ECONOMICS OF THE PHARMACEUTICAL INDUSTRY 25 th March 2004

34
ECONOMICS OF THE PHARMACEUTICAL INDUSTRY 25 th March 2004 Jon Sussex Office of Health Economics www.ohe.org

description

ECONOMICS OF THE PHARMACEUTICAL INDUSTRY 25 th March 2004. Jon Sussex Office of Health Economics www.ohe.org. Agenda. The supply side – R&D Demand for medicines NICE – the cost-effectiveness ‘4 th hurdle’ Regulating medicine prices. Characteristics of Medicines Markets. - PowerPoint PPT Presentation

Transcript of ECONOMICS OF THE PHARMACEUTICAL INDUSTRY 25 th March 2004

Page 1: ECONOMICS OF THE PHARMACEUTICAL INDUSTRY 25 th  March 2004

ECONOMICS OF THE PHARMACEUTICAL

INDUSTRY

25th March 2004

Jon SussexOffice of Health Economics

www.ohe.org

Page 2: ECONOMICS OF THE PHARMACEUTICAL INDUSTRY 25 th  March 2004

Agenda

1. The supply side – R&D

2. Demand for medicines

3. NICE – the cost-effectiveness ‘4th hurdle’

4. Regulating medicine prices

Page 3: ECONOMICS OF THE PHARMACEUTICAL INDUSTRY 25 th  March 2004

Characteristics of Medicines Markets

• Supply is R&D intensive, which implies:– Intellectual property rights (patents)– Long lead times– High risk– Dynamic competition as important as static– Generic competition after patent expiry

• Demand is regulated – governments and social insurers are major buyers of medicines

• Prices are regulated

Page 4: ECONOMICS OF THE PHARMACEUTICAL INDUSTRY 25 th  March 2004

Supply Side – Main Characteristics (1)

• Patents are an incentive for dynamic efficiency – by promising temporary monopoly if successful

• Patents last 20 years; first 9-11 of which are spent getting the medicine to market, i.e. research & development (R&D)

• Commercial success in R&D-based companies depends on finding ‘blockbusters’

Page 5: ECONOMICS OF THE PHARMACEUTICAL INDUSTRY 25 th  March 2004

Supply Side – Main Characteristics (2)

• Average R&D cost of a new medicine up to launch is $800 million

• Includes costs of failures

• Out of pocket costs ≈ 50%

• Opportunity cost of capital ≈ 50%

• Only ≈ 30% of launched medicines earn revenues that exceed their lifetime costs

Page 6: ECONOMICS OF THE PHARMACEUTICAL INDUSTRY 25 th  March 2004

Phase III

Development research

Discovery and Development of a New MedicineDiscovery and Development of a New Medicine

Final patent application

Marketing application

Attrition rates

Cost

Post-mktng devel

3000 + patients

Phase IV

5,000

8-15 4-8 2-3 1 1

$800M

0

Chemical development

Pharmaceutical development

Long-term animal testing

Toxicology and pharmacokinetic studies

Source: CMR International

1993

Discovery research

Investigational new drug

application

1990

Phase I

Phase II

SynthesisBiological testing

& pharmacological

screening

50-100 voluns

200-400 patients

1999

Marketing approval product launch

2001

Regulatory review

Regulations

Time (years)

Phases of drug

development

Basic researc

h

Clinical phases

Page 7: ECONOMICS OF THE PHARMACEUTICAL INDUSTRY 25 th  March 2004

Cash Flow for a Successful Medicine

Launch

Patent expiry

£ p.a. +

_

0Time

Page 8: ECONOMICS OF THE PHARMACEUTICAL INDUSTRY 25 th  March 2004

Supply Side – Main Characteristics (3)

• R&D costs are sunk (global) joint costs

• R&D costs ≈ 17% of pharmaceutical sales p.a.

But ≈ 31% of costs on net present value basis

• => (even long-run) marginal cost << average cost

• => Price discrimination (based on Ramsey rule?) if non-linear pricing is impractical

Parallel trade

Page 9: ECONOMICS OF THE PHARMACEUTICAL INDUSTRY 25 th  March 2004
Page 10: ECONOMICS OF THE PHARMACEUTICAL INDUSTRY 25 th  March 2004

Pharmaceutical Sales as % of GDP 1998-2002

0.74%

0.84%

0.88%

0.95%

1.02%

1.10%

1.12%

1.32%

1.34%

1.34%

1.88%

0.00% 0.50% 1.00% 1.50% 2.00%

Netherlands

Switzerland

United Kingdom

Australia

Sweden

Germany

Canada

Italy

J apan

Spain

France

USA *

1998 1999 2000 2001 2002

Page 11: ECONOMICS OF THE PHARMACEUTICAL INDUSTRY 25 th  March 2004

Types of Medicines

Original brand Branded Unbranded OTCs*

On-patent Off-patent generics generics

NHS

Private

* OTCs = over the counter (i.e. non-prescription) medicines

Page 12: ECONOMICS OF THE PHARMACEUTICAL INDUSTRY 25 th  March 2004

Demand Side Characteristics

Chooses Consumes Pays

Normal market

Consumer Consumer Consumer

Prescriptionmedicines market

Prescriber Patient Government / insurer

Page 13: ECONOMICS OF THE PHARMACEUTICAL INDUSTRY 25 th  March 2004

Measures Affecting Prescriber Price Sensitivity

• Primary Care Trust budgets

• Practice budgets and prescribing incentive schemes

• Provision of information (PACT, NICE guidance, pharmaceutical advisers, etc.)

• Generic prescribing targets

Page 14: ECONOMICS OF THE PHARMACEUTICAL INDUSTRY 25 th  March 2004

National Institute for Clinical Excellence

• Covers England & Wales

• Two main outputs:

1. Technology appraisals

2. Clinical guidelines

Page 15: ECONOMICS OF THE PHARMACEUTICAL INDUSTRY 25 th  March 2004

Technology Appraisal Criteria

• The Institute and Appraisal Committee will have regard to:

– the broad clinical priorities of the Secretary of State for Health and the Welsh Assembly Government

– the degree of clinical need of patients with the condition

– the broad balance of benefits and costs

– any guidance from the Secretary of State for Health and the Welsh Assembly Government on the resources likely to be available and on such other matters as they think fit

– the effective use of available resources

Page 16: ECONOMICS OF THE PHARMACEUTICAL INDUSTRY 25 th  March 2004

NICE’s Guide to Methods of Technology Appraisal

• Below a most plausible incremental cost-effectiveness ratio (ICER) of £20,000/QALY, judgments about the acceptability of a technology as an effective use of NHS resources are based primarily on the cost-effectiveness estimate.

• Above a most plausible ICER of £20,000/QALY, judgments about the acceptability of the technology as an effective use of NHS resources are more likely to make more explicit reference to factors including:

– the degree of uncertainty surrounding the calculation of ICERs

– the innovative nature of the technology– the particular features of the condition and population

receiving the technology– where appropriate, the wider societal costs and benefits

• Above an ICER of £30,000/QALY, the case for supporting the technology on these factors has to be increasingly strong

Page 17: ECONOMICS OF THE PHARMACEUTICAL INDUSTRY 25 th  March 2004

Completed Appraisals (- Jan 2004)

• 75 (including re-appraisals), of which 52 have been of pharmaceuticals:

– restrictions in 32 appraisals e.g. Alzheimer’s drugs recommended in patients with mini

mental state examination>12 e.g. zanamivir, oseltamivir recommended in at-risk

patients with influenza

– a technology has been rejected in 13 appraisals e.g. MS drugs anakinra for rheumatoid arthritis (except in a controlled

long term clinical study)

• NICE has also issued 21 clinical guidelines (11 inherited)

Page 18: ECONOMICS OF THE PHARMACEUTICAL INDUSTRY 25 th  March 2004

Economic Evaluation Elsewhere

• Focused on pharmaceuticals

• Fourth hurdle i.e. reimbursement decisions:

– Public reimbursement: Australia, Baltic countries, Belgium, Canada (British Columbia, Ontario), Czech Republic, Denmark, Finland, France, Hungary, Netherlands, New Zealand, Norway, Portugal, Russia, Slovenia, Sweden

– US managed care formularies

• Pricing negotiations– Australia, France, Italy, New Zealand

• Advice to health service– England and Wales (NICE), Scotland

• Risk sharing arrangements– Australia, New Zealand, UK (only MS drugs to date)

Page 19: ECONOMICS OF THE PHARMACEUTICAL INDUSTRY 25 th  March 2004

Why Regulate? - Market Failure

• Public goods and the free-rider problem (e.g. research)

• Externalities– E.g. your vaccination reduces my risk of

catching an infection – E.g. the caring externality: I’m happy if you’re

cared for

• Incomplete or asymmetric information– Moral hazard (= ‘hidden action’)– Selection problem (= ‘hidden information’)– Principal/agent problems

Page 20: ECONOMICS OF THE PHARMACEUTICAL INDUSTRY 25 th  March 2004

Monopoly Power

• Economies of scale and/or scope – but NB contestability

• Natural (local) monopoly

• Input constraints

• Patents: dynamic efficiency vs static monopoly

Page 21: ECONOMICS OF THE PHARMACEUTICAL INDUSTRY 25 th  March 2004

Net Value of the Pharmaceutical Industry– Economic Rent

Estimates for 2000:

£ million p.a.

Producer rents (exports & overseas) 500-1,500

Labour rents 80-160

R&D spillovers to other sectors 120-360

Total rent 700-2,000

Terms of trade effect ?

Source: Pharmaceutical Industry Competitiveness Task Force (2001) ‘Value of the Pharmaceutical Industry to the UK Economy’

Page 22: ECONOMICS OF THE PHARMACEUTICAL INDUSTRY 25 th  March 2004

Options: Types of Regulation

• ‘No regulation’ = Competition Act only

• Profit, i.e. rate of return, control:– Unbanded– Banded

• Price control:– Baskets of products, as with ‘RPI-X’ control of

utilities’ prices– Individual products, e.g. via reference prices, or

‘cost-plus’, or related to therapeutic benefit

Page 23: ECONOMICS OF THE PHARMACEUTICAL INDUSTRY 25 th  March 2004

1998 Competition Act

• Came into force March 2000• Based on EU Treaty - Articles 81 & 82

• Prohibitions:

– Chapter 1 – Agreements preventing, restricting or distorting competition

– Chapter 2 – Abuse of a dominant market position

• Fines up to 10% of turnover; 3rd parties may sue for damages

Page 24: ECONOMICS OF THE PHARMACEUTICAL INDUSTRY 25 th  March 2004

Banded Rate of Return Regulation

Target RoR

Outturn RoR > threshold => repay excess

Outturn RoR < threshold => may increase prices

%RoR

£ capital employed

0

Page 25: ECONOMICS OF THE PHARMACEUTICAL INDUSTRY 25 th  March 2004

RPI-X Regulation of a Basket of ‘n’ Products

w1p11 + w2p1

2 + w3p13 + …….. + wnp1

n

--------------------------------------------------- -1 x 100 ≤ ΔRPI - X

w1p01 + w2p0

2 + w3p03 + …….. + wnp0

n

Where:

wi = weight for product ‘i’ (e.g. quantity sold in period 0)

pti = price of product ‘i’ in period t = 0,1

ΔRPI = % change in retail price index between period 0 and period 1

X = efficiency factor

{

{

Page 26: ECONOMICS OF THE PHARMACEUTICAL INDUSTRY 25 th  March 2004

Regulation Criteria

• Static efficiency:– Productive efficiency– Allocative efficiency

• Dynamic efficiency

• Benefit to UK plc – economic rent

• Regulatory (administrative) burden

• Equity/other social policy objectives

Page 27: ECONOMICS OF THE PHARMACEUTICAL INDUSTRY 25 th  March 2004

Exercise

• What, if anything, to regulate?– On- and/or off-patent?– Branded and/or unbranded?– Prescribed and/or over-the-counter?– Sales to NHS only, or all UK sales?

• If so, how?– Rate of return control, unbanded– Rate of return control, banded– Price control – basket, RPI-X– Price control – individual products, reference prices

• From 3 perspectives:– General public: patients & taxpayers– Government– Industry

Page 28: ECONOMICS OF THE PHARMACEUTICAL INDUSTRY 25 th  March 2004

Key Questions

1. How price-sensitive are the people making the consumption choices?

2. How much competition is there between one medicine and another, or between medicines and alternative treatments?

3. Do producers have incentives to keep costs down?

4. Will production and consumption choices become increasingly distorted over time?

5. Do producers have incentives to invest in the UK, especially in R&D?

6. Would the regulatory system be costly for the regulator to administer and the companies to comply with?

Page 29: ECONOMICS OF THE PHARMACEUTICAL INDUSTRY 25 th  March 2004

Pharmaceutical Price Regulation Scheme 1999

• Have been variants of PPRS since 1960s• Department of Health acts as regulator for whole UK• Objectives of 1999 PPRS:

– Secure the provision of safe and effective medicines for the NHS at reasonable prices

– Promote a strong and profitable R&D-based pharmaceutical industry

– Encourage efficient and competitive development and supply of medicines

• Voluntary – but (unspecified) statutory alternative scheme for firms that opt out

Page 30: ECONOMICS OF THE PHARMACEUTICAL INDUSTRY 25 th  March 2004

PPRS 1999 (continued)

• Covers all branded medicine sales – on-patent & branded generics – to NHS by companies selling > £1m p.a. to NHS (≈80% of total sales to NHS)

• Return on capital ≥ 29.4% => repay excess to DoH• Return on capital ≤ 8.5% => may apply for price

increase(s) to take RoC to 13.6%• R&D costs allowed up to 20% of sales• Promotion costs allowed up to 7% of sales• Free pricing at launch but no increases then

allowed unless company’ RoC falls to ≤ 8.5%

Page 31: ECONOMICS OF THE PHARMACEUTICAL INDUSTRY 25 th  March 2004

Multilateral, Ex-manufacturer, Price Comparisonsat Market Exchange Rates

Index UK=100

1998 2000 2002 2002 at 5-yr av ex rates

France 85 83 83 83

Germany 109 94 94 94

Italy 88 82 86 86

Spain 77 70 77 77

UK 100 100 100 100

USA 188 241 194 197

Source: Department of Health (2003) PPRS 7th Report to Parliament

Page 32: ECONOMICS OF THE PHARMACEUTICAL INDUSTRY 25 th  March 2004

Understanding the methodological issues

• Manufacturers’ prices or final selling price to the payer?• Brands or generics or molecules?• Sample size and selection (value versus volume, degree

of market coverage)• Bilateral versus multilateral• Match single pack, match product form or price per unit

(tablet, DDD, IMS SUs, Kg)?• Volume weights: unweighted, own country (Paasche) or

foreign weights (Laspeyres)?• Choice of exchange rate

• What exactly is the question you are trying to answer?

Page 33: ECONOMICS OF THE PHARMACEUTICAL INDUSTRY 25 th  March 2004

Pharmaceutical Price Regulation Scheme 1999

• Have been variants of PPRS since 1960s• Department of Health acts as regulator for whole UK• Objectives of 1999 PPRS:

– Secure the provision of safe and effective medicines for the NHS at reasonable prices

– Promote a strong and profitable R&D-based pharmaceutical industry

– Encourage efficient and competitive development and supply of medicines

• Voluntary – but (unspecified) statutory alternative scheme for firms that opt out

Page 34: ECONOMICS OF THE PHARMACEUTICAL INDUSTRY 25 th  March 2004

PPRS 1999 (continued)

• Covers all branded medicine sales – on-patent & branded generics – to NHS by companies selling > £1m p.a. to NHS (≈80% of total sales to NHS)

• Return on capital ≥ 29.4% => repay excess to DoH• Return on capital ≤ 8.5% => may apply for price

increase(s) to take RoC to 13.6%• R&D costs allowed up to 20% of sales• Promotion costs allowed up to 7% of sales• Free pricing at launch but no increases then

allowed unless company’ RoC falls to ≤ 8.5%