GARP and Afriat™s Theorem Productionluca/ECON2100/2018Class/lecture_08.pdf · GARP cannot hold....

134
GARP and Afriats Theorem Production Econ 2100 Fall 2018 Lecture 8, September 24 Outline 1 Generalized Axiom of Revealed Preferences 2 Afriats Theorem 3 Production Sets and Production Functions 4 Prots Maximization, Supply Correspondence, and Prot Function 5 Hotelling and Shephard Lemmas 6 Cost Minimization

Transcript of GARP and Afriat™s Theorem Productionluca/ECON2100/2018Class/lecture_08.pdf · GARP cannot hold....

Page 1: GARP and Afriat™s Theorem Productionluca/ECON2100/2018Class/lecture_08.pdf · GARP cannot hold. Therefore, GARP implies the consumer spends all her money. Now suppose xj %R xk and

GARP and Afriat’s TheoremProduction

Econ 2100 Fall 2018

Lecture 8, September 24

Outline

1 Generalized Axiom of Revealed Preferences2 Afriat’s Theorem3 Production Sets and Production Functions4 Profits Maximization, Supply Correspondence, and Profit Function5 Hotelling and Shephard Lemmas6 Cost Minimization

Page 2: GARP and Afriat™s Theorem Productionluca/ECON2100/2018Class/lecture_08.pdf · GARP cannot hold. Therefore, GARP implies the consumer spends all her money. Now suppose xj %R xk and

From Last Class

{x j , pj ,w j}Nj=1 is a finite set of demand data that satisfy pj · x j ≤ w j .Directly revealed weak preference: x j %R xk if pj · xk ≤ w j

Directly revealed strict preference: x j �R xk if pj · xk < w j

Indirectly revealed weak preference:

x j %I xk if ∃ x i1 , . . . , x im s.t. x j %R x i1 , ..., x im %R xk

Indirectly revealed strict preference:

x j �I xk if ∃ x i1 , . . . , x im s.t. x j %R x i1 , ..., x im %R xk with one strictUsing these definitions, we can find a condition that guarantees choices are theresult of the maximizing a preference relation or a utility function.

Page 3: GARP and Afriat™s Theorem Productionluca/ECON2100/2018Class/lecture_08.pdf · GARP cannot hold. Therefore, GARP implies the consumer spends all her money. Now suppose xj %R xk and

Generalized Axiom of Revealed PreferenceAxiom (Generalized Axiom of Revealed Preference - GARP)

If x j %R xk , then not[xk �I x j

].

If a choice is directly revealed weakly prefered to a bundle, this bundle cannotbe indirectly revealed strictly preferred to that choice.Note that if pj · x j < w j then x j �R x j and therefore x j �I x j and thereforeGARP cannot hold.

Therefore, GARP implies the consumer spends all her money.

Now suppose x j %R xk and xk �I x j . Then there is a chain of weak preferencefrom j to k , and a chain back (from k to j) that has at least one strictpreference.

This is a cycle with a strict preference inside; if such a cycle exists one canconstruct a “money pump” to make money off the consumer and leave herexactly at the bundle she started from.GARP rules these cycles out.

Problem 4, Problem Set 4.

Show that GARP is equivalent to the following: If x j %I xk then not[xk �I x j

].

Page 4: GARP and Afriat™s Theorem Productionluca/ECON2100/2018Class/lecture_08.pdf · GARP cannot hold. Therefore, GARP implies the consumer spends all her money. Now suppose xj %R xk and

Generalized Axiom of Revealed PreferenceAxiom (Generalized Axiom of Revealed Preference - GARP)

If x j %R xk , then not[xk �I x j

].

If a choice is directly revealed weakly prefered to a bundle, this bundle cannotbe indirectly revealed strictly preferred to that choice.

Note that if pj · x j < w j then x j �R x j and therefore x j �I x j and thereforeGARP cannot hold.

Therefore, GARP implies the consumer spends all her money.

Now suppose x j %R xk and xk �I x j . Then there is a chain of weak preferencefrom j to k , and a chain back (from k to j) that has at least one strictpreference.

This is a cycle with a strict preference inside; if such a cycle exists one canconstruct a “money pump” to make money off the consumer and leave herexactly at the bundle she started from.GARP rules these cycles out.

Problem 4, Problem Set 4.

Show that GARP is equivalent to the following: If x j %I xk then not[xk �I x j

].

Page 5: GARP and Afriat™s Theorem Productionluca/ECON2100/2018Class/lecture_08.pdf · GARP cannot hold. Therefore, GARP implies the consumer spends all her money. Now suppose xj %R xk and

Generalized Axiom of Revealed PreferenceAxiom (Generalized Axiom of Revealed Preference - GARP)

If x j %R xk , then not[xk �I x j

].

If a choice is directly revealed weakly prefered to a bundle, this bundle cannotbe indirectly revealed strictly preferred to that choice.Note that if pj · x j < w j then x j �R x j and therefore x j �I x j and thereforeGARP cannot hold.

Therefore, GARP implies the consumer spends all her money.

Now suppose x j %R xk and xk �I x j . Then there is a chain of weak preferencefrom j to k , and a chain back (from k to j) that has at least one strictpreference.

This is a cycle with a strict preference inside; if such a cycle exists one canconstruct a “money pump” to make money off the consumer and leave herexactly at the bundle she started from.GARP rules these cycles out.

Problem 4, Problem Set 4.

Show that GARP is equivalent to the following: If x j %I xk then not[xk �I x j

].

Page 6: GARP and Afriat™s Theorem Productionluca/ECON2100/2018Class/lecture_08.pdf · GARP cannot hold. Therefore, GARP implies the consumer spends all her money. Now suppose xj %R xk and

Generalized Axiom of Revealed PreferenceAxiom (Generalized Axiom of Revealed Preference - GARP)

If x j %R xk , then not[xk �I x j

].

If a choice is directly revealed weakly prefered to a bundle, this bundle cannotbe indirectly revealed strictly preferred to that choice.Note that if pj · x j < w j then x j �R x j and therefore x j �I x j and thereforeGARP cannot hold.

Therefore, GARP implies the consumer spends all her money.

Now suppose x j %R xk and xk �I x j . Then there is a chain of weak preferencefrom j to k , and a chain back (from k to j) that has at least one strictpreference.

This is a cycle with a strict preference inside; if such a cycle exists one canconstruct a “money pump” to make money off the consumer and leave herexactly at the bundle she started from.GARP rules these cycles out.

Problem 4, Problem Set 4.

Show that GARP is equivalent to the following: If x j %I xk then not[xk �I x j

].

Page 7: GARP and Afriat™s Theorem Productionluca/ECON2100/2018Class/lecture_08.pdf · GARP cannot hold. Therefore, GARP implies the consumer spends all her money. Now suppose xj %R xk and

Generalized Axiom of Revealed PreferenceAxiom (Generalized Axiom of Revealed Preference - GARP)

If x j %R xk , then not[xk �I x j

].

If a choice is directly revealed weakly prefered to a bundle, this bundle cannotbe indirectly revealed strictly preferred to that choice.Note that if pj · x j < w j then x j �R x j and therefore x j �I x j and thereforeGARP cannot hold.

Therefore, GARP implies the consumer spends all her money.

Now suppose x j %R xk and xk �I x j . Then there is a chain of weak preferencefrom j to k , and a chain back (from k to j) that has at least one strictpreference.

This is a cycle with a strict preference inside; if such a cycle exists one canconstruct a “money pump” to make money off the consumer and leave herexactly at the bundle she started from.GARP rules these cycles out.

Problem 4, Problem Set 4.

Show that GARP is equivalent to the following: If x j %I xk then not[xk �I x j

].

Page 8: GARP and Afriat™s Theorem Productionluca/ECON2100/2018Class/lecture_08.pdf · GARP cannot hold. Therefore, GARP implies the consumer spends all her money. Now suppose xj %R xk and

Generalized Axiom of Revealed PreferenceAxiom (Generalized Axiom of Revealed Preference - GARP)

If x j %R xk , then not[xk �I x j

].

If a choice is directly revealed weakly prefered to a bundle, this bundle cannotbe indirectly revealed strictly preferred to that choice.Note that if pj · x j < w j then x j �R x j and therefore x j �I x j and thereforeGARP cannot hold.

Therefore, GARP implies the consumer spends all her money.

Now suppose x j %R xk and xk �I x j . Then there is a chain of weak preferencefrom j to k , and a chain back (from k to j) that has at least one strictpreference.

This is a cycle with a strict preference inside; if such a cycle exists one canconstruct a “money pump” to make money off the consumer and leave herexactly at the bundle she started from.

GARP rules these cycles out.

Problem 4, Problem Set 4.

Show that GARP is equivalent to the following: If x j %I xk then not[xk �I x j

].

Page 9: GARP and Afriat™s Theorem Productionluca/ECON2100/2018Class/lecture_08.pdf · GARP cannot hold. Therefore, GARP implies the consumer spends all her money. Now suppose xj %R xk and

Generalized Axiom of Revealed PreferenceAxiom (Generalized Axiom of Revealed Preference - GARP)

If x j %R xk , then not[xk �I x j

].

If a choice is directly revealed weakly prefered to a bundle, this bundle cannotbe indirectly revealed strictly preferred to that choice.Note that if pj · x j < w j then x j �R x j and therefore x j �I x j and thereforeGARP cannot hold.

Therefore, GARP implies the consumer spends all her money.

Now suppose x j %R xk and xk �I x j . Then there is a chain of weak preferencefrom j to k , and a chain back (from k to j) that has at least one strictpreference.

This is a cycle with a strict preference inside; if such a cycle exists one canconstruct a “money pump” to make money off the consumer and leave herexactly at the bundle she started from.GARP rules these cycles out.

Problem 4, Problem Set 4.

Show that GARP is equivalent to the following: If x j %I xk then not[xk �I x j

].

Page 10: GARP and Afriat™s Theorem Productionluca/ECON2100/2018Class/lecture_08.pdf · GARP cannot hold. Therefore, GARP implies the consumer spends all her money. Now suppose xj %R xk and

Generalized Axiom of Revealed PreferenceAxiom (Generalized Axiom of Revealed Preference - GARP)

If x j %R xk , then not[xk �I x j

].

If a choice is directly revealed weakly prefered to a bundle, this bundle cannotbe indirectly revealed strictly preferred to that choice.Note that if pj · x j < w j then x j �R x j and therefore x j �I x j and thereforeGARP cannot hold.

Therefore, GARP implies the consumer spends all her money.

Now suppose x j %R xk and xk �I x j . Then there is a chain of weak preferencefrom j to k , and a chain back (from k to j) that has at least one strictpreference.

This is a cycle with a strict preference inside; if such a cycle exists one canconstruct a “money pump” to make money off the consumer and leave herexactly at the bundle she started from.GARP rules these cycles out.

Problem 4, Problem Set 4.

Show that GARP is equivalent to the following: If x j %I xk then not[xk �I x j

].

Page 11: GARP and Afriat™s Theorem Productionluca/ECON2100/2018Class/lecture_08.pdf · GARP cannot hold. Therefore, GARP implies the consumer spends all her money. Now suppose xj %R xk and

Utility and Demand Data

DefinitionA utility function u : Rn+ → R rationalizes a finite set of demand data{x j , pj ,w j}Nj=1 if

u(x j ) ≥ u(x) whenever pj · x ≤ w j

This definition can alternatively be stated by the condition

x j ∈ arg maxx∈Rn+

u(x) subject to pj · x ≤ w j

If the observations satisfy the definition, the data is consistent with thebehavior of an individual who, in each observation, chooses autility-maximizing bundle subject to the corresponding budget constraint.

Page 12: GARP and Afriat™s Theorem Productionluca/ECON2100/2018Class/lecture_08.pdf · GARP cannot hold. Therefore, GARP implies the consumer spends all her money. Now suppose xj %R xk and

Utility and Demand Data

DefinitionA utility function u : Rn+ → R rationalizes a finite set of demand data{x j , pj ,w j}Nj=1 if

u(x j ) ≥ u(x) whenever pj · x ≤ w j

This definition can alternatively be stated by the condition

x j ∈ arg maxx∈Rn+

u(x) subject to pj · x ≤ w j

If the observations satisfy the definition, the data is consistent with thebehavior of an individual who, in each observation, chooses autility-maximizing bundle subject to the corresponding budget constraint.

Page 13: GARP and Afriat™s Theorem Productionluca/ECON2100/2018Class/lecture_08.pdf · GARP cannot hold. Therefore, GARP implies the consumer spends all her money. Now suppose xj %R xk and

Utility and Demand Data

DefinitionA utility function u : Rn+ → R rationalizes a finite set of demand data{x j , pj ,w j}Nj=1 if

u(x j ) ≥ u(x) whenever pj · x ≤ w j

This definition can alternatively be stated by the condition

x j ∈ arg maxx∈Rn+

u(x) subject to pj · x ≤ w j

If the observations satisfy the definition, the data is consistent with thebehavior of an individual who, in each observation, chooses autility-maximizing bundle subject to the corresponding budget constraint.

Page 14: GARP and Afriat™s Theorem Productionluca/ECON2100/2018Class/lecture_08.pdf · GARP cannot hold. Therefore, GARP implies the consumer spends all her money. Now suppose xj %R xk and

Afriat’s Theorem

Theorem (Afriat)

Given a finite set of demand data {(x j , pj ,w j )}Nk=1, the following are equivalent:

1 There exists a locally nonsatiated utility function which rationalizes the data.2 The data satisfy the Generalized Axiom of Revealed Preference.3 There exist numbers v j , λj > 0 such that

v k ≤ v j + λj [pj · xk − w j ], for all j , k = 1, . . . ,N (G)4 There exists a continuous, strictly increasing, and concave utility functionwhich rationalizes the data.

Under GARP, the consumer behaved as if each choice was optimal (i.e.utility-maximizing).

The fact (4) implies (1) is immediate (strictly increasing implies locally nonsatiated). We will skip the remainder of the proof, but see Kreps or Varian forit.

Page 15: GARP and Afriat™s Theorem Productionluca/ECON2100/2018Class/lecture_08.pdf · GARP cannot hold. Therefore, GARP implies the consumer spends all her money. Now suppose xj %R xk and

Afriat’s Theorem

Theorem (Afriat)

Given a finite set of demand data {(x j , pj ,w j )}Nk=1, the following are equivalent:

1 There exists a locally nonsatiated utility function which rationalizes the data.

2 The data satisfy the Generalized Axiom of Revealed Preference.3 There exist numbers v j , λj > 0 such that

v k ≤ v j + λj [pj · xk − w j ], for all j , k = 1, . . . ,N (G)4 There exists a continuous, strictly increasing, and concave utility functionwhich rationalizes the data.

Under GARP, the consumer behaved as if each choice was optimal (i.e.utility-maximizing).

The fact (4) implies (1) is immediate (strictly increasing implies locally nonsatiated). We will skip the remainder of the proof, but see Kreps or Varian forit.

Page 16: GARP and Afriat™s Theorem Productionluca/ECON2100/2018Class/lecture_08.pdf · GARP cannot hold. Therefore, GARP implies the consumer spends all her money. Now suppose xj %R xk and

Afriat’s Theorem

Theorem (Afriat)

Given a finite set of demand data {(x j , pj ,w j )}Nk=1, the following are equivalent:

1 There exists a locally nonsatiated utility function which rationalizes the data.2 The data satisfy the Generalized Axiom of Revealed Preference.

3 There exist numbers v j , λj > 0 such that

v k ≤ v j + λj [pj · xk − w j ], for all j , k = 1, . . . ,N (G)4 There exists a continuous, strictly increasing, and concave utility functionwhich rationalizes the data.

Under GARP, the consumer behaved as if each choice was optimal (i.e.utility-maximizing).

The fact (4) implies (1) is immediate (strictly increasing implies locally nonsatiated). We will skip the remainder of the proof, but see Kreps or Varian forit.

Page 17: GARP and Afriat™s Theorem Productionluca/ECON2100/2018Class/lecture_08.pdf · GARP cannot hold. Therefore, GARP implies the consumer spends all her money. Now suppose xj %R xk and

Afriat’s Theorem

Theorem (Afriat)

Given a finite set of demand data {(x j , pj ,w j )}Nk=1, the following are equivalent:

1 There exists a locally nonsatiated utility function which rationalizes the data.2 The data satisfy the Generalized Axiom of Revealed Preference.3 There exist numbers v j , λj > 0 such that

v k ≤ v j + λj [pj · xk − w j ], for all j , k = 1, . . . ,N (G)

4 There exists a continuous, strictly increasing, and concave utility functionwhich rationalizes the data.

Under GARP, the consumer behaved as if each choice was optimal (i.e.utility-maximizing).

The fact (4) implies (1) is immediate (strictly increasing implies locally nonsatiated). We will skip the remainder of the proof, but see Kreps or Varian forit.

Page 18: GARP and Afriat™s Theorem Productionluca/ECON2100/2018Class/lecture_08.pdf · GARP cannot hold. Therefore, GARP implies the consumer spends all her money. Now suppose xj %R xk and

Afriat’s Theorem

Theorem (Afriat)

Given a finite set of demand data {(x j , pj ,w j )}Nk=1, the following are equivalent:

1 There exists a locally nonsatiated utility function which rationalizes the data.2 The data satisfy the Generalized Axiom of Revealed Preference.3 There exist numbers v j , λj > 0 such that

v k ≤ v j + λj [pj · xk − w j ], for all j , k = 1, . . . ,N (G)4 There exists a continuous, strictly increasing, and concave utility functionwhich rationalizes the data.

Under GARP, the consumer behaved as if each choice was optimal (i.e.utility-maximizing).

The fact (4) implies (1) is immediate (strictly increasing implies locally nonsatiated). We will skip the remainder of the proof, but see Kreps or Varian forit.

Page 19: GARP and Afriat™s Theorem Productionluca/ECON2100/2018Class/lecture_08.pdf · GARP cannot hold. Therefore, GARP implies the consumer spends all her money. Now suppose xj %R xk and

Afriat’s Theorem

Theorem (Afriat)

Given a finite set of demand data {(x j , pj ,w j )}Nk=1, the following are equivalent:

1 There exists a locally nonsatiated utility function which rationalizes the data.2 The data satisfy the Generalized Axiom of Revealed Preference.3 There exist numbers v j , λj > 0 such that

v k ≤ v j + λj [pj · xk − w j ], for all j , k = 1, . . . ,N (G)4 There exists a continuous, strictly increasing, and concave utility functionwhich rationalizes the data.

Under GARP, the consumer behaved as if each choice was optimal (i.e.utility-maximizing).

The fact (4) implies (1) is immediate (strictly increasing implies locally nonsatiated). We will skip the remainder of the proof, but see Kreps or Varian forit.

Page 20: GARP and Afriat™s Theorem Productionluca/ECON2100/2018Class/lecture_08.pdf · GARP cannot hold. Therefore, GARP implies the consumer spends all her money. Now suppose xj %R xk and

Afriat’s Theorem

Theorem (Afriat)

Given a finite set of demand data {(x j , pj ,w j )}Nk=1, the following are equivalent:

1 There exists a locally nonsatiated utility function which rationalizes the data.2 The data satisfy the Generalized Axiom of Revealed Preference.3 There exist numbers v j , λj > 0 such that

v k ≤ v j + λj [pj · xk − w j ], for all j , k = 1, . . . ,N (G)4 There exists a continuous, strictly increasing, and concave utility functionwhich rationalizes the data.

Under GARP, the consumer behaved as if each choice was optimal (i.e.utility-maximizing).

The fact (4) implies (1) is immediate (strictly increasing implies locally nonsatiated). We will skip the remainder of the proof, but see Kreps or Varian forit.

Page 21: GARP and Afriat™s Theorem Productionluca/ECON2100/2018Class/lecture_08.pdf · GARP cannot hold. Therefore, GARP implies the consumer spends all her money. Now suppose xj %R xk and

Afriat’s TheoremTheorem (Afriat)

Given a finite set of demand data {(x j , pj ,w j )}Nk=1, the following are equivalent:

1 There exists a locally nonsatiated utility function which rationalizes the data.2 The data satisfy the Generalized Axiom of Revealed Preference.3 There exist numbers v j , λj > 0 such that

v k ≤ v j + λj [pj · xk − w j ], for all j , k = 1, . . . ,N (G)4 There exists a continuous, strictly increasing, and concave utility functionwhich rationalizes the data.

For finite data, the only implication of preference maximization is GARP;conversely, if the data violate GARP, the consumer is not maximizing anycontinuous, strictly monotone, and convex preference relation.Using a finite number of observations, one cannot distinguish a continuous,strictly monotone, and convex preference from a locally nonsatiated one.One way to test if demand data falsify utility maximization is to see if one canfind the numbers in (G).

These numbers help us construct a function that rationalizes data: eachobservation has “utils” v i and a “budget violating penalty/prize”λi ; everychoice is rational given these.

Page 22: GARP and Afriat™s Theorem Productionluca/ECON2100/2018Class/lecture_08.pdf · GARP cannot hold. Therefore, GARP implies the consumer spends all her money. Now suppose xj %R xk and

Afriat’s TheoremTheorem (Afriat)

Given a finite set of demand data {(x j , pj ,w j )}Nk=1, the following are equivalent:

1 There exists a locally nonsatiated utility function which rationalizes the data.2 The data satisfy the Generalized Axiom of Revealed Preference.3 There exist numbers v j , λj > 0 such that

v k ≤ v j + λj [pj · xk − w j ], for all j , k = 1, . . . ,N (G)4 There exists a continuous, strictly increasing, and concave utility functionwhich rationalizes the data.

For finite data, the only implication of preference maximization is GARP;conversely, if the data violate GARP, the consumer is not maximizing anycontinuous, strictly monotone, and convex preference relation.

Using a finite number of observations, one cannot distinguish a continuous,strictly monotone, and convex preference from a locally nonsatiated one.One way to test if demand data falsify utility maximization is to see if one canfind the numbers in (G).

These numbers help us construct a function that rationalizes data: eachobservation has “utils” v i and a “budget violating penalty/prize”λi ; everychoice is rational given these.

Page 23: GARP and Afriat™s Theorem Productionluca/ECON2100/2018Class/lecture_08.pdf · GARP cannot hold. Therefore, GARP implies the consumer spends all her money. Now suppose xj %R xk and

Afriat’s TheoremTheorem (Afriat)

Given a finite set of demand data {(x j , pj ,w j )}Nk=1, the following are equivalent:

1 There exists a locally nonsatiated utility function which rationalizes the data.2 The data satisfy the Generalized Axiom of Revealed Preference.3 There exist numbers v j , λj > 0 such that

v k ≤ v j + λj [pj · xk − w j ], for all j , k = 1, . . . ,N (G)4 There exists a continuous, strictly increasing, and concave utility functionwhich rationalizes the data.

For finite data, the only implication of preference maximization is GARP;conversely, if the data violate GARP, the consumer is not maximizing anycontinuous, strictly monotone, and convex preference relation.Using a finite number of observations, one cannot distinguish a continuous,strictly monotone, and convex preference from a locally nonsatiated one.

One way to test if demand data falsify utility maximization is to see if one canfind the numbers in (G).

These numbers help us construct a function that rationalizes data: eachobservation has “utils” v i and a “budget violating penalty/prize”λi ; everychoice is rational given these.

Page 24: GARP and Afriat™s Theorem Productionluca/ECON2100/2018Class/lecture_08.pdf · GARP cannot hold. Therefore, GARP implies the consumer spends all her money. Now suppose xj %R xk and

Afriat’s TheoremTheorem (Afriat)

Given a finite set of demand data {(x j , pj ,w j )}Nk=1, the following are equivalent:

1 There exists a locally nonsatiated utility function which rationalizes the data.2 The data satisfy the Generalized Axiom of Revealed Preference.3 There exist numbers v j , λj > 0 such that

v k ≤ v j + λj [pj · xk − w j ], for all j , k = 1, . . . ,N (G)4 There exists a continuous, strictly increasing, and concave utility functionwhich rationalizes the data.

For finite data, the only implication of preference maximization is GARP;conversely, if the data violate GARP, the consumer is not maximizing anycontinuous, strictly monotone, and convex preference relation.Using a finite number of observations, one cannot distinguish a continuous,strictly monotone, and convex preference from a locally nonsatiated one.One way to test if demand data falsify utility maximization is to see if one canfind the numbers in (G).

These numbers help us construct a function that rationalizes data: eachobservation has “utils” v i and a “budget violating penalty/prize”λi ; everychoice is rational given these.

Page 25: GARP and Afriat™s Theorem Productionluca/ECON2100/2018Class/lecture_08.pdf · GARP cannot hold. Therefore, GARP implies the consumer spends all her money. Now suppose xj %R xk and

Afriat’s TheoremTheorem (Afriat)

Given a finite set of demand data {(x j , pj ,w j )}Nk=1, the following are equivalent:

1 There exists a locally nonsatiated utility function which rationalizes the data.2 The data satisfy the Generalized Axiom of Revealed Preference.3 There exist numbers v j , λj > 0 such that

v k ≤ v j + λj [pj · xk − w j ], for all j , k = 1, . . . ,N (G)4 There exists a continuous, strictly increasing, and concave utility functionwhich rationalizes the data.

For finite data, the only implication of preference maximization is GARP;conversely, if the data violate GARP, the consumer is not maximizing anycontinuous, strictly monotone, and convex preference relation.Using a finite number of observations, one cannot distinguish a continuous,strictly monotone, and convex preference from a locally nonsatiated one.One way to test if demand data falsify utility maximization is to see if one canfind the numbers in (G).

These numbers help us construct a function that rationalizes data: eachobservation has “utils” v i and a “budget violating penalty/prize”λi ; everychoice is rational given these.

Page 26: GARP and Afriat™s Theorem Productionluca/ECON2100/2018Class/lecture_08.pdf · GARP cannot hold. Therefore, GARP implies the consumer spends all her money. Now suppose xj %R xk and

The Afriat Numbers∃v j , λj > 0 s.t. v k ≤ v j + λj [pj · xk − w j ] for all j , k = 1, . . . ,N (G)

One uses the numbers v k and λk to construct a function that rationalizes thedata;

the theorem then says that every choice is rational.

Where are the Afriat’s numbers coming from?

Consider utility maximization subject to a budget constraint:

x∗ ∈ arg maxx∈Rn+

u(x) s.t. p · x ≤ w .

The solution maximizes the Lagrangean:

L(x , λ) = u(x) + λ(w − p · x).

Let x∗ and λ∗ be the optimal consumption and multiplier values, respectively.Then we have L(x∗, λ∗) ≥ L(x , λ∗) for all x ∈ Rn+. That is,

u(x∗) + λ∗ (w − p · x∗)︸ ︷︷ ︸=0 since budget constraint binds

≥ u(x) + λ∗(w − p · x).

Thus for all x ∈ Rn+u(x) ≤ u(x∗) + λ∗(p · x − w )

Page 27: GARP and Afriat™s Theorem Productionluca/ECON2100/2018Class/lecture_08.pdf · GARP cannot hold. Therefore, GARP implies the consumer spends all her money. Now suppose xj %R xk and

The Afriat Numbers∃v j , λj > 0 s.t. v k ≤ v j + λj [pj · xk − w j ] for all j , k = 1, . . . ,N (G)

One uses the numbers v k and λk to construct a function that rationalizes thedata;

the theorem then says that every choice is rational.

Where are the Afriat’s numbers coming from?Consider utility maximization subject to a budget constraint:

x∗ ∈ arg maxx∈Rn+

u(x) s.t. p · x ≤ w .

The solution maximizes the Lagrangean:

L(x , λ) = u(x) + λ(w − p · x).

Let x∗ and λ∗ be the optimal consumption and multiplier values, respectively.Then we have L(x∗, λ∗) ≥ L(x , λ∗) for all x ∈ Rn+. That is,

u(x∗) + λ∗ (w − p · x∗)︸ ︷︷ ︸=0 since budget constraint binds

≥ u(x) + λ∗(w − p · x).

Thus for all x ∈ Rn+u(x) ≤ u(x∗) + λ∗(p · x − w )

Page 28: GARP and Afriat™s Theorem Productionluca/ECON2100/2018Class/lecture_08.pdf · GARP cannot hold. Therefore, GARP implies the consumer spends all her money. Now suppose xj %R xk and

The Afriat Numbers∃v j , λj > 0 s.t. v k ≤ v j + λj [pj · xk − w j ] for all j , k = 1, . . . ,N (G)

One uses the numbers v k and λk to construct a function that rationalizes thedata;

the theorem then says that every choice is rational.

Where are the Afriat’s numbers coming from?Consider utility maximization subject to a budget constraint:

x∗ ∈ arg maxx∈Rn+

u(x) s.t. p · x ≤ w .

The solution maximizes the Lagrangean:

L(x , λ) = u(x) + λ(w − p · x).

Let x∗ and λ∗ be the optimal consumption and multiplier values, respectively.Then we have L(x∗, λ∗) ≥ L(x , λ∗) for all x ∈ Rn+. That is,

u(x∗) + λ∗ (w − p · x∗)︸ ︷︷ ︸=0 since budget constraint binds

≥ u(x) + λ∗(w − p · x).

Thus for all x ∈ Rn+u(x) ≤ u(x∗) + λ∗(p · x − w )

Page 29: GARP and Afriat™s Theorem Productionluca/ECON2100/2018Class/lecture_08.pdf · GARP cannot hold. Therefore, GARP implies the consumer spends all her money. Now suppose xj %R xk and

The Afriat Numbers∃v j , λj > 0 s.t. v k ≤ v j + λj [pj · xk − w j ] for all j , k = 1, . . . ,N (G)

One uses the numbers v k and λk to construct a function that rationalizes thedata;

the theorem then says that every choice is rational.

Where are the Afriat’s numbers coming from?Consider utility maximization subject to a budget constraint:

x∗ ∈ arg maxx∈Rn+

u(x) s.t. p · x ≤ w .

The solution maximizes the Lagrangean:

L(x , λ) = u(x) + λ(w − p · x).

Let x∗ and λ∗ be the optimal consumption and multiplier values, respectively.

Then we have L(x∗, λ∗) ≥ L(x , λ∗) for all x ∈ Rn+. That is,u(x∗) + λ∗ (w − p · x∗)︸ ︷︷ ︸

=0 since budget constraint binds

≥ u(x) + λ∗(w − p · x).

Thus for all x ∈ Rn+u(x) ≤ u(x∗) + λ∗(p · x − w )

Page 30: GARP and Afriat™s Theorem Productionluca/ECON2100/2018Class/lecture_08.pdf · GARP cannot hold. Therefore, GARP implies the consumer spends all her money. Now suppose xj %R xk and

The Afriat Numbers∃v j , λj > 0 s.t. v k ≤ v j + λj [pj · xk − w j ] for all j , k = 1, . . . ,N (G)

One uses the numbers v k and λk to construct a function that rationalizes thedata;

the theorem then says that every choice is rational.

Where are the Afriat’s numbers coming from?Consider utility maximization subject to a budget constraint:

x∗ ∈ arg maxx∈Rn+

u(x) s.t. p · x ≤ w .

The solution maximizes the Lagrangean:

L(x , λ) = u(x) + λ(w − p · x).

Let x∗ and λ∗ be the optimal consumption and multiplier values, respectively.Then we have L(x∗, λ∗) ≥ L(x , λ∗) for all x ∈ Rn+. That is,

u(x∗) + λ∗ (w − p · x∗)︸ ︷︷ ︸=0 since budget constraint binds

≥ u(x) + λ∗(w − p · x).

Thus for all x ∈ Rn+u(x) ≤ u(x∗) + λ∗(p · x − w )

Page 31: GARP and Afriat™s Theorem Productionluca/ECON2100/2018Class/lecture_08.pdf · GARP cannot hold. Therefore, GARP implies the consumer spends all her money. Now suppose xj %R xk and

The Afriat Numbers∃v j , λj > 0 s.t. v k ≤ v j + λj [pj · xk − w j ] for all j , k = 1, . . . ,N (G)

One uses the numbers v k and λk to construct a function that rationalizes thedata;

the theorem then says that every choice is rational.

Where are the Afriat’s numbers coming from?Consider utility maximization subject to a budget constraint:

x∗ ∈ arg maxx∈Rn+

u(x) s.t. p · x ≤ w .

The solution maximizes the Lagrangean:

L(x , λ) = u(x) + λ(w − p · x).

Let x∗ and λ∗ be the optimal consumption and multiplier values, respectively.Then we have L(x∗, λ∗) ≥ L(x , λ∗) for all x ∈ Rn+. That is,

u(x∗) + λ∗ (w − p · x∗)︸ ︷︷ ︸=0 since budget constraint binds

≥ u(x) + λ∗(w − p · x).

Thus for all x ∈ Rn+u(x) ≤ u(x∗) + λ∗(p · x − w )

Page 32: GARP and Afriat™s Theorem Productionluca/ECON2100/2018Class/lecture_08.pdf · GARP cannot hold. Therefore, GARP implies the consumer spends all her money. Now suppose xj %R xk and

Intuition Behind the Afriat Numbers

∃v j , λj > 0 s.t. v k ≤ v j + λj [pj · xk − w j ] for all j , k = 1, . . . ,N (G)

Another intuition behind Afriat’s numbersRewrite (G) as

v k − v j ≤ λj [pj · xk − w j ].Suppose that pj · xk − w j > 0. Then xk was unaffordable at pj and w j .

Even if x k yields more “utils” than x j , at p j and w j the penalty for violating thebudget constraint (given by λj [p j · x k − w j ]) is too large for the change in thevalue of the choice (given by v k − v j ) to compensate for it.Thus, the decision maker chose x j over all other alternatives at p j and w j .

Suppose that pj · xk − w j ≤ 0. Then xk was affordable at pj and w j .But then (G) implies that

v j − v k ≥ λj [w j − p j · x k ].So the decision maker chose x j over x k because the difference in “utils” ishigher than the bonus from having some extra money left over by choosing x k

instead of x j .

Page 33: GARP and Afriat™s Theorem Productionluca/ECON2100/2018Class/lecture_08.pdf · GARP cannot hold. Therefore, GARP implies the consumer spends all her money. Now suppose xj %R xk and

Producers and Production SetsProducers are profit maximizing firms that buy inputs and use them to produce andthen sell outputs.

The plural is important because most firms produce more than one good.

The standard undergraduate textbook description focuses on one ouput and afew inputs (two in most cases).

In that framework, production is described by a function that takes inputs asthe domain and output(s) as the range.

Here we focus on a more general and abstract version of production.

DefinitionA production set is a subset Y ⊆ Rn .

y = (y1, ..., yN ) denotes production (input-output) vectors.

A production vector has outputs as non-negative numbers and inputs asnon-positive numbers: yi ≤ 0 when i is an input, and yi ≥ 0 if i is an output.What is p · y in this notation?

Page 34: GARP and Afriat™s Theorem Productionluca/ECON2100/2018Class/lecture_08.pdf · GARP cannot hold. Therefore, GARP implies the consumer spends all her money. Now suppose xj %R xk and

Producers and Production SetsProducers are profit maximizing firms that buy inputs and use them to produce andthen sell outputs.

The plural is important because most firms produce more than one good.

The standard undergraduate textbook description focuses on one ouput and afew inputs (two in most cases).

In that framework, production is described by a function that takes inputs asthe domain and output(s) as the range.

Here we focus on a more general and abstract version of production.

DefinitionA production set is a subset Y ⊆ Rn .

y = (y1, ..., yN ) denotes production (input-output) vectors.

A production vector has outputs as non-negative numbers and inputs asnon-positive numbers: yi ≤ 0 when i is an input, and yi ≥ 0 if i is an output.What is p · y in this notation?

Page 35: GARP and Afriat™s Theorem Productionluca/ECON2100/2018Class/lecture_08.pdf · GARP cannot hold. Therefore, GARP implies the consumer spends all her money. Now suppose xj %R xk and

Producers and Production SetsProducers are profit maximizing firms that buy inputs and use them to produce andthen sell outputs.

The plural is important because most firms produce more than one good.

The standard undergraduate textbook description focuses on one ouput and afew inputs (two in most cases).

In that framework, production is described by a function that takes inputs asthe domain and output(s) as the range.

Here we focus on a more general and abstract version of production.

DefinitionA production set is a subset Y ⊆ Rn .

y = (y1, ..., yN ) denotes production (input-output) vectors.

A production vector has outputs as non-negative numbers and inputs asnon-positive numbers: yi ≤ 0 when i is an input, and yi ≥ 0 if i is an output.What is p · y in this notation?

Page 36: GARP and Afriat™s Theorem Productionluca/ECON2100/2018Class/lecture_08.pdf · GARP cannot hold. Therefore, GARP implies the consumer spends all her money. Now suppose xj %R xk and

Producers and Production SetsProducers are profit maximizing firms that buy inputs and use them to produce andthen sell outputs.

The plural is important because most firms produce more than one good.

The standard undergraduate textbook description focuses on one ouput and afew inputs (two in most cases).

In that framework, production is described by a function that takes inputs asthe domain and output(s) as the range.

Here we focus on a more general and abstract version of production.

DefinitionA production set is a subset Y ⊆ Rn .

y = (y1, ..., yN ) denotes production (input-output) vectors.

A production vector has outputs as non-negative numbers and inputs asnon-positive numbers: yi ≤ 0 when i is an input, and yi ≥ 0 if i is an output.What is p · y in this notation?

Page 37: GARP and Afriat™s Theorem Productionluca/ECON2100/2018Class/lecture_08.pdf · GARP cannot hold. Therefore, GARP implies the consumer spends all her money. Now suppose xj %R xk and

Producers and Production SetsProducers are profit maximizing firms that buy inputs and use them to produce andthen sell outputs.

The plural is important because most firms produce more than one good.

The standard undergraduate textbook description focuses on one ouput and afew inputs (two in most cases).

In that framework, production is described by a function that takes inputs asthe domain and output(s) as the range.

Here we focus on a more general and abstract version of production.

DefinitionA production set is a subset Y ⊆ Rn .

y = (y1, ..., yN ) denotes production (input-output) vectors.

A production vector has outputs as non-negative numbers and inputs asnon-positive numbers: yi ≤ 0 when i is an input, and yi ≥ 0 if i is an output.What is p · y in this notation?

Page 38: GARP and Afriat™s Theorem Productionluca/ECON2100/2018Class/lecture_08.pdf · GARP cannot hold. Therefore, GARP implies the consumer spends all her money. Now suppose xj %R xk and

Producers and Production SetsProducers are profit maximizing firms that buy inputs and use them to produce andthen sell outputs.

The plural is important because most firms produce more than one good.

The standard undergraduate textbook description focuses on one ouput and afew inputs (two in most cases).

In that framework, production is described by a function that takes inputs asthe domain and output(s) as the range.

Here we focus on a more general and abstract version of production.

DefinitionA production set is a subset Y ⊆ Rn .

y = (y1, ..., yN ) denotes production (input-output) vectors.

A production vector has outputs as non-negative numbers and inputs asnon-positive numbers: yi ≤ 0 when i is an input, and yi ≥ 0 if i is an output.What is p · y in this notation?

Page 39: GARP and Afriat™s Theorem Productionluca/ECON2100/2018Class/lecture_08.pdf · GARP cannot hold. Therefore, GARP implies the consumer spends all her money. Now suppose xj %R xk and

Producers and Production SetsProducers are profit maximizing firms that buy inputs and use them to produce andthen sell outputs.

The plural is important because most firms produce more than one good.

The standard undergraduate textbook description focuses on one ouput and afew inputs (two in most cases).

In that framework, production is described by a function that takes inputs asthe domain and output(s) as the range.

Here we focus on a more general and abstract version of production.

DefinitionA production set is a subset Y ⊆ Rn .

y = (y1, ..., yN ) denotes production (input-output) vectors.

A production vector has outputs as non-negative numbers and inputs asnon-positive numbers: yi ≤ 0 when i is an input, and yi ≥ 0 if i is an output.

What is p · y in this notation?

Page 40: GARP and Afriat™s Theorem Productionluca/ECON2100/2018Class/lecture_08.pdf · GARP cannot hold. Therefore, GARP implies the consumer spends all her money. Now suppose xj %R xk and

Producers and Production SetsProducers are profit maximizing firms that buy inputs and use them to produce andthen sell outputs.

The plural is important because most firms produce more than one good.

The standard undergraduate textbook description focuses on one ouput and afew inputs (two in most cases).

In that framework, production is described by a function that takes inputs asthe domain and output(s) as the range.

Here we focus on a more general and abstract version of production.

DefinitionA production set is a subset Y ⊆ Rn .

y = (y1, ..., yN ) denotes production (input-output) vectors.

A production vector has outputs as non-negative numbers and inputs asnon-positive numbers: yi ≤ 0 when i is an input, and yi ≥ 0 if i is an output.What is p · y in this notation?

Page 41: GARP and Afriat™s Theorem Productionluca/ECON2100/2018Class/lecture_08.pdf · GARP cannot hold. Therefore, GARP implies the consumer spends all her money. Now suppose xj %R xk and

Production Set Properties

DefinitionY ⊆ Rn satisfies:

no free lunch if Y ∩ Rn+ ⊆ {0n};possibility of inaction if 0n ∈ Y ;free disposal if y ∈ Y implies y ′ ∈ Y for all y ′ ≤ y ;irreversibility if y ∈ Y and y 6= 0n imply −y /∈ Y ;nonincreasing returns to scale if y ∈ Y implies αy ∈ Y for all α ∈ [0, 1];

nondecreasing returns to scale if y ∈ Y implies αy ∈ Y for all α ≥ 1;constant returns to scale if y ∈ Y implies αy ∈ Y for all α ≥ 0;additivity if y , y ′ ∈ Y imply y + y ′ ∈ Y ;convexity if Y is convex;

Y is a convex cone if for any y , y ′ ∈ Y and α, β ≥ 0, αy + βy ′ ∈ Y .

Draw Pictures.

Page 42: GARP and Afriat™s Theorem Productionluca/ECON2100/2018Class/lecture_08.pdf · GARP cannot hold. Therefore, GARP implies the consumer spends all her money. Now suppose xj %R xk and

Production Set Properties

DefinitionY ⊆ Rn satisfies:

no free lunch if Y ∩ Rn+ ⊆ {0n};

possibility of inaction if 0n ∈ Y ;free disposal if y ∈ Y implies y ′ ∈ Y for all y ′ ≤ y ;irreversibility if y ∈ Y and y 6= 0n imply −y /∈ Y ;nonincreasing returns to scale if y ∈ Y implies αy ∈ Y for all α ∈ [0, 1];

nondecreasing returns to scale if y ∈ Y implies αy ∈ Y for all α ≥ 1;constant returns to scale if y ∈ Y implies αy ∈ Y for all α ≥ 0;additivity if y , y ′ ∈ Y imply y + y ′ ∈ Y ;convexity if Y is convex;

Y is a convex cone if for any y , y ′ ∈ Y and α, β ≥ 0, αy + βy ′ ∈ Y .

Draw Pictures.

Page 43: GARP and Afriat™s Theorem Productionluca/ECON2100/2018Class/lecture_08.pdf · GARP cannot hold. Therefore, GARP implies the consumer spends all her money. Now suppose xj %R xk and

Production Set Properties

DefinitionY ⊆ Rn satisfies:

no free lunch if Y ∩ Rn+ ⊆ {0n};possibility of inaction if 0n ∈ Y ;

free disposal if y ∈ Y implies y ′ ∈ Y for all y ′ ≤ y ;irreversibility if y ∈ Y and y 6= 0n imply −y /∈ Y ;nonincreasing returns to scale if y ∈ Y implies αy ∈ Y for all α ∈ [0, 1];

nondecreasing returns to scale if y ∈ Y implies αy ∈ Y for all α ≥ 1;constant returns to scale if y ∈ Y implies αy ∈ Y for all α ≥ 0;additivity if y , y ′ ∈ Y imply y + y ′ ∈ Y ;convexity if Y is convex;

Y is a convex cone if for any y , y ′ ∈ Y and α, β ≥ 0, αy + βy ′ ∈ Y .

Draw Pictures.

Page 44: GARP and Afriat™s Theorem Productionluca/ECON2100/2018Class/lecture_08.pdf · GARP cannot hold. Therefore, GARP implies the consumer spends all her money. Now suppose xj %R xk and

Production Set Properties

DefinitionY ⊆ Rn satisfies:

no free lunch if Y ∩ Rn+ ⊆ {0n};possibility of inaction if 0n ∈ Y ;free disposal if y ∈ Y implies y ′ ∈ Y for all y ′ ≤ y ;

irreversibility if y ∈ Y and y 6= 0n imply −y /∈ Y ;nonincreasing returns to scale if y ∈ Y implies αy ∈ Y for all α ∈ [0, 1];

nondecreasing returns to scale if y ∈ Y implies αy ∈ Y for all α ≥ 1;constant returns to scale if y ∈ Y implies αy ∈ Y for all α ≥ 0;additivity if y , y ′ ∈ Y imply y + y ′ ∈ Y ;convexity if Y is convex;

Y is a convex cone if for any y , y ′ ∈ Y and α, β ≥ 0, αy + βy ′ ∈ Y .

Draw Pictures.

Page 45: GARP and Afriat™s Theorem Productionluca/ECON2100/2018Class/lecture_08.pdf · GARP cannot hold. Therefore, GARP implies the consumer spends all her money. Now suppose xj %R xk and

Production Set Properties

DefinitionY ⊆ Rn satisfies:

no free lunch if Y ∩ Rn+ ⊆ {0n};possibility of inaction if 0n ∈ Y ;free disposal if y ∈ Y implies y ′ ∈ Y for all y ′ ≤ y ;irreversibility if y ∈ Y and y 6= 0n imply −y /∈ Y ;

nonincreasing returns to scale if y ∈ Y implies αy ∈ Y for all α ∈ [0, 1];

nondecreasing returns to scale if y ∈ Y implies αy ∈ Y for all α ≥ 1;constant returns to scale if y ∈ Y implies αy ∈ Y for all α ≥ 0;additivity if y , y ′ ∈ Y imply y + y ′ ∈ Y ;convexity if Y is convex;

Y is a convex cone if for any y , y ′ ∈ Y and α, β ≥ 0, αy + βy ′ ∈ Y .

Draw Pictures.

Page 46: GARP and Afriat™s Theorem Productionluca/ECON2100/2018Class/lecture_08.pdf · GARP cannot hold. Therefore, GARP implies the consumer spends all her money. Now suppose xj %R xk and

Production Set Properties

DefinitionY ⊆ Rn satisfies:

no free lunch if Y ∩ Rn+ ⊆ {0n};possibility of inaction if 0n ∈ Y ;free disposal if y ∈ Y implies y ′ ∈ Y for all y ′ ≤ y ;irreversibility if y ∈ Y and y 6= 0n imply −y /∈ Y ;nonincreasing returns to scale if y ∈ Y implies αy ∈ Y for all α ∈ [0, 1];

nondecreasing returns to scale if y ∈ Y implies αy ∈ Y for all α ≥ 1;constant returns to scale if y ∈ Y implies αy ∈ Y for all α ≥ 0;additivity if y , y ′ ∈ Y imply y + y ′ ∈ Y ;convexity if Y is convex;

Y is a convex cone if for any y , y ′ ∈ Y and α, β ≥ 0, αy + βy ′ ∈ Y .

Draw Pictures.

Page 47: GARP and Afriat™s Theorem Productionluca/ECON2100/2018Class/lecture_08.pdf · GARP cannot hold. Therefore, GARP implies the consumer spends all her money. Now suppose xj %R xk and

Production Set Properties

DefinitionY ⊆ Rn satisfies:

no free lunch if Y ∩ Rn+ ⊆ {0n};possibility of inaction if 0n ∈ Y ;free disposal if y ∈ Y implies y ′ ∈ Y for all y ′ ≤ y ;irreversibility if y ∈ Y and y 6= 0n imply −y /∈ Y ;nonincreasing returns to scale if y ∈ Y implies αy ∈ Y for all α ∈ [0, 1];

nondecreasing returns to scale if y ∈ Y implies αy ∈ Y for all α ≥ 1;

constant returns to scale if y ∈ Y implies αy ∈ Y for all α ≥ 0;additivity if y , y ′ ∈ Y imply y + y ′ ∈ Y ;convexity if Y is convex;

Y is a convex cone if for any y , y ′ ∈ Y and α, β ≥ 0, αy + βy ′ ∈ Y .

Draw Pictures.

Page 48: GARP and Afriat™s Theorem Productionluca/ECON2100/2018Class/lecture_08.pdf · GARP cannot hold. Therefore, GARP implies the consumer spends all her money. Now suppose xj %R xk and

Production Set Properties

DefinitionY ⊆ Rn satisfies:

no free lunch if Y ∩ Rn+ ⊆ {0n};possibility of inaction if 0n ∈ Y ;free disposal if y ∈ Y implies y ′ ∈ Y for all y ′ ≤ y ;irreversibility if y ∈ Y and y 6= 0n imply −y /∈ Y ;nonincreasing returns to scale if y ∈ Y implies αy ∈ Y for all α ∈ [0, 1];

nondecreasing returns to scale if y ∈ Y implies αy ∈ Y for all α ≥ 1;constant returns to scale if y ∈ Y implies αy ∈ Y for all α ≥ 0;

additivity if y , y ′ ∈ Y imply y + y ′ ∈ Y ;convexity if Y is convex;

Y is a convex cone if for any y , y ′ ∈ Y and α, β ≥ 0, αy + βy ′ ∈ Y .

Draw Pictures.

Page 49: GARP and Afriat™s Theorem Productionluca/ECON2100/2018Class/lecture_08.pdf · GARP cannot hold. Therefore, GARP implies the consumer spends all her money. Now suppose xj %R xk and

Production Set Properties

DefinitionY ⊆ Rn satisfies:

no free lunch if Y ∩ Rn+ ⊆ {0n};possibility of inaction if 0n ∈ Y ;free disposal if y ∈ Y implies y ′ ∈ Y for all y ′ ≤ y ;irreversibility if y ∈ Y and y 6= 0n imply −y /∈ Y ;nonincreasing returns to scale if y ∈ Y implies αy ∈ Y for all α ∈ [0, 1];

nondecreasing returns to scale if y ∈ Y implies αy ∈ Y for all α ≥ 1;constant returns to scale if y ∈ Y implies αy ∈ Y for all α ≥ 0;additivity if y , y ′ ∈ Y imply y + y ′ ∈ Y ;

convexity if Y is convex;

Y is a convex cone if for any y , y ′ ∈ Y and α, β ≥ 0, αy + βy ′ ∈ Y .

Draw Pictures.

Page 50: GARP and Afriat™s Theorem Productionluca/ECON2100/2018Class/lecture_08.pdf · GARP cannot hold. Therefore, GARP implies the consumer spends all her money. Now suppose xj %R xk and

Production Set Properties

DefinitionY ⊆ Rn satisfies:

no free lunch if Y ∩ Rn+ ⊆ {0n};possibility of inaction if 0n ∈ Y ;free disposal if y ∈ Y implies y ′ ∈ Y for all y ′ ≤ y ;irreversibility if y ∈ Y and y 6= 0n imply −y /∈ Y ;nonincreasing returns to scale if y ∈ Y implies αy ∈ Y for all α ∈ [0, 1];

nondecreasing returns to scale if y ∈ Y implies αy ∈ Y for all α ≥ 1;constant returns to scale if y ∈ Y implies αy ∈ Y for all α ≥ 0;additivity if y , y ′ ∈ Y imply y + y ′ ∈ Y ;convexity if Y is convex;

Y is a convex cone if for any y , y ′ ∈ Y and α, β ≥ 0, αy + βy ′ ∈ Y .

Draw Pictures.

Page 51: GARP and Afriat™s Theorem Productionluca/ECON2100/2018Class/lecture_08.pdf · GARP cannot hold. Therefore, GARP implies the consumer spends all her money. Now suppose xj %R xk and

Production Set Properties

DefinitionY ⊆ Rn satisfies:

no free lunch if Y ∩ Rn+ ⊆ {0n};possibility of inaction if 0n ∈ Y ;free disposal if y ∈ Y implies y ′ ∈ Y for all y ′ ≤ y ;irreversibility if y ∈ Y and y 6= 0n imply −y /∈ Y ;nonincreasing returns to scale if y ∈ Y implies αy ∈ Y for all α ∈ [0, 1];

nondecreasing returns to scale if y ∈ Y implies αy ∈ Y for all α ≥ 1;constant returns to scale if y ∈ Y implies αy ∈ Y for all α ≥ 0;additivity if y , y ′ ∈ Y imply y + y ′ ∈ Y ;convexity if Y is convex;

Y is a convex cone if for any y , y ′ ∈ Y and α, β ≥ 0, αy + βy ′ ∈ Y .

Draw Pictures.

Page 52: GARP and Afriat™s Theorem Productionluca/ECON2100/2018Class/lecture_08.pdf · GARP cannot hold. Therefore, GARP implies the consumer spends all her money. Now suppose xj %R xk and

Production Set Properties Are Related

Some of these properties are related to each other.

ExerciseY satisfies additivity and nonincreasing returns if and only if it is a convex cone.

Exercise

For any convex Y ⊂ Rn such that 0n ∈ Y , there is a convex Y ′ ⊂ Rn+1 thatsatisfies constant returns such that Y = {y ∈ Rn : (y ,−1) ∈ Rn+1}.

Page 53: GARP and Afriat™s Theorem Productionluca/ECON2100/2018Class/lecture_08.pdf · GARP cannot hold. Therefore, GARP implies the consumer spends all her money. Now suppose xj %R xk and

Production Set Properties Are Related

Some of these properties are related to each other.

ExerciseY satisfies additivity and nonincreasing returns if and only if it is a convex cone.

Exercise

For any convex Y ⊂ Rn such that 0n ∈ Y , there is a convex Y ′ ⊂ Rn+1 thatsatisfies constant returns such that Y = {y ∈ Rn : (y ,−1) ∈ Rn+1}.

Page 54: GARP and Afriat™s Theorem Productionluca/ECON2100/2018Class/lecture_08.pdf · GARP cannot hold. Therefore, GARP implies the consumer spends all her money. Now suppose xj %R xk and

Production FunctionsLet y ∈ Rm+ denote outputs while x ∈ Rn+ represent inputs; if the two are related bya function f : Rn+ → Rm+, we write y = f (x) to say that y units of outputs areproduced using x amount of the inputs.

When m = 1, this is the familiar one output many inputs production function.

Production sets and the familiar production function are related.

ExerciseSuppose the firm’s production set is generated by a production functionf : Rn+ → Rm+, where Rn+ represents its n inputs and R+ represents its m outputs.Let

Y = {(−x , y) ∈ Rn− × Rm+ : y ≤ f (x)}.Prove the following:

1 Y satisfies no free lunch, possibility of inaction, free disposal, and irreversibility.2 Suppose m = 1. Y satisfies constant returns to scale if and only if f ishomogeneous of degree one, i.e. f (αx) = αf (x) for all α ≥ 0.

3 Suppose m = 1. Y satisfies convexity if and only if f is concave.

Page 55: GARP and Afriat™s Theorem Productionluca/ECON2100/2018Class/lecture_08.pdf · GARP cannot hold. Therefore, GARP implies the consumer spends all her money. Now suppose xj %R xk and

Production FunctionsLet y ∈ Rm+ denote outputs while x ∈ Rn+ represent inputs; if the two are related bya function f : Rn+ → Rm+, we write y = f (x) to say that y units of outputs areproduced using x amount of the inputs.

When m = 1, this is the familiar one output many inputs production function.

Production sets and the familiar production function are related.

ExerciseSuppose the firm’s production set is generated by a production functionf : Rn+ → Rm+, where Rn+ represents its n inputs and R+ represents its m outputs.Let

Y = {(−x , y) ∈ Rn− × Rm+ : y ≤ f (x)}.Prove the following:

1 Y satisfies no free lunch, possibility of inaction, free disposal, and irreversibility.2 Suppose m = 1. Y satisfies constant returns to scale if and only if f ishomogeneous of degree one, i.e. f (αx) = αf (x) for all α ≥ 0.

3 Suppose m = 1. Y satisfies convexity if and only if f is concave.

Page 56: GARP and Afriat™s Theorem Productionluca/ECON2100/2018Class/lecture_08.pdf · GARP cannot hold. Therefore, GARP implies the consumer spends all her money. Now suppose xj %R xk and

Production FunctionsLet y ∈ Rm+ denote outputs while x ∈ Rn+ represent inputs; if the two are related bya function f : Rn+ → Rm+, we write y = f (x) to say that y units of outputs areproduced using x amount of the inputs.

When m = 1, this is the familiar one output many inputs production function.

Production sets and the familiar production function are related.

ExerciseSuppose the firm’s production set is generated by a production functionf : Rn+ → Rm+, where Rn+ represents its n inputs and R+ represents its m outputs.Let

Y = {(−x , y) ∈ Rn− × Rm+ : y ≤ f (x)}.Prove the following:

1 Y satisfies no free lunch, possibility of inaction, free disposal, and irreversibility.2 Suppose m = 1. Y satisfies constant returns to scale if and only if f ishomogeneous of degree one, i.e. f (αx) = αf (x) for all α ≥ 0.

3 Suppose m = 1. Y satisfies convexity if and only if f is concave.

Page 57: GARP and Afriat™s Theorem Productionluca/ECON2100/2018Class/lecture_08.pdf · GARP cannot hold. Therefore, GARP implies the consumer spends all her money. Now suppose xj %R xk and

Production FunctionsLet y ∈ Rm+ denote outputs while x ∈ Rn+ represent inputs; if the two are related bya function f : Rn+ → Rm+, we write y = f (x) to say that y units of outputs areproduced using x amount of the inputs.

When m = 1, this is the familiar one output many inputs production function.

Production sets and the familiar production function are related.

ExerciseSuppose the firm’s production set is generated by a production functionf : Rn+ → Rm+, where Rn+ represents its n inputs and R+ represents its m outputs.Let

Y = {(−x , y) ∈ Rn− × Rm+ : y ≤ f (x)}.Prove the following:

1 Y satisfies no free lunch, possibility of inaction, free disposal, and irreversibility.2 Suppose m = 1. Y satisfies constant returns to scale if and only if f ishomogeneous of degree one, i.e. f (αx) = αf (x) for all α ≥ 0.

3 Suppose m = 1. Y satisfies convexity if and only if f is concave.

Page 58: GARP and Afriat™s Theorem Productionluca/ECON2100/2018Class/lecture_08.pdf · GARP cannot hold. Therefore, GARP implies the consumer spends all her money. Now suppose xj %R xk and

Transformation FunctionWe can describe production sets using a function.

DefinitionGiven a production set Y ⊆ Rn , the transformation function F : Y → R is definedby

Y = {y ∈ Y : F (y) ≤ 0 and F (y) = 0 if and only if y is on the boundary of Y } ;

the transformation frontier is

{y ∈ Rn : F (y) = 0}

DefinitionGiven a differentiable transformation function F and a point on its transformationfrontier y , the marginal rate of transformation for goods i and j is given by

MRTi ,j =

∂F (y )∂yi∂F (y )∂yj

Since F (y) = 0 we have∂F (y)

∂yidyi +

∂F (y)

∂yjdyj = 0

MRT is the slope of the transformation frontier at y .

Page 59: GARP and Afriat™s Theorem Productionluca/ECON2100/2018Class/lecture_08.pdf · GARP cannot hold. Therefore, GARP implies the consumer spends all her money. Now suppose xj %R xk and

Transformation FunctionWe can describe production sets using a function.

DefinitionGiven a production set Y ⊆ Rn , the transformation function F : Y → R is definedby

Y = {y ∈ Y : F (y) ≤ 0 and F (y) = 0 if and only if y is on the boundary of Y } ;

the transformation frontier is

{y ∈ Rn : F (y) = 0}

DefinitionGiven a differentiable transformation function F and a point on its transformationfrontier y , the marginal rate of transformation for goods i and j is given by

MRTi ,j =

∂F (y )∂yi∂F (y )∂yj

Since F (y) = 0 we have∂F (y)

∂yidyi +

∂F (y)

∂yjdyj = 0

MRT is the slope of the transformation frontier at y .

Page 60: GARP and Afriat™s Theorem Productionluca/ECON2100/2018Class/lecture_08.pdf · GARP cannot hold. Therefore, GARP implies the consumer spends all her money. Now suppose xj %R xk and

Transformation FunctionWe can describe production sets using a function.

DefinitionGiven a production set Y ⊆ Rn , the transformation function F : Y → R is definedby

Y = {y ∈ Y : F (y) ≤ 0 and F (y) = 0 if and only if y is on the boundary of Y } ;

the transformation frontier is

{y ∈ Rn : F (y) = 0}

DefinitionGiven a differentiable transformation function F and a point on its transformationfrontier y , the marginal rate of transformation for goods i and j is given by

MRTi ,j =

∂F (y )∂yi∂F (y )∂yj

Since F (y) = 0 we have∂F (y)

∂yidyi +

∂F (y)

∂yjdyj = 0

MRT is the slope of the transformation frontier at y .

Page 61: GARP and Afriat™s Theorem Productionluca/ECON2100/2018Class/lecture_08.pdf · GARP cannot hold. Therefore, GARP implies the consumer spends all her money. Now suppose xj %R xk and

Transformation FunctionWe can describe production sets using a function.

DefinitionGiven a production set Y ⊆ Rn , the transformation function F : Y → R is definedby

Y = {y ∈ Y : F (y) ≤ 0 and F (y) = 0 if and only if y is on the boundary of Y } ;

the transformation frontier is

{y ∈ Rn : F (y) = 0}

DefinitionGiven a differentiable transformation function F and a point on its transformationfrontier y , the marginal rate of transformation for goods i and j is given by

MRTi ,j =

∂F (y )∂yi∂F (y )∂yj

Since F (y) = 0 we have∂F (y)

∂yidyi +

∂F (y)

∂yjdyj = 0

MRT is the slope of the transformation frontier at y .

Page 62: GARP and Afriat™s Theorem Productionluca/ECON2100/2018Class/lecture_08.pdf · GARP cannot hold. Therefore, GARP implies the consumer spends all her money. Now suppose xj %R xk and

Profit Maximization

Profit Maximizing AssumptionThe firm’s objective is to choose a production vector on the trasformation frontieras to maximize profits given prices p ∈ Rn++:

maxy∈Y

p · y

or equivalentlymax p · y subject to F (y) ≤ 0

Does this distinguish between revenues and costs? How?

Using the single output production function:

maxx≥0

pf (x)− w · x

here p ∈ R++ is the price of output and w ∈ Rl++ is the price of inputs.

Page 63: GARP and Afriat™s Theorem Productionluca/ECON2100/2018Class/lecture_08.pdf · GARP cannot hold. Therefore, GARP implies the consumer spends all her money. Now suppose xj %R xk and

Profit Maximization

Profit Maximizing AssumptionThe firm’s objective is to choose a production vector on the trasformation frontieras to maximize profits given prices p ∈ Rn++:

maxy∈Y

p · y

or equivalentlymax p · y subject to F (y) ≤ 0

Does this distinguish between revenues and costs? How?

Using the single output production function:

maxx≥0

pf (x)− w · x

here p ∈ R++ is the price of output and w ∈ Rl++ is the price of inputs.

Page 64: GARP and Afriat™s Theorem Productionluca/ECON2100/2018Class/lecture_08.pdf · GARP cannot hold. Therefore, GARP implies the consumer spends all her money. Now suppose xj %R xk and

Profit Maximization

Profit Maximizing AssumptionThe firm’s objective is to choose a production vector on the trasformation frontieras to maximize profits given prices p ∈ Rn++:

maxy∈Y

p · y

or equivalentlymax p · y subject to F (y) ≤ 0

Does this distinguish between revenues and costs? How?

Using the single output production function:

maxx≥0

pf (x)− w · x

here p ∈ R++ is the price of output and w ∈ Rl++ is the price of inputs.

Page 65: GARP and Afriat™s Theorem Productionluca/ECON2100/2018Class/lecture_08.pdf · GARP cannot hold. Therefore, GARP implies the consumer spends all her money. Now suppose xj %R xk and

Profit Maximization

Profit Maximizing AssumptionThe firm’s objective is to choose a production vector on the trasformation frontieras to maximize profits given prices p ∈ Rn++:

maxy∈Y

p · y

or equivalentlymax p · y subject to F (y) ≤ 0

Does this distinguish between revenues and costs? How?

Using the single output production function:

maxx≥0

pf (x)− w · x

here p ∈ R++ is the price of output and w ∈ Rl++ is the price of inputs.

Page 66: GARP and Afriat™s Theorem Productionluca/ECON2100/2018Class/lecture_08.pdf · GARP cannot hold. Therefore, GARP implies the consumer spends all her money. Now suppose xj %R xk and

First Order Conditions For Profit Maximization

max p · y subject to F (y) = 0

Profit Maximizing

The FOC are

pi = λ∂F (y)

∂yifor each i or p︸︷︷︸

1×n

= λ∇F (y)︸ ︷︷ ︸1×n

in matrix form

Therefore1λ

=

∂F (y )∂yi

pifor each i

the marginal product per dollar spent or received is equal across all goods.

Using this formula for i and j :∂F (y )∂yi∂F (y )∂yj

= MRTi ,j =pipjfor each i , j

the Marginal Rate of Transformation equals the price ratio.

Page 67: GARP and Afriat™s Theorem Productionluca/ECON2100/2018Class/lecture_08.pdf · GARP cannot hold. Therefore, GARP implies the consumer spends all her money. Now suppose xj %R xk and

First Order Conditions For Profit Maximization

max p · y subject to F (y) = 0

Profit MaximizingThe FOC are

pi = λ∂F (y)

∂yifor each i or p︸︷︷︸

1×n

= λ∇F (y)︸ ︷︷ ︸1×n

in matrix form

Therefore1λ

=

∂F (y )∂yi

pifor each i

the marginal product per dollar spent or received is equal across all goods.

Using this formula for i and j :∂F (y )∂yi∂F (y )∂yj

= MRTi ,j =pipjfor each i , j

the Marginal Rate of Transformation equals the price ratio.

Page 68: GARP and Afriat™s Theorem Productionluca/ECON2100/2018Class/lecture_08.pdf · GARP cannot hold. Therefore, GARP implies the consumer spends all her money. Now suppose xj %R xk and

First Order Conditions For Profit Maximization

max p · y subject to F (y) = 0

Profit MaximizingThe FOC are

pi = λ∂F (y)

∂yifor each i or p︸︷︷︸

1×n

= λ∇F (y)︸ ︷︷ ︸1×n

in matrix form

Therefore1λ

=

∂F (y )∂yi

pifor each i

the marginal product per dollar spent or received is equal across all goods.

Using this formula for i and j :∂F (y )∂yi∂F (y )∂yj

= MRTi ,j =pipjfor each i , j

the Marginal Rate of Transformation equals the price ratio.

Page 69: GARP and Afriat™s Theorem Productionluca/ECON2100/2018Class/lecture_08.pdf · GARP cannot hold. Therefore, GARP implies the consumer spends all her money. Now suppose xj %R xk and

First Order Conditions For Profit Maximization

max p · y subject to F (y) = 0

Profit MaximizingThe FOC are

pi = λ∂F (y)

∂yifor each i or p︸︷︷︸

1×n

= λ∇F (y)︸ ︷︷ ︸1×n

in matrix form

Therefore1λ

=

∂F (y )∂yi

pifor each i

the marginal product per dollar spent or received is equal across all goods.

Using this formula for i and j :∂F (y )∂yi∂F (y )∂yj

= MRTi ,j =pipjfor each i , j

the Marginal Rate of Transformation equals the price ratio.

Page 70: GARP and Afriat™s Theorem Productionluca/ECON2100/2018Class/lecture_08.pdf · GARP cannot hold. Therefore, GARP implies the consumer spends all her money. Now suppose xj %R xk and

First Order Conditions For Profit Maximization

max p · y subject to F (y) = 0

Profit MaximizingThe FOC are

pi = λ∂F (y)

∂yifor each i or p︸︷︷︸

1×n

= λ∇F (y)︸ ︷︷ ︸1×n

in matrix form

Therefore1λ

=

∂F (y )∂yi

pifor each i

the marginal product per dollar spent or received is equal across all goods.

Using this formula for i and j :∂F (y )∂yi∂F (y )∂yj

= MRTi ,j =pipjfor each i , j

the Marginal Rate of Transformation equals the price ratio.

Page 71: GARP and Afriat™s Theorem Productionluca/ECON2100/2018Class/lecture_08.pdf · GARP cannot hold. Therefore, GARP implies the consumer spends all her money. Now suppose xj %R xk and

First Order Conditions For Profit Maximization

max p · y subject to F (y) = 0

Profit MaximizingThe FOC are

pi = λ∂F (y)

∂yifor each i or p︸︷︷︸

1×n

= λ∇F (y)︸ ︷︷ ︸1×n

in matrix form

Therefore1λ

=

∂F (y )∂yi

pifor each i

the marginal product per dollar spent or received is equal across all goods.

Using this formula for i and j :∂F (y )∂yi∂F (y )∂yj

= MRTi ,j =pipjfor each i , j

the Marginal Rate of Transformation equals the price ratio.

Page 72: GARP and Afriat™s Theorem Productionluca/ECON2100/2018Class/lecture_08.pdf · GARP cannot hold. Therefore, GARP implies the consumer spends all her money. Now suppose xj %R xk and

Supply Correspondence and Profit FunctionsDefinitionGiven a production set Y ⊆ Rn , the supply correspondence y∗ : Rn++ → Rn is:

y∗(p) = argmaxy∈Y

p · y .

Tracks the optimal choice as prices change (similar to Walrasian demand).

DefinitionGiven a production set Y ⊆ Rn , the profit function π : Rn++ → R is:

π(p) = maxy∈Y

p · y .

Tracks maximized profits as prices change (similar to indirect utility function).

Proposition

If Y satisfies non decreasing returns to scale either π(p) ≤ 0 or π(p) = +∞.

Proof.Question 6, Problem Set 5.

Page 73: GARP and Afriat™s Theorem Productionluca/ECON2100/2018Class/lecture_08.pdf · GARP cannot hold. Therefore, GARP implies the consumer spends all her money. Now suppose xj %R xk and

Supply Correspondence and Profit FunctionsDefinitionGiven a production set Y ⊆ Rn , the supply correspondence y∗ : Rn++ → Rn is:

y∗(p) = argmaxy∈Y

p · y .

Tracks the optimal choice as prices change (similar to Walrasian demand).

DefinitionGiven a production set Y ⊆ Rn , the profit function π : Rn++ → R is:

π(p) = maxy∈Y

p · y .

Tracks maximized profits as prices change (similar to indirect utility function).

Proposition

If Y satisfies non decreasing returns to scale either π(p) ≤ 0 or π(p) = +∞.

Proof.Question 6, Problem Set 5.

Page 74: GARP and Afriat™s Theorem Productionluca/ECON2100/2018Class/lecture_08.pdf · GARP cannot hold. Therefore, GARP implies the consumer spends all her money. Now suppose xj %R xk and

Supply Correspondence and Profit FunctionsDefinitionGiven a production set Y ⊆ Rn , the supply correspondence y∗ : Rn++ → Rn is:

y∗(p) = argmaxy∈Y

p · y .

Tracks the optimal choice as prices change (similar to Walrasian demand).

DefinitionGiven a production set Y ⊆ Rn , the profit function π : Rn++ → R is:

π(p) = maxy∈Y

p · y .

Tracks maximized profits as prices change (similar to indirect utility function).

Proposition

If Y satisfies non decreasing returns to scale either π(p) ≤ 0 or π(p) = +∞.

Proof.Question 6, Problem Set 5.

Page 75: GARP and Afriat™s Theorem Productionluca/ECON2100/2018Class/lecture_08.pdf · GARP cannot hold. Therefore, GARP implies the consumer spends all her money. Now suppose xj %R xk and

Supply Correspondence and Profit FunctionsDefinitionGiven a production set Y ⊆ Rn , the supply correspondence y∗ : Rn++ → Rn is:

y∗(p) = argmaxy∈Y

p · y .

Tracks the optimal choice as prices change (similar to Walrasian demand).

DefinitionGiven a production set Y ⊆ Rn , the profit function π : Rn++ → R is:

π(p) = maxy∈Y

p · y .

Tracks maximized profits as prices change (similar to indirect utility function).

Proposition

If Y satisfies non decreasing returns to scale either π(p) ≤ 0 or π(p) = +∞.

Proof.Question 6, Problem Set 5.

Page 76: GARP and Afriat™s Theorem Productionluca/ECON2100/2018Class/lecture_08.pdf · GARP cannot hold. Therefore, GARP implies the consumer spends all her money. Now suppose xj %R xk and

Supply Correspondence and Profit FunctionsDefinitionGiven a production set Y ⊆ Rn , the supply correspondence y∗ : Rn++ → Rn is:

y∗(p) = argmaxy∈Y

p · y .

Tracks the optimal choice as prices change (similar to Walrasian demand).

DefinitionGiven a production set Y ⊆ Rn , the profit function π : Rn++ → R is:

π(p) = maxy∈Y

p · y .

Tracks maximized profits as prices change (similar to indirect utility function).

Proposition

If Y satisfies non decreasing returns to scale either π(p) ≤ 0 or π(p) = +∞.

Proof.Question 6, Problem Set 5.

Page 77: GARP and Afriat™s Theorem Productionluca/ECON2100/2018Class/lecture_08.pdf · GARP cannot hold. Therefore, GARP implies the consumer spends all her money. Now suppose xj %R xk and

Properties of Supply and Profit Functions

PropositionSuppose Y is closed and satisfies free disposal. Then:

π(αp) = απ(p) for all α > 0;

π is convex in p;

y∗(αp) = y∗(p) for all α > 0;

if Y is convex, then y∗(p) is convex;

if |y∗(p)| = 1, then π is differentiable at p and ∇π(p) = y∗(p) (Hotelling’sLemma).

if y∗(p) is differentiable at p, then Dy∗(p) = D2π(p) is symmetric andpositive semidefinite with Dy∗(p)p = 0.

Page 78: GARP and Afriat™s Theorem Productionluca/ECON2100/2018Class/lecture_08.pdf · GARP cannot hold. Therefore, GARP implies the consumer spends all her money. Now suppose xj %R xk and

Properties of Supply and Profit Functions

PropositionSuppose Y is closed and satisfies free disposal. Then:

π(αp) = απ(p) for all α > 0;

π is convex in p;

y∗(αp) = y∗(p) for all α > 0;

if Y is convex, then y∗(p) is convex;

if |y∗(p)| = 1, then π is differentiable at p and ∇π(p) = y∗(p) (Hotelling’sLemma).

if y∗(p) is differentiable at p, then Dy∗(p) = D2π(p) is symmetric andpositive semidefinite with Dy∗(p)p = 0.

Page 79: GARP and Afriat™s Theorem Productionluca/ECON2100/2018Class/lecture_08.pdf · GARP cannot hold. Therefore, GARP implies the consumer spends all her money. Now suppose xj %R xk and

Properties of Supply and Profit Functions

PropositionSuppose Y is closed and satisfies free disposal. Then:

π(αp) = απ(p) for all α > 0;

π is convex in p;

y∗(αp) = y∗(p) for all α > 0;

if Y is convex, then y∗(p) is convex;

if |y∗(p)| = 1, then π is differentiable at p and ∇π(p) = y∗(p) (Hotelling’sLemma).

if y∗(p) is differentiable at p, then Dy∗(p) = D2π(p) is symmetric andpositive semidefinite with Dy∗(p)p = 0.

Page 80: GARP and Afriat™s Theorem Productionluca/ECON2100/2018Class/lecture_08.pdf · GARP cannot hold. Therefore, GARP implies the consumer spends all her money. Now suppose xj %R xk and

Properties of Supply and Profit Functions

PropositionSuppose Y is closed and satisfies free disposal. Then:

π(αp) = απ(p) for all α > 0;

π is convex in p;

y∗(αp) = y∗(p) for all α > 0;

if Y is convex, then y∗(p) is convex;

if |y∗(p)| = 1, then π is differentiable at p and ∇π(p) = y∗(p) (Hotelling’sLemma).

if y∗(p) is differentiable at p, then Dy∗(p) = D2π(p) is symmetric andpositive semidefinite with Dy∗(p)p = 0.

Page 81: GARP and Afriat™s Theorem Productionluca/ECON2100/2018Class/lecture_08.pdf · GARP cannot hold. Therefore, GARP implies the consumer spends all her money. Now suppose xj %R xk and

Properties of Supply and Profit Functions

PropositionSuppose Y is closed and satisfies free disposal. Then:

π(αp) = απ(p) for all α > 0;

π is convex in p;

y∗(αp) = y∗(p) for all α > 0;

if Y is convex, then y∗(p) is convex;

if |y∗(p)| = 1, then π is differentiable at p and ∇π(p) = y∗(p) (Hotelling’sLemma).

if y∗(p) is differentiable at p, then Dy∗(p) = D2π(p) is symmetric andpositive semidefinite with Dy∗(p)p = 0.

Page 82: GARP and Afriat™s Theorem Productionluca/ECON2100/2018Class/lecture_08.pdf · GARP cannot hold. Therefore, GARP implies the consumer spends all her money. Now suppose xj %R xk and

Properties of Supply and Profit Functions

PropositionSuppose Y is closed and satisfies free disposal. Then:

π(αp) = απ(p) for all α > 0;

π is convex in p;

y∗(αp) = y∗(p) for all α > 0;

if Y is convex, then y∗(p) is convex;

if |y∗(p)| = 1, then π is differentiable at p and ∇π(p) = y∗(p) (Hotelling’sLemma).

if y∗(p) is differentiable at p, then Dy∗(p) = D2π(p) is symmetric andpositive semidefinite with Dy∗(p)p = 0.

Page 83: GARP and Afriat™s Theorem Productionluca/ECON2100/2018Class/lecture_08.pdf · GARP cannot hold. Therefore, GARP implies the consumer spends all her money. Now suppose xj %R xk and

Properties of Supply and Profit Functions

PropositionSuppose Y is closed and satisfies free disposal. Then:

π(αp) = απ(p) for all α > 0;

π is convex in p;

y∗(αp) = y∗(p) for all α > 0;

if Y is convex, then y∗(p) is convex;

if |y∗(p)| = 1, then π is differentiable at p and ∇π(p) = y∗(p) (Hotelling’sLemma).

if y∗(p) is differentiable at p, then Dy∗(p) = D2π(p) is symmetric andpositive semidefinite with Dy∗(p)p = 0.

Page 84: GARP and Afriat™s Theorem Productionluca/ECON2100/2018Class/lecture_08.pdf · GARP cannot hold. Therefore, GARP implies the consumer spends all her money. Now suppose xj %R xk and

The Profit Function Is Convex

Proof.

Let p,p′ ∈ Rn++ and let the corresponding profit maximizing solutions be y and y′.

For any λ ∈ (0, 1) let p = λp + (1− λ) p′ and let y be the profit maximizingoutput vector when prices are p.

By “revealed preferences”

p · y ≥ p · y and p′ · y ′ ≥ p′ · y

why?

multiply these inequalities by λ and 1− λλp · y ≥ λp · y and (1− λ) p′ · y ′ ≥ (1− λ) p′ · y

summing up

λp · y + (1− λ) p′ · y ′ ≥ [λp + (1− λ) p′] · yusing the definition of profit function:

λπ (p) + (1− λ)π (p′) ≥ π (λp + (1− λ) p′)

proving convexity of π (p).

Page 85: GARP and Afriat™s Theorem Productionluca/ECON2100/2018Class/lecture_08.pdf · GARP cannot hold. Therefore, GARP implies the consumer spends all her money. Now suppose xj %R xk and

The Profit Function Is Convex

Proof.

Let p,p′ ∈ Rn++ and let the corresponding profit maximizing solutions be y and y′.

For any λ ∈ (0, 1) let p = λp + (1− λ) p′ and let y be the profit maximizingoutput vector when prices are p.

By “revealed preferences”

p · y ≥ p · y and p′ · y ′ ≥ p′ · y

why?

multiply these inequalities by λ and 1− λλp · y ≥ λp · y and (1− λ) p′ · y ′ ≥ (1− λ) p′ · y

summing up

λp · y + (1− λ) p′ · y ′ ≥ [λp + (1− λ) p′] · yusing the definition of profit function:

λπ (p) + (1− λ)π (p′) ≥ π (λp + (1− λ) p′)

proving convexity of π (p).

Page 86: GARP and Afriat™s Theorem Productionluca/ECON2100/2018Class/lecture_08.pdf · GARP cannot hold. Therefore, GARP implies the consumer spends all her money. Now suppose xj %R xk and

The Profit Function Is Convex

Proof.

Let p,p′ ∈ Rn++ and let the corresponding profit maximizing solutions be y and y′.

For any λ ∈ (0, 1) let p = λp + (1− λ) p′ and let y be the profit maximizingoutput vector when prices are p.

By “revealed preferences”

p · y ≥ p · y and p′ · y ′ ≥ p′ · y

why?

multiply these inequalities by λ and 1− λλp · y ≥ λp · y and (1− λ) p′ · y ′ ≥ (1− λ) p′ · y

summing up

λp · y + (1− λ) p′ · y ′ ≥ [λp + (1− λ) p′] · yusing the definition of profit function:

λπ (p) + (1− λ)π (p′) ≥ π (λp + (1− λ) p′)

proving convexity of π (p).

Page 87: GARP and Afriat™s Theorem Productionluca/ECON2100/2018Class/lecture_08.pdf · GARP cannot hold. Therefore, GARP implies the consumer spends all her money. Now suppose xj %R xk and

The Profit Function Is Convex

Proof.

Let p,p′ ∈ Rn++ and let the corresponding profit maximizing solutions be y and y′.

For any λ ∈ (0, 1) let p = λp + (1− λ) p′ and let y be the profit maximizingoutput vector when prices are p.

By “revealed preferences”

p · y ≥ p · y and p′ · y ′ ≥ p′ · y

why?

multiply these inequalities by λ and 1− λλp · y ≥ λp · y and (1− λ) p′ · y ′ ≥ (1− λ) p′ · y

summing up

λp · y + (1− λ) p′ · y ′ ≥ [λp + (1− λ) p′] · yusing the definition of profit function:

λπ (p) + (1− λ)π (p′) ≥ π (λp + (1− λ) p′)

proving convexity of π (p).

Page 88: GARP and Afriat™s Theorem Productionluca/ECON2100/2018Class/lecture_08.pdf · GARP cannot hold. Therefore, GARP implies the consumer spends all her money. Now suppose xj %R xk and

The Profit Function Is Convex

Proof.

Let p,p′ ∈ Rn++ and let the corresponding profit maximizing solutions be y and y′.

For any λ ∈ (0, 1) let p = λp + (1− λ) p′ and let y be the profit maximizingoutput vector when prices are p.

By “revealed preferences”

p · y ≥ p · y and p′ · y ′ ≥ p′ · y

why?

multiply these inequalities by λ and 1− λλp · y ≥ λp · y and (1− λ) p′ · y ′ ≥ (1− λ) p′ · y

summing up

λp · y + (1− λ) p′ · y ′ ≥ [λp + (1− λ) p′] · yusing the definition of profit function:

λπ (p) + (1− λ)π (p′) ≥ π (λp + (1− λ) p′)

proving convexity of π (p).

Page 89: GARP and Afriat™s Theorem Productionluca/ECON2100/2018Class/lecture_08.pdf · GARP cannot hold. Therefore, GARP implies the consumer spends all her money. Now suppose xj %R xk and

The Profit Function Is Convex

Proof.

Let p,p′ ∈ Rn++ and let the corresponding profit maximizing solutions be y and y′.

For any λ ∈ (0, 1) let p = λp + (1− λ) p′ and let y be the profit maximizingoutput vector when prices are p.

By “revealed preferences”

p · y ≥ p · y and p′ · y ′ ≥ p′ · y

why?

multiply these inequalities by λ and 1− λλp · y ≥ λp · y and (1− λ) p′ · y ′ ≥ (1− λ) p′ · y

summing up

λp · y + (1− λ) p′ · y ′ ≥ [λp + (1− λ) p′] · y

using the definition of profit function:

λπ (p) + (1− λ)π (p′) ≥ π (λp + (1− λ) p′)

proving convexity of π (p).

Page 90: GARP and Afriat™s Theorem Productionluca/ECON2100/2018Class/lecture_08.pdf · GARP cannot hold. Therefore, GARP implies the consumer spends all her money. Now suppose xj %R xk and

The Profit Function Is Convex

Proof.

Let p,p′ ∈ Rn++ and let the corresponding profit maximizing solutions be y and y′.

For any λ ∈ (0, 1) let p = λp + (1− λ) p′ and let y be the profit maximizingoutput vector when prices are p.

By “revealed preferences”

p · y ≥ p · y and p′ · y ′ ≥ p′ · y

why?

multiply these inequalities by λ and 1− λλp · y ≥ λp · y and (1− λ) p′ · y ′ ≥ (1− λ) p′ · y

summing up

λp · y + (1− λ) p′ · y ′ ≥ [λp + (1− λ) p′] · yusing the definition of profit function:

λπ (p) + (1− λ)π (p′) ≥ π (λp + (1− λ) p′)

proving convexity of π (p).

Page 91: GARP and Afriat™s Theorem Productionluca/ECON2100/2018Class/lecture_08.pdf · GARP cannot hold. Therefore, GARP implies the consumer spends all her money. Now suppose xj %R xk and

The Supply Correspondence Is Convex

Proof.

Let p ∈ Rn++ and let y , y′ ∈ y∗(p).

We need to show that if Y is convex then

λy + (1− λ) y ′ ∈ y∗(p) for any λ ∈ (0, 1)

By definition:

p · y ≥ p · y for any y ∈ Y and p · y ′ ≥ p · y for any y ∈ Y

multiplying by λ and 1− λ we getλp · y ≥ λp · y and (1− λ) p · y ′ ≥ (1− λ) p · y

Therefore, summing up, we have

λp · y + (1− λ) p · y ′ ≥ [λ+ (1− λ)] p · yRearranging:

p · [λy + (1− λ) y ′] ≥ p · yproving convexity of y∗(p).

Page 92: GARP and Afriat™s Theorem Productionluca/ECON2100/2018Class/lecture_08.pdf · GARP cannot hold. Therefore, GARP implies the consumer spends all her money. Now suppose xj %R xk and

The Supply Correspondence Is Convex

Proof.

Let p ∈ Rn++ and let y , y′ ∈ y∗(p).

We need to show that if Y is convex then

λy + (1− λ) y ′ ∈ y∗(p) for any λ ∈ (0, 1)

By definition:

p · y ≥ p · y for any y ∈ Y

and p · y ′ ≥ p · y for any y ∈ Y

multiplying by λ and 1− λ we getλp · y ≥ λp · y and (1− λ) p · y ′ ≥ (1− λ) p · y

Therefore, summing up, we have

λp · y + (1− λ) p · y ′ ≥ [λ+ (1− λ)] p · yRearranging:

p · [λy + (1− λ) y ′] ≥ p · yproving convexity of y∗(p).

Page 93: GARP and Afriat™s Theorem Productionluca/ECON2100/2018Class/lecture_08.pdf · GARP cannot hold. Therefore, GARP implies the consumer spends all her money. Now suppose xj %R xk and

The Supply Correspondence Is Convex

Proof.

Let p ∈ Rn++ and let y , y′ ∈ y∗(p).

We need to show that if Y is convex then

λy + (1− λ) y ′ ∈ y∗(p) for any λ ∈ (0, 1)

By definition:

p · y ≥ p · y for any y ∈ Y

and p · y ′ ≥ p · y for any y ∈ Y

multiplying by λ and 1− λ we getλp · y ≥ λp · y and (1− λ) p · y ′ ≥ (1− λ) p · y

Therefore, summing up, we have

λp · y + (1− λ) p · y ′ ≥ [λ+ (1− λ)] p · yRearranging:

p · [λy + (1− λ) y ′] ≥ p · yproving convexity of y∗(p).

Page 94: GARP and Afriat™s Theorem Productionluca/ECON2100/2018Class/lecture_08.pdf · GARP cannot hold. Therefore, GARP implies the consumer spends all her money. Now suppose xj %R xk and

The Supply Correspondence Is Convex

Proof.

Let p ∈ Rn++ and let y , y′ ∈ y∗(p).

We need to show that if Y is convex then

λy + (1− λ) y ′ ∈ y∗(p) for any λ ∈ (0, 1)

By definition:

p · y ≥ p · y for any y ∈ Y and p · y ′ ≥ p · y for any y ∈ Y

multiplying by λ and 1− λ we getλp · y ≥ λp · y and (1− λ) p · y ′ ≥ (1− λ) p · y

Therefore, summing up, we have

λp · y + (1− λ) p · y ′ ≥ [λ+ (1− λ)] p · yRearranging:

p · [λy + (1− λ) y ′] ≥ p · yproving convexity of y∗(p).

Page 95: GARP and Afriat™s Theorem Productionluca/ECON2100/2018Class/lecture_08.pdf · GARP cannot hold. Therefore, GARP implies the consumer spends all her money. Now suppose xj %R xk and

The Supply Correspondence Is Convex

Proof.

Let p ∈ Rn++ and let y , y′ ∈ y∗(p).

We need to show that if Y is convex then

λy + (1− λ) y ′ ∈ y∗(p) for any λ ∈ (0, 1)

By definition:

p · y ≥ p · y for any y ∈ Y and p · y ′ ≥ p · y for any y ∈ Y

multiplying by λ and 1− λ we getλp · y ≥ λp · y and (1− λ) p · y ′ ≥ (1− λ) p · y

Therefore, summing up, we have

λp · y + (1− λ) p · y ′ ≥ [λ+ (1− λ)] p · yRearranging:

p · [λy + (1− λ) y ′] ≥ p · yproving convexity of y∗(p).

Page 96: GARP and Afriat™s Theorem Productionluca/ECON2100/2018Class/lecture_08.pdf · GARP cannot hold. Therefore, GARP implies the consumer spends all her money. Now suppose xj %R xk and

The Supply Correspondence Is Convex

Proof.

Let p ∈ Rn++ and let y , y′ ∈ y∗(p).

We need to show that if Y is convex then

λy + (1− λ) y ′ ∈ y∗(p) for any λ ∈ (0, 1)

By definition:

p · y ≥ p · y for any y ∈ Y and p · y ′ ≥ p · y for any y ∈ Y

multiplying by λ and 1− λ we getλp · y ≥ λp · y and (1− λ) p · y ′ ≥ (1− λ) p · y

Therefore, summing up, we have

λp · y + (1− λ) p · y ′ ≥ [λ+ (1− λ)] p · y

Rearranging:p · [λy + (1− λ) y ′] ≥ p · y

proving convexity of y∗(p).

Page 97: GARP and Afriat™s Theorem Productionluca/ECON2100/2018Class/lecture_08.pdf · GARP cannot hold. Therefore, GARP implies the consumer spends all her money. Now suppose xj %R xk and

The Supply Correspondence Is Convex

Proof.

Let p ∈ Rn++ and let y , y′ ∈ y∗(p).

We need to show that if Y is convex then

λy + (1− λ) y ′ ∈ y∗(p) for any λ ∈ (0, 1)

By definition:

p · y ≥ p · y for any y ∈ Y and p · y ′ ≥ p · y for any y ∈ Y

multiplying by λ and 1− λ we getλp · y ≥ λp · y and (1− λ) p · y ′ ≥ (1− λ) p · y

Therefore, summing up, we have

λp · y + (1− λ) p · y ′ ≥ [λ+ (1− λ)] p · yRearranging:

p · [λy + (1− λ) y ′] ≥ p · yproving convexity of y∗(p).

Page 98: GARP and Afriat™s Theorem Productionluca/ECON2100/2018Class/lecture_08.pdf · GARP cannot hold. Therefore, GARP implies the consumer spends all her money. Now suppose xj %R xk and

Hotelling’s Lemmaif |y∗(p)| = 1, then π is differentiable at p and ∇π(p) = y∗(p)

Proof.

Suppose y∗(p) is the unique solution to max p · y subject to F (y) = 0.

The Envelope Theorem says

Dqφ(x∗(q); q) = Dqφ(x , q)|x=x∗(q),q=q − [λ∗(q)]> DqF (x , q)|x=x∗(q),q=q

In our setting,

φ(x , q) = p · y ,F (x , q) = F (y ), andφ(x∗(q); q) = π(p).

Thus, by the envelope theorem:

∇π(p) = Dp(p · y)|y=y∗(p)−[λ∗(p)]> DpF (y)|y=y∗(p)

= y |y=y∗(p)−[λ∗(p)]> 0

because p · y is linear in p and DpF (y ) = 0.

Therefore∇π(p) = y∗(p)

as desired.

Page 99: GARP and Afriat™s Theorem Productionluca/ECON2100/2018Class/lecture_08.pdf · GARP cannot hold. Therefore, GARP implies the consumer spends all her money. Now suppose xj %R xk and

Hotelling’s Lemmaif |y∗(p)| = 1, then π is differentiable at p and ∇π(p) = y∗(p)

Proof.

Suppose y∗(p) is the unique solution to max p · y subject to F (y) = 0.

The Envelope Theorem says

Dqφ(x∗(q); q) = Dqφ(x , q)|x=x∗(q),q=q − [λ∗(q)]> DqF (x , q)|x=x∗(q),q=q

In our setting,

φ(x , q) = p · y ,F (x , q) = F (y ), andφ(x∗(q); q) = π(p).

Thus, by the envelope theorem:

∇π(p) = Dp(p · y)|y=y∗(p)−[λ∗(p)]> DpF (y)|y=y∗(p)

= y |y=y∗(p)−[λ∗(p)]> 0

because p · y is linear in p and DpF (y ) = 0.

Therefore∇π(p) = y∗(p)

as desired.

Page 100: GARP and Afriat™s Theorem Productionluca/ECON2100/2018Class/lecture_08.pdf · GARP cannot hold. Therefore, GARP implies the consumer spends all her money. Now suppose xj %R xk and

Hotelling’s Lemmaif |y∗(p)| = 1, then π is differentiable at p and ∇π(p) = y∗(p)

Proof.

Suppose y∗(p) is the unique solution to max p · y subject to F (y) = 0.

The Envelope Theorem says

Dqφ(x∗(q); q) = Dqφ(x , q)|x=x∗(q),q=q − [λ∗(q)]> DqF (x , q)|x=x∗(q),q=q

In our setting,

φ(x , q) = p · y ,F (x , q) = F (y ), andφ(x∗(q); q) = π(p).

Thus, by the envelope theorem:

∇π(p) = Dp(p · y)|y=y∗(p)−[λ∗(p)]> DpF (y)|y=y∗(p)

= y |y=y∗(p)−[λ∗(p)]> 0

because p · y is linear in p and DpF (y ) = 0.

Therefore∇π(p) = y∗(p)

as desired.

Page 101: GARP and Afriat™s Theorem Productionluca/ECON2100/2018Class/lecture_08.pdf · GARP cannot hold. Therefore, GARP implies the consumer spends all her money. Now suppose xj %R xk and

Hotelling’s Lemmaif |y∗(p)| = 1, then π is differentiable at p and ∇π(p) = y∗(p)

Proof.

Suppose y∗(p) is the unique solution to max p · y subject to F (y) = 0.

The Envelope Theorem says

Dqφ(x∗(q); q) = Dqφ(x , q)|x=x∗(q),q=q − [λ∗(q)]> DqF (x , q)|x=x∗(q),q=q

In our setting,

φ(x , q) = p · y ,

F (x , q) = F (y ), andφ(x∗(q); q) = π(p).

Thus, by the envelope theorem:

∇π(p) = Dp(p · y)|y=y∗(p)−[λ∗(p)]> DpF (y)|y=y∗(p)

= y |y=y∗(p)−[λ∗(p)]> 0

because p · y is linear in p and DpF (y ) = 0.

Therefore∇π(p) = y∗(p)

as desired.

Page 102: GARP and Afriat™s Theorem Productionluca/ECON2100/2018Class/lecture_08.pdf · GARP cannot hold. Therefore, GARP implies the consumer spends all her money. Now suppose xj %R xk and

Hotelling’s Lemmaif |y∗(p)| = 1, then π is differentiable at p and ∇π(p) = y∗(p)

Proof.

Suppose y∗(p) is the unique solution to max p · y subject to F (y) = 0.

The Envelope Theorem says

Dqφ(x∗(q); q) = Dqφ(x , q)|x=x∗(q),q=q − [λ∗(q)]> DqF (x , q)|x=x∗(q),q=q

In our setting,

φ(x , q) = p · y ,F (x , q) = F (y ), and

φ(x∗(q); q) = π(p).

Thus, by the envelope theorem:

∇π(p) = Dp(p · y)|y=y∗(p)−[λ∗(p)]> DpF (y)|y=y∗(p)

= y |y=y∗(p)−[λ∗(p)]> 0

because p · y is linear in p and DpF (y ) = 0.

Therefore∇π(p) = y∗(p)

as desired.

Page 103: GARP and Afriat™s Theorem Productionluca/ECON2100/2018Class/lecture_08.pdf · GARP cannot hold. Therefore, GARP implies the consumer spends all her money. Now suppose xj %R xk and

Hotelling’s Lemmaif |y∗(p)| = 1, then π is differentiable at p and ∇π(p) = y∗(p)

Proof.

Suppose y∗(p) is the unique solution to max p · y subject to F (y) = 0.

The Envelope Theorem says

Dqφ(x∗(q); q) = Dqφ(x , q)|x=x∗(q),q=q − [λ∗(q)]> DqF (x , q)|x=x∗(q),q=q

In our setting,

φ(x , q) = p · y ,F (x , q) = F (y ), andφ(x∗(q); q) = π(p).

Thus, by the envelope theorem:

∇π(p) = Dp(p · y)|y=y∗(p)−[λ∗(p)]> DpF (y)|y=y∗(p)

= y |y=y∗(p)−[λ∗(p)]> 0

because p · y is linear in p and DpF (y ) = 0.

Therefore∇π(p) = y∗(p)

as desired.

Page 104: GARP and Afriat™s Theorem Productionluca/ECON2100/2018Class/lecture_08.pdf · GARP cannot hold. Therefore, GARP implies the consumer spends all her money. Now suppose xj %R xk and

Hotelling’s Lemmaif |y∗(p)| = 1, then π is differentiable at p and ∇π(p) = y∗(p)

Proof.

Suppose y∗(p) is the unique solution to max p · y subject to F (y) = 0.

The Envelope Theorem says

Dqφ(x∗(q); q) = Dqφ(x , q)|x=x∗(q),q=q − [λ∗(q)]> DqF (x , q)|x=x∗(q),q=q

In our setting,

φ(x , q) = p · y ,F (x , q) = F (y ), andφ(x∗(q); q) = π(p).

Thus, by the envelope theorem:

∇π(p) = Dp(p · y)|y=y∗(p)−[λ∗(p)]> DpF (y)|y=y∗(p)

= y |y=y∗(p)−[λ∗(p)]> 0

because p · y is linear in p and DpF (y ) = 0.

Therefore∇π(p) = y∗(p)

as desired.

Page 105: GARP and Afriat™s Theorem Productionluca/ECON2100/2018Class/lecture_08.pdf · GARP cannot hold. Therefore, GARP implies the consumer spends all her money. Now suppose xj %R xk and

Hotelling’s Lemmaif |y∗(p)| = 1, then π is differentiable at p and ∇π(p) = y∗(p)

Proof.

Suppose y∗(p) is the unique solution to max p · y subject to F (y) = 0.

The Envelope Theorem says

Dqφ(x∗(q); q) = Dqφ(x , q)|x=x∗(q),q=q − [λ∗(q)]> DqF (x , q)|x=x∗(q),q=q

In our setting,

φ(x , q) = p · y ,F (x , q) = F (y ), andφ(x∗(q); q) = π(p).

Thus, by the envelope theorem:

∇π(p) = Dp(p · y)|y=y∗(p)−[λ∗(p)]> DpF (y)|y=y∗(p) = y |y=y∗(p)−[λ∗(p)]

> 0

because p · y is linear in p and DpF (y ) = 0.

Therefore∇π(p) = y∗(p)

as desired.

Page 106: GARP and Afriat™s Theorem Productionluca/ECON2100/2018Class/lecture_08.pdf · GARP cannot hold. Therefore, GARP implies the consumer spends all her money. Now suppose xj %R xk and

Hotelling’s Lemmaif |y∗(p)| = 1, then π is differentiable at p and ∇π(p) = y∗(p)

Proof.

Suppose y∗(p) is the unique solution to max p · y subject to F (y) = 0.

The Envelope Theorem says

Dqφ(x∗(q); q) = Dqφ(x , q)|x=x∗(q),q=q − [λ∗(q)]> DqF (x , q)|x=x∗(q),q=q

In our setting,

φ(x , q) = p · y ,F (x , q) = F (y ), andφ(x∗(q); q) = π(p).

Thus, by the envelope theorem:

∇π(p) = Dp(p · y)|y=y∗(p)−[λ∗(p)]> DpF (y)|y=y∗(p) = y |y=y∗(p)−[λ∗(p)]

> 0

because p · y is linear in p and DpF (y ) = 0.

Therefore∇π(p) = y∗(p)

as desired.

Page 107: GARP and Afriat™s Theorem Productionluca/ECON2100/2018Class/lecture_08.pdf · GARP cannot hold. Therefore, GARP implies the consumer spends all her money. Now suppose xj %R xk and

Hotelling’s Lemmaif |y∗(p)| = 1, then π is differentiable at p and ∇π(p) = y∗(p)

Proof.

Suppose y∗(p) is the unique solution to max p · y subject to F (y) = 0.

The Envelope Theorem says

Dqφ(x∗(q); q) = Dqφ(x , q)|x=x∗(q),q=q − [λ∗(q)]> DqF (x , q)|x=x∗(q),q=q

In our setting,

φ(x , q) = p · y ,F (x , q) = F (y ), andφ(x∗(q); q) = π(p).

Thus, by the envelope theorem:

∇π(p) = Dp(p · y)|y=y∗(p)−[λ∗(p)]> DpF (y)|y=y∗(p) = y |y=y∗(p)−[λ∗(p)]

> 0

because p · y is linear in p and DpF (y ) = 0.

Therefore∇π(p) = y∗(p)

as desired.

Page 108: GARP and Afriat™s Theorem Productionluca/ECON2100/2018Class/lecture_08.pdf · GARP cannot hold. Therefore, GARP implies the consumer spends all her money. Now suppose xj %R xk and

Law of SupplyRemark

If y∗(p) is differentiable at p, then Dy∗(p) = D2π(p) is positive semidefinite.

Write the LagrangianL = p · y − λF (y)

By the Envelope Theorem:∂π(p)

∂pi=

∂L∂pi

∣∣∣∣y=y∗

= y∗i (p)

Therefore, we have∂2π(p)

∂pi=∂y∗i (p)

∂pi≥ 0

where the inequality follows from convexity of the profit function.

This is called the Law of Supply: quantity responds in the same direction asprices.

Notice that here yi can be either input or output.

What does this mean for outputs?What does this mean for inputs?

Page 109: GARP and Afriat™s Theorem Productionluca/ECON2100/2018Class/lecture_08.pdf · GARP cannot hold. Therefore, GARP implies the consumer spends all her money. Now suppose xj %R xk and

Law of SupplyRemark

If y∗(p) is differentiable at p, then Dy∗(p) = D2π(p) is positive semidefinite.

Write the LagrangianL = p · y − λF (y)

By the Envelope Theorem:∂π(p)

∂pi=

∂L∂pi

∣∣∣∣y=y∗

= y∗i (p)

Therefore, we have∂2π(p)

∂pi=∂y∗i (p)

∂pi≥ 0

where the inequality follows from convexity of the profit function.

This is called the Law of Supply: quantity responds in the same direction asprices.

Notice that here yi can be either input or output.

What does this mean for outputs?What does this mean for inputs?

Page 110: GARP and Afriat™s Theorem Productionluca/ECON2100/2018Class/lecture_08.pdf · GARP cannot hold. Therefore, GARP implies the consumer spends all her money. Now suppose xj %R xk and

Law of SupplyRemark

If y∗(p) is differentiable at p, then Dy∗(p) = D2π(p) is positive semidefinite.

Write the LagrangianL = p · y − λF (y)

By the Envelope Theorem:∂π(p)

∂pi=

∂L∂pi

∣∣∣∣y=y∗

= y∗i (p)

Therefore, we have∂2π(p)

∂pi=∂y∗i (p)

∂pi

≥ 0

where the inequality follows from convexity of the profit function.

This is called the Law of Supply: quantity responds in the same direction asprices.

Notice that here yi can be either input or output.

What does this mean for outputs?What does this mean for inputs?

Page 111: GARP and Afriat™s Theorem Productionluca/ECON2100/2018Class/lecture_08.pdf · GARP cannot hold. Therefore, GARP implies the consumer spends all her money. Now suppose xj %R xk and

Law of SupplyRemark

If y∗(p) is differentiable at p, then Dy∗(p) = D2π(p) is positive semidefinite.

Write the LagrangianL = p · y − λF (y)

By the Envelope Theorem:∂π(p)

∂pi=

∂L∂pi

∣∣∣∣y=y∗

= y∗i (p)

Therefore, we have∂2π(p)

∂pi=∂y∗i (p)

∂pi

≥ 0

where the inequality follows from convexity of the profit function.

This is called the Law of Supply: quantity responds in the same direction asprices.

Notice that here yi can be either input or output.

What does this mean for outputs?What does this mean for inputs?

Page 112: GARP and Afriat™s Theorem Productionluca/ECON2100/2018Class/lecture_08.pdf · GARP cannot hold. Therefore, GARP implies the consumer spends all her money. Now suppose xj %R xk and

Law of SupplyRemark

If y∗(p) is differentiable at p, then Dy∗(p) = D2π(p) is positive semidefinite.

Write the LagrangianL = p · y − λF (y)

By the Envelope Theorem:∂π(p)

∂pi=

∂L∂pi

∣∣∣∣y=y∗

= y∗i (p)

Therefore, we have∂2π(p)

∂pi=∂y∗i (p)

∂pi≥ 0

where the inequality follows from convexity of the profit function.

This is called the Law of Supply: quantity responds in the same direction asprices.

Notice that here yi can be either input or output.

What does this mean for outputs?What does this mean for inputs?

Page 113: GARP and Afriat™s Theorem Productionluca/ECON2100/2018Class/lecture_08.pdf · GARP cannot hold. Therefore, GARP implies the consumer spends all her money. Now suppose xj %R xk and

Law of SupplyRemark

If y∗(p) is differentiable at p, then Dy∗(p) = D2π(p) is positive semidefinite.

Write the LagrangianL = p · y − λF (y)

By the Envelope Theorem:∂π(p)

∂pi=

∂L∂pi

∣∣∣∣y=y∗

= y∗i (p)

Therefore, we have∂2π(p)

∂pi=∂y∗i (p)

∂pi≥ 0

where the inequality follows from convexity of the profit function.

This is called the Law of Supply: quantity responds in the same direction asprices.

Notice that here yi can be either input or output.

What does this mean for outputs?What does this mean for inputs?

Page 114: GARP and Afriat™s Theorem Productionluca/ECON2100/2018Class/lecture_08.pdf · GARP cannot hold. Therefore, GARP implies the consumer spends all her money. Now suppose xj %R xk and

Law of SupplyRemark

If y∗(p) is differentiable at p, then Dy∗(p) = D2π(p) is positive semidefinite.

Write the LagrangianL = p · y − λF (y)

By the Envelope Theorem:∂π(p)

∂pi=

∂L∂pi

∣∣∣∣y=y∗

= y∗i (p)

Therefore, we have∂2π(p)

∂pi=∂y∗i (p)

∂pi≥ 0

where the inequality follows from convexity of the profit function.

This is called the Law of Supply: quantity responds in the same direction asprices.

Notice that here yi can be either input or output.

What does this mean for outputs?What does this mean for inputs?

Page 115: GARP and Afriat™s Theorem Productionluca/ECON2100/2018Class/lecture_08.pdf · GARP cannot hold. Therefore, GARP implies the consumer spends all her money. Now suppose xj %R xk and

Law of SupplyRemark

If y∗(p) is differentiable at p, then Dy∗(p) = D2π(p) is positive semidefinite.

Write the LagrangianL = p · y − λF (y)

By the Envelope Theorem:∂π(p)

∂pi=

∂L∂pi

∣∣∣∣y=y∗

= y∗i (p)

Therefore, we have∂2π(p)

∂pi=∂y∗i (p)

∂pi≥ 0

where the inequality follows from convexity of the profit function.

This is called the Law of Supply: quantity responds in the same direction asprices.

Notice that here yi can be either input or output.

What does this mean for outputs?What does this mean for inputs?

Page 116: GARP and Afriat™s Theorem Productionluca/ECON2100/2018Class/lecture_08.pdf · GARP cannot hold. Therefore, GARP implies the consumer spends all her money. Now suppose xj %R xk and

Law of SupplyRemark

If y∗(p) is differentiable at p, then Dy∗(p) = D2π(p) is positive semidefinite.

Write the LagrangianL = p · y − λF (y)

By the Envelope Theorem:∂π(p)

∂pi=

∂L∂pi

∣∣∣∣y=y∗

= y∗i (p)

Therefore, we have∂2π(p)

∂pi=∂y∗i (p)

∂pi≥ 0

where the inequality follows from convexity of the profit function.

This is called the Law of Supply: quantity responds in the same direction asprices.

Notice that here yi can be either input or output.What does this mean for outputs?

What does this mean for inputs?

Page 117: GARP and Afriat™s Theorem Productionluca/ECON2100/2018Class/lecture_08.pdf · GARP cannot hold. Therefore, GARP implies the consumer spends all her money. Now suppose xj %R xk and

Law of SupplyRemark

If y∗(p) is differentiable at p, then Dy∗(p) = D2π(p) is positive semidefinite.

Write the LagrangianL = p · y − λF (y)

By the Envelope Theorem:∂π(p)

∂pi=

∂L∂pi

∣∣∣∣y=y∗

= y∗i (p)

Therefore, we have∂2π(p)

∂pi=∂y∗i (p)

∂pi≥ 0

where the inequality follows from convexity of the profit function.

This is called the Law of Supply: quantity responds in the same direction asprices.

Notice that here yi can be either input or output.What does this mean for outputs?What does this mean for inputs?

Page 118: GARP and Afriat™s Theorem Productionluca/ECON2100/2018Class/lecture_08.pdf · GARP cannot hold. Therefore, GARP implies the consumer spends all her money. Now suppose xj %R xk and

Factor Demand, Supply, and Profit Function

The previous concepts can be stated using the production function notation.

DefinitionGiven p ∈ R++ and w ∈ Rn++ and a production function f : Rn+ → R+, the firm’sfactor demand is

x∗ (p,w) = argmaxx{py − w · x subject to f (x) = y} = argmax

xpf (x)− w · x .

DefinitionGiven p ∈ R++ and w ∈ Rn++ and a production function f : Rn+ → R+, the firm’ssupply y∗ : Rn+ → R is defined by

y∗(p,w) = f (x∗ (p,w)) .

DefinitionGiven p ∈ R++ and w ∈ Rn++ and a production function f : Rn+ → R+, the firm’sprofit function π : R++ × Rn++ → R is defined by

π(p,w) = py∗(p,w)− w · x∗ (p,w) .

Page 119: GARP and Afriat™s Theorem Productionluca/ECON2100/2018Class/lecture_08.pdf · GARP cannot hold. Therefore, GARP implies the consumer spends all her money. Now suppose xj %R xk and

Factor Demand, Supply, and Profit Function

The previous concepts can be stated using the production function notation.

DefinitionGiven p ∈ R++ and w ∈ Rn++ and a production function f : Rn+ → R+, the firm’sfactor demand is

x∗ (p,w) = argmaxx{py − w · x subject to f (x) = y}

= argmaxxpf (x)− w · x .

DefinitionGiven p ∈ R++ and w ∈ Rn++ and a production function f : Rn+ → R+, the firm’ssupply y∗ : Rn+ → R is defined by

y∗(p,w) = f (x∗ (p,w)) .

DefinitionGiven p ∈ R++ and w ∈ Rn++ and a production function f : Rn+ → R+, the firm’sprofit function π : R++ × Rn++ → R is defined by

π(p,w) = py∗(p,w)− w · x∗ (p,w) .

Page 120: GARP and Afriat™s Theorem Productionluca/ECON2100/2018Class/lecture_08.pdf · GARP cannot hold. Therefore, GARP implies the consumer spends all her money. Now suppose xj %R xk and

Factor Demand, Supply, and Profit Function

The previous concepts can be stated using the production function notation.

DefinitionGiven p ∈ R++ and w ∈ Rn++ and a production function f : Rn+ → R+, the firm’sfactor demand is

x∗ (p,w) = argmaxx{py − w · x subject to f (x) = y} = argmax

xpf (x)− w · x .

DefinitionGiven p ∈ R++ and w ∈ Rn++ and a production function f : Rn+ → R+, the firm’ssupply y∗ : Rn+ → R is defined by

y∗(p,w) = f (x∗ (p,w)) .

DefinitionGiven p ∈ R++ and w ∈ Rn++ and a production function f : Rn+ → R+, the firm’sprofit function π : R++ × Rn++ → R is defined by

π(p,w) = py∗(p,w)− w · x∗ (p,w) .

Page 121: GARP and Afriat™s Theorem Productionluca/ECON2100/2018Class/lecture_08.pdf · GARP cannot hold. Therefore, GARP implies the consumer spends all her money. Now suppose xj %R xk and

Factor Demand, Supply, and Profit Function

The previous concepts can be stated using the production function notation.

DefinitionGiven p ∈ R++ and w ∈ Rn++ and a production function f : Rn+ → R+, the firm’sfactor demand is

x∗ (p,w) = argmaxx{py − w · x subject to f (x) = y} = argmax

xpf (x)− w · x .

DefinitionGiven p ∈ R++ and w ∈ Rn++ and a production function f : Rn+ → R+, the firm’ssupply y∗ : Rn+ → R is defined by

y∗(p,w) = f (x∗ (p,w)) .

DefinitionGiven p ∈ R++ and w ∈ Rn++ and a production function f : Rn+ → R+, the firm’sprofit function π : R++ × Rn++ → R is defined by

π(p,w) = py∗(p,w)− w · x∗ (p,w) .

Page 122: GARP and Afriat™s Theorem Productionluca/ECON2100/2018Class/lecture_08.pdf · GARP cannot hold. Therefore, GARP implies the consumer spends all her money. Now suppose xj %R xk and

Factor Demand, Supply, and Profit Function

The previous concepts can be stated using the production function notation.

DefinitionGiven p ∈ R++ and w ∈ Rn++ and a production function f : Rn+ → R+, the firm’sfactor demand is

x∗ (p,w) = argmaxx{py − w · x subject to f (x) = y} = argmax

xpf (x)− w · x .

DefinitionGiven p ∈ R++ and w ∈ Rn++ and a production function f : Rn+ → R+, the firm’ssupply y∗ : Rn+ → R is defined by

y∗(p,w) = f (x∗ (p,w)) .

DefinitionGiven p ∈ R++ and w ∈ Rn++ and a production function f : Rn+ → R+, the firm’sprofit function π : R++ × Rn++ → R is defined by

π(p,w) = py∗(p,w)− w · x∗ (p,w) .

Page 123: GARP and Afriat™s Theorem Productionluca/ECON2100/2018Class/lecture_08.pdf · GARP cannot hold. Therefore, GARP implies the consumer spends all her money. Now suppose xj %R xk and

Factor Demand Properties

Given these definitions, the following results “translate” the results for outputsets to production functions.

PropositionGiven p ∈ R++ and w ∈ Rn++ and a production function f : Rn+ → R+,

1 π(p,w) is convex in (p,w).

2 y∗(p,w) is non decreasing in p (i.e. ∂y∗(p,w )∂p ≥ 0) and x∗ (p,w) is non

increasing in w (i.e. ∂x∗i (p,w )∂wi

≤ 0) (Hotelling’s Lemma).

Proof.Problem 7a,b; Problem Set 4.

Page 124: GARP and Afriat™s Theorem Productionluca/ECON2100/2018Class/lecture_08.pdf · GARP cannot hold. Therefore, GARP implies the consumer spends all her money. Now suppose xj %R xk and

Factor Demand Properties

Given these definitions, the following results “translate” the results for outputsets to production functions.

PropositionGiven p ∈ R++ and w ∈ Rn++ and a production function f : Rn+ → R+,

1 π(p,w) is convex in (p,w).

2 y∗(p,w) is non decreasing in p (i.e. ∂y∗(p,w )∂p ≥ 0) and x∗ (p,w) is non

increasing in w (i.e. ∂x∗i (p,w )∂wi

≤ 0) (Hotelling’s Lemma).

Proof.Problem 7a,b; Problem Set 4.

Page 125: GARP and Afriat™s Theorem Productionluca/ECON2100/2018Class/lecture_08.pdf · GARP cannot hold. Therefore, GARP implies the consumer spends all her money. Now suppose xj %R xk and

Cost MinimizationCost Minimizing

Consider the single output case and suppose the firm wants to deliver a givenoutput quantity at the lowest possible costs. The firm solves

minw · x subject to f (x) = y

This has no simple equivalent in the output vector notation.

DefinitionGiven w ∈ Rn++ and a production function f : Rn+ → R+, the firm’s conditionalfactor demand is

x∗ (w , y) = argmin {w · x subject to f (x) = y} ;

DefinitionGiven w ∈ Rn++ and a production function f : Rn+ → R+, the firm’s cost functionC : Rn++ × R+ → R is defined by

C (w , y) = w · x∗ (w , y) .

Page 126: GARP and Afriat™s Theorem Productionluca/ECON2100/2018Class/lecture_08.pdf · GARP cannot hold. Therefore, GARP implies the consumer spends all her money. Now suppose xj %R xk and

Cost MinimizationCost Minimizing

Consider the single output case and suppose the firm wants to deliver a givenoutput quantity at the lowest possible costs. The firm solves

minw · x subject to f (x) = y

This has no simple equivalent in the output vector notation.

DefinitionGiven w ∈ Rn++ and a production function f : Rn+ → R+, the firm’s conditionalfactor demand is

x∗ (w , y) = argmin {w · x subject to f (x) = y} ;

DefinitionGiven w ∈ Rn++ and a production function f : Rn+ → R+, the firm’s cost functionC : Rn++ × R+ → R is defined by

C (w , y) = w · x∗ (w , y) .

Page 127: GARP and Afriat™s Theorem Productionluca/ECON2100/2018Class/lecture_08.pdf · GARP cannot hold. Therefore, GARP implies the consumer spends all her money. Now suppose xj %R xk and

Cost MinimizationCost Minimizing

Consider the single output case and suppose the firm wants to deliver a givenoutput quantity at the lowest possible costs. The firm solves

minw · x subject to f (x) = y

This has no simple equivalent in the output vector notation.

DefinitionGiven w ∈ Rn++ and a production function f : Rn+ → R+, the firm’s conditionalfactor demand is

x∗ (w , y) = argmin {w · x subject to f (x) = y} ;

DefinitionGiven w ∈ Rn++ and a production function f : Rn+ → R+, the firm’s cost functionC : Rn++ × R+ → R is defined by

C (w , y) = w · x∗ (w , y) .

Page 128: GARP and Afriat™s Theorem Productionluca/ECON2100/2018Class/lecture_08.pdf · GARP cannot hold. Therefore, GARP implies the consumer spends all her money. Now suppose xj %R xk and

Cost MinimizationCost Minimizing

Consider the single output case and suppose the firm wants to deliver a givenoutput quantity at the lowest possible costs. The firm solves

minw · x subject to f (x) = y

This has no simple equivalent in the output vector notation.

DefinitionGiven w ∈ Rn++ and a production function f : Rn+ → R+, the firm’s conditionalfactor demand is

x∗ (w , y) = argmin {w · x subject to f (x) = y} ;

DefinitionGiven w ∈ Rn++ and a production function f : Rn+ → R+, the firm’s cost functionC : Rn++ × R+ → R is defined by

C (w , y) = w · x∗ (w , y) .

Page 129: GARP and Afriat™s Theorem Productionluca/ECON2100/2018Class/lecture_08.pdf · GARP cannot hold. Therefore, GARP implies the consumer spends all her money. Now suppose xj %R xk and

Properties of Cost FunctionsProposition

Given a production function f : Rn+ → R+, the corresponding cost function C (w , y)is concave in w.

Proof.

Question 7c; Problem Set 4. (Hint: use a ‘revealed preferences’argument)

Shephard’s Lemma

Write the LagrangianL = w · x − λ [f (x)− y ]

by the Envelope Theorem∂C (w , y)

∂wi=

∂L∂wi

= x∗i (w , y)

Conditional factor demands are downward sloping

Differentiating one more time: ∂C 2(w ,y )∂wi∂wi

=∂x∗i (w ,y )∂wi

≤ 0 where theinequality follows concavity of C (w , y).

Page 130: GARP and Afriat™s Theorem Productionluca/ECON2100/2018Class/lecture_08.pdf · GARP cannot hold. Therefore, GARP implies the consumer spends all her money. Now suppose xj %R xk and

Properties of Cost FunctionsProposition

Given a production function f : Rn+ → R+, the corresponding cost function C (w , y)is concave in w.

Proof.

Question 7c; Problem Set 4. (Hint: use a ‘revealed preferences’argument)

Shephard’s Lemma

Write the LagrangianL = w · x − λ [f (x)− y ]

by the Envelope Theorem∂C (w , y)

∂wi=

∂L∂wi

= x∗i (w , y)

Conditional factor demands are downward sloping

Differentiating one more time: ∂C 2(w ,y )∂wi∂wi

=∂x∗i (w ,y )∂wi

≤ 0 where theinequality follows concavity of C (w , y).

Page 131: GARP and Afriat™s Theorem Productionluca/ECON2100/2018Class/lecture_08.pdf · GARP cannot hold. Therefore, GARP implies the consumer spends all her money. Now suppose xj %R xk and

Properties of Cost FunctionsProposition

Given a production function f : Rn+ → R+, the corresponding cost function C (w , y)is concave in w.

Proof.

Question 7c; Problem Set 4. (Hint: use a ‘revealed preferences’argument)

Shephard’s LemmaWrite the Lagrangian

L = w · x − λ [f (x)− y ]

by the Envelope Theorem∂C (w , y)

∂wi=

∂L∂wi

= x∗i (w , y)

Conditional factor demands are downward sloping

Differentiating one more time: ∂C 2(w ,y )∂wi∂wi

=∂x∗i (w ,y )∂wi

≤ 0 where theinequality follows concavity of C (w , y).

Page 132: GARP and Afriat™s Theorem Productionluca/ECON2100/2018Class/lecture_08.pdf · GARP cannot hold. Therefore, GARP implies the consumer spends all her money. Now suppose xj %R xk and

Properties of Cost FunctionsProposition

Given a production function f : Rn+ → R+, the corresponding cost function C (w , y)is concave in w.

Proof.

Question 7c; Problem Set 4. (Hint: use a ‘revealed preferences’argument)

Shephard’s LemmaWrite the Lagrangian

L = w · x − λ [f (x)− y ]

by the Envelope Theorem∂C (w , y)

∂wi=

∂L∂wi

= x∗i (w , y)

Conditional factor demands are downward sloping

Differentiating one more time: ∂C 2(w ,y )∂wi∂wi

=∂x∗i (w ,y )∂wi

≤ 0 where theinequality follows concavity of C (w , y).

Page 133: GARP and Afriat™s Theorem Productionluca/ECON2100/2018Class/lecture_08.pdf · GARP cannot hold. Therefore, GARP implies the consumer spends all her money. Now suppose xj %R xk and

Properties of Cost FunctionsProposition

Given a production function f : Rn+ → R+, the corresponding cost function C (w , y)is concave in w.

Proof.

Question 7c; Problem Set 4. (Hint: use a ‘revealed preferences’argument)

Shephard’s LemmaWrite the Lagrangian

L = w · x − λ [f (x)− y ]

by the Envelope Theorem∂C (w , y)

∂wi=

∂L∂wi

= x∗i (w , y)

Conditional factor demands are downward sloping

Differentiating one more time: ∂C 2(w ,y )∂wi∂wi

=∂x∗i (w ,y )∂wi

≤ 0 where theinequality follows concavity of C (w , y).

Page 134: GARP and Afriat™s Theorem Productionluca/ECON2100/2018Class/lecture_08.pdf · GARP cannot hold. Therefore, GARP implies the consumer spends all her money. Now suppose xj %R xk and

Next Class

Decision Making Under Uncertainty

Expected Utility Representation