Discussion Paper 16 - Share Valuation

9
SHARE VALUATION: DETERMINATION OF COMPANIES FUNDAMENTAL VALUES Rowland Bismark Fernando Pasaribu

description

While the bubble research in financial economics expands its view onthe accumulated market behaviours, accounting researchers stand on thecompany-specific accounting information assessing the relation betweencompanies’ fundamental values and their prices in the stock market. They aimto obtain a valuation model which is able to best explain stock prices byregressing stock prices or returns with fundamental variables. Thespecification of the model is conducted by checking the stability of parametersand the explanatory power of fundamental variables with respect to stockprices or returns, i.e. R2. Since we intend to combine fundamental values andbubbles in the firm-level modeling of stock prices so as to achieve themeasurement of bubbles for individual stocks, models of fundamentalvaluation in the past should be examined and then carefully quoted to thepart of fundamental values in our model.

Transcript of Discussion Paper 16 - Share Valuation

Page 1: Discussion Paper 16 - Share Valuation

SHARE VALUATION:DETERMINATION OF COMPANIES

FUNDAMENTAL VALUES Rowland Bismark Fernando Pasaribu

Page 2: Discussion Paper 16 - Share Valuation

DISCLAIMER:

Kertas kerja staff pada Serial Diskusi ECONARCH Institute adalah materi pendahuluan yang disirkulasikan untuk menstimulasi diskusi dan komentar kritis. Analisis dan kesimpulan yang dihasilkan penulis tidak mengindikasikan konsensus anggota staff penelitian lainnya, BOD atau institusi. Referensi pada publikasi Serial Diskusi harus dinyatakan secara jelas oleh penulis untuk melindungi karakter tentatif pada kertas Diskusi ini.

2

Page 3: Discussion Paper 16 - Share Valuation

SHARE VALUATION:DETERMINATION OF COMPANIES

FUNDAMENTAL VALUES

While the bubble research in financial economics expands its view on

the accumulated market behaviours, accounting researchers stand on the

company-specific accounting information assessing the relation between

companies’ fundamental values and their prices in the stock market. They aim

to obtain a valuation model which is able to best explain stock prices by

regressing stock prices or returns with fundamental variables. The

specification of the model is conducted by checking the stability of parameters

and the explanatory power of fundamental variables with respect to stock

prices or returns, i.e. R2. Since we intend to combine fundamental values and

bubbles in the firm-level modeling of stock prices so as to achieve the

measurement of bubbles for individual stocks, models of fundamental

valuation in the past should be examined and then carefully quoted to the

part of fundamental values in our model.

The investigation in the area of fundamental valuation has experienced

two stages:primary attempts in the early days of EMH and the recent

extensive work with an acceptance of the stock market inefficiency.

Researches of these two stages will be reviewed below.

Research on the Fundamental Valuation in the Early Time

The research linking accounting numbers to stock prices can be traced

to the 1960s, when the modern capital market theories were developed. In the

early days, this topic was known as the market-based accounting research

(MBAR). Lev and Ohlson (1982) defined this research area as “the search into

the relationship between publicly disclosed accounting information and the

consequences of the use of the information by the major group of users:

3

Page 4: Discussion Paper 16 - Share Valuation

equity investors, as such consequences are reflected in characteristics of

common stocks traded in major exchanges.” Its rudiments are some

frameworks integrating the accounting information, prices and other market

variables, and expected utilities of contingent consumption patterns.

However, the investigation of fundamental values was initially only a

very small part of MBAR and stood along with the efficient capital market

theory. The model started from the association between asset returns and

accounting information. However, as Lev and Ohlson (1982) pointed out, the

explanatory power of the examined variables with respect to the distribution

of stock returns is rather low. Thus, an alternative method relating to stock

prices was considered thereafter. The effort can be traced to the 1930s. Meader

(1935) formulated a model to explain stock prices by five independent

variables: stock turnover, book value per share, net working capital per share,

earnings per share, and dividends per share. Since then, the empirical efforts

had halted due to the unsatisfactory results from Meader’s work until the

1960s.

Many researchers, such as Whitbeck and Kisor (1963), Malkiel and

Cragg (1970), and Litzenberger and Rao (1971), attempted to construct a

powerful and stable model to assess the fundamental values of stocks, but

their results were not optimal. The slim progress is exhibited by incorporating

the macroeconomic variables, such as interest rates, into models.

Due to the limit of econometric methods, the analysis of cross-sectional

or time series data is hardly trustworthy to estimate the stable parameters. In

addition, the acceptance of the efficient market theory in MBAR gives rise to

the difficulty in acquiring stable parameters with the high explanatory power

by regressing stock prices with respect to fundamental variables. Lev and

Ohlson (1982) pointed out this discrepancy by stating that “early studies

appearing to indicate investor rationality have given way to discomfiting

findings. It is now clear that the existence of some investor irrationality cannot

be precluded. This is very disturbing because there are no satisfactory

behavioral alternatives to investor rationality.” However, since

4

Page 5: Discussion Paper 16 - Share Valuation

methodological refinement was one of the major difficulties waiting to break

through in that age and the ignorance of the market inefficiency causes the

valuation model heavy in hand, the MBAR research was more in the spirit of

“the beginning of the end” than “the end of the beginning”, as Lev and

Ohlson (1982) also noted.

Recent Studies on the Fundamental Valuation

Until the late 1980s, as the opposite of the efficient market advocators,

the school of stock bubbles had been gaining more influence in expecting the

burst of bubbles and so the collapse of stock markets. Thus, with the

development of stock markets and its corresponding theories against EMH,

the research of capital asset valuation by fundamental variables expanded

rapidly, and was named “valuation and fundamental analysis research”. All

of these researches were aimed not only at establishing a channel between the

financial market and accounting numbers, but also at seeking to determine

firms’ intrinsic values under a demand for practically identifying mispriced

securities for investment purposes. Kothari (2001) concluded that “the

principal motivation for fundamental analysis research and its use in practice

is to identify mispriced securities for investment purposes…” With sound

motivation, however, the attention is mainly focused on estimating stable

parameters and there are still no any elements representing the inefficiency in

the valuation modeling.

Their inference is that in an inefficient capital market, a good model of

fundamental value should predictably generate positive or negative abnormal

returns. Therefore, it is worthwhile establishing a valuation model which best

explains share prices and/or has the most predictive power with respect to

future returns (Kothari, 2001).

Over several decades’ exploration, researchers and professional

financial analysts have constructed a succession of valuation models which

can be mainly divided into two streams: statistical valuation models and

deduced valuation models (Skogsvik, 2002). The first kind of model tries to

explain the market prices or returns directly by financial ratios conceived

5

Page 6: Discussion Paper 16 - Share Valuation

relative to the fundamental values, while the other kind is deduced precisely

upon the financial theories. Furthermore, in the deduced valuation models,

two divisions respectively called the “residual income” and “value added”

valuation model have been growing separately over the years.

Some researchers, such as Francis, Olsson and Oswald (2000) and

Skogsvik (2002) reviewed and summarized the valuation models at a

standpoint of practice, on the basis of which the strengths and weaknesses of

these models were numerated. The models of the first kind yield the merit of

simplicity. They are extremely easy to use as long as there are enough

empirical data to hand. However, the difficulties are located in the modeling

logic, which calls for complicated work on the statistical specification.

Moreover, the efficient market hypothesis is the precondition of the model,

due to the principles of this method which intend to find reasonable and

stable parameters reflecting the relation of stock prices and a series of

fundamental variables.

The residual income valuation model developed from a dividend-

discounting model was originated by Williams (1938). Generally, the

dividend-discounting model defines share price as the present value of

expected future dividends discounted at their risk-adjusted expected rate of

return (Kothari, 2001). The discounted dividend model is abstracted from the

financial theories which premise no arbitrage in markets and the investors

evaluate the reasonable prices (fundamental values) by the total acquirable

dividends from this investment. However, for the purpose of value

estimation, the prediction of dividends is a barrier hardly conquered. Since

the unrealistic assumptions are imposed in the estimation, the empirical work

based on this model is bare of credit. Such a problem is sorted out by its

transformation residual income model. Although prediction is still the focal

point of the research, the residual income model simplifies this process.

Holding the idea that future dividends can be explained by the

forecasted values of earnings and investments, Fama and Miller (1972,

Chapter 2) transformed the dividend-discounting model to an earnings

6

Page 7: Discussion Paper 16 - Share Valuation

capitalization model. This model yields a basic point that value depends on

the forecasted profitability of current and future investment which offers

some new and understandable viewpoints to explain the fundamental value.

However, this valuation model is regardless of the capital expansion either

through the reinvestment or issuance of new equity.

In line with the conclusion reached by pioneer accounting researchers,

a path-breaking achievement was made by Ohlson and Feltham (F-O) whose

contribution is deemed as the milestone of this area. Kothari (2001)

concluded: “Ohlson (1995) and Feltham and Ohlson (1995) deserve credit for

successfully reviving the residual income valuation idea, for developing this

idea more rigorously and for impacting the empirical literature”. In their

model, the fundamental value is defined as the sum of the current book value

and the discounted present value of expected abnormal earnings which is the

profit above a capital charge.

Regardless of the algebraic derivation, Penman (1997) analyzed the

equity valuation in the sight of accounting. Following the idea that any

differences between the benchmark price and market price are treated as

mispricing in the market, he investigated approximate benchmark valuations

by combining two elements, book value and earnings, which are traditionally

considered separately. His research focuses on the weights of the two

components, but differs from the F-O model in that weights change over time

rather than being fixed.

Finally, the value-added valuation model comes from the

consideration of company free cash flow. This model has become increasingly

popular in recent years in virtue of caring about the accounting details.

Nevertheless, some arguments revolve around the calculation of free cash

flow: the more comprehensive variables are considered, the more biases are

produced from the unavoidable accounting record mistakes.

Furthermore, the complicated process of calculation makes the model

heavy-handed. In summary, in the recent literatures, there are two basic

approaches to convey the linkage between accounting numbers and stock

7

Page 8: Discussion Paper 16 - Share Valuation

prices. One is statistical valuation models which excel due to their simplicity.

Another is deduced valuation models which bear the virtue of containing

more delicate calculations and theories.

Summary

The research of fundamental valuation has been enhanced with the

development of capital market theories. The early attempts in the light of the

efficient market theory and the recent efforts with an acceptance of market

inefficiency have conveyed extensive valuation models which are designed

under the criteria of best explaining stock prices. However, although all of

these approaches employ stock prices as the dependent variable in their

empirical estimation and some of them accept the opinion of an inefficient

market, the linkage established between stock prices and fundamental

variables doesn’t embrace bubbles, which are the part of stock prices in excess

of fundamental values, since the aim of their studies is to find the best

combination of fundamental variables to reveal companies’ values, not to

model stock prices. In our study of stock price modeling, stock prices are

composed by two parts: fundamental values and bubbles. The most popular

residual income valuation model will be adopted in the model to obtain the

part of fundamental values. Having formulated the firm-level model of stock

prices, the measurement of bubbles for all individual stocks in the sample can

be made in the empirical work.

8

Page 9: Discussion Paper 16 - Share Valuation

REFERENCE

Fama, Eugene F. and Miller, M.,1972, “the Theory of Finance,” Dryden Press.

Feltham, G. and Ohlson, J., 1995, “Valuation and Clean Surplus Accounting for Operating and Financial Activities,” Contemporary Accounting Research 11, 689-731.

Francis, Jennifer, Olsson, Per and Oswald, Dennis R., 2000, “Comparing the Accuracy and Explainability of Dividend, Free Cash Flow and Abnormal Earnings Equity Value Estimates,” Journal of Accounting Research, Vol.38, No.1.

Kothari, S.P., 2001, “Capital Markets Research In Accounting,” Journal of Accounting and Economics, 31, 105-231.

Lev., Baruch and Ohlson, James A., 1982, “Market-Based Empirical Research in Accounting: A Review, Interpretation, and Extension, ” Journal of Accounting Research, Vol.20.

Litzenberger, Robert H. and Rao, Cherukuri B., 1971, “Estimates of the Marginal Rate of Prime Preference and Average Risk Aversion of Investors in Electric Utility Shares: 1960-66,” Bell J. Econ. And Management, 2, 265-77.

Malkiel, B. G., and Cragg, J.C. 1970, “Expectations and the Structure of Share Prices,” American Economic Review, (September, 1970), 601-17.

Meader, J. W., 1935, “A Formular for Determining Basic Values Underlying Common Stock Prices,” The Analyst (November 29,1935), 749

Ohlson, James A., 1995, “Earnings, Book Values, and Dividends in Equity Valuation,” Contemporary Accounting Research, Vol.11, No.2, 661-687.

Penman, Stephen H., 1997, “Combining Earnings and Book Value in Equity Valuation,” Working Paper.

Skogsvik, Kenth, 2002, “A Tutorial on Residual Income Valuation and Value added Valuation,” Working Paper.

Whitbeck, V. and Kisor, M., 1963, “A New Tool in Investment Decision Making,” Financial Analysts J., 19, 55-62.

Williams, J., 1938, “the Theory of Investment Value,” Harvard University Press.

9