How to Pay for War by Keynes - Penalties of Debt Borrowing

download How to Pay for War by Keynes - Penalties of Debt Borrowing

of 13

Transcript of How to Pay for War by Keynes - Penalties of Debt Borrowing

  • 8/10/2019 How to Pay for War by Keynes - Penalties of Debt Borrowing

    1/13

    Inflation, Taxation and Equity: How to Pay for the War Revisited

    Author(s): Shlomo MaitalSource: The Economic Journal, Vol. 82, No. 325 (Mar., 1972), pp. 158-169Published by: Wileyon behalf of the Royal Economic SocietyStable URL: http://www.jstor.org/stable/2230212.

    Accessed: 28/05/2013 20:50

    Your use of the JSTOR archive indicates your acceptance of the Terms & Conditions of Use, available at.http://www.jstor.org/page/info/about/policies/terms.jsp

    .JSTOR is a not-for-profit service that helps scholars, researchers, and students discover, use, and build upon a wide range of

    content in a trusted digital archive. We use information technology and tools to increase productivity and facilitate new formsof scholarship. For more information about JSTOR, please contact [email protected].

    .

    WileyandRoyal Economic Societyare collaborating with JSTOR to digitize, preserve and extend access to The

    Economic Journal.

    http://www.jstor.org

    This content downloaded from 207.233.32.18 on Tue, 28 May 2013 20:50:57 PMAll use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions

    http://www.jstor.org/action/showPublisher?publisherCode=blackhttp://www.jstor.org/action/showPublisher?publisherCode=reshttp://www.jstor.org/stable/2230212?origin=JSTOR-pdfhttp://www.jstor.org/page/info/about/policies/terms.jsphttp://www.jstor.org/page/info/about/policies/terms.jsphttp://www.jstor.org/page/info/about/policies/terms.jsphttp://www.jstor.org/page/info/about/policies/terms.jsphttp://www.jstor.org/page/info/about/policies/terms.jsphttp://www.jstor.org/stable/2230212?origin=JSTOR-pdfhttp://www.jstor.org/action/showPublisher?publisherCode=reshttp://www.jstor.org/action/showPublisher?publisherCode=black
  • 8/10/2019 How to Pay for War by Keynes - Penalties of Debt Borrowing

    2/13

    INFLATION,

    TAXATION AND

    EQUITY:

    HOW TO PAY

    FOR THE

    WAR

    REVISITED'

    IN

    August and November 1914, 31-year-old Maynard Keynes published

    two articles

    in

    the

    ECONOMIC

    JOURNAL, claiming that the

    First World War

    would be

    short since

    governments would find it hard

    to appropriate

    the

    resources

    needed to support the war

    [10]. By a

    quirk of fate, precisely

    twenty-five

    years later, Keynes was again

    writing

    articles on a World War.

    Sadder and

    wiser, he

    determinedly pressed the

    need for

    long-haul

    war

    finance

    through compulsory savings and

    taxation rather

    than borrowing and

    inflation.

    Out of these articles, which

    first

    appeared in The Times,

    came

    How

    to Payfor

    the War [12].

    This persuasive little

    88-page pamphlet, written

    with fervour and

    clarity,

    is an

    explicit exercise in

    the macro mechanics of

    income

    distribution and

    inflation. Strangely, the

    voluminous

    literature on income

    distribution

    theory

    has

    given it little

    attention.

    Indeed, none of the key articles on the

    subject even

    lists How toPay for the War in

    the

    bibliography.2 Perhaps

    this

    is because it was written

    largely for laymen, or because

    it set out to

    answer a

    specific,

    soon

    obsolete question of how the

    England of 1939 could best

    accom-

    plish

    a

    huge increase in defence output.

    Since the

    wellspring of Keynesian

    exegesis, The GeneralTheory,is content merely to register dissatisfaction with

    the

    marginal

    productivity theory of

    income

    distribution without supplying

    an

    explicit alternative,3

    the whole body

    of work on Cambridge

    distribution

    theory,

    ostensibly shaped in the master's

    image, seems at times to

    have very

    flimsy

    grounding.

    The

    intention here is

    to extract

    from

    How to Pay for

    the War

    the

    simplest

    of

    Keynesian

    income distribution models

    and

    use

    it to

    analyse

    and

    generalise

    Keynes' own specific

    conclusions on war

    finance. From the model there

    emerge quantitative

    short-run

    interrelationships

    between inflation, taxation

    and equity when, at full employment, an increase in defence spending occurs.

    The discussion

    can,

    of

    course, be

    set

    in

    a

    framework

    much broader than

    military

    expenditures alone-for

    instance, the need

    to curtail an import

    surplus or boost

    investment, both of which

    actions increase

    aggregate

    demand.

    One

    finding

    is

    that,

    for a

    given

    defence burden the

    differential

    incidence

    of

    even a

    'regressive' tax

    increase (i.e., the rate of tax

    falls with increase of

    income)

    is

    more

    equitable

    than

    that of

    inflation.

    This means that

    according

    1

    I wish to

    acknowledge, without

    implicating, the helpful scepticism of

    my colleagues

    Eitan

    Berglas,

    Yoram Weiss, Y. Atieh and

    the prompt and

    precise comments of D. E.

    Moggridge

    and the

    editors.

    2

    How

    to Payfor

    the

    War is mentioned in

    none of the following books and

    articles: [3],

    [5], [7],

    [15], [16], [20], [23].

    An

    interesting attempt to synthesise

    Cambridge and

    neo-classical distribu-

    tion

    theory

    is

    found

    in

    [20], with ensuing controversy

    in

    [24]

    and

    [21].

    3

    See

    [11], pp. 257-60.

    158

    This content downloaded from 207.233.32.18 on Tue, 28 May 2013 20:50:57 PMAll use subject toJSTOR Terms and Conditions

    http://www.jstor.org/page/info/about/policies/terms.jsphttp://www.jstor.org/page/info/about/policies/terms.jsphttp://www.jstor.org/page/info/about/policies/terms.jsphttp://www.jstor.org/page/info/about/policies/terms.jsp
  • 8/10/2019 How to Pay for War by Keynes - Penalties of Debt Borrowing

    3/13

    MARCH 1972] INFLATION,

    TAXATION

    AND

    EQUITY

    159

    to

    the

    Keynesian

    model, inflation

    is

    much more cruel

    in equity terms than

    the

    most cruel

    of regressive taxes. May this explain some of

    the

    urgency

    with

    which the wartime

    Keynes pursued

    his views?

    II

    Consider

    an

    economy

    made

    up of two groups,

    workers and rentiers,

    whose propensities

    (average

    and

    marginal)

    to consume

    out of

    realised

    and

    imputed

    income are, respectively, U

    and

    V, where U > V.1

    The

    Key-

    nesian, or as

    it is sometimes

    called widow's

    cruse distribution

    theory,

    asserts

    that for a given ratio

    of aggregate

    non-consumption

    spending

    (investment

    +

    net

    exports + public

    defence and non-defence

    spending)

    to

    output,

    which ratio we shall call gt, there is a unique distribution of income between

    workers

    and rentiers which will equate aggregate planned savings

    with

    aggregate

    planned non-consumption

    demand.

    Call the equilibrium

    share

    of wages in national

    income,

    at time t, at.

    Then:

    at

    -V

    .

    (1)

    where, by definition,

    the consumption-output

    ratio

    ct

    =

    1-

    gt.2

    For each

    percentage point

    change

    in

    ct,

    the equilibrium

    wage

    share

    changes by

    l/(U

    -

    V) percentage

    points, in order

    to restore

    balance

    between aggregate

    demand and

    output

    by transferring

    income

    to (or from)

    the thriftier

    rentiers. The closer

    U and V are in

    value,

    the larger the poten-

    tial

    inequity

    required to bring

    about

    equilibrium

    and price stability.

    1

    /(U

    -

    V) may

    be interpreted

    as a full

    employment

    'distribution-multiplier'

    substituting for

    the usual 'employment-multiplier.'

    To be

    complete, the model

    must set out

    the connection

    between

    the

    composition of aggregate demand and the division of income between wages

    and

    profits. This necessarily

    involves a treatment

    of the wage-price

    nexus.

    Wages

    and

    prices

    have

    been

    causally joined

    in

    theory

    in a

    multitude of

    ways,

    including Kaldor's

    theory of the

    firm [8] and

    Kalecki's degree

    of

    monopoly [9].

    Keynes'

    own method,

    related

    specifically

    to

    wartime and

    the short run,

    was

    disarmingly simple.

    He postulated

    an

    institutional

    parameter

    which

    we

    shall call

    0,

    defined

    as the percentage

    change

    in money

    1

    Keynes held

    that rentiers are thriftier

    than workers, largely because corporations

    tend to

    retain, rather than

    distribute, profits imputable to rentiers.

    ". . .

    the profits

    will largely belong

    to companies which will be disinclined, for various reasons, to distribute the bulk of them in higher

    dividends but will prefer

    in

    the circumstances

    to save them

    on behalf of their shareholders " [12, pt

    65]. Rentiers' income

    is therefore so defined as to include

    undistributed profits.

    2

    Since

    at

    equilibrium

    planned consumption

    and non-consumption spending

    must add up to

    income

    (Y):

    Yt=YeaeU+

    Yt(l-at)

    V+gYe . . . . (la)

    Substituting gt

    =

    1

    -

    ct,

    dividing

    through by

    Yt

    and solving

    for at yields (1) directly.

    This content downloaded from 207.233.32.18 on Tue, 28 May 2013 20:50:57 PMAll use subject toJSTOR Terms and Conditions

    http://www.jstor.org/page/info/about/policies/terms.jsphttp://www.jstor.org/page/info/about/policies/terms.jsphttp://www.jstor.org/page/info/about/policies/terms.jsphttp://www.jstor.org/page/info/about/policies/terms.jsp
  • 8/10/2019 How to Pay for War by Keynes - Penalties of Debt Borrowing

    4/13

    160

    THE

    ECONOMIC JOURNAL [MARCH

    wages

    caused

    by

    a 1

    % change

    in

    prices.' Owing

    to

    the

    lag

    between

    prices

    and wages, he thought f would

    take on values of the order of 0 50 to

    0.85.2

    It is,

    of course, true that in peacetime money wages

    rise faster than

    prices.

    Direct scrutiny of data would thus show b to be almost invariably greater

    than one, a result explicitly

    excluded below. But this

    poses no problem.

    Keynes'

    parameter

    b

    aims

    essentially to capture the short run impact

    of

    prices on

    money wages, ceteris

    aribus,

    n a wartime situation. We may con-

    ceive of

    money wages as rising by some constant

    percentage each year, plus

    a

    fraction of the

    percentage rise in prices;

    b

    can

    thus be considered

    to

    capture the latter

    fraction,

    without the trend component.

    For

    a

    given fall in the

    consumption-output ratio, ct,

    the amount

    of infla-

    tion

    v

    needed

    to

    redistribute ncome and restore

    equilibrium is:

    =

    ao

    -

    at

    (2)

    at

    -

    aO

    where

    ao

    is the initial wage share

    and at

    is

    the wage share

    after

    equilibrium

    is

    restored.3

    If

    money wages are rigid, i.e.,

    b =

    0, the

    required

    amount

    of

    inflation is

    simply

    the

    percentage

    change (Paasche index) in the wage

    share.

    It

    is important to stress that

    v measures the total,

    once-and-for-all

    ise in

    price

    needed

    to

    cut real wages and private consumption

    sufficiently

    to

    accommodate the lower value of

    ct. The integral time period over

    which

    inflation

    works to

    redistribute income therefore becomes

    important.

    A

    10

    %

    price

    rise

    spread over five

    years

    is

    quite different

    from the same

    price

    rise

    occurring

    in the

    space of six

    months,

    even

    though

    identical

    wage

    shares

    result.

    Furthermore, the longer the time

    span,

    the less

    satisfactory

    is the

    +-theory

    of

    wages

    and

    prices,

    and

    the more

    important

    are

    the other

    neglected

    variables

    which act

    on

    money wages.

    These

    are the bare bones of the Keynesian

    distribution model, in par-

    ticular

    as

    expressed

    in

    How to

    Pay for

    the

    War.

    Much

    embroidery

    can

    be

    added, without in any way improvingor substantiallyalteringthe substance.

    1

    Other, later authors

    have used a similar

    parameter;

    see Holzman [6], Maynard

    [14] and

    Solow and

    Stiglitz [20].

    2 "6

    Wages

    and

    other

    costs

    will chase prices upwards, but

    nevertheless prices will

    always (on

    the

    above assumptions)

    keep 20 per

    cent ahead. However

    much wages are increased, the act

    of

    spending these wages

    will always push prices

    this much in

    advance " [12, pp. 66-7].

    On pp.

    20

    and 37, Keynes asserts

    that

    f =

    0

    5 at the start of 1940, and

    on p. 71 he claims that

    during the

    First

    World

    War,

    f

    = 0-85; these two numbers are not strictly comparable,

    in

    view

    of the inflation

    which preceded

    he First World War.

    Solow and Stiglitz

    use a parameter k, similar

    in

    meaning

    to

    k,

    and

    assert:

    "

    Some econometric studies

    suggest

    that

    k

    may

    be less than

    one half"

    [20, p.

    545].

    For a full bibliography

    and a sceptical view

    of the wage-price

    lag, see Cargill

    [1].

    3

    Let

    vf

    be the percentage rise in prices required to bring at to its equilibrium level as defined by

    (1). From

    the definition

    of

    k,

    it follows that

    money wages

    rise by i+% while money income

    rises

    by

    iT% since at full employment

    real income

    is constant. Let

    Wo

    and

    Y0 be total

    money wages

    and money incomes, respectively,

    at time 0.

    Then:

    a=W (1

    +

    ov)

    =ao(

    + ) . . .

    . .

    (2a)

    Solving

    (2a) for vf yields (2).

    This content downloaded from 207.233.32.18 on Tue, 28 May 2013 20:50:57 PMAll use subject toJSTOR Terms and Conditions

    http://www.jstor.org/page/info/about/policies/terms.jsphttp://www.jstor.org/page/info/about/policies/terms.jsphttp://www.jstor.org/page/info/about/policies/terms.jsphttp://www.jstor.org/page/info/about/policies/terms.jsp
  • 8/10/2019 How to Pay for War by Keynes - Penalties of Debt Borrowing

    5/13

    1972]

    INFLATION.

    TAXATION

    AND

    EQUITY

    161

    Keynes gives

    a step-by-step

    verbal

    account of how

    the model works on

    pages

    65-8,

    too

    lengthy to

    quote in

    full.

    The following

    passage must

    suffice:

    "

    The only

    condition

    for

    the success

    of inflation

    in restoring

    equili-

    brium is that

    prices should

    rise relatively

    to

    wages to

    the

    extent necessary

    to divert

    the right

    amount of working

    class

    and other incomes into

    the

    hands of the

    profiteers

    and

    thence

    into

    the hands

    of

    the Treasury,

    largely

    in the

    form of

    taxes and

    partly

    in the

    form

    of extra

    voluntary

    savings

    by the

    profiteers

    "

    [12,

    p. 67].

    III

    As suggested

    by the above

    quote, to

    be useful

    for

    shaping policy,

    rates

    of tax must

    be added to the

    model.

    U

    and V were

    defined

    as propensities

    to consume out of before-tax income. Therefore, if u and v are propensities

    to consume

    out

    of

    disposable

    ncome,

    for

    workers

    and

    rentiers respectively,

    and

    t,

    and

    t,

    are

    the respective

    rates of

    tax on wages

    and profits,

    it is

    true

    that:

    U u

    (I

    t

    and V-~

    v(1

    -

    G)

    .

    .(3)

    Under

    some

    conditions,

    sales

    taxes and

    income

    taxes are

    completely

    inter-

    changeable

    in this

    model.

    Consider

    an

    incremental

    before-tax

    pound

    of

    wage

    income,

    to which

    an income ax of rate

    t.

    is applied.

    After taxes,

    1

    -tu

    remains, of which u (1

    -

    t.) is consumed. Now let tu be an equal rate of

    tax,

    this time applied

    to consumption

    pending.

    Out of

    an

    incremental

    wage

    pound,

    u is spent

    on

    gross

    (tax

    included)

    consumption,

    and net (tax

    deducted)

    consumption

    is

    (1

    -

    t.)

    u,

    the same as

    under the

    income

    tax. The key assump-

    tion,

    of

    course,

    is that

    the

    propensity

    to

    consume

    is

    independent

    of the manner

    in

    which

    taxes

    are imposed.

    Since

    saving

    is

    more

    worth while

    at the

    margin

    under

    a

    consumption

    tax,

    compared

    with

    an income

    tax,

    this

    assumption

    is

    not tenable

    over

    the long

    run.

    For

    the

    short

    run

    analysis

    undertaken

    here, however,

    it

    can

    be reasonably

    assumed

    that, from force

    of

    habit,

    u and

    v are invariant

    with

    respect

    to

    how

    taxes are

    applied.

    Substitute

    (3)

    into

    (1):

    at

    u(-ct

    -

    v(l

    t)(4)

    t

    t__

    _ _ _ _ _ _ _ _ _ _ _

    The mechanism

    required

    for

    exposing

    the inter-relationship

    between infla-

    tion,

    taxation

    and

    equity,

    consisting

    of

    equations

    (2)

    and

    (4),

    is now

    com-

    plete.

    Three

    propositions

    present

    themselves:

    1

    (1) Any

    tax increase,

    whether on workers

    or

    rentiers,

    raises

    the

    net

    (after-tax)

    wage

    share.

    This

    implies

    that the

    inequity

    attendant

    upon

    an

    expanded

    defence

    effort,

    and

    subsequent

    inflation,

    can

    be offset

    even

    l

    All of the

    following

    propositions

    are

    easily proved

    by

    deriving

    the

    net

    (after-tax)

    wages

    share

    with

    respect

    to

    tu

    and

    tv,

    and

    using (4).

    No.

    325-VOL.

    82.

    M

    This content downloaded from 207.233.32.18 on Tue, 28 May 2013 20:50:57 PMAll use subject toJSTOR Terms and Conditions

    http://www.jstor.org/page/info/about/policies/terms.jsphttp://www.jstor.org/page/info/about/policies/terms.jsphttp://www.jstor.org/page/info/about/policies/terms.jsphttp://www.jstor.org/page/info/about/policies/terms.jsp
  • 8/10/2019 How to Pay for War by Keynes - Penalties of Debt Borrowing

    6/13

    162 THE

    ECONOMIC JOURNAL

    [MARCH

    by a tax

    increase falling solely upon

    wages. A nominally

    regressive

    tax may

    therefore be highly

    progressive, in terms of its effect

    upon the

    functional

    income distribution. This

    applies even to a sales tax im-

    posed on essential goods bought largely by workers.

    There is a simple verbal

    explanation for

    this proposition. Inflation

    restores

    equilibrium by, in effect, taxing

    cash from the

    pockets of

    workers

    and transferring it

    to the already

    well-lined pockets of rentiers.

    On the other

    hand, taxes, even those

    imposed on workers

    alone, con-

    fiscate income without

    transferring t to rentiers. Clearly,

    restoring equili-

    brium through increased

    leakage is more

    equitable than restoring it

    through

    income transfer.

    (2)

    Increased taxes on workers

    may

    raise

    the net

    wages

    share to a

    greater or lesser extent than an equal tax increase on rentiers, depending

    on

    whether

    at(1

    -

    t,)

    is

    greater

    or

    less

    than (1

    -

    at) (1

    -

    ta).

    Para-

    doxically, this means that

    higher taxes on

    workers may actually

    raise

    the

    net wage

    share

    more

    han

    an

    equal percentage point rise

    in

    taxes on

    rentiers, although this is not

    always the case.

    (3)

    An

    increase in taxes

    on workers is always more

    effective

    in

    curtailing

    inflation

    than an

    equal

    tax

    increase on rentiers. This is

    self-evident, and stems

    from the assumption that workers

    consume

    proportionately more

    of their

    incomes than

    rentiers.

    The

    above

    propositions are graphed and

    summarised in Fig. 1. For a

    given ct,

    each

    curve

    represents

    some war

    finance

    plan

    and its

    implied

    level

    of

    inflation, which,

    in

    turn, depends

    on

    q.

    Successively lower curves

    result

    from

    finance

    plans which rely

    more and more

    heavily

    on tax

    increases.

    Along

    a

    given curve,

    the

    net

    wages

    share is

    constant.

    Thus,

    the more

    tightly wages are linked to

    prices,

    the

    higher is the

    amount

    of

    inflation,

    without

    any offsetting improvement

    in

    equity.'

    This

    explains,

    perhaps,

    why Keynes

    was

    so

    vehement

    about

    the

    need for

    wage

    restraint, as

    witnessed

    by the following passages:

    "

    .

    a

    demand

    on the

    part of the Trade

    Unions

    for

    an

    increase

    in

    money

    rates of

    wages

    to

    compensate

    for

    every increase

    in the

    cost of

    living

    is

    futile, and greatly to the

    disadvantage

    of

    the

    working

    class.

    Like the dog

    in the fable, they lost the

    substance in gaping at the

    shadow.

    It is true

    that the better

    organized

    sections

    might

    benefit at

    the

    expense

    of other

    consumers. But

    except

    as

    an

    effort

    at

    group

    selfishness,

    as a

    means

    of

    hustling

    someone else

    out

    of the

    queue,

    it is a

    mug's

    game

    to

    play.

    In their minds and

    hearts the leaders of the Trade Unions know

    this as well as anyone else. They do not want what they ask. But

    they

    dare

    not

    abate

    their demands until

    they

    know what alternative

    policy

    is

    offered

    "

    [12, pp. 6,

    7].

    1

    Contractual

    linking

    of

    wages

    to

    prices

    is

    widespread

    in

    Israel

    and at times has deterred

    the

    government

    from

    much

    needed

    increases in

    indirect

    taxes,

    since the result would have been auto-

    matic

    wage

    increases and

    spiralling

    inflation.

    The next

    episode

    of

    this sort

    will

    be

    in

    1972,

    at

    which

    time

    a

    value

    added tax will

    be

    imposed.

    This content downloaded from 207.233.32.18 on Tue, 28 May 2013 20:50:57 PMAll use subject toJSTOR Terms and Conditions

    http://www.jstor.org/page/info/about/policies/terms.jsphttp://www.jstor.org/page/info/about/policies/terms.jsphttp://www.jstor.org/page/info/about/policies/terms.jsphttp://www.jstor.org/page/info/about/policies/terms.jsp
  • 8/10/2019 How to Pay for War by Keynes - Penalties of Debt Borrowing

    7/13

    1972]

    INFLATION,

    TAXATION AND

    EQUITY

    163

    "But

    what a ridiculous system with

    wages and prices chasing one

    another

    upwards in this

    manner in World War I No

    one benefited

    except

    the profiteer. The

    seeds of much subsequent trouble

    were sown.

    And we ended up with

    a National Debt vastly greater in

    terms of money

    than was necessary and very ill distributed through the community"

    [12,

    p. 73].

    Pure Inflation Finance

    ir (?/ )

    Small Tax Increase

    Large

    Tax

    Increase

    0

    FIG.

    1. Inflation

    (Tr)

    as a Function of Wage-Price

    Parameter

    (0)

    for

    Various Policies.

    IV

    In

    conclusion,

    let us return the

    offspring

    to

    its

    parent,

    and use the model

    to

    analyse

    How

    to

    Pay for

    the War.

    In

    1939, Keynes

    foresaw

    a

    war-propelled doubling

    in

    real

    non-consump-

    tion

    spending

    in the United

    Kingdom.

    Although

    a

    good portion

    of

    the

    required

    resources could

    come

    out

    of

    the excess

    capacity

    left over

    from the

    depression,

    some

    had to

    come

    at the

    expense

    of

    private consumption.

    The

    incidence

    of

    this cut in

    consumption upon

    rich and

    poor

    was

    at the core of

    the war finance controversy, and the central

    concern

    of How to

    Payfor

    the War.

    Keynes

    said

    that

    while

    real

    output

    could

    rise

    by

    a maximum

    of

    /825

    million,

    non-consumption spending

    would

    rise

    by /J1,350

    million, meaning

    that,

    other

    things equal, private

    consumption

    had to fall

    by

    J525

    million.'

    1

    Keynes actually

    forecast added

    annual wartime

    spending

    of

    /1,850 million,

    f350

    million of

    which would be

    offset

    by

    sales of

    assets abroad and

    150 million

    in

    "

    depreciation

    not made

    good."

    See

    the

    notes

    to Table Ia.

    This content downloaded from 207.233.32.18 on Tue, 28 May 2013 20:50:57 PMAll use subject toJSTOR Terms and Conditions

    http://www.jstor.org/page/info/about/policies/terms.jsphttp://www.jstor.org/page/info/about/policies/terms.jsphttp://www.jstor.org/page/info/about/policies/terms.jsphttp://www.jstor.org/page/info/about/policies/terms.jsp
  • 8/10/2019 How to Pay for War by Keynes - Penalties of Debt Borrowing

    8/13

    164 THE ECONOMIC JOURNAL [MARCH

    He

    proposed a war

    finance

    plan which included higher taxes, increased

    savings (both compulsory and voluntary), a cheap ration of necessities,

    family allowances and a post-war capital levy. This would both free the

    needed resources and preserve or even improve equity.

    Based on data in Table Ia (appendix), the parameters implicit in the

    Keynes plan may be calculated. Since Keynes discussed not the functional

    (wages

    and

    profits)

    income distribution but

    the global one, with &250

    annual income as

    the

    dividing line between 'poor' and 'rich,' defining at as

    the gross wages share is semantically and conceptually inaccurate. Such a

    division implies an improbable savings function with a sharp kink at the

    ,C250

    mark. This

    savings

    function can be

    regarded

    as an

    approximation

    to

    a more accurate one that would obtain if a finer division of income classes

    were used. The data in How to Pay for the War do not permit such an im-

    provement.

    Even

    if

    they did,

    the

    gain

    in

    accuracy

    would be

    somewhat

    offset

    by a

    loss of

    elegance,

    since

    equation (2) would

    no

    longer hold. How-

    ever, we ought not to minimise the many statistical and theoretical difficul-

    ties inherent in the assumed

    identity between

    functional

    income distribution

    and an arbitrarily categorised global income distribution. The ensuing

    calculations should be

    regarded

    less

    as

    firm

    projections

    than as

    illustrative

    of

    Keynes' macro-distribution theory. With

    this

    caveat in mind, henceforth

    '

    wages

    share'

    will be used in

    place

    of 'share in

    income of those

    with

    incomes

    under

    C250 per annum.'

    Table I contrasts Keynes' war finance plan with pure inflation finance

    and the Keynes plan

    minus

    increased taxes.

    If

    adopted, Keynes' plan

    would have

    placed

    the bulk

    of

    the

    real burden

    upon

    those with

    annual

    in-

    comes

    above C250. Specifically higher

    income

    groups' consumption

    was

    to fall

    by more than

    a

    third,

    by C475 million, while that of poorer groups

    was

    to

    fall

    by C50 million. (The

    two

    sums,

    of

    course, add

    to

    C525m.)

    Since the

    f50

    million can

    be regarded

    as the

    poor's

    share

    of

    'depreciation

    not made good,' the poor's real consumption of goods and services would be

    reduced not at all.

    For

    0

    =

    05, the plan

    would have

    implied only

    4%

    inflation

    during

    the course of

    the

    war

    and,

    if

    money wages

    were

    held con-

    stant, only 2% inflation.

    This

    coincides,

    more or

    less,

    with

    Keynes'

    own

    projection. He seemed to imply that apart from higher import prices, the

    adoption

    of

    his

    plan

    would

    eliminate

    any price

    increases.

    In absolute

    terms, Keynes proposed

    tax

    increases

    totalling only J400

    million,

    less

    than half the

    proposed

    rise in

    voluntary

    and

    compulsory savings.

    From

    Table

    I, however,

    it is

    clear how

    important

    a role

    the

    higher

    taxes were

    to play in distributing fairly the C525 million war burden and curtailing

    inflation.

    If

    that

    part only

    of

    Keynes' plan calling

    for

    added

    savings

    were

    implemented,

    the net

    wages

    share

    (after-tax wages/total income)

    would fall

    by

    about six

    percentage points,

    the net

    profits

    share

    would

    rise

    by

    about

    five,

    and,

    more

    important,

    the

    larger part

    of the

    real

    defence

    burden

    would

    fall

    upon

    the

    workers, cutting

    their real

    consumption by f283 million,

    with

    the

    This content downloaded from 207.233.32.18 on Tue, 28 May 2013 20:50:57 PMAll use subject toJSTOR Terms and Conditions

    http://www.jstor.org/page/info/about/policies/terms.jsphttp://www.jstor.org/page/info/about/policies/terms.jsphttp://www.jstor.org/page/info/about/policies/terms.jsphttp://www.jstor.org/page/info/about/policies/terms.jsp
  • 8/10/2019 How to Pay for War by Keynes - Penalties of Debt Borrowing

    9/13

    1972]

    INFLATION,

    TAXATION AND

    EQUITY

    165

    remaining

    C242 million falling

    upon rentiers.

    Further,

    depending on i,

    the

    amount

    of inflation

    required

    to effect the needed

    income

    distribution

    would

    be

    seven

    to twelve times

    greater

    than under

    the full Keynes

    plan.

    The

    marginal impact of his proposed tax increase is thus very large, larger than

    TABLE

    I

    NetShares,

    Real

    Consumption

    ndInflation

    UnderAlternate

    War

    FinancePlans

    *

    Net Net

    Workers' Rentiers'

    Amount

    of

    Finance

    Plan. Parameters.

    wages profits

    real

    real inflation.

    share.

    share.

    cons'n. cons'n.

    1

    ir

    1. Pre-war

    c

    =

    077

    u = 096

    v

    =

    0081 0519

    0

    329

    2420

    1290

    -

    tu=

    0-04

    tv=

    028

    2. Wartime:

    c

    =

    0-56

    (a)

    KEYNES' PLAN

    U =

    0 82

    v = 0-49

    0

    2%

    tu-=

    005 0*505

    0295

    2370

    815 0 5 4%

    tv

    =

    0*37

    075

    8%

    (b)

    PURE INFLATION

    u =

    0-96

    v = 0-81

    Not

    Feasible

    0

    tu = 004 05

    -

    tv

    = 0*28

    075

    (C)

    INFLATION

    &

    u = 0-82

    ADDED SAVING

    V

    =

    0*49

    0

    14%

    tt=

    004

    0-458

    0*377 2137

    1048

    0 5

    32%

    tv

    =

    0*28

    l075

    93%

    *

    For source

    of

    data,

    see

    Appendix,

    Table

    Ia.

    might

    be expected from

    looking at

    the

    numbers

    themselves

    (Keynes'

    tax

    proposalswould have raised the net rate of tax on workersfrom 4% to 5

    %

    and

    on rentiers

    from

    28%

    to

    37%).

    Given the

    prevailing

    pre-war

    values of

    the

    parameters, pure

    inflation

    alone could

    not have

    freed the needed

    resources

    to

    finance the war.

    The

    wartime consumption-output

    ratio

    had to

    fall to

    0-56,

    and the

    pre-war

    propensity

    to consume of the

    rentiers

    was

    above

    this

    [(0.81)

    (1-

    0

    28)

    =

    0.58].

    No

    amount

    of

    income redistribution

    in favour

    of

    the

    rentiers,

    through

    inflation, would

    have

    restoredequilibrium.

    What

    in fact was

    Britain's

    wartime

    economic

    policy

    and

    to what

    extent

    did it reflect the concepts and proposalsset out in How to Payfor the War?

    Only

    a

    brief,

    and therefore

    inadequate,

    survey

    can be

    attempted

    here.

    A

    fuller account is found in Sayers

    [18].

    Lekachman

    states flatly

    that in

    the British Treasury,

    the Second

    World

    War

    was

    fought

    according

    to

    Keynesian

    principles

    of

    finance

    [13, p. 149].

    Keynes'

    immediate

    influence

    was felt

    in

    Kingsley

    Wood's

    1941

    stabilisation

    This content downloaded from 207.233.32.18 on Tue, 28 May 2013 20:50:57 PMAll use subject toJSTOR Terms and Conditions

    http://www.jstor.org/page/info/about/policies/terms.jsphttp://www.jstor.org/page/info/about/policies/terms.jsphttp://www.jstor.org/page/info/about/policies/terms.jsphttp://www.jstor.org/page/info/about/policies/terms.jsp
  • 8/10/2019 How to Pay for War by Keynes - Penalties of Debt Borrowing

    10/13

    166 THE

    ECONOMIC JOURNAL

    [MARCH

    budget, which explicitly adopted

    as

    official

    orthodoxy the idea that the

    inflationary gap would in the

    end be closed either by

    taxation or by infla-

    tion, and that

    the former was

    much

    superior

    to the

    latter.

    By

    then, Keynes

    was a member of the Chancellor of the Exchequer's Consultative Council

    and

    in

    a

    strong position to plead

    for

    his own

    proposals.

    During the course of the

    war, tax revenues more

    than tripled, owing

    to

    a

    doubling

    of income

    tax,

    a

    tough

    surtax

    levied on

    large incomes

    and

    a

    general increase in

    direct taxes. Public spending grew

    by

    a factor of

    five,

    with

    tax

    revenues

    covering

    about half

    of

    it

    [2, pp. 845,

    846].

    The

    "

    deferred earnings

    "

    proposal of Keynes calling for C550 million

    in

    annual compulsory savings was

    adopted only

    in

    part; the

    average

    for the

    war

    years

    amounted to less

    than

    a

    quarter

    of

    the

    suggested sum.

    But

    rationing, price fixing and other direct controls (which Keynes had wished

    to

    avoid)

    brought

    about

    larger

    voluntary savings

    than he had

    expected

    [13, p.

    149].

    Despite

    the

    price controls,

    there

    was

    considerable

    inflation. From the

    fall

    of Czechoslovakia to

    V-E Day, wholesale prices rose about

    70%

    [2, p.

    848],

    attributable in

    part

    to

    higher

    import prices.

    Dudley

    Seers

    estimated

    that

    for

    the

    same

    period,

    retail

    prices

    rose

    "just

    over

    50%

    "

    [19, p. 320].

    This was much less than in the

    First World War, when the cost-of-living

    index rose from 100 inJuly 1914 to 220 inJanuary 1919.

    How to

    Pay for

    the War

    highlighted

    the

    lack

    of

    national income

    statistics

    so

    vital to

    shaping policy.

    Ten

    months

    after

    Keynes'

    articles in

    The Times

    appeared,James Meade and Richard Stone were set to

    work compiling the

    needed data

    [22]. Today, when

    national

    accounts series

    stretching back

    many

    decades

    are

    available,

    we tend

    to

    forget

    that

    only

    thirty years ago,

    such

    data were

    almost

    non-existent. Since

    then,

    the

    progressive

    elaboration

    of

    the

    national

    accounts,

    claims

    Dow,

    constitutes

    nothing less

    than a

    revolution

    [4, p.

    182].

    For

    this,

    the

    author

    of

    How

    to

    Pay or the Warwas

    in

    large part

    responsible[22].

    SHLOMOMAITAL

    Tel-Aviv

    University.

    REFERENCES

    1. Thomas Cargill,

    "

    An Empirical

    Investigation of the Wage Lag Hypothesis,"

    American Economic Review, Vol. LIX,

    No.

    4

    (December 1969).

    2. S. B.

    Clough

    and C. W.

    Cole,

    Economic

    istoryof Europe Boston:

    Heath, 1958).

    3. P. Davidson, Theories f Aggregate

    ncomeDistribution Rutgers, N. J.: Rutgers

    University Press, 1959).

    4.

    J.

    C.

    R. Dow,

    The

    Management of

    the

    British Economy, 1945-60 (Cambridge:

    Cambridge University Press, 1964).

    5.

    William

    Fellner,

    "

    Significance

    and Limitations of

    Contemporary

    Distribu-

    tion

    Theory," American conomicReview,Vol. XXXIII, No. 2 (May 1953).

    This content downloaded from 207.233.32.18 on Tue, 28 May 2013 20:50:57 PMAll use subject toJSTOR Terms and Conditions

    http://www.jstor.org/page/info/about/policies/terms.jsphttp://www.jstor.org/page/info/about/policies/terms.jsphttp://www.jstor.org/page/info/about/policies/terms.jsphttp://www.jstor.org/page/info/about/policies/terms.jsp
  • 8/10/2019 How to Pay for War by Keynes - Penalties of Debt Borrowing

    11/13

    1972]

    INFLATION, TAXATION AND

    EQUITY 167

    6. F. Holzman,

    "

    Income Determination in Inflation," Reviewof Economics nd

    Statistics,Vol. XXXII

    (May 1950).

    7. Nicholas

    Kaldor,

    "

    Alternative

    Theories of

    Distribution," Reviewof Economic

    Studies,Vol.

    XXIII (1955-56).

    8. Nicholas Kaldor, " Capital Accumulation and Economic Growth," in F.

    Lutz and D.

    Hague, eds.,

    The Theory

    of

    Capital

    (New York: St. Martins

    Press, 1961).

    9. M.

    Kalecki, Theory f

    Economic

    Dynamics London:

    Allen

    &

    Unwin, 1956).

    10. John

    Maynard Keynes,

    "

    War and the Financial System

    "

    and

    "

    The Pros-

    pects

    of

    Money,"

    ECONOMIC

    JOURNAL

    (August

    and November 1914).

    11. John

    Maynard Keynes, The General Theory of

    Employment, Interest and Money

    (London: Macmillan, 1936).

    12. John Maynard

    Keynes, How

    to

    Pay for the War

    (London: Macmillan, 1940).

    13. Robert Lekachman, The Age of Keynes New York: Random House, 1966).

    14. Geoffrey Maynard, Economic Development and

    the Price Level (London: Mac-

    millan,

    1963).

    15. L. Pasinetti,

    "

    Rate of Profit and Income

    Distribution

    in

    Relation to the Rate

    of Economic

    Growth,"

    Review

    of

    Economic

    Studies,

    Vol. XXIX

    (1962).

    16. P. Riach,

    "

    A

    Framework for Macro Distribution Analysis," Kyklos, Vol.

    XXII, No.

    3

    (1969).

    17. Joan

    Robinson, CollectedEconomic

    Papers,

    Vol.

    II

    (Oxford: Blackwell, 1960).

    18. R. S. Sayers, FinancialPolicy, 1939-45 (London:

    Longmans, Green, 1956).

    19. Dudley Seers,

    "

    The National Product Before and After the War," Bulletinof

    the

    Oxford

    University

    Institute

    of Statistics, Vol.

    X

    (October 1948).

    20.

    R. Solow and

    J. Stiglitz,

    "

    Output, Employment

    and

    Wages

    in the

    Short

    Run,"

    Quarterly

    Journal

    of Economics,

    Vol.

    LXXXII,

    No.

    4

    (November 1968).

    21.

    R. Solow and

    J. Stiglitz,

    "

    Reply," Quarterly

    Journal

    of Economics,

    Vol.

    LXXXIV,

    No.

    1

    (February 1970).

    22.

    R.

    Stone,

    "

    The

    Use and

    Development

    of

    National

    Income

    and

    Expenditure

    Estimates,"

    in: D.

    N.

    Chester,

    ed.,

    Lessons

    of

    the

    British

    War

    Economy.

    23.

    Sidney

    Weintraub,

    An

    Approach

    to

    the

    Theory

    of

    Income Distribution

    (Phila-

    delphia:

    Chilton, 1958).

    24. Sidney Weintraub, " Solow and Stiglitz on Employment and Distribution:

    A

    New

    Romance with an

    Old

    Model?

    "

    Quarterly

    Journal

    of Economics,

    Vol.

    LXXXIV, No.

    1

    (February 1970).

    This content downloaded from 207.233.32.18 on Tue, 28 May 2013 20:50:57 PMAll use subject toJSTOR Terms and Conditions

    http://www.jstor.org/page/info/about/policies/terms.jsphttp://www.jstor.org/page/info/about/policies/terms.jsphttp://www.jstor.org/page/info/about/policies/terms.jsphttp://www.jstor.org/page/info/about/policies/terms.jsp
  • 8/10/2019 How to Pay for War by Keynes - Penalties of Debt Borrowing

    12/13

    168 THE ECONOMIC JOURNAL

    [MARCH

    TABLE

    Ia.

    Data

    Used

    in

    Constructing

    Table

    L*

    ($C

    million)

    LOW

    INCOME

    GROUP.

    HIGH

    INCOME

    GROUP.

    Non-con-

    Gross

    Net

    Net

    Saving

    Real

    con-

    Gross

    Net

    Net

    Saving

    Real

    con-

    sumption

    TOTAL.

    income.

    taxes.

    income.

    .

    sumption.

    income.

    taxes.

    income.

    .

    sumption.

    spending.

    1.

    PRE-WAR

    2,630

    110

    2,520

    100

    2,220

    624

    1,596

    306

    2,420

    1,290

    1,140

    4,850

    2.

    WARTIME:

    Keynes'

    Plan

    (a)

    higher

    real

    income,

    +425

    +400

    +825

    output

    (b)

    increase

    in

    voluntary

    +200

    +200

    saving

    (c)

    increased

    non-con-

    +

    1,350

    sumption

    spending

    (d)

    higher

    taxes

    +50

    +350

    (e)

    compulsory

    saving

    +225

    +325

    TOTAL

    3,055

    160

    2,895

    525

    2,620

    974

    1,646

    831

    2,370

    815

    2,490

    5,675

    *

    See

    notes

    below.

    This content downloaded from 207.233.32.18 on Tue, 28 May 2013 20:50:57 PMAll use subject toJSTOR Terms and Conditions

    http://www.jstor.org/page/info/about/policies/terms.jsphttp://www.jstor.org/page/info/about/policies/terms.jsphttp://www.jstor.org/page/info/about/policies/terms.jsphttp://www.jstor.org/page/info/about/policies/terms.jsp
  • 8/10/2019 How to Pay for War by Keynes - Penalties of Debt Borrowing

    13/13

    1972]

    INFLATION,

    TAXATION

    AND EQUITY

    169

    Source

    or Data,

    Table Ia.

    Page

    numbers refer

    to How to Pay for

    the War.

    Data are in

    C

    millions.

    A.

    PRE-WAR.

    Annual Income.

    Notes.

    Below

    $i250.

    Above

    $i250.

    (1)

    Net income 2,520

    1,560

    +

    36 From p. 82.

    Income of

    charities,

    +

    Taxes

    +390 +830

    +

    14

    $50,

    is

    imputed

    to

    the

    above-;J250

    -Transfers

    -280

    -220 group

    and is

    split between net

    income (36) and

    taxes (14)

    accord-

    ing to the prevailing

    pre-war

    tax

    Gross income

    2,630

    2,220

    rate

    of 28% (see below).

    (2)

    Tax rates:

    Net taxes

    110 624 From

    p. 82.

    Gross income 2,630

    2,220

    Rate of

    tax

    0

    04

    0-28

    (3) Propensities to consume:

    Net income 2,520 1,596

    From

    p. 82.

    It is assumed

    that

    the

    Saving

    100

    306 36

    of

    net income

    imputed to the

    Consumption

    2,420

    1,290

    above-/?250

    group from

    charities

    Consumption .

    Income

    0-96

    0-81 is all

    saved.

    B.

    WARTIME (Keynes'

    Plan)

    (1)

    Net

    income

    2,895

    1,646 Added wartime

    income

    of 825

    is

    +

    Taxes

    +540

    +

    1,194

    divided

    as 425

    and 400

    between

    the

    -Transfers

    -380

    -220

    two groups (p.

    37). The "rich"

    would

    pay an

    extra 350 in taxes;

    Gross income

    3,055

    2,620

    the

    "

    poor," an extra 150,

    offset

    by an added 100 in subsidies (p. 37).

    (2)

    Tax

    rates:

    Net

    taxes

    160

    974

    See

    above.

    Gross income 3,055

    2,620

    Rate of

    tax

    0-05

    0-37

    (3) Propensities

    to consume:

    Net

    income

    2,895

    1,646

    The

    added

    400

    in

    voluntary savings

    Savings:

    which Keynes

    assumes (p. 23) is

    Pre-war

    100 306 split equally among

    the two groups.

    Added voluntary

    +200

    +200

    Total

    deferred earnings of 600 were

    Added

    compulsory

    +225

    +325

    proposed,

    reduced to

    550

    by

    "

    con-

    --

    cessions " (p. 36), and allocated

    Total

    525

    831

    225

    and

    325 between

    the two

    Consumption

    2,370

    845

    groups.

    Consumption

    .-

    Income

    0

    82

    0 49

    (4)

    Non

    consumption

    spending:

    Source:

    pp. 79,

    23.

    Pre-war investment

    290

    Pre-war

    public

    consumption

    +850

    Added wartime

    spending

    +

    1,850

    Less:

    Sales

    of assets

    abroad -350

    Less:

    Depreciation

    not

    made

    good

    -150

    Wartime

    non-consumption

    spending

    2,490

    Non-consumption spending

    Output

    044

    (=2,490/5,675)