INSTITUTE FOR ECONOMIC RESEARCH AND POLICY...

35
INSTITUTE FOR ECONOMIC RESEARCH AND POLICY CONSULTING Working Paper No.16 Nina Legeida The Economic Implications of Government Support for the Steel Industry: The Case of Ukraine September 2002 Reytarska 8/5-А, 01034 Kyiv, Tel.: + 38 044 228-63-42, + 38 044 228-63-60, Fax: + 38 044 228-63-36 E-mail: [email protected] http://www.ier.kiev.ua

Transcript of INSTITUTE FOR ECONOMIC RESEARCH AND POLICY...

Page 1: INSTITUTE FOR ECONOMIC RESEARCH AND POLICY CONSULTINGpdc.ceu.hu/archive/00001668/01/WP_16_eng.pdf · 2004-04-29 · INSTITUTE FOR ECONOMIC RESEARCH AND POLICY CONSULTING Working Paper

INSTITUTE FOR ECONOMIC RESEARCH AND POLICY CONSULTING

Working Paper No.16

Nina Legeida

The Economic Implications of Government Support

for the Steel Industry: The Case of Ukraine

September 2002

Reytarska 8/5-А, 01034 Kyiv,

Tel.: + 38 044 228-63-42,

+ 38 044 228-63-60,

Fax: + 38 044 228-63-36

E-mail: [email protected]

http://www.ier.kiev.ua

Page 2: INSTITUTE FOR ECONOMIC RESEARCH AND POLICY CONSULTINGpdc.ceu.hu/archive/00001668/01/WP_16_eng.pdf · 2004-04-29 · INSTITUTE FOR ECONOMIC RESEARCH AND POLICY CONSULTING Working Paper

Working Paper No. 16 Nina Legeida

The Economic Implications of Government Support

for the Steel Industry: The Case of Ukraine

September 2002

Nina Legeida: Research associate. Focuses on fiscal policy analysis, in particular, implicit subsidies, taxation, public deficit and various budget issues as well as industrial policy issues, especially in the sphere of ferrous metallurgy. Education at the National University of “Kyiv-Mohyla Academy” (MA in Economics) and the Nyzhin State Pedagogical University.

Page 3: INSTITUTE FOR ECONOMIC RESEARCH AND POLICY CONSULTINGpdc.ceu.hu/archive/00001668/01/WP_16_eng.pdf · 2004-04-29 · INSTITUTE FOR ECONOMIC RESEARCH AND POLICY CONSULTING Working Paper

INSTITUTE FOR ECONOMIC RESEARCH AND POLICY CONSULTING

The Economic Implications of Government Support for the Steel Industry: The Case of Ukraine1

Nina Legeida

Abstract

So far during the transition period, the Ukrainian steel industry appears to have been one of the industries favoured by the government. The favours came and still come in different ways of soft budget constraints: tax subsidies in the form of tax arrears, write-offs and restructuring of arrears, tax privileges in the guise of an “economic experiment” at ore-mining and metallurgical enterprises; forbearance towards overdue payables and non-monetary transactions; and granting of bank loans with government guarantees. The major objective of the paper is to look at the economic implications of this kind of government support for the steel industry, and in particular at the net welfare implications. Government interventions usually tend to create dead-weight losses that should be taken into account when government policies are designed and implemented; and the overall benefits should be compared with these public costs. In this paper, a partial equilibrium analysis is applied to study the effects of an ad-valorem subsidy in the form of foregone budget revenues, resulting from reducing the existing EPT rate (30%) down to 9% for metallurgical enterprises under small- and large-country assumptions. The paper concludes with policy implications and recommendations.

1 The author is very grateful to Prof. Hans Fehr, Prof. Stefan Lutz, Dr. V.

Vincentz and Dr. Ulrich Thiessen for useful comments and suggestions.

1

Page 4: INSTITUTE FOR ECONOMIC RESEARCH AND POLICY CONSULTINGpdc.ceu.hu/archive/00001668/01/WP_16_eng.pdf · 2004-04-29 · INSTITUTE FOR ECONOMIC RESEARCH AND POLICY CONSULTING Working Paper

INSTITUTE FOR ECONOMIC RESEARCH AND POLICY CONSULTING

Contents

Abstract...................................................................................................... 1

1 Introduction ............................................................................................ 3

2 Role of the steel industry in Ukraine’s economy and the government support it receives.................................................................. 4

2.1 Government support for the steel industry ............................................. 4

Government support for the steel industry throughout the world .............. 4

Arguments for government support for the steel industry in Ukraine ......... 6

2.2 Brief industry overview ....................................................................... 8

Domestic production .......................................................................... 8

Domestic consumption ..................................................................... 10

Trade developments ........................................................................ 11

2.3 The major soft budget constraints employed in the steel industry............ 13

State support (tax subsidies, government guarantees on foreign credits). 13

Tax subsidies .................................................................................. 13

Government guarantees on foreign credits .......................................... 14

Inter-enterprise soft budget constraints .............................................. 14

3 The theoretical and methodological framework for measuring the economic and welfare effects of government policies................................................. 16

3.1 General issues ................................................................................. 16

3.2 The case of Ukraine.......................................................................... 17

Small country assumption................................................................. 18

Large country assumption................................................................. 19

4 Estimating the results for the Ukrainian case.............................................. 21

4.1 Results of the experiment.................................................................. 21

4.2 Estimation of the net welfare effects ................................................... 23

4.3 Interpretation of the results............................................................... 25

5 Conclusions and policy implications........................................................... 27

References ................................................................................................ 28

Appendices................................................................................................ 31

2

Page 5: INSTITUTE FOR ECONOMIC RESEARCH AND POLICY CONSULTINGpdc.ceu.hu/archive/00001668/01/WP_16_eng.pdf · 2004-04-29 · INSTITUTE FOR ECONOMIC RESEARCH AND POLICY CONSULTING Working Paper

INSTITUTE FOR ECONOMIC RESEARCH AND POLICY CONSULTING

1 Introduction

Economic subsidies, though less than before, continue to be some of the most important expenditures in many transition economies. Of course, subsidies are widespread in market economies as well. Subsidies to the energy, water, transport and agricultural sectors (essentially price subsidies) are characteristic for many industrialised and developing economies. The major distinction between such subsidies in transition and developed countries lies in their volumes, transparency and control.

The motives for government support are similar in developed and developing countries: economic development, protection of employment and investments, protection of the domestic industry, support of the poor, etc. The effects of government support, however, appear to differ considerably from country to country. For instance, on the one hand, the Irish Industrial Development Authority’s strategy to attract investment into the computer hardware and software industries resulted in a rapid economic development of this country in the 1990s. On the other hand, the UK government’s strategy to support its coal-mining industry through grants and subsidies resulted in the eventual shutting-down of a number of mines (Downey 2000). Usually, government support is associated with negative effects, such as inefficient resource allocation, impediments to competition, trade distortions, fiscal burdens, etc.

In transition economies the problem of subsidies becomes more complicated due to the existence of a variety of indirect subsidies, e.g., privileged taxation, soft credits, trade credits, debts on banking credits and to the state, etc. Some of these occur in advanced economies as well, where they are, however, better controllable and more transparent. For a number of countries of the former Soviet Union including Ukraine, indirect support of economic activities was most pronounced during the 2nd half of 1990s.

Though the structure of expenditures in the consolidated budget of Ukraine shows that the government has set definite policy priorities, with social expenditures occupying a noticeable part in the expenditure structure, the government's impact on the economy remains very strong due to widespread indirect subsidies to Ukrainian enterprises. The share of direct subsidies is declining, while the share of indirect subsidies grows, but the total amount of the subsidies remains quite considerable. Nevertheless, a positive tendency towards reducing the total amount of subsidies to the economy can be observed. This may be consistent with the role of governments in market economies, where private enterprises drive the economic activity and the government is responsible for delivering public goods and services.

Based on the results of my previous research2, it can be asserted that the most directly subsidised sectors of the Ukrainian economy are agriculture, construction, the coal industry, the energy sector and transport. The most

2 For more detail, see Legeida (2001).

3

Page 6: INSTITUTE FOR ECONOMIC RESEARCH AND POLICY CONSULTINGpdc.ceu.hu/archive/00001668/01/WP_16_eng.pdf · 2004-04-29 · INSTITUTE FOR ECONOMIC RESEARCH AND POLICY CONSULTING Working Paper

INSTITUTE FOR ECONOMIC RESEARCH AND POLICY CONSULTING

indirectly subsidised sectors are agriculture, energy, ferrous metals, coal mining and machine building.

The mining and metallurgical complex has great strategic importance for the Ukrainian economy. It consists of about 300 enterprises. About 500 thousand workers are employed in the industry. The development of the industry was fostered by the existence of a rich raw materials base. Despite its ageing technology and the relatively low quality of the steel produced, the Ukrainian steel industry still plays a significant role in Ukraine's external trade and in the economic growth process. Foreign steel producers often accuse the Ukrainian steel producers of being state subsidised and, hence of having an unfair advantage. These constant accusations do not seem quite fair, as steel makers in other countries receive different forms of government support as well.

One of the most widely accepted tools for studying government interventions is the partial equilibrium analysis, based on the economic surplus method, which is actually a refinement of the cost-benefit analysis. It measures the distribution of economic benefits between consumers and producers, and welfare gains or losses.

This paper is organised as follows: Chapter 2 describes the role of the steel industry within the Ukrainian economy, the government support it receives, and gives a brief industry overview. Chapter 3 provides the theoretical and methodological framework for the measurement of the economic impacts of these government policies in general, and for the Ukrainian case in particular. Chapter 4 presents the measurement results for the Ukrainian case, and the implications resulting therefrom. The paper ends with conclusions.

2 Role of the steel industry in Ukraine’s economy and the government support it receives

2.1 Government support for the steel industry

Government support for the steel industry throughout the world

Before discussing government support for the steel sector in Ukraine, it might be instructive to look at the government support steel makers receive in other regions throughout the world, both in developed and developing countries. This will help us to more objectively evaluate the different types of government support for the Ukrainian steel industry and their necessity. Today, the international steel trade is distorted by subsidies, cartels, and many trade restrictions. “One way or another, steel companies around the world benefit from government practices and policies that forestall adjustments mandated by the market. As a result, market forces are not able to bring world capacity and supply in line with demand” (US Department of Commerce 2001). However, it has also been

4

Page 7: INSTITUTE FOR ECONOMIC RESEARCH AND POLICY CONSULTINGpdc.ceu.hu/archive/00001668/01/WP_16_eng.pdf · 2004-04-29 · INSTITUTE FOR ECONOMIC RESEARCH AND POLICY CONSULTING Working Paper

INSTITUTE FOR ECONOMIC RESEARCH AND POLICY CONSULTING

argued that there has been a tendency recently towards privatisation of steel mills and elimination of subsidies all over the world (AIIS 2001). Following are some examples of the types of government support the steel industry receives in different countries.

USA: Over the past two decades, U.S. steel makers have received government assistance in the form of direct grants, loan guarantees, accelerated depreciation allowances, “tax abatements, interest free loans, infrastructure grants, special electric-power rates”, etc. under different federal, state and local subsidy programs (AIIS 1999). Very often they are granted to the un-competitive, high-cost producers needing to invest in production modernisation. To protect the American steel producers from increasing international competition, two major programs were approved. During 1978-1981 the Trigger Price Mechanism (TMP) 1 was in effect. In 1984 President Reagan approved the Voluntary Restraint Agreement (VRA) that set a limit for steel imports into the USA. Among the most recent examples of government support are the Program of State Credit Guarantees, approved in 1999, the program of the state support to non-competitive steel producers, and a great number of lower-level government programs.

Japan: In their book Krugman and Obstfeld (1997) describe the strategic trade policy of Japan. Two stages in Japan’s trade policy can be identified. Between 1950 and the early 1970s the government had much influence on the allocation of resources (foreign exchange and credit) and, therefore, the direction of the economy’s growth. Since the mid-1970s the government’s role has significantly decreased, the major emphasis being laid on the development of high-technology industries. In the 1950 and 60s the government directed the funds into heavy industries, considering them to be essential for Japan’s future competitive advantage. Intermediate goods industries, in particular the steel industry, were especially favoured. Between 1963 and 1970 steel production in Japan tripled, turning Japan into the largest world steel-exporter. Japan is a resource-poor country and all raw materials have to be imported into the country. By the early 1970s Japan had ‘the most modern steel plants with the lowest operating costs’. Then the question arose whether the resources employed in steel production could not yield a higher payoff to society if utilised elsewhere, that is, whether the steel sector growth made the whole Japanese economy grow faster. It was argued that the return from resources directed into the steel sector was not as high as that directed into other production. In the 1960s, capital invested into steel production yielded a rate of return a bit higher than the average rate of return in Japanese manufacturing, but fell during the 1970s. There were no important marginal social benefits. Steel industry growth cannot produce large technological externalities, since it is not a high-tech industry. Creation of new jobs was not a good argument either, as the Japanese economy was running at full employment at that time. Due to the absence of marginal social benefits, economists argued that the steel support in Japan in spite of its growth was wrong. The resources were not directed to those areas where they could produce the highest returns. Japan’s case demonstrates clearly that while evaluating the success of a particular strategic trade policy, one should not look at the industry growth rate or its market share only. Today Japan grants trade protection to sectors with high value added and with a high level of

5

Page 8: INSTITUTE FOR ECONOMIC RESEARCH AND POLICY CONSULTINGpdc.ceu.hu/archive/00001668/01/WP_16_eng.pdf · 2004-04-29 · INSTITUTE FOR ECONOMIC RESEARCH AND POLICY CONSULTING Working Paper

INSTITUTE FOR ECONOMIC RESEARCH AND POLICY CONSULTING

technology, such as the semiconductor and computer industries (Howell 1993).

EU: In Europe the various governments support their steel sectors as well. The commercial EU steel industry policy is governed by the Treaty of Paris (expiring on July 23, 2002), which created the European Coal and Steel Community, and by the European Community Treaty of Rome (1957). According to EC Treaty, state aid is prohibited in principle, nevertheless Article 92 grants a list of exemptions. European steel production, mostly semi-finished and hot-rolled products, is regulated by the European Steel and Coal Community Treaty, which regulates the issues of state aid and competition within steel industry. Article 4 of the Treaty prohibits state support for the steel makers under normal circumstances, but Article 95 allows granting state aid under unforeseen difficulties. Six Steel Aid Codes have been adopted at different times to allow state aid under special circumstances on equal grounds to all EU steel companies. The first Steel Aid Code was approved in 1980. The last Steel Aid Code approved in 1996 covers the years 1997-2002. The existing categories of state aid comprise aid for environmental improvement, for research and development, for social costs of restructuring and for closure.

Transition and developing countries: The governments in Russia, Asia and Latin America support their steel facilities as well. The Polish steel industry faces major problems with over-capacity, over-employment and obsolete equipment (Prus 1998) and receives support in the form of preferential loans, grants from the National and Regional Fund for Environmental Protection, and commercial loans from foreign banks guaranteed by the Polish government. Government–planned investment projects to introduce new technologies and improve productivity have been undertaken in China (US Department of Commerce 2001), which is the largest crude steel producer in the world. Indian Government uses such forms of assistance as government loans, loan guarantees for private sector loans, debt write-offs and tax breaks.

Arguments for government support for the steel industry in Ukraine

Theoretical arguments in favour of government support comprise assistance to an infant industry, improvement in the terms-of-trade, reduction in unemployment, fairness, income distribution, trade protection, assistance to a developing nation, national safety, defence, and correction of a market failure (new protectionism theory, Dickson (1999). Which of these arguments are true for Ukraine? One can enumerate many reasons why Ukraine’s Government and Parliament have a particular interest in supporting the ore-mining and metallurgical industries. However, it should be stressed that the argument that steel industry is supported throughout the world should not be the major argument for supporting the steel industry in Ukraine.

Firstly, the domestic economic structure inherited from Soviet times is one of the determinants. Reliance on heavy industry (metallurgy, machine-building, etc.) is a historical legacy, characterising the Ukrainian economy. The development of this industry can be to a large extent explained by the rich raw materials base and low labour costs. However, Ukraine is poor in energy resources. The share of ferrous metal production in the total

6

Page 9: INSTITUTE FOR ECONOMIC RESEARCH AND POLICY CONSULTINGpdc.ceu.hu/archive/00001668/01/WP_16_eng.pdf · 2004-04-29 · INSTITUTE FOR ECONOMIC RESEARCH AND POLICY CONSULTING Working Paper

INSTITUTE FOR ECONOMIC RESEARCH AND POLICY CONSULTING

industrial production went up from 11% in 1990 to 27.4% in 2000. More informative, however, are the data on value added, which better reflect the contribution of the industry to the welfare of the economy. By this measure, metallurgy’s share in the industry’s value added was slightly more than 11% in 2000, while only 5% of GDP was created by the steel industry.

The metallurgical sector is the major exporting industry and, thus, is the major source of the foreign exchange that is needed by the National Bank of Ukraine to increase its foreign exchange reserves and by the government to make external debt payments. Approximately 40% of the foreign exchange revenues are received from the metallurgical sector.

Secondly, the industry has strong political support and a very strong sectoral lobby, which consists of company managers (“red directors”), representatives of sectoral administrative structures, big business associations, and sectoral trade union leaders who all can influence governmental and parliamentary decisions (Foreign and Security Policy of Ukraine 2000). The industry creates a huge field for rent seeking.

Thirdly, the industry is supported for social reasons: a large share of the Ukrainian workforce is employed in metallurgical plants and in enterprises of other industries whose products are used in ferrous metals production, e.g. ore or coal mining enterprises. The production and hence employment are highly concentrated in some regions, further complicating the issue of layoffs.

Finally, the government itself is significantly involved in the sector: it is a part owner of many plants. The ore-mining and metallurgical complex of Ukraine comprises about 300 enterprises and organizations. According to the State Property Fund information, as of start 2001 only 128 enterprises were fully privatised. “Kryvorizhstal” is the largest metallurgical enterprise and is still fully state-owned.

Among the reasons for government support such reasons as environmental protection, necessity to finance technological research, closure of inefficient and abundant capacities, modernization of the remaining steel capacities, increase in the working capital of enterprises, etc. are often named.

It is important to differentiate between short and long run effects of government support in Ukraine. In the short run government support can achieve the following objectives: overcoming an economic crisis, increasing ferrous metal exports, achieving higher economic growth in the country, solving or easing the problems of payment crises and of lack of working capital of the enterprises, and alleviating social problems. However, through state support the government can never reach the long run objectives, foremost among them achieving sustainable economic growth, which will help to reach other important objectives. If at this point in time economic growth depends so much on ferrous metallurgy growth, then the sustainable growth of the industry becomes important. This growth can primarily be achieved by increasing the competitiveness of Ukrainian steel products on the international and domestic markets, which requires deep restructuring of the industry (lowering production costs, increasing the production efficiency increasing product quality, and increasing the available product range). These efforts are now being slowly implemented.

7

Page 10: INSTITUTE FOR ECONOMIC RESEARCH AND POLICY CONSULTINGpdc.ceu.hu/archive/00001668/01/WP_16_eng.pdf · 2004-04-29 · INSTITUTE FOR ECONOMIC RESEARCH AND POLICY CONSULTING Working Paper

INSTITUTE FOR ECONOMIC RESEARCH AND POLICY CONSULTING

The achievement of the short run objectives may not always be helpful for reaching the eventual long run objectives. It should be also borne in mind that steel industry does not belong to booming industries at present and cannot produce large technological externalities. Demand for steel is highly cyclical. Therefore, grounding economic growth in the country on the base of steel industry growth may not be a reasonable decision.

2.2 Brief industry overview

Domestic production

Ferrous metals in Ukraine (steel, cast iron, rolled steel, etc.) are largely produced by 14 enterprises. The industry is characterised by economies of scale, where the four largest enterprises (Kryvorizhstal, Azovstal, Zaporizhstal, and Mariupol Illiych) account for a substantial proportion of the industry’s output. After the Asian crisis Ukraine’s steel industry seems to have recovered and increased its production levels in the 2nd half of 1999 and in 2000.

About 50% of Ukrainian steel is produced by the open-hearth method. Although the use of other production methods, such as continuous casting, has gained a little since 1999, its application still lags behind the world practice, which is about 80%. At the end of 1999, the depreciation rate of the existing total capital stock for ferrous metallurgy reached 57% for machinery and 63% for equipment. Technological innovations are being slowly implemented, mostly in the largest steel mills. The major funding sources for these technological innovations are profits and amortisation. Domestic credit resources remain unavailable due to high interest rates. Nevertheless, the capital investment index for ferrous metallurgy shows increases in capital investment in recent years: 1997 – 77%, 1998 – 110.2%, 1999 – 100.3%, 2000 – 142.1%.

Due to antiquated technologies and a decaying capital stock the production is extremely energy intensive. Energy costs are estimated to be more than 30% of the total production costs. In general, Ukrainian metallurgy is highly material intensive and the share of value added in gross production is less than 20%.

One of the major problems of all metallurgical enterprises is the abundance of production capacity. At present the level of capacity utilisation varies from 30 to 70%. The usage of the production capacity is below the optimum, which is about 80%. Reducing the production capacities to a level consistent with external and internal demand was determined to be one of the priorities of the industry's development (Grishchenko 2000). Another priority direction is to increase the competitiveness of the products through decreasing their energy and raw materials input costs, decreasing their labour costs, improving infrastructure development, and implementing major technological innovations.

The profitability of the industry is not likely to be high. According to official data, that was true in the mid-nineties, but has changed for the better in 1999 and 2000. However, the steel production by open-hearth furnaces caused large losses in 2000. It should be noted that the data on profits are

8

Page 11: INSTITUTE FOR ECONOMIC RESEARCH AND POLICY CONSULTINGpdc.ceu.hu/archive/00001668/01/WP_16_eng.pdf · 2004-04-29 · INSTITUTE FOR ECONOMIC RESEARCH AND POLICY CONSULTING Working Paper

INSTITUTE FOR ECONOMIC RESEARCH AND POLICY CONSULTING

plagued by many problems and were not reliable in the past. Except for deficiencies in the (old) bookkeeping methods, profits are highly influenced by subsidies as well as by problems of accounting for amortisation.

From an international perspective, labour productivity in the Ukrainian steel industry is extremely low. For example, Brazil with an almost identical steel output as Ukraine employs only 15% of the workforce Ukraine does in this sector. While in the EU one worker produces between 500 and 600 metric tons of crude steel per year, the corresponding figure for Ukraine is less than 150 metric tons.

The viability of any industry depends not only on its production efficiency, especially in the long run, but on the costs of the domestic factors of production, whose rise can significantly lower the profitability of the industry. Major steel industry players continuously demand lower prices or tariffs for inputs.

Basically, primary (iron ore) and secondary (scrap metal) raw materials are used in steel production. The use of iron-and-steel-scrap instead of cast iron may have contributed to the good performance of the ferrous metal industry in 2000. The iron-and-steel scrap is an important raw material that can significantly decrease the production cost of a ton of steel. A reduced supply of the iron-and-steel scrap leads to additional energy costs and the intensification of the ecological problems.

The transport tariffs for metallurgical enterprises are much higher than for other sectors or for passenger transport due to cross-subsidisation (Dodonov et al. 2001). Industrial enterprises pay much higher transport tariffs than they should really pay, while passenger transport is favoured to a degree, which may not cover the expenses of the transport enterprises.

Metallurgical enterprises are the largest energy consumers. In the early 1990s, they received energy subsidies because of the low energy prices. Today industrial enterprises in Ukraine cross-subsidise households by paying higher electricity tariffs (Dodonov, Opitz, and Pfaffenberger 2001). The National Committee on Electricity Regulation (NCER) stated that the electricity tariffs for industry cover long run average costs and are even higher because of the low tariffs for households. In spite of this, industrial electricity tariffs in Ukraine are lower those in other transition countries3. Metallurgical enterprises did not incur any new significant electricity payment arrears in 2000-2001 (there was even a decrease in their payables for goods, work and services). They also belong to those enterprises, which settle their electricity invoices almost fully in cash, according to data provided by the Ministry of Fuel and Energy of Ukraine.

To ensure a reliable gas supply has been quite a problem for the metallurgical enterprises. Due to the low level of payment for gas supplies in previous years, the enterprises were often disconnected from the gas supply. Sometimes the gas supply was further restricted during the winter. Ukraine imports gas either from Russia or from Turkmenistan. “Naftogaz Ukrainy” sets gas prices for industrial customers. Gas prices in Ukraine are

3 The 1999 electricity tariffs for industry (in USD/kWh) were: 0.0483 in the

Czech Republic, 0.0550 in Hungary, 0.0369 in Poland, and 0.0249 in Ukraine (Dodonov, Opitz, Pfaffenberger 2001).

9

Page 12: INSTITUTE FOR ECONOMIC RESEARCH AND POLICY CONSULTINGpdc.ceu.hu/archive/00001668/01/WP_16_eng.pdf · 2004-04-29 · INSTITUTE FOR ECONOMIC RESEARCH AND POLICY CONSULTING Working Paper

INSTITUTE FOR ECONOMIC RESEARCH AND POLICY CONSULTING

distorted in their structure and in nominal terms (Dodonov, Opitz 2001). Tariffs for private households, budget organisations and communal heating enterprises are much lower than for industrial enterprises. In absolute terms, gas prices, too are lower in Ukraine than in the neighbouring transition economies4. The metallurgical enterprises had no debt for the consumed natural gas as of January 1, 2001 according to data provided by “Naftogaz Ukrainy”.

A low-cost and abundant labour force reduces the wage content of the overall production cost. According to US producers, this, together with less restrictive environmental regulations, creates a competitive advantage for Ukrainian producers on international markets. Moreover, Ukraine’s steel mills are well located for export with easy access to the Black Sea.

Domestic consumption

After the breakdown of the Soviet Union, Ukraine inherited a large complex of mining and metallurgical enterprises (about 35% of the whole USSR industry). The industry, whose products had mostly been consumed by the internal market, had to be reoriented into external markets due to the internal recession.

Sales of steel production to the domestic market in Ukraine account for about 25%5. The largest steel consuming countries are, of course, the most developed countries (E.g. compare 20 kg/capita per year in Africa to 635 kg/capita in Japan). However, due to their rapidly growing economies, the largest consumers are Asian countries: Singapore (1200 kg/capita), Taiwan ROC (over 970 kg) and the Republic of Korea (830 kg). In 1999 per capita steel consumption in Ukraine amounted to 82.5 kg, which is 5 to 8 times less than in the developed countries and 1.5 times less than in Russia (Pikovsky 2000). During 1990-1998 domestic consumption of ferrous metals decreased from 13.0 m ton to 5.2 m ton per year. Thus, steel production in Ukraine is sustained by exports.

The domestic steel market is developing very slowly. Favourable external conditions have put pressure on the domestic market by providing it with an insufficient supply of ferrous metals and raising steel prices. In 2000 quite a significant increase of ferrous metal imports to Ukraine (by a factor of 2.3) was noted. Metallurgical production being attuned to the external market, specific steel products necessary for internal production - but unpopular on the external markets - were not produced any more. This is the cost of today’s policy directed at increasing the exports of semi-finished steel products, which can be seen as losing the domestic market of final products to foreign competitors.

4 Gas prices for industrial consumers (USD/tcm, including transportation and

distribution costs) in 2000 were: 112.0 in the Czech Republic, 94.7 in Hungary, 101.9 in Poland, 76.9 in the Slovak Republic, and 63.3 in Ukraine. The gas price for private consumers in Ukraine was 33.6 in 2000.

5 According to different sources, the export share varies from 70 to 80%. In Russia the internal consumption of the steel it produces is about 43%. Around 50% of the UK steel production was exported in 1998.

10

Page 13: INSTITUTE FOR ECONOMIC RESEARCH AND POLICY CONSULTINGpdc.ceu.hu/archive/00001668/01/WP_16_eng.pdf · 2004-04-29 · INSTITUTE FOR ECONOMIC RESEARCH AND POLICY CONSULTING Working Paper

INSTITUTE FOR ECONOMIC RESEARCH AND POLICY CONSULTING

Trade developments

The external trade activity of the Ukrainian metallurgical industry was developing under the influences of the liberalisation of exports and imports and trade regulation through indicative prices (Maser, Ivan 2000). The industry could not compete with less expensive and higher quality rolled metal from other exporting nations and hence was forced to sell products at lower prices. That resulted in a number of anti-dumping investigations and eventually in financial sanctions. Anti dumping suits initially targeted high-grade steel products, which may have caused Ukrainian steel makers to switch to primary and semi-finished products.

According to information supplied by the Ministry of Economy and European Integration, 86 cases of antidumping and special investigations have been registered since 1992. In 60 cases these were investigations concerning metallurgical products. Ukraine is accused of granting state subsidies to the industry, which allow the metallurgical enterprises to produce cheap products. US producers also accuse the metallurgical industry of dumping on external markets (selling below market cost), while the Ministry of Industrial Policy of Ukraine argues that the price for the metallurgical products corresponds to their quality.

Ukraine is treated as a non-market economy in the antidumping investigations in many countries; i.e. sanctions are imposed not against particular enterprises that sell their products at dumping prices but against all enterprises of the industry. Dumping is generally discovered by constructing a comparable price, which is calculated assuming usual trade conditions for this good, when assigned for sale on the domestic market. The difference between this home price and the export price then constitutes the “dumping margin” (TACIS 2001). When dealing with a "non-market" economy, where significant state control of the economy is assumed, distorting prices and costs, the authorities investigating the antidumping claim can use a country "analogous" to Ukraine (for example, Slovenia or Brazil) to study the cost structure of steel production and the resulting prices6, and to discover the effects of dumping (this method is known as the "analogous country method"). According to economic theory, dumping should be treated as a negative phenomenon only when it results in stifling competition and in market monopolisation. Market monopolisation is not an issue here because Ukraine’s market share in the world steel market was only 4% in 2000 according to IISI information, though Ukraine belongs to the 10 largest world steel producers. Thus, the argument of unfair competition is of more relevance here. In 2000, only the EU and Canada gave Ukraine the status of a country with a market economy within their antidumping legislation.

The difficult situation of Ukrainian steel exporters on foreign markets was, to a large extent, influenced by a lack of specialists in external trade, and by non-participation of the Ukrainian steel producers in any international

6 A so-called ‘surrogate’ price can also be constructed: the cost of labor from

Brasil, the price for energy from Turkey, etc. So-called “natural comparative advantages” can be taken into account while constructing the surrogate value, such as access to raw materials, or a more efficient production process (TACIS 2001).

11

Page 14: INSTITUTE FOR ECONOMIC RESEARCH AND POLICY CONSULTINGpdc.ceu.hu/archive/00001668/01/WP_16_eng.pdf · 2004-04-29 · INSTITUTE FOR ECONOMIC RESEARCH AND POLICY CONSULTING Working Paper

INSTITUTE FOR ECONOMIC RESEARCH AND POLICY CONSULTING

steel organisation. This was made worse by the absence of a long-term pricing policy, a weak marketing policy, and the large number of traders or intermediaries who have permission to export the steel to countries other than those specified in the contract (while the price of steel, of course, varies from region to region).

The ferrous metals export volume rose by 7.8% in 2000, as compared to 1999. Products with low value added (primary goods and semi-finished products) and low quality products predominated in the structure of Ukrainian steel exports.

Recently the geographical distribution of Ukrainian steel exports has changed significantly. If earlier the major consumers of Ukrainian ferrous metals were the CIS countries, now the major partners are China and the "Asian tigers" (although even for these markets Ukraine should fight since they themselves introduce new steel capacities). The exports to the Middle East and to Southeast Asian countries made up about 54% in 2000, thus, the industry is very much dependent on the economic growth in these regions. Half of the steel exports are to 7 countries: China, Russia, Turkey, Taiwan, USA, Italy and Bulgaria. Ukrainian exports to the USA are restricted by US protectionism; exports to North America amounted to about 9%. The exports to EU countries are not large (about 7%) either, as they are also restricted by EU protectionist policy. The EU is the largest steel producer followed by China, the US, Japan and Russia. In recent years, the EU has reduced its production capacity under a restructuring policy. This happened simultaneously to increasing exports from Eastern European steel-makers, who increased their market share in the EU.

Ukraine is not the only country to emerge strongly on the world market. Russia, China and India, too are new competitors on the world stage. Ukraine has to prove itself in competition against the new as well as the established steel suppliers of the world. This will likely be a competition over productivity. There is an oversupply of steel capacities in the world and international endeavours strive to reduce these worldwide capacities. Price competition, currently backed by plenty of capacity, will in future be much more governed by advances in productivity. In fact, Ukraine is competing on the markets for simple steel products. These products could be exported to the US as well as the EU because their domestic productions concentrate on more sophisticated products. This is different for Ukrainian exports to developing countries, e.g. China, which mainly produce the same product range as the Ukrainian steel firms. Here the competition is mainly among producers of lower quality products.

12

Page 15: INSTITUTE FOR ECONOMIC RESEARCH AND POLICY CONSULTINGpdc.ceu.hu/archive/00001668/01/WP_16_eng.pdf · 2004-04-29 · INSTITUTE FOR ECONOMIC RESEARCH AND POLICY CONSULTING Working Paper

INSTITUTE FOR ECONOMIC RESEARCH AND POLICY CONSULTING

2.3 The major soft budget constraints employed in the steel industry

State support (tax subsidies, government guarantees on foreign credits)

Tax subsidies

The practice of granting tax exemptions to individual metallurgical enterprises and restructuring of the debt they owed to the state was widespread in early 1990s.

It should be noted that in July 1997 the ECSC and Ukraine signed an agreement on trade in certain steel products under the Partnership and Cooperation Agreement (PCA). The basic principles, objectives and targets concerning competition, steel aid and environmental protection comparable to those applied in the European Community were presented in the so-called Protocol B. State aid could be for research and development, environmental protection, or for the closure of the plant or social support measures in the boundaries of the closure. The country was granted a 5-year period of grace or transitional period when it could continue to subsidize the industry, i.e., provide state aid on an exceptional basis for restructuring purposes to individual steel firms under certain conditions. The progress of the Ukrainian authorities in the implementation of the commitments was evaluated as rather limited (Horovitz 2001).

The “economic experiment” for metallurgical enterprises

In July 1999, the Parliament of Ukraine approved the Law “On Conducting an Economic Experiment at Ore-mining and Metallurgical Enterprises of Ukraine”. The Law was aimed at overcoming a crisis situation in the ore-mining and metallurgical industries, at increasing the volumes of production and government revenues through granting tax privileges. The experiment was in effect between July 1, 1999 and January 1, 2002. Sixty-seven ore-mining and metallurgical enterprises participated in the experiment, among which 12 were steel mills.

Article 2 of the Law states that all fines and penalties arising from delays in paying taxes, fees and other obligatory payments prior to July 1, 1999 will be written off for all participants in the ‘experiment’. Any fines and penalties on new arrears accumulated during the ‘experiment's’ term would be assessed at 50% of the existing rates.

The following tax exemptions were granted:

• Enterprise Profits Tax: Participating enterprises had their tax rate set at 30% of the general tax rate (30%), that is 9%. Savings resulting from the reduction of the EPT rate were meant to be directed towards replenishment of the working capital of these enterprises (lack of working capital is considered to be one of the major problems of metallurgical enterprises). As of 2001, the participants paid 15% EPT (Article 5).

• Roads Fund Fee: zero (Article 3),

13

Page 16: INSTITUTE FOR ECONOMIC RESEARCH AND POLICY CONSULTINGpdc.ceu.hu/archive/00001668/01/WP_16_eng.pdf · 2004-04-29 · INSTITUTE FOR ECONOMIC RESEARCH AND POLICY CONSULTING Working Paper

INSTITUTE FOR ECONOMIC RESEARCH AND POLICY CONSULTING

• State Innovation Fund Fee7: 50% of the existing tax rate (Article 3),

• Fee for environmental pollution: 30% of these revenues were to be directed to state revenues at different levels, 70% were to be used by the enterprises for internal environmental protection measures. Sanctions are imposed for the non-targeted usage of funds. The deductions should not exceed 0.15% of gross expenditures.

Article 4 allows the State Tax Administration of Ukraine to grant deferrals on paying taxes, fees and other obligatory payments to the participants of the experiment for up to 36 months and to impose a zero payment rate for tax credits.

Aside from the “economic” experiment, another source of tax subsidies for metallurgical enterprises were arrears to different governmental levels (see Table 1).

Government guarantees on foreign credits

At the beginning of the 1990s selected metallurgical enterprises received credits under government guarantees. As of March 1, 2001, the overdue debt to the state for these credits had reached $ 1005.7 m, of which the Makyivskyi metallurgical plant owed 9.3%, and Krivorizhstal 5.7%.

Inter-enterprise soft budget constraints

Payables, a form of trade credit, constitute another part of the “soft budget constraints” to Ukrainian metallurgical enterprises. Arrears are a means of financing enterprise operations and a way of short-term or long-term lending. Payables for goods, work and services occupy the lion’s share of the payables between enterprises, with budgetary and extra-budgetary arrears following next in the list of payables between enterprises. During the period of time under review, a significant reduction of payables can be observed, specifically in 1999-2000, which coincides with the period of the “economic experiment” at the metallurgical enterprises. However, during this period the recession came to an end, too, so that it is difficult to argue that the “tax experiment” was the main contributor for this reduction. Nevertheless, the total of payables made up UAH 14.3 bn, or 8.3% of GDP, and total receivables were UAH 5.6 bn, or 5.2% as of 01.01.01. Up to 1998, net total arrears (total payables – total receivables) of the ferrous metallurgy enterprises grew, during 1999-2000 they decreased.

7 Since January 1, 2000, the Roads Fund fee and the State Innovation Fund fee

have been abolished. Therefore, the major tax privilege for the enterprises was the EPT exemption.

14

Page 17: INSTITUTE FOR ECONOMIC RESEARCH AND POLICY CONSULTINGpdc.ceu.hu/archive/00001668/01/WP_16_eng.pdf · 2004-04-29 · INSTITUTE FOR ECONOMIC RESEARCH AND POLICY CONSULTING Working Paper

INSTITUTE FOR ECONOMIC RESEARCH AND POLICY CONSULTING

Table 1 Ukraine: Payables by ferrous metallurgical enterprises (total industry), flow, UAH m

1998 1999 2000 Ferrous metallurgy

Total Overdue Total Overdue Total Overdue

Total 5019.7 1899.5 600.6 -2163.1 -806.6 -929.6

1. Between enterprises 4600.8 1861.6 226.6 -2137.2 -776.3 -1073.8

Goods, work, services 2353.3 1290.1 -470.8 -826.8 -160.7 -601.2

Wages 114.9 44.8 -96.5 -100.4 -43.4 -93.7

On tax payments 91 14.8 -2,7 8.8 -88.3 -23.6

State revenues 670.7 478 -956.8 -740 1.0 -37.3

Extra budgetary funds 173.3 111.7 -342.2 -288.7 -94.2 -48.3

2. With former SU countries

-165.6 -142.7 410.2 10.6 -284.9 -2.4

3. With other countries -515.6 -347.8 875.4 50.6 39.3 1.6

Source: State Statistics Committee of Ukraine: company accounting balance sheet:

form 1b

Though the government had granted an indirect support to the metallurgical enterprises, it simultaneously imposed an indirect tax on them by not returning VAT reimbursement amounts. One of the negative consequences of this policy was the reduction in working capital available to the enterprises. This problem became especially acute due to the increase in steel exports in 2000. Up to 2000, the arrears of the ferrous metal industry to state revenues always exceeded the VAT reimbursement arrears (i.e. the industry was a net debtor of the state). In 2000 however, the situation reversed: receivables from the state (UAH 700 m as of 01.01.2001) were larger than payables to it (UAH 460 m as of 01.01.01), the industry became a net creditor to the state8. To solve somehow the problem of VAT refund debt, the enterprises were allowed to conduct mutual settlements with budget and energy companies. The VAT problem was considered as a transitory one and was not taken into account while calculating the amount of the tax production subsidy.

Barter transactions in export and domestic operations were quite frequent in recent years, occurring primarily within the domestic market. Barter decreased significantly in 2000: the share of products supplied through barter arrangements as a percent of the general volume of factory shipments for ferrous metals (total ferrous metallurgy) went down from 40.8% in 1998 to 9.5% in 2000, much more than for the whole industry of Ukraine. The fact that barter decreased more in the steel industry than

8 However, one should be careful when arriving at such a conclusion, since the

major part of the enterprises’ receivables from the state are likely to be the VAT reimbursement arrears and the amount to be reimbursed may be exaggerated due to weaknesses in the VAT administration or fraud.

15

Page 18: INSTITUTE FOR ECONOMIC RESEARCH AND POLICY CONSULTINGpdc.ceu.hu/archive/00001668/01/WP_16_eng.pdf · 2004-04-29 · INSTITUTE FOR ECONOMIC RESEARCH AND POLICY CONSULTING Working Paper

INSTITUTE FOR ECONOMIC RESEARCH AND POLICY CONSULTING

elsewhere may be ascribed to “economic experiment” effects. On the other hand, it may be explained by the growth of exports supply of ferrous metals, and within export operations barter transactions are less likely.

The following major conclusion can be drawn from reviewing the main channels of government support and other soft budget constraints for the steel industry. Over time the composition of soft budget constraints changed. In the early 1990s, tax subsidies in the form of individual tax privileges, credits with government guarantees and electricity subsidies predominated. In the mid-1990s and up to 1999, arrears to state revenues and extra-budgetary funds accumulated and payables between enterprises and barter operations increased. Starting with the 2nd half of 1999 the "economic experiment" at the ore-mining and metallurgical enterprises came into force.

3 The theoretical and methodological framework for measuring the economic and welfare effects of government policies

3.1 General issues

A broad subsidy concept is often used to cover the whole range of the on- and off- budget measures:

• Direct state expenditures.

• Tax subsidies: tax credits, exemptions, deferrals, restructuring or forgiveness of debt, etc.

• Domestic policies: price supports, etc.

• Trade policies: import and export tariffs, non-tariff barriers.

These subsidies are recognised by the Agreement on Subsidies and Countervailing Measures (Subsidies Agreement of WTO) and by US Law. The Subsidies Agreement provides the rules applicable to government subsidies (three types of subsidies are distinguished: prohibited, actionable and non-actionable) and defines remedies against subsidised trade.

According to the System of National Accounts definition (OECD 1997), “subsidies on production are grants which state and private enterprises receive from the government and which represent additions to the receipts by producers of goods and services over and above what they receive from the sales of their output”. These grants will not constitute a part of the market value of the output; nevertheless, they can offset a part of the production costs. Production subsidies include subsidies on products, which are paid for each unit of good or service produced, and cover import subsidies and export subsidies. Domestic production subsidies are based on the output or production, irrespectively of where it is sold. They may be specified as an ad-valorem subsidy (% of the value of the production) or a specific subsidy (payment per unit of output). Generally production subsidies are given to increase the incomes of the producers of a particular

16

Page 19: INSTITUTE FOR ECONOMIC RESEARCH AND POLICY CONSULTINGpdc.ceu.hu/archive/00001668/01/WP_16_eng.pdf · 2004-04-29 · INSTITUTE FOR ECONOMIC RESEARCH AND POLICY CONSULTING Working Paper

INSTITUTE FOR ECONOMIC RESEARCH AND POLICY CONSULTING

industry (in many countries they are granted for agricultural commodities to raise the incomes of the agricultural producers) or to stimulate the production of a particular good (often granted for steel, motor vehicles, etc.).

To study the effects of subsidies (price effect, demand effect, production effect, export effect, net welfare effects, etc.), a partial equilibrium analysis is often used. This graphical analysis can be very useful for capturing the welfare effects of distortions of consumer and producer behaviour.

3.2 The case of Ukraine

In this paper, the standard microeconomic approach to measuring different economic and welfare effects of government interventions is applied, based on the application example of Rosenberg et al. (1999) for the case of Uzbekistan. Their approach used a simple partial equilibrium analysis to study the effects of exchange rate controls on the exports of cotton fibre and the effects of appreciated exchange rates on the import of capital goods. A simple graphical and numerical analysis was employed to derive the welfare effects, based on the implicit subsidy, or tax rate and export supply elasticity, or import demand elasticity.

The prime objective of the economic experiment at ore-mining and metallurgical enterprises was to increase total production. Therefore, the government subsidy reducing the EPT rate to 30% of the existing general tax rate can be treated as an ad-valorem production subsidy. The subsidy increases the working capital of the subsidised enterprises and lowers the effective cost of producing of each unit by the amount "s". However, this production subsidy can be referred to as a special production subsidy, which is a kind of the implicit export subsidy, since Ukrainian metallurgical enterprises export the major part of their production and the subsidy may have consequences for international trade causing exports to be higher than they otherwise would be.

There were actually two prime factors determining the ferrous metals export growth in 1999-2000: an increase in the world demand for steel, which created favourable conditions for Ukrainian steel exporters, and the “economic experiment” at the metallurgical enterprises.

Only the effects of this ad-valorem EPT subsidy will be looked at, holding everything else constant and assuming no other market distortions, or imperfections. Although the world steel market is distorted by trade restrictions we assume here that Ukrainian producers could easily find new markets for their increased steel supply. The major part of steel is exported to Southeast Asia and Near East markets, which are less restricted. The economic growth in the trading partners allowed the absorption of the increased Ukraine’s steel supply. Figures 1 and 2 illustrate the price, quantity and welfare effects of this government tax subsidy on the metallurgical industry.

17

Page 20: INSTITUTE FOR ECONOMIC RESEARCH AND POLICY CONSULTINGpdc.ceu.hu/archive/00001668/01/WP_16_eng.pdf · 2004-04-29 · INSTITUTE FOR ECONOMIC RESEARCH AND POLICY CONSULTING Working Paper

INSTITUTE FOR ECONOMIC RESEARCH AND POLICY CONSULTING

Small country assumption

First, let us assume a small open economy with a perfectly competitive industry. This assumption implies a horizontal, or perfectly elastic export demand function in the rest of the world.

Figure 1 presents a graphical analysis of the Ukrainian steel market: SUkr = Ukrainian steel supply curve (right hand quadrant),

DUkr = Ukrainian steel demand curve,

XUkr = Ukrainian steel exports supply function (left hand quadrant),

DRoW = demand function for Ukrainian steel exports.

With “small country assumption” we mean that domestic policies do not affect the world price of the commodity under investigation.

Without the subsidy, the following situation applies at the markets: oc = the world price of steel,

cf = domestic steel production,

ce = domestic steel consumption,

ef = bc = quantity of the Ukrainian steel exports.

The tax subsidy pivots the supply function of Ukrainian steel producers from SUkr to SUkr

subs by the amount of the ad-valorem subsidy s (ps = pws

(1+s)), where ps - price under the subsidy,

pws – price without the subsidy.

The export supply function pivots from XUkr to XUkr subs. Exports increase to ki = ml = ac. Domestic price and consumption remain unaffected. These are the economic impacts of the subsidy. To evaluate the welfare consequences, the concepts of producer and consumer surpluses are applied.

The net social welfare can be calculated as the sum of these surpluses minus the government tax subsidy. Producers gain as a result of the subsidy: ∆ PS (producer surplus) = + lifc. The consumer surplus (∆ CS) does not change. The government grants the subsidy in the following amount: tax subsidy (TS) = - lijc. Hence the net welfare effect = PS + CS - TS = + lifc – lijc = - ijf = - mba.

These triangles represent net dead-weight losses (the so-called Harberger triangles) that measure the degree of inefficiency of the government policy, i.e. inefficiency in resource allocation as the subsidy distorts incentives to consume and to produce. For the mathematical derivation of the net welfare loss, a log-linear export supply function for ferrous metals is assumed:

PX = B * Xβ, where β>0 (1)

The elasticity of the export supply is:

18

Page 21: INSTITUTE FOR ECONOMIC RESEARCH AND POLICY CONSULTINGpdc.ceu.hu/archive/00001668/01/WP_16_eng.pdf · 2004-04-29 · INSTITUTE FOR ECONOMIC RESEARCH AND POLICY CONSULTING Working Paper

INSTITUTE FOR ECONOMIC RESEARCH AND POLICY CONSULTING

β/1* ==XP

dPdXE X

XX (2)

The derived analytical expression (its derivation and necessary explanations are presented in Appendix 1) for the net welfare losses is:

SSSSSS Xss

XPNDL ∗−

+

−∗∗∗+

=+β

βββ

1

/1)1(11

1 (3)

As can be seen from equation (3), the subsidy rate (s), the price elasticity (β), the steel price under the subsidy (PSS), and the quantity of the steel export supply under subsidy (XSS) are needed in order to calculate the dead-weight losses under small-country assumption.

Graph 1 Effects of a production tax subsidy to steel producers (small-country assumption)

sUkrsubs

US $ /ton Ukrainian steel market Rest of the world steel market

0 Steel, ton

a

b c e f

j

i klm

SUkr XUkr

XUkrsubs

DUkr

DRoW

Large country assumption

The assumption of the horizontal demand for Ukrainian steel from the rest of the world may seem not quite correct due to the large influence of the Ukrainian steel producers at international markets. Ukraine was in 7th place among the major crude steel producers in 2000; its 4 major steel producing companies are among the 60 largest steel mills in the world. Ukraine's share in worldwide steel exports in 2000 was approximately 7%; it occupied the 4th place among the world's largest exporters (www.worldsteel.org). However, it cannot be argued that Ukraine is a large

19

Page 22: INSTITUTE FOR ECONOMIC RESEARCH AND POLICY CONSULTINGpdc.ceu.hu/archive/00001668/01/WP_16_eng.pdf · 2004-04-29 · INSTITUTE FOR ECONOMIC RESEARCH AND POLICY CONSULTING Working Paper

INSTITUTE FOR ECONOMIC RESEARCH AND POLICY CONSULTING

monopolistic power on international markets. According to the IISI, Ukraine’s world market share in 2000 made up 4%. The export volume of Ukrainian products is limited by the protectionist policies of foreign governments: anti-dumping duties, quota restrictions, prohibitive import tariffs, etc. Any reduction of Ukrainian exports can easily be made up for by exports from other countries. Other countries have increased their production in recent years, and now world steel supply exceeds world steel demand. For these reasons, the large country assumption may be useful mostly for providing a sensitivity analysis of different welfare effects under various assumptions.

The “large-country assumption” implies that the country's exports represent a large share of the world steel market. Thus, the production tax subsidy will affect supply and demand and hence welfare, both domestically and internationally. The subsidy leads to the expansion of the country’s exports and to a slight increase in the domestic consumption of the commodity. This case is presented in Graph 2.

Graph 2 Effects of a production tax subsidy to steel producers (large-country assumption)

US $ /ton Ukrainian steel market Rest of the world steel market

0 Steel, ton

a

b

c

d e

f j

i kl

m

SUkr

SUkrsubs

XUkr

XUkrsubs

DUkr

DRoW

n r

Without the subsidy, oc is the world price of steel, cr is the quantity of the steel produced in Ukraine, of which cn is consumed at home and nr = mc is exported. As a result of the subsidy, the production amount rises to li = dj, and the supply function pivots from SUkr to SUkr

subs by the amount of the ad-valorem subsidy "s". The export supply pivots from XUkr to XUkr

subs, but by less than the amount of the subsidy, since the production amount increase is distributed between the internal and external markets. Therefore, exports rise from nr to ej = ad, and domestic consumption rises from cn to de, caused by the market price decrease from oc to od. As a result of the

20

Page 23: INSTITUTE FOR ECONOMIC RESEARCH AND POLICY CONSULTINGpdc.ceu.hu/archive/00001668/01/WP_16_eng.pdf · 2004-04-29 · INSTITUTE FOR ECONOMIC RESEARCH AND POLICY CONSULTING Working Paper

INSTITUTE FOR ECONOMIC RESEARCH AND POLICY CONSULTING

subsidy, producers get higher prices (ol) and consumers, both the domestic and foreign ones, pay lower prices (od).

The welfare effects can be illustrated in the following way: TS = - lijd is the amount of the government subsidy, ∆ PS = + lirc is the producers gain as a result of the subsidy, and ∆ CS = + cned the consumers gain as a result of the subsidy. Therefore the net welfare effect = CS + PS – TS = - lijd + lirc + cned = -nrfe - ijf. The triangle ijf is the dead-weight loss, or the resource waste. The welfare loss in the form of nrfe is the loss due to the terms of trade deterioration, i.e., it is a redistribution of welfare from Ukraine (exporting country) to the rest of the world, since foreign customers now pay less for their imports.

The dead-weight loss represented by the triangle ijf can be found in a way similar to that used in the small-country assumption (assuming the same constant elasticity function for the steel supply function in Ukraine, as for the export supply function, i.e. PX=B * Xβ, where β>0:

{ SLSLSLijf

Xss

XPNDL ∗−

+

−∗∗∗+

=+β

βββ

1

/1)1(11

1 (4),

where β is the price elasticity of the supply, s the ad-valorem subsidy, PSL the price received by producers under the subsidy, and XSL the domestic steel production volume under the subsidy in the case of a large-country assumption.

The derivation of the trapezoid nrfe (welfare loss due to the terms of trade deterioration (WL)) is given in Appendix 2:

{ ( ) 2111

/1CL

BLnrfe

Ps

PWL −

+

∗+

∗=β

ββ (5),

where PBL is the steel price before the subsidy, and PCL the price to steel consumers under the subsidy.

The same elasticity is used in both cases since the Ukrainian supply of the ferrous metals is actually very close to the export volume of ferrous metals.

4 Estimating the results for the Ukrainian case

4.1 Results of the experiment

Many different opinions are being held concerning the success of the experiment at ore-mining and metallurgical enterprises. It goes without saying that the experiment benefited the steel makers, resulting in improvements to production and to the financial indicators of the enterprises. However, the concurrent overall economic upswing in the

21

Page 24: INSTITUTE FOR ECONOMIC RESEARCH AND POLICY CONSULTINGpdc.ceu.hu/archive/00001668/01/WP_16_eng.pdf · 2004-04-29 · INSTITUTE FOR ECONOMIC RESEARCH AND POLICY CONSULTING Working Paper

INSTITUTE FOR ECONOMIC RESEARCH AND POLICY CONSULTING

country and favourable external conditions should not be underestimated here.

According to the Accounting Chamber of Ukraine, the tax privileges created a favourable climate for overcoming the crisis situation in the ore-mining and metallurgical enterprises. The major objective of the experiment was achieved: the participants increased their production volumes (real production growth made up 20.3%), sales, and payments to the state and to the Pension Fund. Payments for energy and natural gas purchases also grew. The participants of the experiment were exempted from paying taxes, fees and other obligatory payments in the amount of UAH 2013 m during the 2nd half of 1999 and in 2000. Furthermore, UAH 714.9 m in fines and penalties were written off, UAH 1919.2 m in arrears to the state were restructured. The widening of the tax base contributed to an increase in the amount of tax payments to the state. However, lowering the tax burden of metallurgical enterprises implies an automatically increase in the tax burden for other industries and sectors of the economy. The number of the workers in the participating enterprises rose by 12000, average wages increased by 28.2%. An important short-run benefit of the experiment was the lowering social tensions. However, that proves that even the passive restructuring (reduction of the production facilities in response to changed demand, and reduction of the inefficiencies through lay-offs) usually preceding strategic changes, was not properly applied. Moreover, real labour productivity decreased.

Notwithstanding the positive effects, the analysis discovered that the production growth was not sustainable, since it was largely rather dependent on external market conditions and not on a growing internal demand, as proven by the slowing production rates and decreasing profitability by year-end. These factors are likely to contribute to slower industry growth rates in the subsequent years. There were also no significant or sufficient structural changes implemented by the enterprises.

The Ministry of Economy and European Integration has presented a brief analysis of the effects on the production and on the financial and economic activity of all enterprises participating in the experiment, comparing 2000 to 1999 (See Table 2). The results of the experiment are presented for all participating ore-mining and metallurgical enterprises together. Since data for individual metallurgical enterprises are not available, we have to assume that the overall trends hold true for single plants as well.

Enterprises managed to overcome the working capital deficit, distanced themselves from give-and-take schemes and barter operations, and started to reinvest. The experiment added more transparency to transactions within the ferrous metals industry and reduced the number of intermediaries. However, an audit conducted by the Accounting Chamber discovered some violations. Not all enterprises made payments to the government in a timely fashion and followed the legal requirements. Many enterprises did not direct the funds, made available by the EPT rate reduction, to the replenishment of working capital.

22

Page 25: INSTITUTE FOR ECONOMIC RESEARCH AND POLICY CONSULTINGpdc.ceu.hu/archive/00001668/01/WP_16_eng.pdf · 2004-04-29 · INSTITUTE FOR ECONOMIC RESEARCH AND POLICY CONSULTING Working Paper

INSTITUTE FOR ECONOMIC RESEARCH AND POLICY CONSULTING

Table 2 Ukraine: Results of the economic experiment at ore-mining and metallurgical enterprises, 2000 compared to 1999

Net profits from sales ↑ by 57.2 %

Export volumes ↑ by 1.9 times

Profitability (profit/output) of sold products

26.3 %

Barter operations ↓ from 36.1% in 1999 to 11.1% in 2000

Government revenue at all levels ↑ by 48.2%

Payments to the Pension Fund ↑ by 52.2%

Wage arrears ↓ by more than 2 times

Expenses for improving production capacities

↑ by 25.4%

Deficit of the working capital ↓ from UAH 3452 m as of 01.01.2000 to

UAH 596 m as of 01.01.2001

Source: Dzerkalo ekonomichnoi politiky (Mirror of Economic Policy), March 2001.

Department for Economic Strategy, Ministry of Economy and European Integration

One should be also careful about the growth of government revenues at all levels and payments to the Pension Fund. The base for comparison in the previous year can be rather low due to the non-payments of taxes and fees. The widening of the tax base as a result of growing profits together with the necessity to keep up with the strict law requirements concerning payments to the state contributed to the larger tax payments of enterprises. However, 21% of potential EPT revenues remained at enterprises’ disposal.

4.2 Estimation of the net welfare effects

A tax exemption subsidy may not constitute a part of the market value of the output but can help offset a part of the production costs. The statistics available at this time concerning the results of the experiment at ore-mining and metallurgical enterprises presents aggregate data on the amount of the tax privileges and write-offs or restructuring of tax arrears for those enterprises participating in the experiment. As this paper concentrates on the steel enterprises only, and since disaggregated data is not available, the most appropriate way to calculate the subsidy amount is to take the data on the before-tax profits of the enterprises and simply calculate the amount of the tax exemptions by reducing the EPT rate from 30% to 9%:

Subsidy amount = 21% of the before-tax profits9 of the metallurgical enterprises.

9 International standards of bookkeeping accounting should have been

introduced at Ukrainian enterprises in January 1, 2000. This is an attempt to

23

Page 26: INSTITUTE FOR ECONOMIC RESEARCH AND POLICY CONSULTINGpdc.ceu.hu/archive/00001668/01/WP_16_eng.pdf · 2004-04-29 · INSTITUTE FOR ECONOMIC RESEARCH AND POLICY CONSULTING Working Paper

INSTITUTE FOR ECONOMIC RESEARCH AND POLICY CONSULTING

Under this assumption, the total amount of the government subsidy to the metallurgical enterprises amounts roughly to about UAH 700 m, or USD 130 m. The ad-valorem subsidy rate equals s=2.6%.

Since the estimation of the export steel supply function for Ukraine and, respectively, of the necessary export supply elasticity is complicated due to lack of data reliability and availability, the existing research on this issue was reviewed in order to obtain a reasonable range of the steel export supply elasticities to estimate the welfare effects.

In the economic research, most of the import and export elasticities have been derived from the demand side. Very few studies estimate export supply elasticities, using both single equation models and simultaneous equations models (Goldstein and Khan 1978). The theoretical approach in the demand-side studies is to assume that the export supply is perfectly elastic.

Based on the estimation of the inverse supply of US iron and steel products, the following elasticity estimates were obtained: the price elasticity of demand for US exports was –2.7, the price elasticity of the export supply for the USA amounted to 16.7 (Irwin 2000).

In the studies of the effects of the US-Canada Free Trade Agreement (conducted by Mount Union College in the USA), the export supply price elasticity for steel-mill products was estimated to be 5.2.

Unfortunately, there exist very few studies on ferrous metals in Ukraine. According to one of the studies available (Grygorenko 2001), the price elasticity of the export supply of Ukrainian steel is 0.1.

To calculate the dead-weight losses, formulas (3) to (5) are used. The price resulting from the subsidy program is based on the weighted average price for Ukrainian steel. The export price elasticities estimated in other studies are applied here, to perform a sensitivity analysis of the welfare losses to export supply price elasticity. In general, many partial equilibrium and computable general equilibrium models that estimate dead-weight losses from different trade policies, rely on demand and supply elasticities obtained in other studies (Feenstra 1992). Table 3 presents the results of our calculations. As can be seen, the estimated welfare losses amount to between $ 0.1 and 14 m under the small-country assumption and to between $ 0.1 and 15 m under the large-country assumption. In the worst case, the excess burden per dollar of the subsidy payment is $ 0.11 under the small-country assumption, and $ 0.12 under the large-country assumption.

bring the bookkeeping and tax accounting into agreement. The difference between the two can be explained by two factors: 1) the method of accounting, and 2) the definition of gross revenues and expenditures. According to general standards, the accounting income should form the basis for the taxation income. In this case, to get the amount of the subsidy, the financial result of the enterprises before taxation was used.

24

Page 27: INSTITUTE FOR ECONOMIC RESEARCH AND POLICY CONSULTINGpdc.ceu.hu/archive/00001668/01/WP_16_eng.pdf · 2004-04-29 · INSTITUTE FOR ECONOMIC RESEARCH AND POLICY CONSULTING Working Paper

INSTITUTE FOR ECONOMIC RESEARCH AND POLICY CONSULTING

Table 3 Ukraine: Net welfare effects from the EPT subsidy in 2000 (small-country and large-country assumptions)

β 1/β Welfare losses, m, USD

(small-country) Welfare losses, m, USD

(large-country)

0.1 10 -13.67 -15.19

5.2 0.2 -0.29 -0.32

16.7 0.1 -0.08 -0.1

4.3 Interpretation of the results

The production tax subsidy is distortionary in its character and welfare reducing. However, the dead-weight losses turned out to be rather low under both assumptions, a result which is characteristic for many similar studies. The welfare losses rise with the elasticity of the export supply of the ferrous metals and depend on, whether the country is modelled as a small or large economy: under the large-country assumption, the welfare losses are larger.

Many research studies show that subsidies fail to achieve their primary objective. In this case, the subsidy seems to have reached its primary objective, as defined in the Law, i.e. raising the supply of ferrous metals and improving the financial situation of the enterprises so as to reduce payment arrears. However, significant structural changes did not occur.

The cost of the subsidy is borne by the government in the form of foregone state revenues (notwithstanding the overall growth in payments to the state), while the benefits are shared between producers, steel mill workers and suppliers. Under large-country assumption, foreign steel consumers also benefited from the government policy in Ukraine, while foreign steel producers are likely to have suffered from it.

Nevertheless, one should be careful about concurring with the estimate’s low welfare losses resulting from the government support. They are calculated for 2000 only and could be much higher if other distortions in the steel market were taken into account, in particular prior to 1999.

First of all, the amount of the subsidies to the steel mills might in reality be higher, taking into account enterprise payables and the amount of the other tax exemptions. However, the enterprises’ receivables should be also taken into account.

The ferrous metals industry is one of the most energy-intensive ones in the Ukrainian economy, which has several negative consequences. Firstly, metallurgical enterprises used to accumulate large energy payment arrears, at the same time objecting to compulsory disconnection from the energy supplies. Non-payment for energy in turn caused the energy sector to default on payments to the state. Secondly, an energy-intensive production implies a high demand for energy production. Ukraine cannot satisfy its demand for energy with its own production and is dependent on the import of energy resources and gas from Russia or other countries. The

25

Page 28: INSTITUTE FOR ECONOMIC RESEARCH AND POLICY CONSULTINGpdc.ceu.hu/archive/00001668/01/WP_16_eng.pdf · 2004-04-29 · INSTITUTE FOR ECONOMIC RESEARCH AND POLICY CONSULTING Working Paper

INSTITUTE FOR ECONOMIC RESEARCH AND POLICY CONSULTING

non-payments for these supplies lead to the accumulation of state or corporate gas debt toward Russia and Turkmenistan in the past. Though electricity tariffs and gas prices for metallurgical enterprises have risen considerably during the transition period, they are still below world market prices, which could create a competitive advantage for Ukrainian producers at external steel markets. However, the data for 2000 and 2001 shows that the metallurgical enterprises made almost full and timely payments for the consumed gas and energy, although, there were exceptions.

Secondly, the subsidies may have caused substantial efficiency losses due to a lack of good management. Being able to count on government support may have allowed the managers to concentrate less on profit maximisation, and hence on optimising the production processes. On the other hand, the owners may be interested in making a ‘quick’ profit, not caring much about enterprise restructuring. Weak management (lacking private management expertise) and poor marketing strategies (resulting in inadequate pricing strategies) could offer some explanations for the large number of antidumping investigations being conducted against Ukrainian steel producers. Thus, the estimated welfare losses might be low due to the adverse effects of the subsidies on entrepreneurial behaviour.

Thirdly, the resource waste costs (from misused scarce resources due to price distortions, most products exported being primary goods, or semi-finished products) and the environmental costs, which may become more urgent in the future, should be taken into account.

Also, our quantitative analysis concentrated on the short-run effects. In the long run, the negative effects of the government subsidies could become much larger. At this time, the government subsidy results above all in the expansion of the export supply, which implies an increasing dependence on the external steel market. This dependence may become a danger to the metallurgical enterprises when, having invested a lot in production expansion and updating production capacities, they will be unable to sell their production externally, and the internal market cannot absorb the increased amount of production either. In this way, the government may have solved its present urgent problems by putting the real solution off to a future date and by harming future sustainable economic development and increasing social tension. International evidence shows that steel industries in many EU countries had to undertake measures that resulted in reducing the level of steel mill employment. Thus, protecting the sectoral employment may not be a good argument for protecting the industry. However, if the present economic growth can be sustained, the growing production in other sectors of the economy may, to some extent, solve the problem of employment.

The above discussion of the effects of the subsidies shows that removing the subsidies, though painful, could lead to fiscal, economic and environmental gains.

The applied partial equilibrium analysis did not capture the effects of the subsidy on other sectors of the economy. The study of these effects would require a general equilibrium analysis.

26

Page 29: INSTITUTE FOR ECONOMIC RESEARCH AND POLICY CONSULTINGpdc.ceu.hu/archive/00001668/01/WP_16_eng.pdf · 2004-04-29 · INSTITUTE FOR ECONOMIC RESEARCH AND POLICY CONSULTING Working Paper

INSTITUTE FOR ECONOMIC RESEARCH AND POLICY CONSULTING

5 Conclusions and policy implications

Different sources of governmental support for the steel industry and their consequences were reviewed in this paper. Special emphasis was laid on studying the fiscal and economic implications of the tax exemptions provided by the “economic experiment” at metallurgical enterprises. The effects of the ad-valorem subsidy of reducing the EPT rate from 30% to 9% were carefully studied. The partial equilibrium analysis allowed us to roughly estimate the implications for the major players at the steel market: steel consumers and steel producers. However, the economic implications for the whole economy, as well as environmental and energy implications, were not totally captured.

It is difficult to evaluate the amount of the subsidies exactly, due to the non-transparency of the data about the ‘experiment’ and the lack of information on individual enterprises. More transparency would allow a more precise estimation of the impacts, costs and distributive implications of the subsidies.

The production tax subsidy is distortionary in its nature and is welfare-reducing. The tax burden should be reduced for the whole economy, not just for specific industries or sectors of the economy. The “economic experiment” may have contributed to an improved financial situation for the participating enterprises; the threat of being excluded from the experiment may have provided incentives to work better. But these seem to be short-term improvements, as deep structural changes did not occur. This absence of change can largely be explained by the attitude of the management, who in the knowledge that they will ultimately be bailed out by the state is not seriously motivated to invest in any restructuring effort.

The experiment should be viewed as a temporary one-time measure of government support to help the enterprises to overcome a specific crisis situation in the industry. From now on the enterprises should rely on their own resources, which will improve their economic efficiency and ensure competition both externally and internally. Worldwide experience shows that government protection cannot create a competitive industry. This has now also been proven in Ukraine. That is why the requested prolongation of the experiment should not be approved.

There should be fair relations between the state and the metallurgical enterprises. Though the government supports the industry through tax exemptions, it simultaneously imposes an indirect tax in the form of VAT reimbursement arrears. These problems should not be solved through mutual settlement schemes, however.

Our investigation concentrated on the short-run effects of the subsidies, which should be contrasted with their long-run effects. The long-run effects would appear to be more detrimental, especially since the internal market for steel is not developed and dependency on the external market is predominant. At this time the world market experiences a supply-demand imbalance. Supply exceeds demand, which drives world market prices down. The question arises, whether it is worthwhile to invest large amounts of money in renewing production capacities. To escape the dependence on external sales, greater emphasis should be placed on developing the domestic market for steel, which above all implies

27

Page 30: INSTITUTE FOR ECONOMIC RESEARCH AND POLICY CONSULTINGpdc.ceu.hu/archive/00001668/01/WP_16_eng.pdf · 2004-04-29 · INSTITUTE FOR ECONOMIC RESEARCH AND POLICY CONSULTING Working Paper

INSTITUTE FOR ECONOMIC RESEARCH AND POLICY CONSULTING

developing the machine building, construction, and transport sectors. Ukraine’s situation in the world is complicated by the transitional non-market character of its economy. Antidumping investigations are likely to continue, economic growth in Ukraine's major export destinations may decrease, and hence Ukraine should exploit and develop the domestic market. A tax system reform and a reduction in the regulatory burden could do much good in this regard. Therefore, the internal market for steel industry products may seem to be the major determinant for the industry's growth and prosperity in the long run.

Talking about the relations between the state and metallurgical sector, the state should clearly define its industrial policy in this sector, in the first turn, its long-term policy. It is evident that the state will continue to play an important role in this sector development, in the first turn because of social reasons. But it should have clear reasons for and aims of its policy, including state aid policy and develop appropriate measures to achieve the set aims. The independent control over the implementation of measures and use of funds should be guaranteed.

Subsidy reform in the steel industry is sure to be opposed by many vested interests. This is quite evident now, when the metallurgical enterprises insist on continuing with the "experiment", while demanding increases in the number of enterprises eligible for participation. In the subsidy case studied in this paper, the public more readily understands the benefits than the costs, which are distributed across the whole economy. And, on the other hand, the costs of removing the subsidies are more clearly visible than the benefits derived from getting rid of them.

As for the future research agenda, steel export supply and total steel supply modelling and elasticity estimation should receive more attention. That would allow determining the true determinants of the industry growth, differentiating between the positive effects from the “economic experiment” and favourable external conditions on the industry’s growth, and hypothesising what the industry’s development might have been without the “experiment”, assuming a high world demand for the Ukrainian steel. We admit the deficiencies of our calculations. However, this work provides a first attempt to estimate the welfare costs of the government support to the Ukrainian steel industry and further work in this direction would be welcome.

References

AIIS (American Institute for International Steel) (2001): AIIS Urges Administration to Take Steps to Restructure Domestic Steel and Calls for an End to Protection and Subsidies. Press release, May 24.

AIIS (1999): Subsidies to the US Steel Industry: Are they “Market-Distorting” Practices that “Support Economically Unjustifiable Steel Production?” An Analysis of US Federal, State and Local Assistance to Help US Steel Companies Maintain or Add Steel making Capacity.

Dickson T. (1999): Critically Evaluate the Various arguments for Trade Protection, Economic Research and Analysis (resources for students and researchers). www.tommy.iinet.net.au/essays/essay24.html.

28

Page 31: INSTITUTE FOR ECONOMIC RESEARCH AND POLICY CONSULTINGpdc.ceu.hu/archive/00001668/01/WP_16_eng.pdf · 2004-04-29 · INSTITUTE FOR ECONOMIC RESEARCH AND POLICY CONSULTING Working Paper

INSTITUTE FOR ECONOMIC RESEARCH AND POLICY CONSULTING

Dodonov B. and Opitz P. (2001) Is the Gas Which Ukraine Receives as Transit Fee Used Efficiently? IER/GAG Policy paper Q9.

Dodonov B., P. Opitz, P. Suholov, and C. von Hirschhausen (2001): Monitoring of Infrastructure of Ukraine, IER Working paper No. 8.

Dodonov B., P. Opitz, and W. Pfaffenberger (2001): How Much do Electricity Tariffs Increases in Ukraine Hurt the Poor? IER Working paper No. 7.

Downey M. (2000): Tax Breaks in Ukraine. The Case For and Against their Withdrawal, UEPLAC.

European Parliament (1998): European Parliament Fact Sheets, www.europarl.eu.int.

Goldstein M. and M. Khan (1978): The Supply and Demand for Exports: a Simultaneous Approach. The Review of Economics and Statistics, 60.

Grygorenko Y. (2001): Industry Performance under Transitional Institutions: the Case of Ukrainian Ferrous Metals Industry. Unpublished EERC Master’s Thesis.

Feenstra R. C. (1992): How Costly is Protectionism? The Journal of Economic Perspectives, Volume 6, Issue 3, Summer.

Foreign and Security Policy of Ukraine (2000): Peculiarities of Lobbying External Economic Interests in the Metal Mining Complex of Ukraine. Occasional paper 34.

Horovitz, Dan (2001): Regulatory Challenges to Post-ECSC European Steel in an Enlarging Europe and a Globalising World. 2nd EUROMETAL Congress ‘A Changing Europe in a Globalising World’, Luxembourg, 19-23 May.

Howell T. R. (1993): Trade Protection: Rethinking the American Perspective, New York University. Journal of International Law and Politics, Volume 25, Winter, No. 2.

Irwin D. A. (2000): How Did the United States Become a Net Exporter of Manufactured Goods? Department of Economics, Dartmouth College, Hanover, NH and NBER, Draft, April 12.

Krugman P. R. and M. Obstfeld (1997): International Economics: Theory and Policy. Addison-Wesley.

Legeida N. (2001): Implicit Subsidies in Ukraine: Estimation, Developments, Policy Implications. IER Working paper No. 10.

Mount Union College (1997): The U.S. – Canada Free Trade Agreement: Impact on the US Steel Industry. www.muc.edu.

OECD (1997): Framework for the Measurement of Unrecorded Economic Activities in Transition Economies. OECD Working paper No. 177.

Prus A. (1998): Poland Steel Industry, Industry Sector Analysis. Tradeport.

Rosenberg C., A. Ruocco, and W. Wiegard (1999): Explicit and Implicit Taxation in Uzbekistan. Regensburger Diskussionsbeiträge, June.

TACIS (2001): Anti-Dumping Policy of the European Union. Practical Manual for Ukrainian Producers and Exporters, prepared by Antidumping services of the EC, the Mission of Ukraine to the EU with assistance of Hammond Suddards Edge law firm, Brussels.

US department of Commerce (2001): Report to the President. Global Steel Trade: Structural Problems and Future Solutions, ternational Trade Administration. July, www.ita.doc.ua.

29

Page 32: INSTITUTE FOR ECONOMIC RESEARCH AND POLICY CONSULTINGpdc.ceu.hu/archive/00001668/01/WP_16_eng.pdf · 2004-04-29 · INSTITUTE FOR ECONOMIC RESEARCH AND POLICY CONSULTING Working Paper

INSTITUTE FOR ECONOMIC RESEARCH AND POLICY CONSULTING

Верховна Рада України (1999): Закон України “Про проведення економічного експерименту на підприємствах гірничо-металургійного комплексу України”, 14 липня 1999 року, № 934-14.

Грищенко С. (2000): Горно-металлургический комплекс Украины: состояние, проблемы, перспективы развития. Металл № 5.

Мазур В. П., Иванов А. А. (2000): Состояние и прогноз производства, потребления, экспорта и импорта металлопроката в Украине. Металлургическая и горнорудная промышленность, №2.

Пиковский В. (2000): Экспортный потенциал металлургии Украины. Металл № 5.

Пиковский В. (2000): Естественный отбор – западные подходы к приватизации черной металлургии. Металл, №10.

30

Page 33: INSTITUTE FOR ECONOMIC RESEARCH AND POLICY CONSULTINGpdc.ceu.hu/archive/00001668/01/WP_16_eng.pdf · 2004-04-29 · INSTITUTE FOR ECONOMIC RESEARCH AND POLICY CONSULTING Working Paper

INSTITUTE FOR ECONOMIC RESEARCH AND POLICY CONSULTING

Appendices

Appendix 1

Small country assumption

For the mathematical derivation, it is convenient to use a simplified picture of the Ukrainian export market as presented in the graph below:

X

P XS

XBS XSS

PBS

PSS

A

B

C

D

G

F

where XS is the export supply function, PSS the steel price under the subsidy, PBS the steel price before the subsidy, XBS the steel export supply before the subsidy, and XSS the steel export supply under the subsidy.

The net welfare loss in the graph is equal to the area D (corresponding to the triangle mab in Figure 1). To derive it, we apply integral calculus to find the area of the necessary triangle. The analytical expression for the net welfare losses is:

31

Page 34: INSTITUTE FOR ECONOMIC RESEARCH AND POLICY CONSULTINGpdc.ceu.hu/archive/00001668/01/WP_16_eng.pdf · 2004-04-29 · INSTITUTE FOR ECONOMIC RESEARCH AND POLICY CONSULTING Working Paper

INSTITUTE FOR ECONOMIC RESEARCH AND POLICY CONSULTING

{

SSSS

BSSS

SSSS

BSSS

SSBSSS

SSBSSS

SSBS

BSSS

SS

SSBS

BSBSSS

SSSS

SSBSBSBSSSSSSS

DCB

SS

GGA

BSBSBS

GFDGFDCBA

SSSSSS

D

XsXX

XB

XsXX

XB

XsXXB

XsXBXB

XsX

BXBX

BXB

XsX

BXXBX

BXXB

XsXBXPXBXP

XsdXXX

BXPdXXX

BXPNDL

∗−

−∗∗

+∗

=

=∗−

−∗

+∗

=

=∗−−∗+∗

=

=∗−+

−∗∗−+

−∗∗=

=∗−+

∗+∗−+

∗−∗=

=∗−+

∗+∗∗−+

∗−∗∗=

=∗−

+−∗−

+−∗=

=∗−

∗∗−∗−

∗∗−∗=

+

+

+

++

++

++

++

++

++

++

++−+−−−+++++

∫∫

11

1

11

11

11

11

11

11

11

11

11

)(1

)1

11()1

11(

11

11

11

00

ββ

β

ββ

ββ

ββ

ββ

ββ

ββ

ββ

ββ

ββ

ββ

ββ

ββ

ββ

ββ

ββ

ββ

32144444 344444 2144444 344444 21

(1)

The following expression can be obtained from the export supply function:

( )( ) ( ) ( ) βββ

β

β

ββ

/11/1

/1

/1

/1/1

11

11

1 ssPP

sPP

PP

XX

BS

BS

BS

BS

SS

BS

SS

BS

+=

+∗=

+=

=

+ (2)

and

SSSSSSSSSS XPXXBXB ∗=∗∗=∗ + ββ 1 (3)

By substituting (2) and (3) into (1), we obtain the following expression used in our calculations:

SSSSSS Xss

XPNDL ∗−

+

−∗∗∗+

=+β

βββ

1

/1)1(11

1 (4)

32

Page 35: INSTITUTE FOR ECONOMIC RESEARCH AND POLICY CONSULTINGpdc.ceu.hu/archive/00001668/01/WP_16_eng.pdf · 2004-04-29 · INSTITUTE FOR ECONOMIC RESEARCH AND POLICY CONSULTING Working Paper

INSTITUTE FOR ECONOMIC RESEARCH AND POLICY CONSULTING

Appendix 2

Large-country assumption

To calculate the size of area B in the graph below (corresponding to the trapezoid nrfe in Figure 2), we look again at the export market:

P

PBL

PCL

XCL XBL

XS

A

B

C

D

where XS is the export supply function, PBL the steel price before the subsidy, XBL the steel export supply before the subsidy, PCL the steel price to consumers, and XCL the steel export supply bought by consumers.

The net welfare loss in the graph above is equal to area B.

{

( ) 2111

2111

21

111

21

1

21

121

1

21

/1

1

0

CLBL

CL

CL

BLBL

CLCLBLBLCLCLBLBL

BLBL

CLCLBLBL

BLBLCLCLBL

BLBL

a

CLCL

dc

X

dcba

BLBLB

Ps

P

PXXP

XPXPXPXPXP

XPXXBXPXPXBXP

XPdXXBXPNDLBL

+

∗+

∗=

=−

+

−∗∗=

=∗−

+

−∗∗=∗−+∗

−∗=

=∗−+

∗∗−∗=∗−

+∗−∗=

=∗−∗∗−∗=

+

++++

ββ

β

ββ

ββ

β

ββ

β

4 34 2144 344 21434 21

(5)

33