Immigrants’ Assimilation Process in a Segmented Labor Marketthis analysis difficult to undertake....

55
DISCUSSION PAPER SERIES Forschungsinstitut zur Zukunft der Arbeit Institute for the Study of Labor Immigrants’ Assimilation Process in a Segmented Labor Market IZA DP No. 4394 September 2009 Miguel Angel Alcobendas Núria Rodríguez-Planas

Transcript of Immigrants’ Assimilation Process in a Segmented Labor Marketthis analysis difficult to undertake....

  • DI

    SC

    US

    SI

    ON

    P

    AP

    ER

    S

    ER

    IE

    S

    Forschungsinstitut zur Zukunft der ArbeitInstitute for the Study of Labor

    Immigrants’ Assimilation Process in a Segmented Labor Market

    IZA DP No. 4394

    September 2009

    Miguel Angel AlcobendasNúria Rodríguez-Planas

  • Immigrants’ Assimilation Process

    in a Segmented Labor Market

    Miguel Angel Alcobendas Universitat Autònoma de Barcelona

    and Inside-Spain

    Núria Rodríguez-Planas Universitat Autònoma de Barcelona,

    FEDEA, Inside-Spain and IZA

    Discussion Paper No. 4394 September 2009

    IZA

    P.O. Box 7240 53072 Bonn

    Germany

    Phone: +49-228-3894-0 Fax: +49-228-3894-180

    E-mail: [email protected]

    Any opinions expressed here are those of the author(s) and not those of IZA. Research published in this series may include views on policy, but the institute itself takes no institutional policy positions. The Institute for the Study of Labor (IZA) in Bonn is a local and virtual international research center and a place of communication between science, politics and business. IZA is an independent nonprofit organization supported by Deutsche Post Foundation. The center is associated with the University of Bonn and offers a stimulating research environment through its international network, workshops and conferences, data service, project support, research visits and doctoral program. IZA engages in (i) original and internationally competitive research in all fields of labor economics, (ii) development of policy concepts, and (iii) dissemination of research results and concepts to the interested public. IZA Discussion Papers often represent preliminary work and are circulated to encourage discussion. Citation of such a paper should account for its provisional character. A revised version may be available directly from the author.

  • IZA Discussion Paper No. 4394 September 2009

    ABSTRACT

    Immigrants’ Assimilation Process in a Segmented Labor Market* While much of the literature on immigrants’ assimilation has focused on countries with a large tradition of receiving immigrants and with flexible labor markets, very little is known on how immigrants adjust to other types of host economies. With its severe dual labor market, and an unprecedented immigration boom, Spain presents a perfect natural experiment to analyze immigrations’ assimilation process. Using data from the 2000 to 2008 Spanish Labor Force Survey, we find that immigrants are more occupationally mobile than natives, and that much of this greater flexibility is explained by immigrants’ assimilation process soon after arrival. However, we find little evidence of convergence, especially among women and high skilled immigrants. This suggests that instead of integrating, immigrants are occupationally segregating, implying that there is both imperfect substitutability and underutilization of immigrants’ human capital. JEL Classification: J15, J24, J61, J62 Keywords: immigrants’ assimilation effects, cohort effects, occupational distributions and

    mobility, segmented labor markets Corresponding author: Núria Rodríguez-Planas Unitat de Fonaments de l'Anàlisi Econòmica Edifici B Universitat Autònoma de Barcelona 08193 Bellaterra Spain E-mail: [email protected]

    * Financial support from the Spanish ministry of Education and Science (grant SEJ2006-712) and the Generalitat de Catalunya (grant SGR2005-712) is also gratefully acknowledged.

  • 2

    I. Introduction

    Much of the literature on immigrants’ assimilation has focused on countries with

    a long tradition of receiving immigrants, such as Australia (Chiswick and Miller, 1995),

    Canada (Baker and Benjamin, 1994; and Hum and Simpson, 2000, 2004), Germany

    (Pischke, 1993; Schmidt, 1992; and Constant and Massey, 2005), Israel (Sabatallo,

    1979; Flug, Kasir and Ofer, 1992; Friedberg, 2001; and Eckstein and Weiss, 2004,

    among others), and the United States (Chiswick, 1978; Borjas, 1985; Friedberg, 1993;

    LaLonde and Topel, 1992; Borjas, 1995;; Hu, 2000; Lubotsky, 2000; Duleep and

    Dowhan, 2002; Duleep and Regets, 2002; Card, 2005; and Blau and Kahn, 2007, among

    others). In addition, despite the well known institutional and labor market differences

    existing across these countries, these economies represent relatively flexible labor

    markets, in sharp contrast with the segmented labor markets found in southern European

    countries, transition economies or developing countries. Most of these studies find that

    after an initial adaptation period due to lack of knowledge on how to locate job offers

    (Chiswick, 1986; Manning, 2003; and Frijters et al., 2005) and once offers are located,

    difficulties in gaining recognition for credentials acquired in the source country (Green,

    1995), immigrants’ earnings converge towards those of natives. What is still an open

    debate in this literature is whether and to what extent full-convergence takes place—see

    Card, 2005; or Fernandez and Ortega, 2008, for a thorough discussion on these issues.

    In contrast, not much is known on how immigrants adjust to an economy with

    little experience as a host country and in which its labor market presents a strong

    dualism. Understanding immigrants’ assimilation process in such circumstances can be

    of most policy relevance, especially in the midst of the new immigration flows towards

    the fast growing developing economies.1 As Hatton and Williamson (2005) highlight

    1 Recent evidence indicates that South-South migration accounts for half of all migration from the South: According to Ratha and Shaw (2007), “some of the largest migration corridors are in the South. After the

  • 3

    changes in the direction of world-migration trends towards a more South-South

    direction are likely to create new problems for newly industrial economies.

    Unfortunately, lack of good data in developing countries (Ratha and Shaw, 2007) makes

    this analysis difficult to undertake.2

    In this paper, we propose to use Spain as a “perfect” natural experiment to

    analyze such issues as the country experienced an unprecedented immigration boom in a

    short period of time—with immigrants representing from 1% of the population in 1990

    to 12% in 2009—,3 and presents an extreme case of labor market dualism—with at least

    one third of its labor force in the secondary labor market for the last two decades.4

    While it is true that, currently, the Spanish economy differs in many ways from a

    developing economy; its social, political and economic situation three decades ago was

    not that different from the present situation of many Eastern European countries or other

    developing countries, implying that much can be learned in the developing world from

    the Spanish experience. In addition, in spite of its spectacular changes, Spain still

    suffers from serious problems similar to those experienced by emerging countries, such

    as, a low productivity growth, excessive borrowing, strong rigidities in its labor market

    and financial and banking systems (Andrés, 2009; Garicano, 2008; de la Rica, 2009).

    The contribution of this paper is to provide new evidence on how immigrants

    adjust to a host country with strongly segmented labor markets. More specifically, we

    Mexico-United States corridor, the next three largest are estimated to be Russia-Ukraine, Ukraine-Russia, and Bangladesh-India. Many of these large migration corridors emerged due to the partitioning of countries. When such corridors are excluded, the largest of the remaining corridors are not all South-North—some are North-North, others South-South. India, Russia, and South Africa are well-known as receiving countries in the South.” 2 To our knowledge Gindling, 2009, is the first one to analyze the impact of immigrants from one developing country (Nicaragua) to another one (Costa Rica). In addition, several studies have studied rural-urban migration in urban China (Wu and Li, 1996; Xiang, 1996; Knight et al., 1999; Meng, 2000; and Meng and Zhang, 2001). Finally, there is some research on the impact of emigration from a developing country on the labor market of the migrant sending country (for example, Aydemir and Borjas, 2007 and Hanson, 2008). 3 Since early 2000s, the average annual flow of immigrants in Spain has been around 500,000 per year, representing an increase of 75% of he population over that period. 4 With the current crisis, the proportion of workers with fixed-term contracts has gone down to 25% for the first time since 1989.

  • 4

    use data on the recent immigration wave in Spain to compare the occupational

    distribution of immigrants to that of native-born Spaniards, and in particular with

    native-born Spaniards with similar observable characteristics. In addition, we examine

    how the occupational distribution of immigrants has changed with time spent in Spain.

    All along, we pay special attention on possible heterogeneity effects, that is, we explore

    whether and to what extent the assimilation process of immigrants varies by gender,

    education level, or continent of origin. The paper provides new evidence on the extent

    the immigrant resource is underutilized in Spain, and improves our understanding of the

    recent wave of immigrants’ adaptation process. The paper concludes with explanations

    for the empirical results and some policy implications for countries with severe

    segmented labor markets.

    While much of the literature on immigrants’ assimilation focuses on earnings

    assimilation, such an approach offers a limited and one-dimensional view of the

    adaptation process of the newly arrived, or as Card (2005) puts it: “On the question of

    immigrant assimilation, … a narrow focus on immigrant earnings is misplaced”. 5 A

    richer and alternative measure of assimilation that conveys both labor market adaptation

    and socioeconomic status attainment is provided by observing the occupational

    distribution of immigrants relative to that of natives as time in the host country

    increases. In addition, as Green (1999) explains: “Information on the occupational

    distribution of immigrants and how it changes with time in a host economy is central to

    understanding how immigrants affect economic growth and how they adjust to a host

    country both in economic and social terms.”

    To conduct our analysis, we estimate separate multinomial logit models of

    occupational choice for immigrants and native-born individuals pooling cross-sectional

    5 Unfortunately, no earnings data is available in the Spanish Labor Force Survey. While earnings data are available for Spain in alternative data sets, their use for the current analysis is not without problems (as discussed in more detail in the data section).

  • 5

    data from the 2000 to 2008 Spanish Labor Force Survey. Our model of occupational

    selection relates selection to observable characteristics such as age, sex, education level,

    and place of residence. In addition, for immigrants the occupational choice is related to

    region of birth as well as to year of arrival in Spain. We follow the synthetic cohort

    analysis proposed by Borjas (1985, 1995) in the immigrant earnings literature and track

    specific immigrant waves across a succession of cross-sections. In this manner, we are

    able to disentangle the cohort effect from the assimilation effect.6

    Our analysis highlights three important results. First, we find that immigrants

    are more occupationally mobile than natives. Most of this greater flexibility is

    explained by immigrants’ assimilation process soon after arrival to the host country:

    Just after arrival, immigrants enter occupations below their skill level and then move

    towards higher skilled occupations. However, our second finding indicates that

    convergence does not occur: Immigrants are underutilized in Spain as they segregate

    into low-skilled occupations (compared to natives with similar observable

    characteristics). Third, we find that, among male immigrants, assimilation is strongest

    the lower the education level.

    This paper is more closely related to the following papers in that they also study

    the assimilation process of the recent wave of immigrants in Spain. To our knowledge,

    one of the first studies to explore this question is that of Amuedo-Dorantes and de la

    Rica, 2007. Using 2001 decennial Population Census data, the authors find evidence of

    immigrants’ progressive employment and occupational mobility as their residence in

    Spain increases. Unfortunately, due to data limitations, their analysis focuses on

    immigrants who arrived during the second half of the 1990s and, therefore, misses most

    of the massive recent inflow of immigrants. Moreover, given that they only have a

    6 Green (1999) has applied this framework to analyze immigrants’ occupational mobility relative to natives.

  • 6

    single cross-section, they are unable to follow the synthetic cohort analysis proposed by

    Borjas and used in this paper.7 When expanding the analysis to the beginning of the

    21st century, the evidence on immigrants’ assimilation is somewhat mixed. On the one

    hand, using cross-sectional data from the 1996 to 2005 Spanish Labor Force Survey,

    Fernandez and Ortega, 2008, find that although the Spanish labor market is able to

    absorb immigrants within five years after arrival, it does so at the expense of allocating

    them in temporary jobs for which they are overqualified.8 On the other hand, using

    recently available panel data from social security records, Izquierdo et al., 2009, find

    that, despite a sizeable and significant wage gap reduction between immigrants and

    natives within the first five years after arrival to Spain, full assimilation of wages does

    not take place. Finally, as highlighted by Bentolila et al., 2008, the Spanish experience

    is comparable to the Israeli one in the steady flow of 1.2% per year over the 1992-2000

    period. However, it differs in that the immigration to Israel has been heavily subsidized

    by its government through the offer of vocational training programs or public housing.

    The structure of our paper is as follows. Section 2 presents the motivation and

    several theoretical considerations. Section 3 presents the Spanish institutional

    background, the data, and descriptive statistics. Section 4 contains the main results. The

    paper concludes with a discussion in Section 5.

    II. Motivation and Theoretical Considerations

    To understand immigrants’ contribution to a host country, it is key to analyze

    immigrants’ education or skill composition at arrival relative to that of the receiving 7 Amuedo-Dorantes and de la Rica, 2007, restrict their analysis to immigrants who arrived between 1996 and 2000, and assume that the quality of immigrant cohorts over this 5-year period has remained unchanged. 8 Fernandez and Ortega, 2008, use the following four measures of immigrants’ success in the Spanish labor market: (1) the labor force participation rate, (2) the unemployment rate, (3) a statistical measure of over-education that considers that a worker is overeducated when his/her level of education is above the mean plus one standard deviation of their occupational category, and (4) the incidence of temporary contracts.

  • 7

    economy, and how this immigrants’ skill composition varies to that of natives over

    time. As Dustmann et al.’s (2005) discussion of the underlying theoretical analysis of

    the labor market effects of immigration emphasizes, “there are no effects of

    immigration to be expected on labor market outcomes of residents if immigration does

    not affect the skill composition of the resident labor force and if capital supply is

    perfectly elastic.” Only if immigrants’ inflows change the skill composition of the

    native labor force, disequilibrium between supply of and demand for different types of

    labor at existing wages and output levels will occur and lead to short-run changes on

    wages and employment of natives as the economy moves to a new equilibrium. The

    authors highlight that whether the economic theory predicts long-run effects depends on

    the assumptions being made on the flexibility of the output mix or the closed ness to

    international trade.

    Clearly, immigrants can change the skill composition of the host country’s resident

    labor force through three different mechanisms: (1) by having different skills from those

    of natives at arrival, (2) by how they assimilate to the host country during the first years

    after arrival, and (3) by whether they adapt differently to the economy than natives. For

    instance, even in the hypothetical case in which immigrants had the same skills as

    natives at arrival to the host country, their lack of knowledge on how to find job offers

    or the difficulties in getting their credentials recognized could well generate a transitory

    disequilibrium in which recently arrived highly qualified immigrants would compete for

    low-skill jobs while building up knowledge of the host country’s labor market, so that,

    with time, they could find jobs that matched their skills. This is the well known

    assimilation process most immigrants initially go through when they first arrive to a

    country, and in and by itself such process can generate short-run disequilibrium in

    certain types of labor markets. Alternatively, even after immigrants have assimilated,

  • 8

    they may well react differently from natives to economic changes. This may occur

    because immigrants may well be less geographically attached than the native labor

    force, have different taste or preferences towards work or different types of work, or

    may care less (or differently) about socio-economic status of certain jobs or

    occupations.

    Clearly, the country’s immigration policy plays a key role in determining the

    occupational distribution of immigrants at arrival. For instance, early research on US

    immigrants, which used data on immigrants who had mainly entered the US prior to the

    1965 Immigration Act, finds that most immigrants were born in Europe and Canada and

    were more likely to be in managerial and professional, service and laborer jobs relative

    to native born, and were under-represented in “precision production, craft and repair”

    jobs and in the agricultural sector. In contrast, research based on more recent

    immigrants, that is, those arriving by the 1980s and after, were more likely to come

    from Mexico, Central America and Asia, to have lower average schooling than natives,

    and to be no longer over-represented in managerial and professional jobs, but instead

    show a slight over-representation in primary and farming jobs (Chiswick, 1978; Borjas,

    1992; Card et al., 2000; and Card, 2005). This shift in the composition of immigrants is

    to a large extent explained by US immigration policy, which went from establishing

    national origin quotas with a strong bias in favor of Northern Europeans prior to 1965,

    to establishing preferences for people with family members already in the country.

    Similarly, Green (1999) finds that immigrants who arrived in Canada in the 1970s,

    when Canada’s immigration system gave priority to immigrants who entered via the

    “independent” class and who were assessed based on a point-scoring system whereby

    potential immigrants were ranked on the basis of skill-related characteristics or wealth,

    tended to be more concentrated in the higher skilled sectors relative to the native born

  • 9

    and less concentrated in more traditional sectors. However, this over-representation in

    the skilled occupations declined across subsequent entry cohorts, reflecting Canadian

    immigration policy’s shift away from a selective system towards a system that gives

    priority to close relatives of those immigrants already in the country and that does not

    assess immigrants on personal skill-related characteristics. Similarly, Sweden has also

    seen the ethnic (and skill composition) of its immigrants change with the nature of its

    immigration (Duvander, 2001). As the Swedish immigration policy changed from

    focusing on labor market immigration in the 1960s, when labor demand was high, to

    refugee and family immigration in the 1970s and onward, the ethnic composition of its

    immigrants has changed from being to a large extent Finnish in the 1960s, to Iranian,

    Chilean, and Polish. In contrast, in Australia, where immigration policy based on a

    points system began in the early 1990s and was reinforced in 1996 and later by

    tightening the selection criteria, the evidence suggests that there was a stronger self-

    selection among prospective migrants leading to higher quality and better employability

    for the later waves of migration (Cobb-Clark, 2000, 2003; Richardson et al., 2001,

    2002; Chiswick and Miller, 2006; and Thapa and Gørgens, 2006). Right after World

    War II, the UK immigration policy initially favored Commonwealth citizens over

    others. However, in the early 1970s, the UK shifted its immigration policy towards a

    preference for European citizens and tightened entry restrictions to citizens of former

    colonies. This change in immigration policy led to a change in the national-origin mix

    of immigrants, which had a significant impact on the skill-characteristics of the different

    cohorts of immigrants, increasing the skill endowment of the successive cohorts of

    immigrants (Bell, 1997).9

    9 The strong link between skill characteristics and country of origin has been highlited by many researchers, Borjas, 1985 and 1995, among others.

  • 10

    Regardless of their initial ethnic-mix and occupational distribution, the evidence

    shows that immigrants go through a similar assimilation pattern in the first couple of

    years after arrival in which they initially face a period of non-employment or

    employment in low skill jobs as they learn how the host country’s labor market works.

    As immigrants spend time in the host country and gradually acquire this country-

    specific knowledge, their labor market performance may improve relative to that of

    their native counterparts (for Canada, see Richmon and Kalback, 1980; Boyd, 1985;

    Green, 1999; for Israel, see Flug et al., 1992; Cohen and Eckstein, 2002; and for the

    United States, see Chiswick 1978b; Jasso and Rosenzweig, 1988, Borjas, 1992).

    However, full convergence of immigrants’ occupational distribution towards that of

    natives may not necessarily occur. First, if the country’s immigration policy has

    imposed restrictions on immigrants’ entry that match immigrants’ skills to host country

    labor demand needs, new immigrants will have an occupational distribution that reflects

    the highest demand growth sectors more than will the distribution of the native born.

    Second, although some convergence may occur over time, complete assimilation is

    unlikely to take place if native-born new labor market entrants move towards sectors

    less saturated by immigrants. In addition, once assimilation of immigrants has taken

    place, it is likely that immigrants end up being more occupationally mobile than natives

    and that they adapt differently to economic shocks than natives (as found by Green,

    1991; Barth et al., 2004 and 2006; and Dustmann et al., 2009).

    Alternative theoretical models are useful to understand the channels that explain

    immigrants’ assimilation process after arrival into the host-country. In the remainder of

    this section, we discuss two alternative theories with distinct predictions: human capital

    theory and segmented labor markets.

  • 11

    Human Capital Theory. Eckstein and Weiss (2004) develop a human capital model

    in which different skills are rewarded differently at different occupations, and that

    describes the investment decisions of immigrants and natives. The added value of this

    model is that there is an explicit introduction of a time-since-arrival effect on prices of

    skills that influence the immigrants’ investment decision process. The acquisition of

    new skills requires some sacrifice of current earnings. The investment decisions

    interact with the changes in the market value of the immigrant’s skills and together

    determine his earnings growth. In particular, rising prices for imported skills provide an

    added incentive for investment because the sacrifice of current earnings is low relative

    to the growth in future earnings capacity. In their model, immigrants fully assimilate if

    the prices of imported skills converge to the same price as that obtained by natives for

    locally produced skills, because increasing prices on imported human capital imply

    higher investment by immigrants. However, if imported skills are of lower quality and

    so their long-run prices falls short of the value of the locally acquired skills, then

    earnings of immigrants may never catch up with those of natives. Such a model

    suggests that assimilation or convergence ought to be easier among higher educated

    immigrants and those coming from countries with higher compatibility of the human

    capital received abroad with the skill requirements of the host-country labor market as it

    ought to be easier for those with higher schooling to build up the host country’s labor

    market specific human capital because of the greater complementarity between pre- and

    post-migration human capital.10

    Segmented Labor Markets. According to the dualistic view, the labor market is

    segmented by two types of jobs: those in the primary sector, characterized by jobs with

    high-productivity growth and good benefits and chances of promotion, and those in the

    10 In this model, transitions up the occupational scale occur exogenously and are fully anticipated. Cohen and Eckstein (2002) estimate a structural model in which occupational switches and investment decisions are jointly determined and find similar predictions.

  • 12

    secondary or informal sector, where less productive jobs with little or no benefits are

    found. Under such view, individuals working in the secondary sector are frequently

    seen as the disadvantaged segment of the labor force rationed out of salaried

    employment (Fajnzylber and Montes Rojas, 2006). In other words, workers with little

    access to the primary labor market enter the secondary sector while queuing for wage

    and salary jobs. Since more vulnerable groups of native workers, such as low-skilled

    workers, youth, and women, tend to be concentrated in the secondary labor market

    (Kahn, 2007), converging towards their occupational distribution ought to be relatively

    easier for low-skill natives than the convergence process of high-skilled immigrants

    towards the occupational distribution of high-skill males natives, who are likely to be

    concentrated in the primary labor market.

    In the remainder of the paper, we will first discuss the Spanish institutional

    background, key to understanding immigrants’ assimilation process. Then we will

    provide descriptive evidence that immigrants are more occupationally mobile than

    natives. Subsequently, we will analyze how the occupational distributions of

    immigrants differ to that of observationally equivalent natives as time in the country

    increases. We shall conclude with a discussion on alternative theoretical explanations

    for our findings.

    III. Background and Data

    III.1. Economic and Institutional Background

    In mid-1970s Spain had very high firing costs inherited from the Franco regime.

    To reduce them, fixed-term labor contracts were introduced in 1984, with the objective

    of adding flexibility and promoting employment in a rigid labor market with stringent

    employment protection legislation and high levels of unemployment. The policy

  • 13

    backfired, and fixed-term employment soared, promptly reaching one third of the

    Spanish labor force, and creating a dual labor market with workers with fixed-term

    contracts holding unstable, low protected and poorly paid jobs, while workers with

    indefinite contracts enjoyed protection and presumably also higher wages—Segura et

    al., 1991; Bentolila and Dolado, 1994; Jimeno and Toharia, 1993, Hernanz, 2002; and

    de la Rica, 2004. The reforms of 1994 and 1997 aimed to enhance the use of permanent

    contracts and reduce its cost. However, both reforms were quite unsuccessful at

    reducing the share of temporary contracts in the labor force—see Kugler et al., 2005,

    and Dolado et al., 2002.

    In the last decade, the immigrant population in Spain has soared. While, as

    recently as a decade ago, immigrants made up less than 2% of the population, they are

    now over 12%. Most of this massive inflow of immigrants has taken place after the turn

    of the new century. Several factors explain this rapid change. First, Spanish booming

    economy and the social promotion—in the form of increased education levels and

    higher labor force participation—of its national (especially female) population

    generated a demand for foreign workers (Carrasco et al., 2008 a; Domingo et al., 2006;

    and Gil and Domingo, 2007).11 Second, its physical proximity to northern Africa and

    eastern Europe places Spain close to countries that supply immigrants.12 Third, its

    shared language and historical pass with Latin Americans facilitates the social and

    cultural assimilation of immigrants from this continent, as illustrated by the fact that

    close to 50% of the immigrants are from Latin America. Finally, the progressive

    culture of post-Franco Spain has also contributed to increase immigrants’ social

    acceptance (New York Times, 2008).

    11 In contrast with northern European countries, the ageing of national working-age population does not explain the arrival of large number of immigrants in Spain (Domingo et al., 2006). 12 17% and 34% of the immigrants in Spain come from Africa and Europe, respectively.

  • 14

    Spain has not had an active policy of attracting immigrants. As early as 1985,

    Spain imposed severe restrictions on non-European Union foreigners who wanted to

    establish Spanish residency and citizenship.13 Beginning 1993, further tightening took

    place with tougher restrictions on work and residency permit renewals and the

    implementation of immigration quotas system, which limited the entry of foreigners to

    about 30,000 immigrants per year. At the turn of the century, Spain updated its

    immigration legislation and assimilated it to that of other European countries.

    However, the free-entrance of foreigners as tourists together with a lax

    implementation of immigration laws and several generous amnesties that have granted

    legal residence to illegal immigrants (1985, 1991, 1996, 2000, 2001, and 2005) have de

    facto converted Spain in an immigrant friendly country (Dolado and Vázquez, 2007;

    Izquierdo et al., 2009, among others). In fact, the most common way of obtaining legal

    status in Spain during the past two decades has been through amnesties. Most

    frequently immigrants arrived in Spain either illegally or as tourists, and they were

    subsequently granted legal status through the multiple amnesties that have been granted

    since the mid-1980s—see Amuedo-Dorantes and de la Rica, 2005, 2008, and Dolado

    and Vazquez, 2007.14 Between 1985 and 1991, as many as 150,000 immigrants

    regularized their status; between 1996 and 2001, a total of 400,000 immigrants did the

    same; and in the last amnesty, that of 2005, as many as 550,000 immigrants got their

    residence permits.

    While it is true that our data may under-represent illegal aliens, the fact that we

    pool LFS years from 2000 to 2008 minimizes the potential biases that may rise from the 13 To have the legal status, immigrants were required to acquire a work and residency permit that restricted them to work in a particular activity and geographic area only for a year. In addition, immigrants were not granted any social benefit despite paying social security taxes when employed. 14 For instance in the 2000 amnesty to become legal aliens, immigrants had to provide proof of one of the following: (i) residence since June 1st, 1999; (ii) having held a work permit any time during the three-year period preceding February 1st, 2000; (iii) being denied asylum before February 2000; (iv) having applied for any type of residence permit before March 30th, 2000; or (v) family ties to legal residents or to individuals in any of the previous categories.

  • 15

    successive amnesties because most undocumented immigrants in our sample with at

    least one year of residence are likely to have been legalized. Therefore, although

    amnesties may affect in some ways the estimates of the year prior to the amnesty for the

    recently arrived immigrants, subsequently these individuals have no reason to misreport

    their date of arrival once they are legal aliens. For this reason, and given that we focus

    on year-to-year differences in assimilation rates, we do not think that amnesties ought to

    be a major concern in our analysis—similar arguments were presented in Amuedo-

    Dorantes and de la Rica, 2007.

    III.2. Data and Descriptive Statistics

    Our analysis is based on data from second quarter of the Spanish Labor Force

    Survey (LFS) from the years 2000 to 2008.15 The Spanish LFS gathers information on

    demographic characteristics (such as, age, years of education, marital status, and region

    of residence), and employment characteristics (such as work status, occupation, and

    industry).16 In addition, for immigrants—defined as foreign-born workers who do not

    have the Spanish nationality, the LFS collects information on the number of years of

    residence in Spain and the country of birth.

    The native-born samples are random samples of males and females aged 20 to 64 at

    the time of the relevant LFS. The immigrant sample consists of all immigrants in the

    relevant LFS who entered Spain after January 1, 1990, were aged 20 to 64 at their time

    of arrival, and are under age 65 at the time of the relevant LFS. Analysis is restricted to

    immigrants aged 20 to 64 at time of arrival to concentrate on individuals who were

    likely headed for the labor force in the near future and to avoid issues of non-

    15 As is common practice in the research using this dataset, we only use the second quarter to avoid repeated observations. The LFS is carried out every quarter on a sample of around 60,000 households. Each quarter, one sixth of the sample is renewed. However, the dataset does not include a variable that allows identification of individuals along the six consecutive interviews. 16 Unfortunately, the EPA does not gather workers’ earnings information.

  • 16

    comparability of the experiences of young immigrants who received part of their basic

    education in Spain and those who arrived at older ages.17 The samples are restricted to

    individuals under age 65 in the LFS year to avoid complications involving retirement

    decisions. The immigrant samples are restricted to those entering in 1990 and after

    because the vast majority of immigrant flows has taken place from the late mid-nineties

    onwards.18

    Table 1 displays personal and demographic descriptive statistics for natives and

    immigrants for each of the LFS years (descriptive statistics by gender, continent of

    origin, and cohort of arrival can be found in Tables A.1 and A.2 in the Appendix). The

    major difference between the two population groups is that immigrants are younger than

    natives.19 In addition, we observe that there are education differences across the two

    groups.20 Within the native population, there has clearly been an increase of workers’

    investment in human capital, as the fraction of natives with a college degree, vocational

    training, or a high-school diploma has increased over the nine years under analysis.

    Although a similar trend is observed for immigrants with less than a college degree

    (with the share of those with vocational training increasing the most), the share of

    immigrants with a college degree has decreased over-time from 22% to 17%.

    Comparing immigrants and natives in our sample, we observe that immigrants are

    slightly more educated than natives (especially in the earlier surveys).21 Finally, it is

    17 This restriction criteria is common in the literature, see Boyd, 1985; Kossoudji, 1989; and Green, 1999, among others. 18 Again this is a common restriction in the Spanish literature, see Amuedo-Dorantes and de la Rica., 2007, and Gonzalez and Ortega, 2008, among others. 19 One exception is in the range between 20 and 24 years old, where we observe that there are more natives than immigrants. This is an artifact of how the sample of immigrants was selected as we restricted immigrants to be 20 years old or older at the time of arrival. 20 Throughout the analysis we consider four education levels: high-school dropouts; individuals with a high-school degree; individuals with some college education or vocational training (they may have a trade certificate, but no college degree); and individuals with completed university studies. 21 Although much of this result is due to the fact that we restricted the sample of immigrants to those arriving after 1990, we are not the first ones to find that the level of education of immigrants is not that different from that of natives (Dolado and Vázquez, 2007).

  • 17

    noteworthy to highlight the change in the continent of origin of immigrants over the last

    decade. While in the early 2000s, immigrants came from Europe, Africa and Latin

    America in similar proportions; by the 2008 LFS, the weight of immigrants from

    Europe and Africa has been reduced drastically, representing only 12% and 17%,

    respectively, and giving room to a large inflow of immigrants from Latin America.

    Table 2 presents the occupational distributions at each LFS for the native born and

    for immigrants from each of the entering cohorts. The occupations are grouped into

    five categories as follows: “Professionals”, which include managers, engineers, social

    scientists, teachers, health occupations, and arts; “Other white-collar” occupations,

    which include clerical, sales, and service occupations; “Qualified blue-collar”

    occupations, which cover qualified workers in agriculture and the fishing industry,

    handcraft workers, mining and construction technical workers; “Non-qualified”

    occupations, which include jobs such as janitors, or non qualified laborers; and “Not

    working”, which includes both the unemployed and persons out of the labor force.22

    The latter category is included because, as argued by Green 1999, it is an important part

    of immigrant adaptation and will likely vary between immigrants and native born.

    There are at least five striking differences in the amount and type of change within

    the immigrant and native-born distributions across LFS years. First, while both

    population groups have shown a clear tendency of moving out of the “not working”

    category over the 2000-2008 period, the change has been considerably larger for

    immigrants arriving after 1999, with reductions of 20 to 28 percentage points, versus

    the—by no means negligible—reduction of 11 percentage points experienced by the

    native-born cohort.23 This shift out of the “not working” category for both population

    22 Notice that the self-employed are included in our sample. 23 Such reductions are not observed for the cohort arriving in 2001 and are considerably smaller for the cohort 2002. This is probably explained by the fact that, due to the 2001 crisis, immigrants entering during 2001 and 2002 did so with favorable job perspective, as reflected by the lower fraction of

  • 18

    groups reflects the Spanish economic growth over the period under analysis. However,

    the fact that this trend is stronger for some, but not all, cohorts of immigrants, added to

    the observation that frequently the earlier cohorts show a movement similar or even

    smaller to that of the native population seems to suggest that part of what is going on is

    the assimilation of the immigrants. Second, the trend of this movement out of the “not

    working” category has also differed across the two populations. For the native-born

    population, the tendency has been gradual over the nine years, while for the immigrants

    most of the shift out of this category has occurred within the first two to three years

    after arrival to Spain, reflecting the initial assimilation process that this population

    experiences.

    Third, the destination of these individuals has also differed for the two groups.

    While the native-born population have seen an increase in the “professional”, and, to a

    lesser extent, the “other white-collar” categories; the immigrant population has mainly

    moved into the “blue-collar” and, to a lesser extend, “other white-collar” categories.

    Among immigrants arrived within the last decade, there is a trend out of the

    “professional” category. Fourth, there is clearly a greater fluidity of the immigrant

    distribution relative to that of the natives, as several cohorts of immigrants experience

    changes within an occupational category of up to 17 percentage points over the decade,

    while no native born category changes by more than 7 percentage points. This greater

    fluidity of the immigrant distribution may well reflect a greater ability to adjust to

    economic changes.

    Finally, when comparing the occupational distributions for earlier cohort of

    immigrants with those of the native born, we find that over-time natives have increased

    immigrants from these cohorts “not working” compared to the other cohorts. The reductions are also smaller for the most recent cohorts, that is, those arriving in the last three years. The data suggests that the smaller reductions are most likely a consequence of these immigrants still assimilating to the new country.

  • 19

    their likelihood of being in the “professional” category, and “other white-collar”

    category compared to immigrants from the 1990s. In contrast, the immigrant

    population is relatively more concentrated in “blue-collar” and “non-qualified”

    occupations. This seems to suggest that there has been a shift towards less manual jobs

    among the native population compared to a shift in the opposite direction for

    immigrants, providing some evidence that these two populations have become more

    complementary over time. Several recent papers have highlighted that native and

    immigrant workers of similar educational attainment specialize in different occupations

    and therefore do not compete for the same jobs, explaining the small effect the inflows

    of immigrants on the wages of the less-educated natives in the U.S. (Ottaviano and Peri,

    2006) as well as in Spain (Carrasco et al., 2008b). For instance, Peri and Sparber, 2008,

    find evidence of imperfect substitutability between natives and immigrants of similar

    educational attainment in the U.S. Dustmann, et al. 2008, also show that natives and

    immigrants in the U.K. of comparable skills do not compete for the same jobs, and

    Carrasco et al., 2008b, and Amuedo and de la Rica, 2009, find evidence of immigrants

    and natives being imperfect substitutes within skill categories in Spain.24

    IV. Methodology

    Tables 1 and 2 indicate that the immigrants’ occupational distribution changes

    more over time than does the native-born distribution. In what follows, we explore the

    reasons for these differences. More specifically, it is unclear whether immigrants’

    relative greater occupational mobility compared to the native born is due to: (1)

    observable differences between immigrants and natives; (2) immigrants’ assimilation

    24Carrasco et al., 2008b, use data from the Spanish Structure of Earnings Survey, of which two waves (1995 and 2002) were available when their paper was written. Only the latter wave has information on worker’s nationality. Amuedo and de la Rica, 2009, use the EPA 1999-2007 and focus on low-skilled workers (with at most a high-school degree). Their analysis on substitutability of natives and immigrants is brief and descriptive, and not the focus of their paper.

  • 20

    process to a new economy—the assimilation effect; or (3) differences in occupational

    skills across successive cohorts of immigrants—the time-invariant cohort effect.25

    To study the importance of these alternative explanations in the Spanish case of

    the beginning of the 21st century, we pool data from all LFS surveys and estimate a

    multinomial logit (MNL) model of occupational selection separately over each of the

    immigrant and native-born samples. The MNL model permits estimation of the effects

    of various characteristics of an individual on his choice from among a set of alternatives

    that do not have a natural ordering, occupations in this case.26

    The MNL can be rationalized using an index model in which the value of a

    particular occupational choice is represented by:

    jctij

    ctctij

    cti XI εβ += (1)

    where j indexes the alternative, c indexes the entry cohort of the immigrant, t indexes

    the LFS year, and i indexes the individual, ctiX is a vector of person-specific

    characteristics, jctβ is a parameter vector that varies by alternative and LFS year, j

    ctiε is

    an error term. The probability that individual i from cohort c chooses alternative j in

    period t is the probability that kctij

    cti II > for all jk ≠ .

    Assuming jctiε follows an independent extreme value distribution, the resulting

    specification for the choice probabilities will be a MNL model with cohort-specific year

    25 An alternative reason might be differences in reaction to economic change between immigrants and natives after accounting for assimilation and time-invariant cohort effects. Despite the newly received academic attention of this reason (see Barth et al., 2004 and 2006, and Dustmann et al., 2009), exploring its relevance in the context of this paper proved unfeasible due to data limitations, as we only have LFS data from 2000 to 2008, which barely covers a whole business cycle. Explorative analysis with the data at hand indicated that such differences were negligible in the time period under analysis. Further research exploiting the current crisis is likely to lead to different results. While this is of great interest, it lies beyond the point of this paper. 26While the MNL has the disadvantage that the relative odds of choosing any one option over another is unrelated to the introduction of further options, we are unable to estimate the multinomial probit (MNP), which allows relaxation of the independence assumption, because individuals are observed making only one occupational choice, and therefore a correlation matrix cannot be estimated with these data.

  • 21

    of arrival dummies and LFS-year dummies. Estimating the following equation for

    immigrants,

    jctij

    ctictij

    cti XP εβ += (2)

    we obtain estimates of the fitted probabilities of choosing alternative j for immigrants:

    jctictij

    cti XP β̂ˆ = (3)

    For native-born individuals, a similar index model is used but omitting the

    region of birth dummy variables and year of entry cohort-dummy variables, as

    explained below. Estimating the following equations for native-born individuals,

    jti

    jtiti

    jnti XP εβ += (4)

    we obtain estimates of the fitted probabilities of choosing alternative j for natives:

    jtitij

    nti XP β̂ˆ = (5)

    The variables used to explain choices among these alternatives include sex, age,

    education, marital status, and LFS-year dummies. In addition, a set of location dummy

    variables are included because immigrants tend to exhibit different location patterns

    from the native born. For immigrants, a second set of variables is also used. These

    include: (1) a set of dummy variables corresponding to the region of birth to pick up

    differences in assimilation that might be related to regional characteristics, and (2) year

    of entry cohort-dummy variables.

    Comparison of the fitted probabilities between a representative immigrant

    (equation 3) and a representative national (equation 5) with similar observable

    characteristics of choosing alternative j at a given LFS survey year t—as reflected by

    equation 6 below—, provides some insight into whether the immigrant resource is being

    underutilized in the sense of being found in lower skilled jobs for the same education

  • 22

    level than the native born and into the effects of characteristics that are used in

    immigrant selection.

    )ˆˆ( jntij

    cti PP − (6)

    We shall estimate these differences in fitted probabilities between a representative

    immigrant and national as time in the country increases for the immigrant, obtaining a

    cross-sectional measure of assimilation.27 While these cross-sectional estimates will

    inform us on the assimilation process of a representative immigrant, they will also

    reflect the immigrants’ time-invariant cohort effect and how this cohort experiences

    changes in the economy (relative to natives).

    To isolate the assimilation effect, we shall compare the same cohort across LFS

    years (using again the native born as a comparison group to eliminate the effects due to

    changes in the economy). As such, comparisons of the fitted probabilities for a

    representative immigrant from cohort c of choosing alternative j between LFS year t and

    LFS year (t-k) normalized by the changes observed in the fitted probabilities

    experienced by a representative native over the same time period yields:

    )ˆˆ()ˆˆ( )()(j

    iktnj

    ntij

    iktcj

    cti PPPP −− −−− (7)

    , which is an estimate of the net assimilation effect, assuming that immigrants and

    natives experience change in the economy in the same way and that X is common

    vector across time.28

    27 Observing how these differences vary as immigrants’ time in Spain increases delivers, in essence, the same analysis presented in Amuedo-Dorantes and de la Rica, 2007, where they use the 2001 Census to estimate immigrants’ assimilation relative to natives. The authors acknowledge that, because they only have a single cross-section, their estimates will be biased if the quality of immigrants across cohorts changes. However, they argue that the quality of immigrants across cohorts has remained unchanged over their sample period as they only focus on immigrants who have arrived within the last 5 years. 28 While this may seem a reasonable assumption given that we are only analyzing a period of nine years, several authors have found evidence against this for the UK and Germany (see for instance Dustmann et al., 2009). In our exploratory work, we have examined whether there were trends in unobservable differences across cohorts, by comparing the fitted probabilities for a representative immigrant from different cohorts observed at the same number of years after arrival in Spain, again normalizing for changes experienced by the native born over the same time period. Any observed differences in these

  • 23

    V. Empirical Results

    V.1. Are Immigrants Underutilized in Spain?

    In this section, we explore whether immigrants are underutilized in Spain by

    comparing the occupational distribution of immigrants to that of their native

    counterparts. In addition, we analyze how this native/immigrant differential evolves

    with immigrants’ time in the host country. For simplicity of exposure, we plot

    differences in fitted probabilities of choosing alternative occupations between natives

    and immigrants as immigrants’ time in Spain increases in Figures 1.A through 1.D. The

    estimates from these Figures are obtained by subtracting the probability that a native-

    born worker of a given type chooses a particular occupation from the probability that an

    immigrant of the same type chooses the same occupation at each LFS survey (as

    indicated by equation 6 above). Since these estimates are calculated at different years

    after arrival in Spain, they represent a cross-sectional measure of assimilation. All

    differences are statistically significant from zero at the 5% level.

    The analysis is done for the following types of workers: For native-born

    individuals, the type 1 person is a male living in Madrid, aged 35 to 39 years old,

    currently married, without a high-school degree. For immigrants, that person is from

    Latin America and arrived in Spain in 2002.29 Type 2 is the same as type 1 but with a

    high-school degree. Type 3 is the same as type 1 but with vocational training or some

    college. Type 4 is the same as type 1 but with a university degree. Type 5 is the same

    as type 4 but comes from the EU15. Type 6 is the same as type 3 but comes from all

    estimates would either reveal that there were unobserved differences across the different cohort of workers or that immigrants and natives reacted differently to economic change. Perhaps not surprisingly, given the short period horizon, we did not find evidence of major differences. 29 Plots of these differences for all the other cohorts, as well as the fitted probabilities for the different types of natives and immigrants are available from the authors upon request. The overall pattern is similar across different cohorts.

  • 24

    European countries, excluding those from the EU15.30 And Type 7 is the same as type

    1 but comes from Africa.31 Types 1 through 4 are displayed in Figure 1.A and types 5,

    3, 6 and 7 are displayed in Figure 1.C.32 Figures 1.B and 1.D report results for women.

    A positive estimate implies that immigrants are over-represented in a given category

    relative to natives with similar observable characteristics. For instance, in the top LHS

    panel of Figure 1.A, the first bar height in the “non-qualified” category indicates that

    immigrant males without a high-school degree who arrived in Spain in 2002 are 15

    percentage points more likely to hold a job in a “non-qualified” occupation in 2002 than

    their natives counterpart. The results are summarized below and clearly show that

    immigrants are underutilized in Spain and that they seem to segregate into low-skilled

    occupations.33

    Compared to natives, immigrants tend to concentrate in the “non-qualified”

    category, regardless of their education, sex, age, and of time in the country.

    Compared to natives, immigrants are over-represented in the “non-qualified” category.

    With the exception of immigrants from EU15—shown in the top LHS chart of Figure

    1.C—, this is true across LFS survey years, for all types of workers, and it does not

    seem to change much with time spent in the country (implying that full assimilation

    does not occur). Moreover, this relative over-representation of immigrants in “non-

    qualified” jobs (regardless of their education, sex and age) is large, representing a hefty

    10 to 20 percentage-points difference or more for males. It is also quite striking that,

    for males, the native/immigrant’s differential does not change with worker’s education

    30 While we would have liked to identify eastern Europeans from other Europeans, this is not possible with the Spanish LFS. 31 When deciding on the types by continent of origin, we decided to choose types based on the average education level for that group, as opposed to holding education constant across different origins. The reason being that in this paper we focus on how immigrants assimilate in Spain, as opposed to analyzing whether immigrants of different origins with identical observable characteristics assimilate differently. 32 Note that type 3 is represented twice. 33 Although not shown, the analysis was also done for an eight type who was the same as type 3 but aged 25 years old instead. Whenever appropriate we include the results in the text. Estimates are available from the authors upon request.

  • 25

    level—as shown in Figure 1.A. For female workers, the difference between immigrants

    and natives is even larger (between the two and four-digit range) and, in contrast with

    the findings from males, the gap between natives and immigrants is considerably larger

    for lower-skilled workers—as shown in Figure 1.B.

    Compared to natives, immigrants without a college degree are under-

    represented in the “not working” category—if not immediately after arrival, within

    two to three years. Moreover, this under-representation increases at two to three after

    arrival in Spain. This pattern is observed both for males and females, and clearly

    suggests that low-skilled immigrants come to Spain to work. For high-school dropout

    immigrants, there is an initial under-representation in the “not working” category

    relative to their native counterparts, and this under-representation increases after two or

    three years in the country. The only exception to this pattern is for African immigrants,

    for which we observe that right after arrival they are heavily over-represented in the

    “non working” category (as shown in the bottom RHS chart of Figure 1.C). This

    sizeable difference of about 10 percentage points decreases considerable after African

    immigrants have been in the country for three to four years. For immigrants with a

    high-school degree or trade certificate, an under-representation in the “not working”

    category relative to their native counterparts arises two to three years after arriving in

    the country. In contrast, for immigrants with a college degree, we observe an initial

    over-representation in the “not-working” category compared to their native counterparts

    hovering 5 percentage points for males and 10 percentage points for females. Two or

    three years after arrival this over-representation of college immigrants in the “not

    working” category looses relevance.

    There is some evidence of convergence between low-skilled male immigrants

    and natives in “blue-collar” occupations around three to five years after arrival in

  • 26

    Spain. For low-skilled male immigrants (that is, those with a high-school degree or

    less), there is an initial under-representation in the “blue-collar” category relative to

    their native counterparts that decreases with time in the host country, and seems to

    disappear three (five) years after arrival for high-school graduates (high-school

    dropouts)—as shown in the top charts of Figure 1.A. Moreover, for high-school

    graduates, after five years in Spain, they are over-represented in this category relative to

    their native counterparts, suggesting that there may be some convergence between low-

    skilled immigrants and natives around three to five years after arrival in Spain. There is

    again a clear exception to this pattern for immigrants from Africa—bottom RHS chart

    of Figure 1.C. In this case, although the under-representation of African immigrants in

    this category decreases with time in the host country, it does not vanish even after 6

    years in the country.34

    High-skilled male immigrants seem to segregate into “qualified blue-collar”

    jobs and “non-qualified” jobs—shown in bottom two chars of Figure 1.A. Relative to

    natives, male immigrants with a trade certificate are over-represented in the “blue-

    collar” and “non-qualified” categories and under-represented in the “professional” and

    “other white-collar” categories. There is no apparent trend suggesting some

    convergence over time. The findings for young male workers with a trade certificate

    (not shown) or male immigrants with a college degree are very similar. The major

    difference is the relative concentration in the different categories for the most educated

    type. For instance, compared to natives they are under-represented in the “professional”

    category and slightly over-represented in the “other white-collar” category. The fact

    that the relative differences between immigrants and natives are not reduced over time

    seems to suggest that there is little convergence within this group.

    34 This non-convergence holds for cohorts who have been longer in the country.

  • 27

    Female immigrants seem to segregate into “non-qualified” jobs—as shown in

    Figure 1.B. Relative to natives, immigrant women with a trade certificate or less are

    over-represented in the “non-qualified” category and under-represented in the

    “professional” and “other white-collar” categories. In the case of women with a college

    degree, they seem to segregate into “non-qualified” jobs and “other white-collar”

    occupations relative to their native counterparts. Again there does not seem to be an

    apparent trend suggesting some convergence over time.

    Coming from (mainly) Spanish speaking countries facilitates the convergence

    between female immigrants and natives. For males, the language advantage has only

    a marginal effect on the type of occupational choice. While the charts in Figure 1.D

    show that coming from Latin America reduces the females’ fitted probabilities of being

    in “non-qualified” and “other white-collar” categories relative to immigrants from

    Europe (excluding the EU15), suggesting that coming from Spanish speaking countries

    facilitates the assimilation process women, no such improvement is observed among

    males. Figure 1.C shows that the differences in the native/immigrants occupational

    fitted distribution between Latino immigrants and their European counterparts

    (excluding the EU15 members) is merely a shift in the distribution between “other

    white-collar” and “blue-collar” occupations. Latino male immigrants are less under-

    represented in the former category, whereas European immigrants are more over-

    represented in the latter category.

    V.2. What Is the Net Assimilation Effect of Immigrants in Spain?

    In what follows, we address the following question: For a given cohort, how

    does the occupational distribution change with time since arrival in Spain? In essence,

    this is equivalent to analyze the net assimilation effect, which compares the change

  • 28

    observed in the fitted probabilities experienced by same cohort of immigrants at

    different points after arrival to the host country (net of the changes observed in the

    native population over the same time period)—as shown by equation 7 above. Figures

    2.A through 2.D show the change in occupational distribution for the different types, as

    their time in Spain increases. In this case, a positive estimate implies that there is an

    over-representation for a particular cohort of immigrants in a given occupation category

    compared to that same cohort t years earlier (net of the changes that have occurred

    within that same period among the natives). For instance, in the top LHS panel of

    Figure 2.A, the sixth bar height in the “blue-collar” category indicates that male

    immigrants without a college degree who arrived in Spain in 2002 are 13 percentage

    points more likely to hold a job in a “blue-collar” occupation in 2008 than in 2002 when

    they first arrived, relative to the change observed over the same period in the same

    occupational category among their natives counterparts. The findings are summarized

    below:

    For male immigrants without high-school degree, the patterns observed in the

    “non-qualified” and “blue-collar” categories clearly suggest an assimilation effect as

    recently arrived immigrants adjust to the new economy. Within the first few years

    after arrival, they first move to “non-qualified” jobs (as shown by the positive estimates

    for the “non-qualified” category). However, within a couple of years after arrival, they

    begin to shift out of “non-qualified” jobs and “not working” category towards “blue-

    collar” occupations. Notice that the move into “blue-collar” occupations occurs around

    the second and third year after arrival in Spain. This pattern is also observed for the

    case of African male immigrants for whom there is a clear movement out of the “not

    working” category into the “non-qualified” category over the first year after arrival and

  • 29

    the “qualified blue-collar” category thereafter (as shown in the RHS bottom chart of

    Figure 2.C).

    Perhaps surprisingly, a very similar assimilation pattern is observed for male

    workers with a high-school degree (as shown in the top RHS chart of Figure 2.A). The

    differences across these two education groups are practically inexistent, suggesting that

    having a high-school degree does not give immigrants an advantage in terms of the

    process of assimilation in Spain nor the occupations where they end up working in.

    Moreover, given that the odds of being in the “professional” and “other white-collar”

    categories increases with the possession of a high-school degree for natives,35 this

    finding suggest that the assimilation process is strongest the lower the education level

    of immigrants, as those with a higher skills segregate in the same occupations as

    those with lower skills.

    This finding is confirmed when observing the change in the predicted

    occupational distribution of immigrants with vocational training or a college degree

    (bottom charts of Figure 2.A). In contrast with the results found for high-school

    dropouts, no such assimilation seems to take place among high-skilled male immigrants.

    College male immigrants move from the “professional” category to “blue-collar” and

    “non-qualified” categories within the first couple of years after arrival and into “blue-

    collar” occupations thereafter. Notice that the flow out of the “professional” category

    most likely reflects some returned migration. Similarly, for male immigrants with

    vocational training, we observe a shift from “professional” and “other white collar”

    occupations into “non-qualified” during the first few years after arrival and into

    “qualified blue-collar” occupations thereafter.

    35 While high-school dropout natives have a fitted probability of being in either category of about 8% and 9%, respectively; for high-school graduates these fitted probabilities increase to 13% and 16%, respectively.

  • 30

    The assimilation pattern of low-skilled female immigrants reveals that they are

    in a more vulnerable situation than their male counterparts, as no catching up seems

    to take place. The top two charts of Figure 2.B show that low-skilled female

    immigrants move from the “not working” and “other white-collar” categories into the

    “non-qualified” category during the first years after arrival. However, in contrast with

    the “catching up” observed among low-skilled male immigrants in the “qualified blue-

    collar” category, no “catching up” takes place for low-skilled women in the “other

    white-collar” category. The pattern for African female immigrants is similar, although

    intensified as the shift is merely from the “not working” category into the “non-

    qualified” category (as shown in the bottom RHS chart of Figure 2.D).

    While education among high-skilled female immigrants seems to help their

    assimilation process a bit, they are far from converging to their native counterparts,

    as observed earlier for skilled male immigrants. Right after arrival, female immigrants

    with a trade certificate or a college degree shift out of the “professional” and “other

    white collar” categories into “non-qualified” occupations. However, very soon

    thereafter, the flow goes from “not working” and “professional” categories into “non-

    qualified” occupations and (within three years after arrival) into “other white-collar”

    occupations.

    VI. Discussion and Further Research

    From our empirical investigation the following three findings stand out: First,

    immigrants in Spain are more occupationally mobile than natives. Most of this greater

    flexibility is explained by immigrants’ assimilation process soon after arrival to the host

    country: Just after arrival, immigrants enter occupations below their skill level and then

    move towards higher skilled occupations. However, our second finding indicates that

  • 31

    convergence does not occur: Immigrants are underutilized in Spain as they segregate

    into low-skilled occupations (compared to natives with similar observable

    characteristics). Third, we find that, among male immigrants, assimilation is strongest

    the lower the education level.

    The first two findings imply that, within the same skill group, immigrants and

    natives may not be perfect substitutes, as recently found by others—see Ottaviano and

    Peri, 2006, and Card and Shleifer, 2009 for the US; Manacorda et al., 2006, and

    Dustmann et al., 2009, for the UK; D’Amuri et al., 2008, for Germany; and Carrasco et

    al., 2008b, and Amuedo and de la Rica, 2009, for Spain. In addition, our finding that

    assimilation is strongest the lower the education level for male immigrants provides

    evidence consistent with segmented labor markets, and rejects the human capital theory.

    In an economy with a dual labor market, immigrants assimilate better if they are low-

    skilled. This occurs because native low-skilled workers are more likely to work in the

    secondary market, which is of easier access to immigrants, facilitating the convergence

    between immigrants and their native counterparts. Should we interpret the lack of this

    finding among female immigrants as evidence against the dual labor market theory?

    Not necessarily. The fact that immigrant women are further marginalized seems to

    indicate that in a segmented labor market, new “underclasses” of workers may appear

    among the most vulnerable individuals—Fernández-Kranz and Rodríguez-Planas, 2009,

    also find that the dual structure of the Spanish labor market further aggravates the

    situation of the most vulnerable workers in the secondary labor market.

    Much of this imperfect substitutability between natives and immigrants in Spain

    might be explained by the segmentation of the labor market, which, if true, leads to

    major concerns on potential efficiency losses for the Spanish economy.36 Important

    36 Amuedo and de la Rica, 2009, explore the reasons for this imperfect substitution among low-skilled workers and find evidence that low-skilled natives relocate to jobs with a lower content of manual tasks.

  • 32

    topics for further research include the following two questions: What are the

    consequences for the Spanish economic growth of underutilizing this large inflow of

    high-skilled immigrants? And second, now that a major recession is taking place, what

    are the social, economic, and welfare consequences of having so many immigrants in

    the most vulnerable jobs, and therefore those most likely to suffer from job destruction?

    Policy proposals aiming at adding labor market flexibility and eliminating rigid and

    dual labor market structures will most likely enhance an efficient allocation of labor.

    However, what seems more policy concerning is to understand the reasons for the imperfect substitution among high-skilled workers as these may be the source of economic inefficiencies.

  • 33

    REFERENCES Andrés J. 2009. “España y los Desequilibrios Globales”, Libro Electrónico Sociedad Abierta-

    Fedea: “La Crisis de la Economía Española: lecciones y propuestas”, 09/02/2009.

    Amuedo-Dorantes C., De la Rica S. 2005. “Immigrants’ Responsiveness to Labor Market

    Conditions and its Implications on Regional Disparities: Evidence from Spain.” IZA Discussion Paper No. 1557.

    —— 2007. “Labor Market Assimilation in Spain.” British Journal of Industrial Relations

    45:2: 0007–1080 pp. 257–284. —— 2008. “Does Immigration Raise Natives’ Income? National and Regional Evidence from Spain” IZA Discussion Paper No. 3486. —— 2009. “Complements or Substitutes? Immigrant and Native Task Specialization in Spain.” IZA Discussion Paper No. 4348. Aydemir A., and G. Borjas, 2007. "Cross-Country Variation in the Impact of International Migration: Canada, Mexico, and the United States," Journal of the European Economic Association, MIT Press, vol. 5(4), pages 663-708, 06. Baker, M., and D. Benjamin. 1994. “The Performance of Immigrants in the Canadian Labour Market.” Journal of Labor Economics 12, 369–405. Barth, E., B. Bratsberg, and O. Raaum. 2004. “Identifying Earnings Assimilation of immigrants under changing macroeconomic conditions.” Scandinavian Journal of Economics 106 (1), 1–22. Barth, E., Bratsberg, B., Raaum, O. 2006. “Local Unemployment and the Relative Wages of Immigrants: Evidence from the Current Population Surveys.” Review of Economics and Statistics 88 (2), 243–263. Bell, B.D., 1997. “The Performance of Immigrants in the United Kingdom: Evidence from the GHS.” Economic Journal 107 (441), 333–344. Bentolila, S. and J. Dolado. 1994. “Labour Flexibility and Wages: Lessons from Spain.”

    Economic Policy 18: 53-99. Borjas, G. 1985. “Assimilation, Changes in Cohort Quality, and the Earnings of Immigrants.”

    Journal of Labor Economics, 3: 463–69. —— 1992. "National Origin and the Skills of Immigrants," in George J. Borjas and Richard B. Freeman, eds., Immigration and the Work Force, Chicago: The University of Chicago Press. —— 1995. “Assimilation and Changes in Cohort Quality Revisited: What Happened to

    Immigrant Earnings in the 1980s?” Journal of Labor Economics, 13: 201–45. Bentolila, S., J. Dolado, and J. F. Jimeno 2008. “Does Immigration Affect the Phillips Curve? Some Evidence for Spain.” European Economic Review 52 (2008) 1398–1423. Blau FD, LM Kahn. 2007. “Gender Assimilation among Mexican Americans.” In: Borjas G (ed) Mexican immigration. University of Chicago Press, Chicago (forthcoming)

  • 34

    Boyd, M. 1985. "Immigration and Occupational Attainment in Canada." In Ascription and Achievement: Studies in Mobility and Status Attain- ment in Canada, edited by M. Boyd, J. Goyder, F. E. Jones, H. A. McRoberts, P. C. Pineo, and J. Porter, pp. 383-445. Ottawa: Carleton University Press.

    Card, D. 2005. “Is the New Immigration Really So Bad?” Economic Journal, 115. Card, D, and J. Dinardo. 2000. “Do Immigrant Inflows Lead to Native Outflows?” American Economic Review, 90, May. Card D., and A. Shleifer, 2009. "Immigration and Inequality," American Economic Review,

    vol. 99(2), pages 1-21, May. Carrasco R., J.F. Jimeno, A.C. Ortega. 2008 a. “The Effect of Immigration on the Employment

    Opportunities of Native-Born Workers: Some Evidence for Spain.” Journal of Population Economics 21:627–648.

    —— 2008 b. “The Impact of Immigration on the Wage Structure: Spain 1995-2002.” Universidad Carlos III working paper 08-16. Chiswick, B. 1978 a. “The Effect of Americanization on the Earnings of Foreign-Born Men.”

    Journal of Political Economy, 86: 897–921. —— 1978 b. “A Longitudinal Analysis of Occupational Mobility of Immigrants.” in ed. Barbara Dennis, Proceedings of the 30th Annual Winter Meeting, Industrial Relations Research Association, December, 1977, Madison, Wisconsin, pp. 20-27. Chiswick B. 1986. “Human Capital and the Labor Market Adjustment of Immigrants: Testing Alternative Hypotheses.” In Stark O (ed) Research in human capital and development: migration, vol 4. Jai, Greenwich, CT, pp 1–26 Chiswick B., P. Miller. 1995. “The Endogeneity Between Language and Earnings: International Analyses.” Journal of Labor Economics, 13(2):246–288 Chiswick, B., and P. Miller. 2006. “Immigration to Australia during the 1990’s: Institutional and Labour Market Influences”, in D.A. Cobb-Clark and S. Khoo (eds.), Public Policy and Immigrant Settlement, Edward Elgar, Cheltenham, UK. Cobb-Clark, D.A. 2000. “Do Selection Criteria Make a Difference? Visa Category and the Labour Market Status of Immigrants to Australia.” Economic Record, 76 (232): 15-31. Cobb-Clark, D.A. (2003) “Public policy and the labor market adjustment of new immigrants to Australia”, Journal of Population Economics, 16: 655-681. Cohen-Goldner, S and Z. Eckstein. 2002. “Labour Mobility of Immigrants: Training, Experience, Language and opportunities.” CEPR Discussion paper series No.3412 Constant A., and D. Massey. 2005. “Labor Market Segmentation and the Earnings of German

    Guestworkers.” Population Research and Policy Review, 2005, 24 (6), 5-30. De la Rica, S. 2009. “De la Crisis Inmobiliaria y Financiera hacia la Recesión en el Mercado

    Laboral. Dónde Estamos y Hacia Dónde Debiéramos Ir“, Libro Electrónico Sociedad Abierta-

    Fedea: “La Crisis de la Economía Española: lecciones y propuestas”, 09/02/2009

  • 35

    De la Rica, S. 2004. "Wage Gaps between Workers with Indefinite and Fixed-Term Contracts: The Impact of Firm and Occupational Segregation." Moneda y Crédito 219: 43-69.

    Dolado, J., R. Duce, and J.F. Jimeno. 1998. "Los Efectos de la Inmigración sobre la Demanda

    Relativa de Trabajo Cualificado, vs. Poco Cualificado: Evidencia para España." Cuadernos Económicos del ICE (1998),vol 63, pp11-30.

    Domingo A., F. Gil, and E. Vidal. 2006. “Participation of Immigrants in the European

    Unions” National Labor Markets in a Context of Complementarity: Substitution and Competition with Local Labor Force.’ Centre d’Estudis Demografics mimeo.

    Duleep, H., and D. Dowhan. 2002. “Insights from Longitudinal Data on the Earnings Growth of U.S. Foreign-born Men.” Demography. Green, D. 1995. "The Early Adjustment of Immigrants: Credentials Rec- ognition and Earnings Growth." Discussion Paper no. 95-12. Vancouver: University of British Columbia, Department of Economics.

    Harriet, O., and M. Regets, 1999. “Immigrants and Human-Capital Investment.” American Economic Review, vol. 89(2), pages 186-191, May.

    Duleep, O., and M. Regets. 2002. “The Elusive Concept of Immigrant “quality”: Evidence from 1970–1990.”, IZA Working Paper No. 631. Hu W-Y. 2000. “Immigrant Earnings Assimilation: Estimates from Longitudinal Data.” American Economic Review 90: 368–372. Hum D., and W. Simpson. 2000. “Closing the Gap: ·Economic Assimilation of Canadian Immigrants Reconsidered.” J Int Migr Integr 1:427–441. Hum D., and W. Simpson. 2004. “Reinterpreting the Performance of Immigrant Wages from Panel Data.” Empirical Economics 29:129–147 Dolado, J., C. García-Serrano, and J.F. Jimeno. 2002. “Drawing Lessons from the Boom of

    Temporary Jobs in Spain,” Economic Journal, 112(480): F270-295. Dolado, J., and Vázquez P. 2007. “Los Efectos Económicos y las Políticas de la Inmigración: Panorámica y Reflexiones.” Fedea Working Paper. Dustmann, C., F. Fabbri, and I. Preston. 2005. “The Impact of Immigration on the British Labour Market”, Economic Journal, Volume 115, Issue 507, Page F324-F341. Dustmann, C., T Hatton and I Preston. 2005. “The Labour Market Effects of Immigration.” editorial, Economic Journal, Volume 115, Issue 507, Page F324-F341. Dustmann, C., T. Frattini, and I. Preston. 2008. “The Effect of Immigration along the Distribution of Wages.” CReAM Discussion Paper # 03/08. Dustmann C., A. Glitz, and T. Vogel. 2009. “Employment, Wages, and the Economic Cycle: Differences between Immigrants and Natives.” Europoean Economic Review. Duvander A. 2001. “Do Country-Specific Skills Lead to Improved Labor Market Positions?: An Analysis of Unemployment and Labor Market Returns to Education among Immigrants in Sweden.” Work and Occupations; 28; 210

  • 36

    D’Amuri, F., G. Ottaviano, and G. Peri. 2008. “The Labor Market Impact of Immigration in Western Germany in the 1990’s.” FEEM Working Paper No. 16, 2008. Eckstein, Z and Y. Weiss. 2004. “On the Wage Growth of Immigrants: Israel 1990-2000.” Journal of European Economic Association, June 2004, pp. 665-695. Fernández, C. and C. Ortega. 2008. “Labor market assimilation of immigrants in Spain: Employment at the Expense of Bad Job-Matches?”, Spanish EconomicReview, vol. 10, n. 2, pp. 83-107. Fernández-Kranz D, and N. Rodríguez-Planas. 2009. “The Part-Time Penalty in a Segmented Labor Market.” IZA discussion paper No. 4342. Friedberg, R. 1993. "The Labor Market Assimilation of Immigrants in the U.S: The Role of Age at Arrival," Brown University, 1993. Friedberg, R. 2001. “The Impact of Mass Migration on the Israeli Labor Market.” The Quarterly Journal of Economics, CXVI(4), November, pp.1373-1408.

    Frijters, P., M. Shields, and S. Price. 2005. “Job Search Methods and their Success: A Comparison of Immigrants and Natives in the UK.” The Economic Journal, 115 (November), F359–F376.

    Garicano L. 2008: “La Transición Económica Pendiente”, en Expansión el 05-12-2008

    Fajnzylber, M., and Montes Rojas. 2006. “Microenterprise Dynamics in Developing Countries:

    How Similar Are They to Those in the Industrialized World? Evidence from México.” The

    World Bank Economic Review, vol. 20: 389-419.

    Flug, K., N. Kasir; and O. Gur. “The Absorption of Soviet Immigrants into the Labor Market from 1990 Onwards: Aspects of Occupational Substitution and Retention.” Bank of Israel Discussion Paper no. 9213. Jerusalem: Central Bank of Israel, April. Gil Alonso, F., and Domingo, A. 2007. "La Participación de los Ciudadanos Latinoamericanos

    en el Mercado de Trabajo Español: Características Diferenciales y Evolución Reciente (2000-2005)". V Congreso sobre la Inmigración en España. Migraciones y desarrollo humano. Valencia: Universidad de Valencia, pp. 62.

    Gindling, T. 2009. “South-South Migration: The Impact of Nicaraguan Immigrants on

    Earnings, Inequality and Poverty in Costa Rica.” Forthcoming in World Development, 2009, 37(1), January.

    Green D. 1999. “Ìmmigrant Occupational Attainment: Assimilation and Mobility over Time.”

    Journal of Labor Economics, vol., 17, no. 11: 49-79. Izquierdo M., Lacuesta A., Vegas R. 2009. “Assimilation of Immigrants in Spain: a

    Longitudinal Analysis.” Labour Economics (forthcoming). Hanson, G. 2008. "The Economic Consequences of the International Migration of Labor,"

    NBER Working Papers 14490, National Bureau of Economic Research. Hatton, T., and Williamson, J. 2005. “What Fundamentals Drive World Migration?” In Borjas, G. & Crisp, J. (Eds.), Poverty, International Migration and Asylum (pp. 15-38).

  • 37

    Hampshire, U.K.: Palgrave-MacMillan for Wider. Hernanz, V. 2002. “El Trabajo Temporal y la Segmentación: Un Estudio de las Transiciones Laborales.” Unpublished Ph