always of higher

magnitude in the case of the first-order contiguity model than in the case of the transport connectivity

model. Nonetheless, the sign and significance of ρ1, ρ2 and ρ3 are similar in both models, excluding

the case of R12 (Manufacture of machinery and mechanical equipment), for which origin dependence

seems to be of higher importance than destination dependence in the transport connectivity model,

whereas the opposite conclusion holds for the first-order contiguity model.

With regards to H5, Table 3 and Table 4 present the results obtained for agriculture and industrial

sectors, respectively, when introducing only sea ports in the connectivity model.

The results obtained in Table 3 show that the spatial lags are positive and significant, and that both

origin and destination dependence seem to be of similar magnitude in agriculture. Therefore, spatial

and transportation networks play a significant role on agriculture interregional trade flows when only

sea ports are considered as logistics platforms.

Table 3: Estimates from the transport connectivity spatial model (only sea ports are considered).

Agriculture sectors

ρ1 ρ2 ρ3

R1 0.15*** 0.17*** -0.03

Page 18: Interregional Trade and Transport Connectivity: An ...

18

(5.92) (7.06) (-1.18) R2 0.16*** 0.18*** 0.01 (6.67) (7.36) (0.44) R3 0.17*** 0.15*** -0.16*** (7.19) (6.59) (-6.39)

Notes: ***, **, * indicate significance at 1%, 5% and 10%, respectively. Z-statistics are given in

brackets. The dependent variable is measured in Tons.

Table 4 shows that ρ1, ρ2 and ρ3 are positive and significant for the industrial exports of most sectors.

Additionally, there is a consistent pattern of parameter ρ2 being more times positive and significant

than ρ1 in a number of sectors, suggesting that neighbors of the destination region in the transport

connectivity model represent the most important determinant of higher levels of industrial commodity

flows between O-D pairs. Overall, sector-by-sector results suggest that a particular region could

benefit from its neighbors’ sea ports, and then intermodality is an issue as logistics networks connect

international and interregional trade flows.

Table 4: Estimates from the transport connectivity spatial model (only sea ports are considered).

Industrial sectors

Notes: ***, **, * indicate significance at 1%, 5% and 10%, respectively. Z-statistics are given in brackets. The dependent variable is measured in Tons.

5. Conclusions and policy implications

This paper analyses the role of transport connectivity on interregional trade flows using a spatial

approach. We find evidence of the importance of transport connectivity, understood in a broad sense,

ρ1 ρ2 ρ3

R4 0.001 0.06** 0.06** (0.08) (2.52) (2.47) R5 -0.06*** 0.09*** 0.08** (-2.59) (4.2) (2.37) R6 0.10*** 0.13*** 0.10*** (3.89) (5.47) (3.54) R7 0.13*** 0.11*** -0.10*** (5.86) (5.31) (-4.61) R8 0.10*** 0.18*** -0.01 (4.41) (7.69) (-0.49) R9 -0.05** 0.11*** 0.04* (-1.96) (5.35) (1.78) R10 0.13*** 0.21*** -0.07*** (5.15) (8.49) (-2.84) R11 0.03 0.18*** -0.02 (1.25) (8.32) (-1.05) R12 -0.004 0.02 0.08*** (-0.157) (0.82) (2.61) R13 0.06** 0.09*** -0.07*** (2.49) (3.94) (-2.98) R14 0.12*** 0.16*** -0.09*** (5.21) (7.53) (-4.07) R15 -0.03 0.16*** 0.06** (-1.33) (7.04) (2.53)

Page 19: Interregional Trade and Transport Connectivity: An ...

19

on trade. Additionally, it is confirmed that the gravity equation replays the determinants of interregional

trade with a large degree of significance in terms of the use of economic and geographical variables

(income, population, area, and distance).

First, we provide evidence that forces leading to flows from an origin region to a destination region

would create similar flows to neighboring destinations and then, a particular region benefits from its

neighbors’ transport networks (H1). Second, we find that the higher the level of territorial breakdown

the higher the positive effect of logistics networks on interregional exports, as a smaller territorial unit

depend to a greater extent on their neighbors’ transportation networks (H2). Third, destination-based

dependence seems to be of higher importance than origin-based dependence in the case of Spanish

interregional trade flows. Opposite to other countries for which transport networks might play a more

important role to increase price competitiveness for exporters (such as Austria), obtained results

support that Spanish provinces mostly specialize in the production of different goods and transport

networks contribute to increase imports related to that industries in destination neighboring regions, as

it is easier to cooperate as importers of commodities than as exporters (H3). By estimating the two

variants of equation (1), we obtain that the connectivity model is a more accurate way to estimate the

role of transport connectivity than the first-order contiguity model (H4). Finally, we disentangle the role

of sea ports on trade of different sectors, and we find that neighboring to logistics platforms located in

the coast plays a significant role on interregional and international trade flows; Spanish sea ports

connect intranational traders with international destinations (H5).

References

• Alamá-Sabater, L. Márquez-Ramos, L. and Suárez-Burguet, C. (2012), “Trade and transport

connectivity: A spatial approach,” Applied Economics, forthcoming.

• Bergstrand, J. H. (1985): “The gravity equation in international trade: Some microeconomic

foundations and empirical evidence”, The Review of Economics and Statistics 67(3), 474-481.

• Bergstrand, J. H. (1989): “The generalized gravity equation, monopolistic competition, and the

factor-proportions theory in international trade”, The Review of Economics and Statistics 71(1),

143-153.

• Clark, X., D. Dollar, and A. Micco (2004): “Port efficiency, maritime transport costs, and bilateral

trade”. Journal of Development Economics 75(2), 417–450.

• Deardorff, A. V. (1995): “Determinants of bilateral trade: Does gravity work in a Neo-classical

word?” NBER Working Paper 5377.

• Eaton, J. and Kortum, S. (2002): “Technology, geography, and trade”. Econometrica 70, 1741–

1779.

• European Commission (EC) (2011) “Proposal for a regulation of the European parliament and of

the council establishing the connecting Europe facility”, COM (2011) 665/3, Brussels.

• Hillberry, R. and Hummels D. (2008): “Trade responses to geographic frictions: A decomposition

using micro-data”. European Economic Review 52, 527–550.

• LeSage J.P. and Pace R.K. (2004): Introduction to Spatial and Spatiotemporal in Spatial and

Spatiotemporal Econometrics. Published by James P. LeSage and R. Kelley Pace. Vol. 18. Oxford:

Elsevier Ltd.

Page 20: Interregional Trade and Transport Connectivity: An ...

20

• LeSage J.P. and Pace R.K. (2008): "Spatial econometric modeling of origin-destination flows."

Journal of Regional Science 5, 941-967.

• LeSage, J. P. and Llano, C. (2006): “A Spatial Interaction Model With Spatially Structured Origin

and Destination Effects”, SSRN: http://ssrn.com/abstract=924603

• LeSage, J. P., and Polasek W. (2008): "Incorporating transportation network structure in spatial

econometric models of commodity flows." Spatial Economic Analysis 3 (2), 225-245.

• Limao, N, and Venables, AJ (2001): “Infrastructure, Geographical Disadvantage and Transport

Costs.” World Bank Economic Review 15, 451-479.

• Llano C.; Esteban, A., Pérez, J., Pulido, A. (2008): “Opening The Interregional Trade “Black Box”:

The C-Intereg Database For The Spanish Economy (1995-2005)”. International Regional Science

Review. Doi:10.1177/0160017610370701.

• Márquez-Ramos, L., Martínez-Zarzoso, I., Pérez-García, E. and Wilmsmeier, G. (2011): “Special

Issue on Latin-American Research” Maritime Networks, Services Structure and Maritime Trade.

Networks and Spatial Economics 11(3), 555-576.

• Melitz, M.J. (2003): “The impact of trade on intra-industry reallocations and aggregate industry

productivity”. Econometrica 71, 1695–1725.

• Micco, A. and Serebrisky, T. (2004): “Infrastructure, competition regimes, and air transport costs:

Cross-country evidence.” Policy Research Working Paper Series 3355, The World Bank.

• PEIT (2005), Plan Estratégico de Infraestructuras y Transporte - Strategic Infrastructures and

Transport Plan (2005-2020), Centro de Publicaciones Secretaría General Técnica Ministerio de

Fomento, Madrid. http://www.fomento.gob.es/MFOM/LANG_CASTELLANO/_ESPECIALES/PEIT/

• Sanchez, R.J., J. Hoffmann, A. Micco, G.V. Pizzolitto, M. Sgut and Wilmsmeier, G. (2003): “Port

Efficiency and International Trade: Port Efficiency as a Determinant of Maritime Transport Costs”.

Maritime Economics & Logistics, 5, 199–218.

• Wilson, J. S., C. L. Mann, and T. Otsuki (2004): “Assessing the Potential Benefit of Trade

Facilitation: A Global Perspective”. Working Paper 3224, The World Bank.

Page 21: Interregional Trade and Transport Connectivity: An ...

21

Appendix

Figure A.1. Provinces in Spain (NUTS3).

Figure A.2. First-order contiguity versus transport connectivity model.

Table A.1: Activity branches. R1- Agriculture, forestry and fishing R2- Mining and quarrying R3- Food Industry R4- Textile and clothing R5- Leather and Footwear Industry R6- Manufacture of wood and cork R7- Paper, printing and graphic arts R8- Chemical Industry R9- Manufacture of rubber and plastic products R10- Industry, non-metallic mineral products R11- Basic metals and fabricated metal products R12- Manufacture of machinery and mechanical equipment R13- Electrical equipment, electronic and optical R14- Manufacture of transport equipment R15- Diverse industries Source: Spanish Statistical Institute, INE, Spain (2010). www.ine.es

Page 22: Interregional Trade and Transport Connectivity: An ...

22

Table A.2. Spanish logistics platforms, by typology.

Air Cargo Province (NUTS3) Autonomous Region (NUTS2)

TC de Palma de Mallorca Palma de Mallorca Islas Baleares

TC de Sevilla Sevilla Andalucía

TC de Zaragoza Zaragoza Aragón

TC de Gran Canaria Las Palmas Islas Canarias

TC de Málaga Málaga Andalucía

TC de Bilbao Vizcaya País Vasco

Puerto de Sta. C. De Tenerife Santa Cruz de Tenerife Islas Canarias

TC de Fuerteventura Las Palmas Islas Canarias

TC de Tenerife sur Santa Cruz de Tenerife Islas Canarias

TC de Santander Santander Cantabria

TC de Santiago Santiago Galicia

TC de Asturias Asturias Principado de Asturias

TC de Tenerife norte Santa Cruz de Tenerife Islas Canarias

TC de Reus Tarragona Cataluña

TC de Girona Gerona Cataluña

TC de Vigo Pontevedra Galicia

TC de A Coruña La Coruña Galicia

TC de San Sebastián Guipúzcoa País Vasco

Centros de Carga Aérea de Madrid-Barajas Madrid Comunidad de Madrid

Centros de Carga Aérea Barcelona-El Prat Barcelona Cataluña

Centros de Carga Aérea Valencia Valencia Comunidad Valenciana

Carga terrestre intermodal (dry ports) Province (NUTS3) Autonomous Region (NUTS2)

Puerto Seco de Castilla-León Palencia Castilla La Mancha

Puerto Seco de Antequera Málaga Andalucía

Puerto Seco de Toral de los Vados (El Bierzo) León Castilla La Mancha

Puerto Seco La Robla León Castilla La Mancha

Puerto Seco Venta de Baños Ventasur Palencia Castilla La Mancha

Puerto Seco de Coslada Madrid Comunidad de Madrid

Puerto Seco Santander-Ebro Zaragoza Aragón

Puerto Seco TMZ. Terminal Marítima de Zaragoza Zaragoza Aragón

Puerto Seco de Azuqueca de Henares Guadalajara Castilla La Mancha

Zona de actividades logísticas (ZAL) Province (NUTS3) Autonomous Region (NUTS2)

ZAL Puerto Real (Cádiz) Cádiz Andalucía

ZAL Bahía de Algeciras Cádiz Andalucía

CILSA-ZAL del Puerto de Barcelona Barcelona Cataluña

Zaldesa Salamanca Castilla La Mancha

ZALIA Zona de Actividades Logísticas de Asturias Asturias Principado de Asturias

ZAL del Puerto de Tarragona Tarragona Cataluña

ZAL del Puerto de Vigo Pontevedra Galicia

ZAL del Puerto de Valencia Valencia Comunidad Valenciana

ZAL del Puerto de Cartagena Murcia Región de Murcia

ZAL del Puerto de Alicante Alicante Comunidad Valenciana

ZAL Sevilla Sevilla Andalucía

ZAL del Puerto de Motril Granada Andalucía

Page 23: Interregional Trade and Transport Connectivity: An ...

23

Parque Gran Europa ZAL Azuqueca A-2 Guadalajara Castilla La Mancha

Train load Province (NUTS3) Autonomous Region (NUTS2)

TM Madrid Abroñigal/Sta.Catalina Madrid Comunidad de Madrid

TM Fuencarral Madrid Comunidad de Madrid

TM Zaragoza PLAZA Zaragoza Aragón

TM Barcelona-Can Tunis Barcelona Cataluña

TM Vicálvaro Madrid Comunidad de Madrid

TM Los Prados Málaga Andalucía

TM Venta de Baños Palencia Castilla La Mancha

TM Miranda Ebro Burgos Castilla y León

TM Noain Navarra Navarra

TM Pla de Vilanoveta Lérida Cataluña

TM La Llagosta Barcelona Cataluña

TM Irún Guipúzcoa País Vasco

TM León León Castilla La Mancha

TM Albacete Albacete Castilla La Mancha

TM Cosmos León Castilla La Mancha

TM Valencia Fuente San Luís Valencia Comunidad Valenciana

TM Murcia Murcia Región de Murcia

Complejo Valladolid Valladolid Castilla La Mancha

TM Huelva Huelva Andalucía

TM Alcázar de San Juan Ciudad Real Castilla La Mancha

TM Salamanca Salamanca Castilla La Mancha

TM Portbou Gerona Cataluña

TM Júndiz Álava País Vasco

TM Ourense Ourense Galicia

TM La Nava de Puertollano Ciudad Real Castilla La Mancha

TM Girona Gerona Cataluña

TM Sevilla Majarabique Sevilla Andalucía

TM Sevilla La Negrilla Sevilla Andalucía

TM Torrelavega Cantabria Cantabria

TM Montcada-Bifurcacio Barcelona Cataluña

Sea Ports Province (NUTS3) Autonomous Region (NUTS2)

A Coruña La Coruña Galicia

Alicante Alicante Comunidad Valenciana

Almería Almería Andalucía

Avilés Asturias Principado de Asturias

Bahía de Algeciras Cádiz Andalucía

Bahía de Cádiz Cádiz Andalucía

Baleares Palma de Mallorca Baleares

Barcelona Barcelona Cataluña

Bilbao Vizcaya País Vasco

Cartagena Murcia Murcia

Castellón Castellón Comunidad Valenciana

Ceuta Ceuta Ceuta

Ferrol-San Cibrao La Coruña Galicia

Page 24: Interregional Trade and Transport Connectivity: An ...

24

Gijón Asturias Principado de Asturias

Huelva Huelva Andalucía

Las Palmas Las Palmas Islas Canarias

Málaga Málaga Andalucía

Marín y Ría de Pontevedra Pontevedra Galicia

Melilla Melilla Melilla

Motril Granada Andalucía

Pasajes Guipúzcoa País Vasco

Santa Cruz de Tenerife Santa Cruz de Tenerife Islas Canarias

Santander Cantabria Cantabria

Sevilla Sevilla Andalucía

Tarragona Tarragona Cataluña

Valencia Valencia Comunidad Valenciana

Vigo Pontevedra Galicia

Vilagarcía Pontevedra Galicia Source: The RELOG project.