Framing Social Security Reform: Behavioral Responses to ... · Framing Social Security Reform:...

38
Framing Social Security Reform: Behavioral Responses to Changes in the Full Retirement Age By Luc Behaghel and David M. Blau* Abstract We use a US Social Security reform as a quasi-experiment to provide evidence on framing effects in retirement behavior. The reform increased the full retirement age (FRA) from 65 to 66 in two month increments per year of birth. We find strong evidence that the spike in the benefit claiming hazard at 65 moved in lockstep along with the FRA. Results on self-reported retirement and exit from employment go in the same direction. The responsiveness to the new FRA is stronger for people with higher cognitive skills. We interpret the findings as evidence of reference dependence with loss aversion. JEL: J26 *Behaghel: Paris School of Economics-INRA and CREST, 48 Boulevard Jourdan, 75014 Paris, France, [email protected]. Blau: Ohio State University and IZA, Arps Hall, 1945 N. High St., Columbus, OH, 43210-1172, [email protected] . The research in this paper was conducted while the second author was a Special Sworn Status researcher of the U.S. Census Bureau at the Triangle Census Research Data Center. Any opinions and conclusions expressed herein are those of the authors and do not necessarily represent the views of the U.S. Census Bureau. All results have been reviewed to ensure that no confidential information is disclosed. Financial support from NIA grant P30- AG024376 and NSF-ITR grant #0427889 is gratefully acknowledged. We thank Sudipto Banerjee for research assistance. We appreciate helpful comments from two referees, seminar participants at MRRC, PSE, and NBER, and from Jonathan Zinman. We are grateful for especially detailed comments from Joe Doyle. The authors are solely responsible for the contents.

Transcript of Framing Social Security Reform: Behavioral Responses to ... · Framing Social Security Reform:...

Page 1: Framing Social Security Reform: Behavioral Responses to ... · Framing Social Security Reform: Behavioral Responses to Changes in the Full Retirement Age By Luc Behaghel and David

Framing Social Security Reform:

Behavioral Responses to Changes in the Full Retirement Age

By Luc Behaghel and David M. Blau*

Abstract

We use a US Social Security reform as a quasi-experiment to provide evidence on framing effects in retirement behavior. The reform increased the full retirement age (FRA) from 65 to 66 in two month increments per year of birth. We find strong evidence that the spike in the benefit claiming hazard at 65 moved in lockstep along with the FRA. Results on self-reported retirement and exit from employment go in the same direction. The responsiveness to the new FRA is stronger for people with higher cognitive skills. We interpret the findings as evidence of reference dependence with loss aversion. JEL: J26 *Behaghel: Paris School of Economics-INRA and CREST, 48 Boulevard Jourdan, 75014 Paris, France, [email protected]. Blau: Ohio State University and IZA, Arps Hall, 1945 N. High St., Columbus, OH, 43210-1172, [email protected]. The research in this paper was conducted while the second author was a Special Sworn Status researcher of the U.S. Census Bureau at the Triangle Census Research Data Center. Any opinions and conclusions expressed herein are those of the authors and do not necessarily represent the views of the U.S. Census Bureau. All results have been reviewed to ensure that no confidential information is disclosed. Financial support from NIA grant P30-AG024376 and NSF-ITR grant #0427889 is gratefully acknowledged. We thank Sudipto Banerjee for research assistance. We appreciate helpful comments from two referees, seminar participants at MRRC, PSE, and NBER, and from Jonathan Zinman. We are grateful for especially detailed comments from Joe Doyle. The authors are solely responsible for the contents.

Page 2: Framing Social Security Reform: Behavioral Responses to ... · Framing Social Security Reform: Behavioral Responses to Changes in the Full Retirement Age By Luc Behaghel and David

Understanding the labor force, benefit take up, and saving decisions of older workers has

become increasingly important in today’s environment of rapid population aging and large Social

Security financial imbalances. The life cycle model provides a powerful framework for modeling

retirement decisions, and has been the basis for a substantial amount of informative and policy-

relevant research. But some aspects of retirement behavior have proven difficult to explain in the

life cycle framework. These include failure to take up employer-provided defined contribution

pension plans that provide very favorable terms such as a generous employer match (Madrian

and Shea, 2001), and lack of knowledge of pension provisions (Chan and Stevens, 2008).

Another feature of retirement behavior that seems hard to reconcile with a life cycle approach is

the persistence of large spikes in exit from the labor force and take up of Social Security benefits

(Old Age and Survivors Insurance, or OASI) in the US at age 65. Costa (1998) shows that there

was little evidence of a spike in labor force exit in the 1900-1920 period, but a spike at age 65

had emerged by 1940, five years after the establishment of Social Security. The size of the spike

was as high as 30% on an annual basis in the mid 1980's (Perrachi and Welch, 1994), and

declined to 19% in the 2000's.1

Several explanations for the age 65 spike have been proposed. Some explanations are

consistent with the life cycle framework: for instance, a sharp nonlinearity at 65 in the

relationship between claiming age and the Social Security benefit, interactions with Defined

Benefit (DB) pension plans, which often have financial incentives to retire at 65, or availability

of health insurance from Medicare, for which eligibility starts at 65. There are two leading

“behavioral” explanations for the age-65 spike that relax the assumptions of farsighted rational

behavior and standard preferences. First, the fact that 65 has been the Full Retirement Age

(FRA) from the beginning of the OASI program until recently may have caused an endorsement

effect. Workers might take this “official” designation as implicit advice from the government

about when to retire and claim benefits; if collecting information or deciding by themselves is

too difficult or too costly, they may decide to follow this advice. Second, the fact that the FRA is

1A 30% spike in the hazard of exit from employment means that 30% of individuals who were working prior to turning 65 left employment with a year after turning 65. Source: author’s calculations from the Health and Retirement Study, described below. A new spike in the hazard rates of labor force exit and benefit claiming emerged after 1962, when early Social Security entitlement at age 62 became available (Moffitt, 1987). Note that exiting employment and claiming the OASI benefit are distinct choices, although they are often closely related in practice.

Page 3: Framing Social Security Reform: Behavioral Responses to ... · Framing Social Security Reform: Behavioral Responses to Changes in the Full Retirement Age By Luc Behaghel and David

3

used as a reference point in Social Security Administration (SSA) explanations of the SS benefit

schedule could influence behavior if workers’ preferences are reference-dependent with loss

aversion. The intuition is as follows: the salience of the FRA makes it a natural starting point for

workers considering when to retire and claim benefits. With standard preferences, for most

workers the FRA would not be the optimal choice, and they would move to a different point,

specific to each of them, where the marginal rate of substitution between leisure and

consumption equals the slope of the benefit schedule. If workers are loss averse, however, some

will not deviate from the FRA, as the utility cost of losing benefits or leisure time would be

amplified. There is little conclusive evidence to date on these different explanations for the age

65 spike. In particular, most of the evidence on behavioral explanations comes from testing and

rejecting other explanations, leaving behavioral economic explanations as the default

(Lumsdaine, Stock, and Wise, 1996).

A Social Security reform enacted into law in 1983 increased the FRA from 65 to 66 in

two month increments per year of birth for cohorts born from 1938 to 1943.2 The cohorts

affected by the reform reached their FRA in 2004-2009, so data on their retirement behavior are

available now. This provides an unusual opportunity to test both life-cycle and behavioral

economic explanations for the age 65 spike. The increase in the FRA is equivalent to a cut in the

Social Security benefit: claiming the benefit at any given age results in a lower benefit than if the

FRA had not changed. This reduces the expected present discounted value of lifetime benefits

(Social Security Wealth), and should cause an increase in the age of retirement if leisure is a

normal good. But, as illustrated in Figure 1 by comparing cohorts 1937 and 1943, the increase in

the FRA did not change the slope of the benefit-claiming-age schedule in the vicinity of the

FRA.3 So there is no economic incentive for someone who, for whatever reason, would have

2The FRA is 65 for cohorts born before 1938, 65 and 2 months for the 1938 birth cohort, 65 and 4

months for the 1939 birth cohort, etc., and 66 for cohorts born from 1943-1954. A similar stepwise increase from 66 to 67 for cohorts born from 1955 to 1960 was also mandated.

3The implied benefit cut is the same at all claiming ages up to and including the FRA except between 62 and 63. The benefit cut implied by a one year increase in the FRA is 5% if the benefit is claimed between 62 and 63, and 6.67% if the benefit is claimed between 63 and 66. Another reform enacted in 1983 gradually increased the Delayed Retirement Credit (DRC), the slope of the benefit-claiming-age profile after the FRA, from 1% for those turning 62 in 1981 to 8% for those turning 62 in 2005. The benefit cut implied by a one year increase in the FRA for an individual who claims the benefit

Page 4: Framing Social Security Reform: Behavioral Responses to ... · Framing Social Security Reform: Behavioral Responses to Changes in the Full Retirement Age By Luc Behaghel and David

4

retired or claimed the benefit at 65 if the FRA had not changed, to instead do so at his FRA of 65

and 2 months, or 65 and 4 months, etc. If the spike in retirement or benefit claiming at age 65

shifts across cohorts in parallel with the increase in the FRA, explanations based on the standard

life cycle framework would be unable to account for this. This would point toward behavioral

economic explanations.

Our first contribution in this paper is to estimate the effect of the increase in the FRA on

the hazard of exiting employment and the hazard of claiming the OASI benefit. Several recent

studies have estimated the effect of the increase in the FRA on the timing of labor force exit or

benefit claiming (Blau and Goodstein, 2010; Kopczuck and Song, 2008; Mastrobuoni, 2009;

Pingle, 2006; Song and Manchester, 2008), but none have focused specifically on the impact on

the spike in retirement at 65. In the first part of the paper, we use data from the Health and

Retirement Study and the Longitudinal Employer-Household Dynamics data to analyze changes

in the retirement and claiming hazards across cohorts. We find strong evidence that the spike in

the OASI benefit claiming hazard moved in lockstep along with the FRA, consistent with

findings from administrative data (Song and Manchester, 2008). Results on self-reported

retirement and exit from the labor force are less clear-cut: we find evidence that the spike in

labor force exit at 65 decreased substantially and in some cases vanished for cohorts whose FRA

increased, but less systematic evidence that new spikes have appeared at the new FRAs. The

difference between effects on claiming and labor force exit may indicate that the change in the

FRA is less salient for leaving employment than for claiming. Depending on the outcome we

examine, the FRA effect can account for 10 to 40% of the initial hazard at age 65.

Our second contribution is to address the more novel question of which groups, defined

by observable characteristics, are most responsive to the change in the FRA, i.e. “who is

behavioral” (Benjamin, Brown, and Shapiro, 2006) with respect to age of retirement. We define

a group of workers as behavioral if the group’s claiming and labor force exit behavior closely

parallels the shift in the FRA. We define groups in several ways: by (1) socioeconomic

characteristics such as gender, education, race, and marital status; (2) job characteristics such as

after the FRA is equal to the DRC for his cohort. The loss in expected present discounted value of lifetime benefits from delaying claiming from 65 to 66 is about two percent at a real interest rate of 3%, using U.S. life table mortality rates. There is a similar loss for delaying claiming past age 66.

Page 5: Framing Social Security Reform: Behavioral Responses to ... · Framing Social Security Reform: Behavioral Responses to Changes in the Full Retirement Age By Luc Behaghel and David

5

pension and health insurance coverage; (3) cognitive ability; (4) financial literacy and planning

horizon; and (5) non-cognitive characteristics such as risk aversion and subjective expectations

about longevity. The most consistent finding is that workers with higher cognitive ability

respond more strongly to the FRA change.

These results are supportive of a behavioral explanation of the age 65 spike. They do not

constitute a full test of which of the leading behavioral explanations – the endorsement effect or

reference dependence with loss aversion – is at play.4 The fact that responsiveness to the FRA

increases with cognitive skills indicates that the endorsement effect could not be the full story,

as the endorsement effect implies unsophisticated decision making and should be less, not more,

prevalent among people with higher cognitive skills. Reference dependence with loss aversion is

a form of non-standard preferences and there is no particular reason to expect non-standard

preferences to be associated with cognitive ability. Thus our findings do not provide direct

support for reference dependence with loss aversion, but are more consistent with that story than

with an endorsement effect. One interpretation consistent with the evidence and with both

behavioral explanations is that people with lower cognitive skills may be less responsive to the

change in the FRA because they do not learn, or learn more slowly about the new “advice” or the

new reference point.

The evidence we present is of inherent interest for understanding retirement behavior, but

it could also have important implications for future Social Security policy. To illustrate these

implications, we develop a simple behavioral model of retirement that incorporates reference

dependence and loss aversion. The model is used to demonstrate that reference dependence can

amplify or dampen the impact on the average age of retirement caused by a reform such as a

change in the FRA, depending on how the reform is framed. Simulations of the model for

plausible parameter values indicate that the manner of framing a policy reform can have a

sizeable effect on its impact on retirement behavior in the presence of reference dependence.

The next section of the paper briefly reviews previous findings and places our

contribution in context. The following section describes the data, and sections III and IV present

evidence on the effect of the shift in the FRA. Section V analyzes heterogeneity in the response

4 By contrast, the fact that the first cohorts exposed to the shift in the FRA responded to the shift

does not seem consistent with a “social norms” story, insofar as social norms evolve slowly.

Page 6: Framing Social Security Reform: Behavioral Responses to ... · Framing Social Security Reform: Behavioral Responses to Changes in the Full Retirement Age By Luc Behaghel and David

6

to the FRA. Section VI describes and analyzes the implications of a simple behavioral model of

retirement. The final section concludes.

I. Previous Studies

Here, we briefly review existing evidence on explanations for the age 65 spike.

(i) Liquidity Constraint. Low income workers who saved little during their working years

could face a liquidity constraint that makes it difficult to finance consumption during retirement

before receiving the OASI benefit (Crawford and Lilien, 1981). This could explain the

prevalence of retirement at the earliest age of eligibility. However, the earliest age of eligibility

for OASI was changed to 62 in 1962, but the spike at age 65 remained and even grew, thus

providing evidence against a liquidity constraint explanation for the age 65 spike.

(ii) Nonlinear Budget Set. Until the 1990s there was a sharp kink at the FRA in the

schedule that determines the Social Security benefit as a function of the age of claiming,

illustrated in Figure 1 for the 1924 birth cohort. Delaying claiming from 62 to 65 resulted in a

benefit increase of 6.67% per year, but delaying claiming past 65 resulted in a much smaller

increase (1% for individuals who turned 62 in 1981; 3% for individuals who turned 62 from

1982 until 1989). The age-65 spike could be rationalized as a response to a kinked intertemporal

budget constraint (Hurd, 1990). However, the 1983 Social Security reforms eliminated the kink,

gradually increasing the reward to delaying claiming past the FRA. For individuals who turned

62 in the mid-2000's there was no longer a kink in the benefit-claiming-age schedule, and today

there is even a slight convex kink, yet the spike in retirement at age 65 for cohorts with an FRA

of 65 persisted.

(iii) Defined Benefit Pensions. DB pension plans often have a normal retirement age of

65, and these plans usually have very strong incentives to retire by the normal age (conditional

on not having retired at the earliest age of eligibility, which is typically quite attractive as well).5

DB pensions are much less common today, having been largely supplanted by Defined

5 In 2005, 59% of DB plans had a normal retirement age of 65. The early retirement age

was 55 in 76% of plans that had an early retirement age (U.S. Department of Labor, 2007, Tables 50 and 52).

Page 7: Framing Social Security Reform: Behavioral Responses to ... · Framing Social Security Reform: Behavioral Responses to Changes in the Full Retirement Age By Luc Behaghel and David

7

Contribution (DC) plans.6 DC plans do not have any incentives to retire at 65 or any other

particular age. However, the switch from DB to DC plans affected the cohorts reaching their mid

60’s in the 2000s less than it has affected more recent cohorts.7 The prevalence of DB pension

coverage in these older cohorts is consistent with the persistence of the age 65 spike. We control

for DB pension coverage and, for those with DB plans, the normal retirement age in the plan.

(iv) Health Insurance. Workers who would lose their employer-provided health insurance

upon retiring might prefer to postpone retirement until Medicare eligibility at age 65 in order to

avoid being uninsured, leading to a spike in retirement at 65 (Madrian, 1994). The age of

eligibility for Medicare has been 65 since the program was introduced in 1965, so there is no

direct evidence on this explanation, although the age-65 spike was present before 1965. It is

possible that Medicare has replaced the other explanations for the age-65 spike as they have

become less relevant, but this is difficult to determine because of the lack of variation in the

Medicare eligibility age.8 We include controls for employer-provided health insurance and

retiree health insurance coverage.

6Measured in terms of annual contributions by employers, DB plans accounted for 60% of total

private sector employer contributions in 1980, and only 13% in 2000 (Poterba, Venti, and Wise, 2007). DB plans remain prevalent in the public sector. Some DB plans are integrated with Social Security, meaning that the pension benefit depends on the amount of the Social Security benefit. This creates a link between the focal retirement ages in Social Security and DB pensions. We have not been able to find information on how the change in the FRA has affected the normal retirement age in DB plans. The results presented below suggest that the majority of DB plans did not change their normal retirement age.

7 In 2000, 40% of private sector employees with a pension were covered by DB plans and 75% by DC plans. The total sums to more than 100% because 15% are covered by both types (U.S. Department of Labor, 2003). In the HRS, the corresponding figures for individuals covered by a pension in 2000 were 46% exclusively DB, 48% exclusively DC, and 5% both (authors’ tabulations).

8Evidence on the role of Medicare in retirement decisions derived from simulations based on structural models is provided in Rust and Phelan (1997), Blau and Gilleskie (2006, 2008), and French and Jones (2011). Rust and Phelan conclude that Medicare was an important determinant of retirement timing in the 1970s, while Blau and Gilleskie conclude that it was much less important in the 1990s. The results of French and Jones for the 1990s are in between. Some workers are covered by the spouse’s health insurance plan, and others purchase a health insurance policy in the market. These possibilities and the option to extend coverage from the employer for up to three years after leaving the firm (so-called COBRA coverage) reduce the potential role of Medicare as an explanation for the age 65 spike.

Page 8: Framing Social Security Reform: Behavioral Responses to ... · Framing Social Security Reform: Behavioral Responses to Changes in the Full Retirement Age By Luc Behaghel and David

8

The most plausible behavioral economic explanations for the age 65 spike are based on

the fact that 65 was the Social Security FRA, until recently (Lumsdaine et al., 1996). The FRA is

not presented as a norm – the SSA presents things in a balanced way: “If you retire early, you

may not have enough income to enjoy the years ahead of you. Likewise, if you retire late, you’ll

have a larger income, but fewer years to enjoy it. Everyone needs to find the right balance based

on his or her own circumstances” (Social Security Advisory Board, 2009). However, in

personalized Social Security statements the FRA is explicitly used as a reference in a bar chart

illustrating benefits as a function of claiming age.9 Moreover, the distinction between retiring

“early” and retiring “late” is explicitly discussed, using the FRA as a reference, in the age-55+

insert sent with the Social Security statement. Clearly, the way the FRA is used in framing

benefits invites people to use it as their point of reference.10 This could result in development of

a social norm, or could be taken as advice by agents with limited ability to evaluate the financial

implications of alternative claiming and labor force behavior, or could serve as a reference point

for individuals whose preferences exhibit loss aversion with reference dependence. Furthermore,

advice from non-government sources about when to claim Social Security often uses the FRA as

a reference point. For example, the AARP web site begins its advice about when to claim with

the statement “If you're healthy and can afford it, you should consider waiting until you reach

your full retirement age of 66, or even 70.”11

There is little direct evidence on the explanatory power of specific behavioral economic

explanations for the age 65 spike. Featherstonehaugh and Ross (1999) and Liebman and Luttmer

(2009) pose hypothetical questions to survey respondents to gauge the importance of framing

effects in the presentation of information about Social Security. Framing effects appear to matter

at some ages and not at other ages, but the scenarios are hypothetical. Brown et al. (2011) report

results from an experiment in which alternative ways of framing the tradeoff between early and

9 See Mastrobuoni (2011) for discussion of the history of the Social Security statement and the impact of its introduction on retirement behavior.

10 This is true both for cohorts with an integer FRA and for those with non-integer FRAs. For instance, for workers born in 1939, the statement reads: “The earliest age at which you can receive an unreduced retirement benefit is 65 and 4 months.” 11 http://www.aarp.org/work/social-security/info-12-2010/top-25-social-security-questions.5.html (question 25). The AARP Social Security calculator contains a bar chart very similar to the one in the Social Security statement, with the FRA as a benchmark.

Page 9: Framing Social Security Reform: Behavioral Responses to ... · Framing Social Security Reform: Behavioral Responses to Changes in the Full Retirement Age By Luc Behaghel and David

9

later claiming were tested. They find some strong effects of framing on the expected age of

claiming benefits. Liebman and Luttmer (2011) find that providing information about Social

Security in a field experiment caused an increase in labor force participation one year later.

The hypothetical experiment we have in mind would cut Social Security benefits by a

given amount, and frame the cut in alternative ways: (1) as a neutral across-the-board cut

irrespective of the age at which the benefit is claimed, (2) as a cut in the benefit available at a

particular reference age, holding constant the slope of the benefit-claiming-age profile, and (3) as

an increase in the age at which a given reference benefit level is available, again holding the

slope constant. In each scenario, individuals would be perfectly well informed about the cut, and

capable of determining their optimal response, given their preferences. This would eliminate lack

of information and limited cognitive ability as confounders, so any differences in responses

across scenarios could be plausibly attributed to reference dependence. The actual quasi-

experiment induced by the reform did hold the benefit-claiming-age profile roughly constant (c.f.

Figure 1), and used framing option 3 (an increase in the FRA). We cannot compare results for

different framing options, so we cannot rule out information and cognitive ability as explanations

for the impact of the FRA. We discuss indirect approaches to assessing the importance of these

issues in sections V and VI.

Recent evidence indicates that the increase in the FRA has affected retirement behavior

(Mastrobuoni (2009), Blau and Goodstein (2010), Pingle (2006)). These studies do not address

the mechanism through which the FRA effect operates, and therefore do not shed light on the

question of why the FRA has affected retirement behavior. The evidence is consistent with a

wealth effect that would alter behavior at all ages, but it does not address the question of whether

there is a shift in the spike at age 65.

In contrast, recent evidence on Social Security claiming clearly suggests a behavioral

economic interpretation. There is no economic incentive to claim the OASI benefit at the FRA,

yet that is precisely what the treated cohorts have done. Song and Manchester (2008) and

Kopczuck and Song (2008) use administrative data to show that the increase in the FRA has

caused the spike in claiming at age 65 to shift almost completely to the new FRA for the affected

cohorts. This finding is difficult to explain in the life cycle framework. The key unanswered

Page 10: Framing Social Security Reform: Behavioral Responses to ... · Framing Social Security Reform: Behavioral Responses to Changes in the Full Retirement Age By Luc Behaghel and David

10

questions that we seek to address are whether there is similar evidence for employment; if so,

how can we explain it; and which types of workers are more responsive to the new FRA.

II. Data

We use data from the Health and Retirement Study (HRS), which provides a rich set of

potential explanatory variables to study behavioral aspects of retirement. These variables are

unique to the HRS and offer the opportunity to distinguish among alternative behavioral

explanations for the age 65 spike.

The main disadvantage of the HRS is the relatively small samples available to study

retirement and claiming behavior at the FRA. Roughly three quarters of workers retire and claim

benefits before reaching the FRA, so despite sample sizes of about 1,000 respondents per year of

birth, the effective sample size is closer to 250 per cohort. This provides about 1,125

observations on the treated cohorts, and 1,750 for the control cohorts. Therefore, we also use

data from the Longitudinal Employer-Household Dynamics (LEHD) files. These files are

derived from administrative state Unemployment Insurance (UI) records, with very large sample

sizes, and they include information on birth date. These administrative data are used to verify

that the trends identified in the HRS are robust. The LEHD is described in the web appendix.

The HRS is a biennial survey of a sample of households containing individuals over the

age of 50, and their spouses. The survey began in 1992 with birth cohorts 1931-1941, and new

cohorts were added in 1998 and 2004. We use the 1992-2008 waves. The analysis sample is birth

cohorts 1931-1942, since these cohorts had reached their FRA as of 2008, while later cohorts had

not. The 1931-37 cohorts are the controls (FRA=65.0) and the 1938-42 cohorts are the treated

cohorts (FRA>65.0).

The HRS records a job history at the first interview, employment status at each interview,

and the start and end dates of all jobs between interviews, to the nearest month. We construct a

monthly employment history. Together with month and year of birth, the employment data are

used to compute the age of labor force exit, defined as the age (in months) at which the

individual is first out of the labor force for an entire month.12

12The sample for the labor force exit analysis includes all months during which the individual was

Page 11: Framing Social Security Reform: Behavioral Responses to ... · Framing Social Security Reform: Behavioral Responses to Changes in the Full Retirement Age By Luc Behaghel and David

11

The HRS contains self-reported information on the month and year in which the

respondent first received a Social Security benefit payment. In some cases, the reported date is

before the respondent turned 62, indicating that he or she first received some type of Social

Security benefit other than OASI, such as disability or dependent benefits. In these cases it is not

possible to identify when the respondent claimed the OASI benefit, so we do not use such cases

in the analysis of claiming behavior.13 The age in months of OASI claiming is the second

outcome of interest.

A third outcome of interest is the self-reported month and year of retirement. This

“subjective” measure is frequently used as an indicator of retirement, and it is of interest to

determine whether “retirement” and “employment” differ with respect to the FRA. However,

there are many longitudinally inconsistent self-reports of retirement age, so only about half the

sample has a self-reported retirement age that is reasonably consistent across waves. We use only

the latter cases in analysis of retirement.

The monthly record is merged with permanent characteristics such as race, gender,

ethnicity, and education, and with time-varying measures recorded at the survey dates, including

health status, the wage rate, household wealth, health insurance and pension coverage, other job

characteristics, and marital status. If there was a change in one of these time-varying variables

between waves, we assume the change occurred midway between the waves.

The HRS contains several variables that are useful in distinguishing among alternative

behavioral explanations for the age 65 spike. These include measures of cognitive ability, risk

aversion, self control, and financial planning horizon. Cognitive ability measures have been

explored by McArdle, Smith and Willis (2011), and we follow their approach to construct

indicators in three dimensions: Telephone Interview of Cognitive Status (TICS), short term

memory, and numeracy (see the web appendix for details). employed for any part of the month. Some people who leave the labor force later return to employment. In such cases there are multiple labor force exits. As a robustness check, we consider that an individual has exited the labor force only if the exit is preceded by an employment spell of at least 3 months, and followed by at least 3 months out of employment.

13If an individual reaches his FRA while receiving Social Security Disability Insurance, the benefit is switched to OASI, but this is purely an administrative adjustment, so it does not provide any information about claiming behavior. Most SSDI recipients never leave the SSDI rolls, and therefore provide no information about OASI claiming behavior.

Page 12: Framing Social Security Reform: Behavioral Responses to ... · Framing Social Security Reform: Behavioral Responses to Changes in the Full Retirement Age By Luc Behaghel and David

12

III. Impact of the FRA increase

In this section, we describe evidence from the HRS on how the change in the FRA has

modified the timing of OASI benefit claiming, labor force exit, and self-reported retirement. The

goal is to test the null hypothesis that the increase in the FRA had only a wealth effect against the

general “behavioral” prediction that the spike at age 65 should shift along with the FRA for

cohorts born after 1937. In the former case we expect an increase in retirement age, but no

substantial shift in the spike. As discussed in section III, there are no economic incentives to

retire or claim benefits at the new FRA, so in effect we are testing the null hypothesis of rational

life cycle behavior against a general unspecified alternative. In Sections V and VI we bring

evidence to bear on specific behavioral explanations.

We start with graphical evidence on the timing of OASI benefit claiming across cohorts,

pooling men and women. Figure 2 displays average monthly claiming hazard rates for pre and

post-reform cohorts. The claiming hazard rate is defined as the probability of claiming at a given

age conditional on not having claimed previously (claiming is an absorbing state). Age is

measured at a bimonthly frequency; e.g. age 65 denotes age 65 0/12 to 65 1/1214 . In each graph

of figure 2, the dotted line depicts the average claiming hazard for workers born between 1931

and 1936. As shown by previous studies, there is a first spike in the hazard at or just after the

early claiming age (62) and a second larger spike at the FRA (65).15 About 20% of workers in

these cohorts claim at 62, and 30% of those who have not claimed before 65 claim at 65. For

each cohort, the vertical lines indicate age 62, age 65, and the FRA (if different from age 65).

The 1937 cohort is displayed separately, to demonstrate that there were no major shifts in

behavior for the last “control” cohort. There is clear evidence that the spike in the claiming

hazard moves in lockstep along with the FRA. The spike at age 65 does not completely disappear

for the treated cohorts, but it becomes progressively smaller. Very similar patterns appear when

14 One reason for measuring age at a bimonthly frequency is to make the graph easier to read. It is

also useful because there is some arbitrariness in measuring the age at which an event occurs. If an individual reports claiming his benefit in April, it is not clear how to classify his claiming status in April without knowing the exact date.

15 The spike at age 62 is slightly after age 62 because benefits are payable beginning in the first month in which a person is 62 throughout the whole month, unless the person was born on the 1st or 2nd day of the month (see Kopczuk and Song, 2008, for discussion).

Page 13: Framing Social Security Reform: Behavioral Responses to ... · Framing Social Security Reform: Behavioral Responses to Changes in the Full Retirement Age By Luc Behaghel and David

13

men and women are disaggregated (not shown). These results confirm the findings of Song and

Manchester (2008), based on administrative data.

Regression analysis is useful here to summarize the graphical evidence and to

quantify the impact of the FRA. We adopt the following difference-in-difference specification:

(1) iaccaiaciaciac xFRAP εδβγθ ++++= ,

where Piac is an indicator variable equal to one if individual i born in cohort c claims at age a (in

months), conditional on not having claimed previously. FRA is the indicator variable for age a

being his FRA, xiac is a set of individual controls, and full sets of cohort and age dummies are

included ( ca δβ , ).The age 65 coefficient (one of the s'β ) captures the part of the spike that is not

explained by the fact that 65 is the FRA for cohorts up to 1937. The parameter of interest θ is

identified by the interaction of age and cohort, under the assumption that the control variables

capture any non-FRA-related motives to claim at the FRA. Results are shown in table 1. The four

columns differ by the estimation sample or the controls. Column 1 has no controls other than age

and cohort effects, and restricts the analysis to ages 64 to 65 11/12. Reaching the FRA increases

the claiming hazard by 14 percentage points. The effect is statistically highly significant, and

robust to the inclusion of controls and to changes in the estimation sample (columns 2 to 3).

Column 4 includes an indicator for whether the individual is subject to the Social Security

Earnings Test (SSET) given his age and birth year. This is intended to control for elimination of

the SSET in 2000 for individuals at or above the FRA. This reform had a noticeable effect on

claiming, but accounting for this policy change does not affect the estimated impact of the FRA.

Quantitatively, the estimated impact of the FRA is sizeable: the average claiming hazard at age

65 is around 30% for cohorts born between 1931 and 1937; more than 40% (14/30) of the claims

occurring at that age for the control cohorts can therefore be explained by the fact that 65 is their

FRA.

Turning to labor force exit behavior, Figure 3 shows that the increase in the FRA resulted

in a progressive fall in the age 65 spike in the labor force exit hazard. However, there is no

systematic evidence of new spikes at the FRA for cohorts born after 1937. Columns 1 to 4 in

table 2 use the same specifications as in table 1. The impact of the FRA is smaller than for

claiming, but is positive and significantly different from zero. For cohorts born before 1937, the

Page 14: Framing Social Security Reform: Behavioral Responses to ... · Framing Social Security Reform: Behavioral Responses to Changes in the Full Retirement Age By Luc Behaghel and David

14

mean monthly hazard of labor force exit at age 65 is 4.6%. Roughly 20% of this spike (0.9/4.6)

can be explained by the fact that 65 is the FRA for these cohorts. As previously shown by Baker

and Benjamin (1999) for the case of Canada, the effect of Social Security reform on benefit

claiming behavior can significantly differ from the effect on labor force participation and

retirement behavior. It is common to work after claiming and to move in and out of the labor

force, but claiming is a one-time event. There may also be more measurement error in the reports

of the timing of labor force exit, as it may not be as salient as claiming. 16

Figure 4 presents evidence on the monthly hazard of entry to self-reported retirement,

comparable to figures 2 and 3. The results are in between. There is some reasonably strong

evidence of a shift in the spike for cohorts born after 1939, consistent with an effect of the FRA

on retirement decisions. However, the spike at the old FRA (age 65) persists for some of these

cohorts. The regression results (table 3) are very imprecise. The point estimate implies a smaller

FRA impact than for claiming and exit from employment. The mean monthly retirement hazard

for the control cohorts at age 65 is around 13%. 10% of this spike (1.1/13) can be accounted for

by the fact that 65 is their FRA. The results are robust to controlling for the elimination of the

earnings test, but in this case the effect of the earnings test is larger than the effect of the FRA.

As noted above, we also used administrative earnings data from the LEHD in order to

verify that the labor force participation results from the HRS are robust. The results from

analysis of the LEHD are generally quite consistent with findings from the HRS. These results

are discussed in the web appendix. Overall, combining the information on labor force transitions

from the LEHD and the HRS as well as from self-reported retirement age from the HRS provides

only mixed evidence that the labor supply decisions of workers have been affected by the change

in the FRA in a manner consistent with a behavioral interpretation. Limited statistical power and

measurement error are issues with the HRS, but the LEHD has very large samples and

16 Results based on a smaller sample that eliminates temporary withdrawals from the labor force

(three months or less) gave very similar results. Note that the monthly hazard rate of labor force exit is much smaller than the monthly hazard of Social Security claiming. For example, at age 65 the latter is equal to about 0.4 for claiming but only 0.02 for employment for the 1931-36 birth cohorts (compare Figures 2 and 3). Some of this difference could be due to measurement error in constructing a monthly labor force history from retrospective between-wave questions. However, claiming can occur before, after, or at the same time as labor force exit, so there is no reason why the levels of the two hazards should be of the same order of magnitude.

Page 15: Framing Social Security Reform: Behavioral Responses to ... · Framing Social Security Reform: Behavioral Responses to Changes in the Full Retirement Age By Luc Behaghel and David

15

administrative data. The combination of findings from the two sources gives us some confidence

that labor supply decisions are affected, though clearly not by as much as claiming decisions.

An important question is whether the changes in labor force and retirement behavior that

we find could be explained solely by wealth effects as a response to the benefit cut implied by

the increase in the FRA. We cannot directly address this question because we do not estimate

the wealth effect; rather, as in Mastrobuoni (2009), we estimate the total effect, including the

wealth effect and any “behavioral” effects. Several papers report estimates of the elasticity of the

hazard of labor force exit with respect to Social Security Wealth (SSW). A direct comparison of

this elasticity to our results is not possible, but some calculations suggest that the wealth effect is

too small to account for more than a minor part of the estimated effect of the FRA on the age 65

spikes17.

Finally, as noted in section II, it has been difficult to rule out Medicare as a cause of the

age 65 spike in labor force exit. If Medicare is an important cause of the age 65 spike, then the

spike should not disappear entirely when the FRA moves away from 65. The evidence presented

in this section shows that the age-65 spikes in labor force exit and self-reported retirement

gradually, if irregularly, disappeared as successive post-1937 birth cohorts reached age 65.

However, these results pertain to the entire population, while the availability of Medicare at 65

may be important only for the subpopulation without retiree benefits from their employer-

provided health insurance plan. When we limit the analysis to this subpopulation, the results are

very close to those of table 1, although they are much less precisely estimated because of the

smaller sample. Overall, the results suggest at most a minor role for Medicare in explaining the

age 65 spike.

17 The largest estimate of the elasticity of labor force exit with respect to SSW presented by Coile

and Gruber (2007) is 0.16. Samwick (1998) estimates the elasticity to be approximately zero. Manoli, Mullen, and Wagner (2009) using Austrian administrative data estimate an elasticity of 0.40. The change in SSW wealth implied by a change in the FRA from 65 to 66 is 6.67%. If we take the largest elasticity estimate, 0.4, this would imply a 2.7% (not percentage point) decrease in the hazard of LF exit. Using the largest estimate from Coile and Gruber, 0.16, implies a 1.07% decline in the hazard. These numbers cannot be compared directly to the results reported in Figures 2-4, but the visual impression from these figures is of effects much larger than 1-3%.

Page 16: Framing Social Security Reform: Behavioral Responses to ... · Framing Social Security Reform: Behavioral Responses to Changes in the Full Retirement Age By Luc Behaghel and David

16

IV. Distinguishing among behavioral economic explanations

Results from section IV provide strong evidence that OASI benefit claiming behavior has

been influenced by the increase in the FRA, and weaker evidence that the same is true of labor

force participation. As argued in section II, this finding leaves behavioral factors as likely

explanations. However, as stressed by Kahneman (1999) and Featherstonehaugh and Ross

(1999), loss aversion is only one of the potential behavioral explanations: the implicit advice or

endorsement of the FRA by the SSA as a “normal” retirement age is another one. A third

possible explanation is that the FRA has become a “social norm”, because it is followed by the

majority. Conceptually, these three leading explanations are different. Loss aversion is a form of

non-standard preferences, whereas allowing one’s behavior to be governed by advice or by social

norms are forms of non-standard decision making.18 Discriminating empirically between these

three explanations is hard, even in an experimental context where one can, as in Brown et al.

(2011), manipulate the framing. The conceptual difference between non-standard decision

making and non-standard preferences however suggests an indirect test, by asking a simpler,

descriptive question: which types of workers respond most strongly to the FRA shift? This is

interesting per se – indeed, the recent retirement literature has stressed the fact that aggregate

retirement behavior may hide considerable heterogeneity (see the discussions by Burtless, 2006;

Liebman et al., 2009; and the empirical applications in Coile et al., 2002, and Chan and Stevens,

2008). It may also shed light on the most likely behavioral mechanism. For instance, if workers

with lower cognitive skills respond more to the FRA, this would point toward non-standard

decision making, making an “advice” or social norm explanation plausible.

A simple way to look at this question is to compare the FRA impacts across

subpopulations. The corresponding regression model is:

(2) iaciacciacacaiaciaciaciac TypeTypeTypeFRAFRAP εζγδβθθ +×+×+++×+= 111121 ,

where Type is an indicator variable that splits the population in two (for instance, Type is 1 for

individuals with higher numeracy, 0 otherwise). The estimate of 2θ reveals whether there is a

18 Advice and social norms are close, but they differ by who sets the norm and by their degree of

inertia: a given authority may change its advice with immediate effects whereas social norms are likely to change slowly.

Page 17: Framing Social Security Reform: Behavioral Responses to ... · Framing Social Security Reform: Behavioral Responses to Changes in the Full Retirement Age By Luc Behaghel and David

17

different response to the FRA in the population characterized by the Type variable. The type

variable is also interacted with cohort and age dummies, and the full sets of main effects from

Tables 1-3 are included as well. Equation (2) basically tests whether the FRA has heterogeneous

effects by a set of observable characteristics. We group the type variables into 3 broad

categories: socioeconomic; pension and job characteristics; and cognition and behavior.

Table 4 shows selected estimates from several specifications of equation (2) that include

alternative combinations of the type variables. The parameters of interest are the coefficient on

the “FRA*interaction term,” ( 2θ ). For instance, -12.5 in column (1) on the “FRA*defined

benefits” line means that workers with a defined benefit pension are 12.5 percentage points less

responsive to the FRA than are other individuals, other things equal. Wealth is associated with

higher responsiveness to the FRA (but the coefficient estimate is not significantly different from

zero). Higher cognitive ability is associated with a larger response to the FRA, with a statistically

significant effect of the memory index. There are no significant differential effects by socio-

demographic dimensions such as race, gender, marital status, or education. Having used the

online SSA calculator to compute future benefits or having the benefit calculated by the SSA has

no statistically significant impact on the responsiveness to the FRA.

Columns 2 to 6 of Table 4 explore the robustness of the positive interaction effect on

cognitive skills. Combining the cognitive measures into a single index yields a highly significant

effect (column 2).19 Dropping the DB variable (only available for a subsample of workers) does

not significantly alter the results (column 3). Adding FRA interactions with stressful and

physically demanding job indicators, health, subjective life expectancy, health insurance

coverage, financial planning horizon, and risk aversion has very little impact on the FRA-

cognition coefficient estimate (column 4). None of these additional FRA interaction coefficients

are significantly different from zero. The FRA-cognition coefficient estimate is also robust to

inclusion of an FRA-earnings test interaction (column 5). Checking for non linear effects, we

find that most of the cognition effect is due to the lowest quartile, with smaller differences

among the upper three quartiles (column 6). By contrast, there is no evidence of nonlinear effects

of wealth.

19 See the web appendix for details on the cognition index.

Page 18: Framing Social Security Reform: Behavioral Responses to ... · Framing Social Security Reform: Behavioral Responses to Changes in the Full Retirement Age By Luc Behaghel and David

18

A potential problem with the results in Table 4 is that the response to the FRA may be

lower for workers with low cognitive skills in absolute (percentage points) term because the age

65 spike is initially lower for them, although the responses may be more similar in relative terms.

Figure 5 (replicating figure 2 by cognitive skill group) shows that this is not the case: the age

profiles of the hazard rate of claiming are very similar for people with higher and lower cognitive

skills born in 1937. Spikes at the new FRAs appear for cohorts born after 1938, but, for people

with lower cognitive skills, the spike at the FRA is somewhat smaller and the spike at age 65

persists. This last fact suggests that people with lower cognitive skills may be slower to learn

about the change in the FRA and adapt it into their decision making. Instead, they may use

workers from earlier cohorts as a reference.20 21 The alternative behavioral explanations – advice

and social norms – imply unsophisticated decision making, which would predict a negative

FRA*cognition effect.

Of course, it may still be the case that these interaction effects are driven by unobserved

sources of heterogeneity. While we are confident that the 1983 reform allows us to identify the

causal effect of the FRA on different groups, the sources of variation that we use do not allow us

to say what causes the differences in response. However, as noted above, a plausible causal

interpretation of the DB interaction effect is that the presence of a DB pension reduces the

salience of the SS FRA, in particular when the DB pension plan maintains a normal retirement

age at 65. Accordingly, when we restrict the sample to DB holders we find that the

20 This section has focused on claiming behavior, for which there is strong and robust evidence of responsiveness to the FRA. Analysis of employment exit and self-reported retirement indicates that there is little heterogeneity that can be detected in the FRA effect on these outcomes (results available from the authors).

21 Other explanations are possible. One would be that the two groups take the FRA as the claiming age recommended by the SSA, but only workers with higher cognitive skills read their statements and learn about the new FRA. We consider this explanation as less plausible given the care taken by the SSA not to imply any advice in their phrasing of the leisure / consumption tradeoff. Another possible explanation is that the loss in expected lifetime utility from claiming at the FRA is small, because the present discounted value of lifetime benefits is intended to be approximately invariant to the age of claiming. If gathering the information needed to make a well-informed decision is costly (Mastrobuoni, 2011) then it could be optimal to simply follow the path of least resistance by claiming at a salient age such as the FRA. And if Social Security wealth provides a smaller share of retirement income for smart and/or wealthy individuals, this could make the utility cost of non-optimal claiming especially small. We cannot evaluate this explanation directly. Coile et al. (2002) find that in many circumstances it is optimal to delay claiming until the FRA but not beyond the FRA. However, their analysis was based on the rules for the 1930 birth cohort, for whom the Delayed Retirement Credit was only 3%.

Page 19: Framing Social Security Reform: Behavioral Responses to ... · Framing Social Security Reform: Behavioral Responses to Changes in the Full Retirement Age By Luc Behaghel and David

19

responsiveness to the SS FRA is lower for those with a DB plan that has a normal retirement age

at 65.22

V. Implications of the results for framing Social Security reform

We interpret the empirical results presented above as suggesting that reference

dependence with loss aversion is the behavioral explanation for the age 65 spike in claiming and

retirement decisions that is most consistent with the evidence. Admittedly, we have no direct

evidence to support this explanation; rather we have at least some evidence against the

alternatives. In this section, we introduce reference dependence in a lifetime labor supply model

in order to draw out its implications for framing of Social Security reforms. Specifically, we

derive conditions under which reference dependence leads to a greater increase in employment in

response to a benefit cut than would be predicted by the wealth effect alone. The model echoes

the way SSA frames the retirement decision, as a tradeoff between income and “years to enjoy

it”.

The set up is as simple as possible. Workers choose their optimal retirement and claiming

age,23 by trading off years of leisure l against lifetime consumption c. The age at death (T) is

fixed and known, so choosing retirement age R is equivalent to choosing lifetime leisure:

RTl −= (for convenience, we assume life begins at labor force entry). The budget constraint is

wRkc += , where wRk + is a linear approximation (in the vicinity of the FRA) to the lifetime

income derived from retiring at age R; k (initial wealth) and w (annual compensation, including

the wage and the increment to the Social Security benefit resulting from an additional year of

work) are fixed parameters in this approximation. This yields the standard static labor supply

model, interpreted as a model of lifetime labor supply:

22 The coefficient on FRA*(DB NRA=65) is -.095 (marginally significant with a standard error

of.059). 23 We assume that retirement and claiming occur at the same for age, for simplicity. This

assumption allows us to avoid introducing dynamics, which would be required to deal with minimum and maximum claiming ages and the possibility of a liquidity constraint. This assumption implies that we ignore the lower bound on claiming age. In the simulations described below, we do account for the lower bound on the claiming age. In practice, the majority of individuals claim at the same age at which they retire (Coile et al., 2002).

Page 20: Framing Social Security Reform: Behavioral Responses to ... · Framing Social Security Reform: Behavioral Responses to Changes in the Full Retirement Age By Luc Behaghel and David

20

(3) ).(..

),(max ,

lTwkctsclUlc

−+=

The SS rules and statements suggest a specific age, the FRA, as a reference. Let cFRA and

lFRA denote the levels of consumption and leisure from retiring and claiming at the FRA. Workers

may experience loss aversion with respect to either leisure or consumption or both: they may be

reluctant to reduce the number of “years to enjoy retirement” below the number implied by

retiring at their FRA, and they may be reluctant to consume less than the level implied by retiring

at the FRA. Following Tversky and Kahneman (1991), we incorporate reference dependence in a

two-good model with no uncertainty by specifying the payoff from choice (c,l) as:

(4) ),()(),( 21 cRlaRclU FRA +=

with FRAFRA

FRAFRA

lliflululRlliflululR

>−=≤−=

)()()())()(()(

1

11 λ

and .)()()(

))()(()(

2

22

FRAFRA

FRAFRA

ccifcvcvcRccifcvcvcR

>−=≤−= λ

1λ and 2λ are the coefficients of loss aversion, with 1, 21 >λλ if there is loss aversion, and

121 == λλ otherwise. u(.) and v(.) are increasing and concave utility subfunctions. Lastly,

0>a is an individual-specific parameter that allows for heterogeneity in the preference for

leisure.24

This specification captures an asymmetry in preferences with regard to losses and gains

around the FRA reference. Starting from the reference set by the FRA, the marginal utility of

increasing consumption by one dollar is )(' FRAcv whereas the utility loss from decreasing

consumption by one dollar is )('2 FRAcvλ . Similarly, increasing leisure time by one day increases

24 We introduce a as the only source of heterogeneity, and derive the distribution of retirement

ages from the distribution of a. One could introduce other sources of heterogeneity, either in preferences – 1λ , 2λ , u(.) and v(.) may vary across individuals – or in budget constraints – variations in k, w or T.

However, these other sources of heterogeneity have similar implications for the retirement age distribution: as long as they are continuously distributed (so that they do not generate a kink in preferences or the budget constraints), they cannot by themselves account for a spike in the retirement hazard.

Page 21: Framing Social Security Reform: Behavioral Responses to ... · Framing Social Security Reform: Behavioral Responses to Changes in the Full Retirement Age By Luc Behaghel and David

21

utility by )(' FRAlau , whereas reducing it by one day decreases utility by )('1 FRAluaλ . Both

dimensions of loss aversion increase the likelihood that the FRA is the optimal retirement age.

It is straightforward to show that the solution to problem 3 given preferences characterized by

equation 4 can be characterized by two critical values of a: individuals with low preference for

leisure ()(')('

1 FRA

FRA

lucvwa

λ< ) retire after the full retirement age; those with high preference for leisure

()(')('

2FRA

FRA

lucvwa λ> ) retire before the full retirement age; and workers with intermediate

preferences for leisure ( ⎥⎦

⎤⎢⎣

⎡∈

)(')(';

)(')('

21 FRA

FRA

FRA

FRA

lucvw

lucvwa λ

λ) retire exactly at the FRA. These three

cases are illustrated in figure 6, which plots UFRA as a function of l, after substituting for

consumption from the budget constraint. UFRA has a kink at lFRA. This kink generates a mass

point at the FRA in the distribution of retirement ages. Let F denote the c.d.f. of a, and PFRA

denote the fraction of workers retiring at the FRA. Then:

(5) .)(')('

)(')('

12 ⎟⎟

⎞⎜⎜⎝

⎛−⎟⎟

⎞⎜⎜⎝

⎛=

FRA

FRA

FRA

FRAFRA lu

cvwFlucvwFP

λλ

The fact that PFRA is strictly positive if either 11 >λ or 12 >λ shows that loss aversion in either

of the two dimensions can generate the spike. However, these two dimensions have opposite

impacts on the rest of the retirement age distribution. Starting from a situation without loss

aversion ( 121 == λλ ), an increase in 1λ attracts workers who would otherwise work longer

toward the FRA, thus reducing the average retirement age (see the web appendix for details). By

contrast, an increase in 2λ attracts workers who would otherwise retire earlier toward the FRA,

thus increasing the average retirement age. Overall, the impact of reference dependence and loss

aversion on the average retirement age is ambiguous a priori.

Page 22: Framing Social Security Reform: Behavioral Responses to ... · Framing Social Security Reform: Behavioral Responses to Changes in the Full Retirement Age By Luc Behaghel and David

22

A. Impact of the 1983 reform

The 1983 reform, as framed by the SSA, can easily be incorporated into the model as a

change in the reference age. In order to maintain the same level of benefits, workers born after

1937 must delay retirement by (FRA - 65 years). In the model’s notation, the reform is such that

0=Δ FRAc and 0<Δ FRAl . All other things equal, this has two effects on the retirement age

distribution: First, the spike in the retirement hazard shifts to the new FRA. Second, the

probability of retiring before the FRA goes up, while the probability of retiring after the FRA

decreases. The combined effect is an increase in the average retirement age. We now ask

whether a different framing of the reform would have yielded different results. Specifically, how

does dkRdE /)( , the response of the average retirement age R to a given shift in the intercept of

the benefit schedule dk, holding the slope (w) constant, vary with the way the reform is framed?

In all cases, we have

(6) ∫−=−= daafalTlETRE )()()()( * ,

where f is the density of a, and )(* al is the level of leisure chosen by a worker given his

preference for leisure. The quantity we are interested in is

(7) ∫−= daafdk

adldk

RdE )()()( *

;

The first framing option we consider is neutral: your benefit schedule is lower than the

schedule of your older peers, without reference to a specific age. In this case the response of

)(* al to the reform is simply given by differentiating the standard first order conditions for an

interior solution, which yields the standard wealth effect (see the web appendix).25

In the second framing option, workers have the same reference point after the reform

( FRAl ). However, SSA tells them that there is a cut in benefits for claiming at the FRA. In other

words, they still perceive that they meet a consumption target if they retire at 65 after the reform,

25 This only holds if there was no loss aversion and framing before the reform. Otherwise, it is

unclear how a neutral framing of the reform would be perceived: would it cancel the initial reference? If not, and if workers keep the initial reference point, the first framing option would be equivalent to the second option, described below.

Page 23: Framing Social Security Reform: Behavioral Responses to ... · Framing Social Security Reform: Behavioral Responses to Changes in the Full Retirement Age By Luc Behaghel and David

23

but the target is now lower. This arises if the reform is framed as a change in the Primary

Insurance Amount (the benefit amount available if claimed at the FRA) with no change in the

FRA itself.

Finally, the third framing option is the one actually mandated by the reform: a change in

the FRA with no mention of a benefit cut. In this case, things remain as in the 2nd framing option

for workers with low and high preference for leisure. Things do however differ for workers with

intermediate preferences for leisure. The condition for claiming at the FRA is the same as under

the second framing option. However, the FRA itself changes, with .1 dkw

dlFRA =

The web appendix shows that 23

)()(⎥⎦⎤

⎢⎣⎡>⎥⎦

⎤⎢⎣⎡

dkRdE

dkRdE , where the subscript indicates the

framing option. In the presence of reference dependence, the reform has a stronger impact on the

average age of retirement and claiming if it is framed as a change in the reference point than if it

is framed as an equivalent change in the benefit at an unchanged reference point. The

comparison with 1

)(⎥⎦⎤

⎢⎣⎡

dkRdE (neutral framing) is less immediate; it depends on the parameters.

However, empirical estimates suggest that 13

)()(⎥⎦⎤

⎢⎣⎡>⎥⎦

⎤⎢⎣⎡

dkRdE

dkRdE . Indeed, Mastrobuoni (2009)

finds that the average response to a 1 year increase in the FRA (under the 3rd framing option,

which is how it was framed by SSA) is a 0.5 year increase in the average retirement age. In the

framework of our model, the .5 response must be a weighted average of 1 for people at the old

FRA (who will move to the new FRA, a one-for-one effect) and δ (the average response for

people above and below the FRA). This implies that 1<δ . More precisely, the magnifying

effect caused by framing under the 3rd framing option is positively correlated with the share of

the population clustered at the FRA. Assuming that the response is roughly constant for other

workers (δ is a constant), we have

(8) [ ] [ ])1((1)1(1)(

3

δδδ −+−=+−−≈⎥⎦⎤

⎢⎣⎡

FRAFRAFRA Pw

PPwdk

RdE

which is increasing in PFRA.

Page 24: Framing Social Security Reform: Behavioral Responses to ... · Framing Social Security Reform: Behavioral Responses to Changes in the Full Retirement Age By Luc Behaghel and David

24

In sum, compared to a situation without a reference point (PFRA = 0), reference

dependence magnifies the impact of a reform if the reform is expressed as a change in the

reference point. This magnifying effect increases with the share of the population initially

clustered at the reference point.26

Is loss aversion enough to explain the unexpectedly strong impact of the 1983 reform

found by Mastrobuoni (2009) and others? Our analysis suggests that reference dependence

matters, by shifting the workers clustered at the old reference point toward the new reference

point. However, as noted above, the share of workers who have not retired or claimed benefits by

the age of 65 is relatively small, so the impact on the average retirement age should be relatively

modest.27 Moreover, Mastrobuoni’s results show that the 1983 reform also strongly affected the

retirement distribution at ages 62 to 64, suggesting that while loss aversion has probably

magnified the impact of the reform, it may not fully explain the large effect of the reform.

VI. Conclusion

This paper has used the 1983 Social Security reform as a quasi-experiment to provide

evidence on framing effects in retirement behavior. From a methodological perspective, the FRA

is particularly well-suited to study reference dependence: in contrast with other applications of

reference dependence to labor supply analysis, the reference is explicitly defined and then

exogenously modified by the 1983 reform. The FRA impact is unambiguously identified by

cohort discontinuities. Although one cannot fully rule out alternative behavioral explanations

such as social norms or reliance on SSA “advice”, the latter explanations seem at odds with the

fact that workers with higher cognitive ability respond more to the FRA change. Responsiveness

to the FRA does not seem to be due to unsophisticated decision making.

Framing effects have been well documented in the related domain of pension plan choice.

Our results indicate that they exist in benefit claiming and retirement as well. Given that around

26 We parameterized the model and simulated the impact of a benefit cut under various assumptions about loss aversion, framing, and parameter values. The results indicate that framing the cut as an increase in the FRA amplifies its effect on the mean retirement age substantially, while neutral framing and framing as a cut in the PIA lead to much smaller effects. The simulation results are described in the web appendix.

27 For instance, if 10% of workers initially retired at their FRA, the amplifying effect due to these workers would be less than .1 years (10% of workers postponing retirement by 1 year).

Page 25: Framing Social Security Reform: Behavioral Responses to ... · Framing Social Security Reform: Behavioral Responses to Changes in the Full Retirement Age By Luc Behaghel and David

25

3 workers out of 4 have already claimed SS benefits before the FRA, the aggregate impact of

loss aversion in the context of the 1983 reform is probably modest. However, the mechanisms at

play are quite general and have potentially important implications for framing of future reforms,

in the same way as findings on savings and pension plan decisions have led to “behavioral

institutional design” recommendations (see, e.g., Benartzi and Thaler, 2004). Indeed, we showed

that in a simple extension of the standard labor supply model, framing provides the decision

maker with a potentially powerful and almost costless tool to influence aggregate labor supply:

framing a reform as a change in the reference point magnifies the impact, whereas framing it as a

benefit cut dampens the response. How to use this knowledge depends on the goals of reform,

and this suggests an important avenue for research: how should policy makers take into account

loss aversion in designing future reforms?

Page 26: Framing Social Security Reform: Behavioral Responses to ... · Framing Social Security Reform: Behavioral Responses to Changes in the Full Retirement Age By Luc Behaghel and David

26

References

Baker, Michael, and Dwayne Benjamin. 1999. “Early Retirement Provisions and the Labor Force

Behavior of Older Men: Evidence from Canada,” Journal of Labor Economics 17 (4),

Part 1, October: 724-756.

Benjamin, Daniel J., Sebastian A. Brown, and Jesse M. Shapiro. 2006. “Who is ‘Behavioral’?

Cognitive Ability and Anomalous Preferences.” Harvard University, mimeo, 2006.

Benartzi, Shlomo and Richard Thaler. 2004. “Save More Tomorrow (TM): Using Behavioral

Economics to Increase Employee Saving,” Journal of Political Economy, 112(S1): S164-S187.

Blau, David M., and Donna Gilleskie. 2008. “The Role of Retiree Health Insurance in the

Employment Behavior of Older Men” International Economic Review, 49 (2): 475-514.

Blau, David M., and Donna Gilleskie. 2006. “Health Insurance and Retirement of Married

Couples” Journal of Applied Econometrics, 21, Nov.: 935–953.

Blau, David M., and Ryan Goodstein. 2010. “Can Social Security Explain Trends in Labor Force

Participation of Older Men in the United States?” Journal of Human Resources. 45 (2):

326-63.

Brown, Jeffrey, Arie Kapteyn, Olivia S. Mitchell. 2011. “Framing Effects and Expected Social

Security Claiming Behavior,” NBER Working Paper 17018, May.

Burtless, Gary. 2006 “Social Norms, Rules of Thumbs, and Retirement: Evidence for Rationality

in Retirement Planning”, in K.W. Schaie and L.L. Carstensen eds. Social Structures, Self-

Regulation, and Aging, New York: Springer.

Chan, Sewin, and Ann Huff Stevens. 2008. “What You Don’t Know Can’t Help You. Pension

Knowledge and Retirement Decision-Making,” Review of Economics and Statistics, May.

Coile, Courtney C., Peter Diamond, Jonathan Gruber, and Alain Jousten. 2002. “Delays in

Claiming Social Security Benefits,” Journal of Public Economics, 84 (3), July: 357-385.

Coile, Courtney, and Jonathan Gruber. 2007. “Future Social Security Entitlements and the

Retirement Decision,” Review of Economics and Statistics 89 (2): 234-46.

Costa, Dora (1998. The Evolution of Retirement: An American Economic History, 1880-1990,

Chicago: University of Chicago Press.

Page 27: Framing Social Security Reform: Behavioral Responses to ... · Framing Social Security Reform: Behavioral Responses to Changes in the Full Retirement Age By Luc Behaghel and David

27

Crawford, Vincent P., and David M. Lilien. 1981. “Social Security and the Retirement

Decision,” Quarterly Journal of Economics 96 (3): 505-29.

Featherstonehaugh, David, and Lee Ross. 1999. “Framing Effects and Income Flow Preferences

in Decisions About Social Security,” in Henry Aaron ed. Behavioral Dimensions of

Retirement Economics Washington DC, Brookings Institution Press and Russell Sage

Foundation: 187-209.

French, Eric, and John Bailey Jones. 2011. “The Effects of Health Insurance and Self-Insurance

on Retirement Behavior, Econometrica 79 (3): 693-732.

Hurd, Michael. 1990. “Research on the Elderly: Economic Status, Retirement, and Consumption

and Saving,” Journal of Economic Literature 28 (2): 565-637.

Kahneman, Daniel. 1999. Comment on “Framing Effects and Income Flow Preferences in

Decisions About Social Security,” by Featherstonehaugh and Ross, in Henry Aaron ed.

Behavioral Dimensions of Retirement Economics Washington DC, Brookings Institution

Press and Russell Sage Foundation: 210-213.

Kopczuk, Wojciech, and Jae Song. 2008. “Stylized Facts and Incentive Effects Related to

Claiming of Retirement Benefits Based on Social Security Administration Data,”

Michigan Retirement Research Center Working Paper 2008-200, October.

Liebman J., E. Luttmer and D. Seif. 2009. “Labor Supply Responses Marginal Social Security

Benefits: Evidence from Discontinuities”, Journal of Public Economics 93 (11-12):

1208-23.

Liebman, Jeffrey B., and Erzo F.P Luttmer. 2009. “The Perception of Social Security Incentives

for Labor Supply and Retirement: The Median Voter Knows a Lot More Than You’d

Think,” Working paper, Harvard University, April.

Liebman, Jeffrey B., and Erzo F.P Luttmer. 2011. “Would People Behave Differently if They

Better Understood Social Security? Evidence from a Field Experiment” NBER Working

Paper 17287, August.

Lumsdaine, Robin L., James H. Stock, and David A. Wise. 1996. “Why Are Retirement Rates So

High at Age 65?” in David A. Wise ed. Advances in the Economics of Aging Chicago:

University of Chicago Press: 61-82.

Page 28: Framing Social Security Reform: Behavioral Responses to ... · Framing Social Security Reform: Behavioral Responses to Changes in the Full Retirement Age By Luc Behaghel and David

28

Madrian, Brigitte C. 1994. “The Effect of Health Insurance on Retirement,” Brookings Papers

on Economic Activity (1): 181-252.

Madrian, Brigitte C., and Dennis F. Shea. 2001. “The Power of Suggestion: Inertia in 401(k)

Participation and Savings Behavior,” Quarterly Journal of Economics 116:1149-87.

Manoli, Dayand, Kathleen Mullen, and Mathis Wagner. 2009. “Risk Aversion and Retirement

Decisions: Using Policy Variation to Identify and Estimate a Structural Model of

Retirement,” Working Paper, UCLA.

Mastrobuoni, Giovanni. 2009. “Labor Supply Effects of the Recent Social Security Benefit Cuts:

Empirical Estimates Using Cohort Discontinuities,” Journal of Public Economics 93 (11-

12), December: 1224-33.

Mastrobuoni, Giovanni. 2011. “The Role of Information in Retirement Behavior: Evidence

Based on the Social Security Statement,” Journal of Public Economics 95 (7-8): 913-25.

McArdle, John, James Smith and Robert Willis. 2011. “Cognition and Economic Outcomes in

the Health and Retirement Survey,” in David Wise (ed.) Explorations in the Economics

of Aging, Chicago: University of Chicago Press for the NBER: 209-33.

Moffitt, Robert A. 1987. “Life Cycle Labor Supply and Social Security: A Time Series

Analysis,” In Work, Health, and Income among the Elderly, ed. Gary Burtless, 183–220

Washington, D.C.: The Brookings Institution.

Perrachi, Franco, and Finis Welch. 1994. “Trends in Labor Force Transitions of Older Men and

Women,” Journal of Labor Economics 12 (2): 210-42.

Poterba, James, Steven Venti, and David A.Wise. 2007. “The changing landscape of pensions in

the United States,” NBER Working Paper 13381, September.

Pingle, Jonathan F. 2006. “Social Security’s Delayed Retirement Credit and the Labor Supply of

Older Men,” Working Paper, Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System, June.

Rust John, and Christopher Phelan. 1997. “How Social Security and Medicare Affect Retirement

Behavior in a World of Incomplete Markets,” Econometrica 65: 781-831.

Samwick, Andrew A. 1998. “New Evidence on Pensions, Social Security, and the Timing of

Retirement,” Journal of Public Economics 70: 207-36.

Page 29: Framing Social Security Reform: Behavioral Responses to ... · Framing Social Security Reform: Behavioral Responses to Changes in the Full Retirement Age By Luc Behaghel and David

29

Social Security Advisory Board. 2009. “The Social Security Statement: How It Can Be

Improved,” http://www.ssab.gov/documents/Pre-

Publication_Version_The_Social_Security_Statement_web.pdf, May, accessed

11/02/2011.

Song, Jae, and Joyce Manchester. 2008. “Have People Delayed Claiming Social Security

Benefits? Responses to Changes in Social Security Rules, Social Security Bulletin 67 (2):

1-23.

Tversky, Amos, and Daniel Kahneman. 1991. “Loss Aversion in Riskless Choice: A Reference

Dependent Model”, Quarterly Journal of Economics 106(4): 1039-1061.

U.S. Department of Labor. 2003. “National Compensation Survey: Employee Benefits in Private

Industry in the United States, 2000,” U.S. Bureau of Labor Statistics, January, Bulletin

2555.

U.S. Department of Labor. 2007. “National Compensation Survey: Employee Benefits in Private

Industry in the United States, 2005,” U.S. Bureau of Labor Statistics, May, Bulletin 2589.

Page 30: Framing Social Security Reform: Behavioral Responses to ... · Framing Social Security Reform: Behavioral Responses to Changes in the Full Retirement Age By Luc Behaghel and David

30

Figure 1: Relationship between Social Security Benefit Claiming Age and Benefit level as a Percent of the Primary Insurance Amount for Three Birth Cohorts

8010

012

014

0

62 64 66 68 70age

born_1924 born_1937born_1943

Source: Authors’ calculation from Social Security rules. Primary Insurance Amount is the benefit amount when claimed at the Full Retirement Age.

Page 31: Framing Social Security Reform: Behavioral Responses to ... · Framing Social Security Reform: Behavioral Responses to Changes in the Full Retirement Age By Luc Behaghel and David

31

0.1

.2.3

.4

62 63 64 65Age (in years)

1937 cohort

0.1

.2.3

.4

62 63 64 65Age (in years)

1938 cohort0

.1.2

.3.4

62 63 64 65Age (in years)

1939 cohort

0.1

.2.3

.4

62 63 64 65Age (in years)

1940 cohort

0.1

.2.3

.4

62 63 64 65Age (in years)

1941 cohort

0.1

.2.3

.4

62 63 64 65Age (in years)

1942 cohort

Figure 2: SS Benefit Claiming Hazard

Notes: The graphs show the average monthly claiming hazard rates for pre and post-reform cohorts. The claiming hazard rate is defined as the probability of claiming at a given age, conditional on not having claimed previously. Age is measured at a bimonthly frequency; e.g. age 65 denotes age 65 0/12 to 65 1/12. In each graph, the dotted line depicts the claiming hazard for workers born between 1931 and 1936. For each cohort, the vertical lines indicate age 62, age 65, and the FRA (if different from age 65).

Page 32: Framing Social Security Reform: Behavioral Responses to ... · Framing Social Security Reform: Behavioral Responses to Changes in the Full Retirement Age By Luc Behaghel and David

32

0.0

2.0

4.0

6

62 63 64 65Age (in years)

1937 cohort

0.0

2.0

4.0

6

62 63 64 65Age (in years)

1938 cohort0

.02

.04

.06

62 63 64 65Age (in years)

1939 cohort

0.0

2.0

4.0

6

62 63 64 65Age (in years)

1940 cohort

0.0

2.0

4.0

6

62 63 64 65Age (in years)

1941 cohort

0.0

2.0

4.0

6

62 63 64 65Age (in years)

1942 cohort

Figure 3: Hazard of Exit from Employment

Notes: see notes to figure 2. The hazard of exit from employment is the probability of not being employed for any part of a given month, conditional on having been employed in at least part of the previous month.

Page 33: Framing Social Security Reform: Behavioral Responses to ... · Framing Social Security Reform: Behavioral Responses to Changes in the Full Retirement Age By Luc Behaghel and David

33

0.0

5.1

.15

.2

62 63 64 65Age (in years)

1937 cohort

0.0

5.1

.15

.2

62 63 64 65Age (in years)

1938 cohort0

.05

.1.1

5.2

62 63 64 65Age (in years)

1939 cohort

0.0

5.1

.15

.2

62 63 64 65Age (in years)

1940 cohort

0.0

5.1

.15

.2

62 63 64 65Age (in years)

1941 cohort

0.0

5.1

.15

.2

62 63 64 65Age (in years)

1942 cohort

Figure 4: Hazard of Retirement

Notes: see notes to figure 2. To keep the same scale on the vertical axis for 1942 as for other birth cohorts, the hazard rate at age 65 10/12 has been arbitrarily set at .2. The observed value is .6 (over only 5 individuals). The hazard of retirement is defined as the probability of reporting being retired in a given month, conditional on not having reported being retired previously.

Page 34: Framing Social Security Reform: Behavioral Responses to ... · Framing Social Security Reform: Behavioral Responses to Changes in the Full Retirement Age By Luc Behaghel and David

34

0.1

.2.3

.4

62 63 64 65Age (in years)

1937 cohort

0.1

.2.3

.4

62 63 64 65Age (in years)

1938 cohort0

.1.2

.3.4

62 63 64 65Age (in years)

1939 cohort0

.1.2

.3.4

62 63 64 65Age (in years)

1940 cohort

0.1

.2.3

.4

62 63 64 65Age (in years)

1941 cohort

0.1

.2.3

.4

62 63 64 65Age (in years)

1942 cohort

Workers with higher vs. lower cognitive skillsFigure 5: SS Benefit Claiming Hazard

Notes: see notes to figure 2. People with a cognitive index above the median are in black dashed lines, people with a cognitive index below the median are in gray full lines.

Page 35: Framing Social Security Reform: Behavioral Responses to ... · Framing Social Security Reform: Behavioral Responses to Changes in the Full Retirement Age By Luc Behaghel and David

35

Figure 6: Heterogeneous preference for leisure and optimal retirement age

Notes: see discussion in the text.

l

UFRA(l,k+w(T-l))

lFRA

High preference for leisure: retiring early

Low preference for leisure: retiring late

Intermediary preference for leisure: retiring at the FRA

l

UFRA(l,k+w(T-l))

lFRA

High preference for leisure: retiring early

Low preference for leisure: retiring late

Intermediary preference for leisure: retiring at the FRA

Page 36: Framing Social Security Reform: Behavioral Responses to ... · Framing Social Security Reform: Behavioral Responses to Changes in the Full Retirement Age By Luc Behaghel and David

36

Table 1: Impact of the FRA on OASI Benefit Claiming Hazard

(1) (2) (3) (4)

FRA 13.8*** 13.6*** 13.3*** 13.6***(1.9) (1.9) (1.9) (1.9)

SS earnings test removal 3.2***(1.0)

Controls No Yes Yes YesAge range 64-66 64-66 62-66 64-66

N 25801 25801 89348 25801R² 0.146 0.154 0.162 0.155

Claiming social security (OASI) benefits

Notes: FRA is a dummy variable equal to 1 if the current month is the FRA and zero otherwise. The coefficients measure the percentage point increase in the SS benefit claiming monthly hazard at the FRA. See equation (1) for the specification. The dependent variable is a dummy for claiming social benefits in the current month. The sample includes all person-months from age 62 to 70 in which an individual had not yet claimed. Cases that claimed before age 62 are excluded. The models were estimated by OLS with standard errors clustered by individuals. Each regression includes a full set of monthly age dummies and birth cohort dummies. Controls in columns (2)-(5): race, sex, marital status, education, health, health insurance coverage, retiree health insurance coverage, pension coverage, pension type, household wealth, average hourly earnings, and measures of cognitive capability, planning horizon, and risk aversion. Sample: HRS waves 1992-2008, cohorts born in 1932-41. Age range included in the regression differs by column. *, **, and *** indicate that the coefficient estimate is significantly different from zero at the 10%, 5%, and 1% level, respectively.

Table 2: Impact of the FRA on the Hazard of Exit from Employment

(1) (2) (3) (4)

FRA 1.0*** 0.9** 0.9** 1.0***(0.4) (0.4) (0.4) (0.4)

SS earnings test removal 0.5*(0.3)

Controls No Yes Yes YesAge range 64-66 64-66 62-66 64-66

N 68952 68952 152753 68952R² 0.016 0.047 0.054 0.047

Exit from Employment

Notes: see notes to Table 1. The dependent variable is a dummy for non-employment in the current month, conditional on employment in the previous month. The sample includes all person-months in which an individual was employed for any part of the month.

Page 37: Framing Social Security Reform: Behavioral Responses to ... · Framing Social Security Reform: Behavioral Responses to Changes in the Full Retirement Age By Luc Behaghel and David

37

Table 3: Impact of the FRA on the Hazard of Retirement

(1) (2) (3) (4)

FRA 1.5 1.1 1.1 1.1(1.6) (1.6) (1.6) (1.6)

SS earnings test removal 2.2**(1.1)

Controls No Yes Yes YesAge range 64-66 64-66 62-66 64-66

N 16387 16387 46737 16387R² 0.056 0.082 0.085 0.083

Retiring

Notes: see notes to Table 1. The dependent variable is a dummy equal to one if the current month corresponds to the respondent’s self-reported retirement age.The sample includes all person-months prior to the date at which the individual reported retiring. Cases that gave longitudinally inconsistent reports are excluded.

Page 38: Framing Social Security Reform: Behavioral Responses to ... · Framing Social Security Reform: Behavioral Responses to Changes in the Full Retirement Age By Luc Behaghel and David

38

Table 4: Differential impact of the FRA on SS Benefit Claiming Hazard, by type of worker

(1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6)

FRA*high wealth 3.8 4.4 6.7 6.2 6.0(7.0) (7.1) (5.6) (6.5) (6.5)

FRA*(2nd quartile wealth) 3.9(7.9)

FRA*(3rd quartile wealth) 0.9(8.3)

FRA*(4th quartile wealth) 6.8(8.4)

FRA*defined benefits -12.5** -12.5**(6.1) (6.2)

FRA*high numeracy 3.7(6.7)

FRA*high memory 14.3**(6.6)

FRA*high TICS 23.0**(9.7)

FRA*cognition index 1.7 2.2** 2.3** 2.3**(1.1) (0.9) (0.9) (0.9)

FRA*(2nd quartile cognition index) 16.0**(8.1)

FRA*(3rd quartile cognition index) 24.2***(8.0)

FRA*(4th quartile cognition index) 26.4***(8.5)

FRA*calculated SS benefits 4.4 5.2 3.7 7.1 7.0 5.6(6.2) (6.2) (4.8) (5.2) (5.2) (5.1)

FRA*years of education 1.2 1.3 0.0 0.3 0.2 0.1(1.1) (1.1) (0.9) (1.1) (1.1) (1.1)

FRA*white -1.1 3.6 -0.6 -8.0 -7.7 -8.3(9.1) (9.4) (7.3) (8.2) (8.1) (7.7)

FRA*woman 7.5 10.4 -1.5 2.4 2.3 2.2(7.6) (7.2) (5.0) (5.6) (5.6) (5.7)

FRA*married 6.5 5.5 -4.5 0.6 0.8 1.4(7.8) (8.0) (5.6) (6.3) (6.3) (6.2)

FRA*stressful job 1.4 1.7 2.8(5.2) (5.2) (5.2)

FRA*physically demanding job -1.0 -0.8 -1.8(5.9) (5.9) (5.9)

FRA*bad health 4.4 3.9 4.5(8.9) (8.9) (8.7)

FRA*long subjective life expectancy -1.5 -1.6 -1.3(5.3) (5.3) (5.3)

FRA*covered by health insurance from job -8.1 -8.0 -7.4(5.5) (5.5) (5.5)

FRA*long financial planning horizon 4.7 4.7 5.9(5.6) (5.5) (5.6)

FRA*risk averse -1.6 -1.4 -1.8(5.1) (5.1) (5.2)

SS earnings test removal*cognition index -0.5 -0.4(0.4) (0.4)

N 28022 28022 57444 45509 45509 45509R² 0.12 0.11 0.15 0.14 0.14 0.14

Claiming social security (OASI) benefits

Notes: see notes to Table 1. See equation (2) for the model specification. Each regression includes a full set of monthly age

dummies and birth cohort dummies interacted with the different interaction variables, as well as a direct FRA effect.