Corp Gov and Stakeholder Theory

download Corp Gov and Stakeholder Theory

of 24

Transcript of Corp Gov and Stakeholder Theory

  • 7/31/2019 Corp Gov and Stakeholder Theory

    1/24

    S TAKEHOLDER THEORY AND CORPORATE GOVERNANCE:

    THE R OLE OF I NTANGIBLE AS S E T S 1

    Abstract (extended)

    Since the beginning of the 21th century, a few serious financial scandals and many cases of

    corporate mismanagement have driven scholars and politicians to devote increasing attention to

    corporate governance, in a close relation with business ethics issues. In academic literature, as

    well as in public policy debates, corporate governance is nowadays acknowledged as a critical

    factor in economic development and financial markets stability.

    Actually, the recent phenomena represent the peak of a long-lasting widespread crisis of

    corporate governance. In the last decades, we observed a general disbelieving for those forms of

    corporate organization that played a fundamental role in the economic development of the

    leading industrialized countries: the public company in the US and in the UK, the bank or state-

    owned corporations in continental Europe, the keiretsu in Japan. In the Anglo-Saxon countries,

    public companies management, in order to comply with short sighted and diversified investors,

    tends to focus on short-term earnings, disregarding those long-term investments badly needed to

    enhance firm performance vis--vis competitors rooted in different systems. On the other side,

    economic systems based on closely held companies and financial intermediaries as primary

    financing source, are increasingly failing in providing an adequate equity base to finance

    successful competitive strategies in global industries.

    In both cases, the evolution in the nature of the firm is among the major causes for the crisis of

    established corporate governance models. The traditional manufacturing companies - vertically

    integrated and capital intensive which emerged at the beginning of the last century and had

    since then prevailed have been challenged by new organizational structures, based on

    intangible assets and networks, more appropriate to a dynamically changing environment, where

    competition is driven by the availability of distinctive competencies, based on firm-specific

    knowledge.

    1

    Arturo Capasso Universit degli Studi del Sannio Tel. +39-0824-305766 Fax +39-0824305777email: [email protected].

  • 7/31/2019 Corp Gov and Stakeholder Theory

    2/24

    Arturo Capasso - Stakeholders Theory and Corporate Governance

    2

    This paper, building on the resource based view of the firm, but also on stakeholder approach to

    strategic management, explores how the growing importance of intangible assets is reshaping, in

    many industries, the basic conditions of corporate governance. The aim is twofold: i) to explain

    logically why intangible assets modifies the allocation of residual claims, as company

    performance can substantially affect the wealth of other stakeholders ii) to determine which

    constituencies should be considered as relevant stakeholders and contribute, to some extent, to

    the corporate governance.

    Company law says that shareholders own the assets and the free cash flows, but this only works

    on the basis of a primitive view of the nature of ownership and employment. The crucial

    intangible assets could be, in many cases, out of the direct control of either shareholders or

    management. They are, in fact, shared in common between the firm and some of its stakeholders,

    like employees, customers, suppliers. In order to build and enhance its intangible endowment a

    firm has to establish and consolidate a trustworthy fiduciary relationship between the firm and

    these stakeholders. The costs to establish and consolidate these relationships can be considered

    as subordinated claims on firms cash flow to remunerate the stakeholders for the irreversible

    investments and commitments that are the main drivers of intangibles assets. Therefore,

    stakeholder can be considered as virtual shareholders, participating to an extensive definition of

    equity value that could be defined stakeholder equity or systemic value. In this perspective,

    stakeholder theory can be extended in order to set the acknowledgment of relevant stakeholder

    claims within the framework of value maximization, although the value to maximize is not that

    pertaining only to shareholders but the value of the business system as a whole.

    With no ambition to give a formally rigorous contribution to the lively debate on the relation

    between business and ethics, the proposed model might enable to overcome those approaches

    regarding ethics either as an additional constraint for company decision making or, at most, as a

    sort of generic investment in establishing a nice-company image, to be valued in terms of

    expected returns.

  • 7/31/2019 Corp Gov and Stakeholder Theory

    3/24

    Arturo Capasso - Stakeholders Theory and Corporate Governance

    3

    S TAKEHOLDER THEORY AND CORPORATE GOVERNANCE:

    THE R OLE OF I NTANGIBLE AS S E T S

    Introduction

    Since the beginning of the 21st century, corporate scandals and mismanagement cases have driven

    academic scholars to devote increasing attention to corporate governance, which is now acknowledged

    as a critical factor in economic development and financial markets stability1. This phenomenon is the

    emerging peak of a longstanding widespread crisis of traditional corporate governance models. In the

    last decades, as a matter of fact, we observed a general disbelieving for those corporate governance

    systems that played a fundamental role in the economic development of the leading industrialized

    countries: the public company in the US and in the UK, the bank or state-owned corporations in

    continental Europe, the keiretsu in Japan.

    The hypothesis discussed in this paper is that the crisis of traditional corporate structures, in the main

    industrialized countries, together with either local or contingent reasons, may have its common root in

    the growing relevance that intangible assets in the composition of firm's assets.Even if the relevance of intangibles is no actual news, as firm success has always been due to its

    distinctive business idea, there are some innovative aspects it is worth stressing:

    i) due to progressive fading of the residual barriers, competition is more intense in many industries,

    consequently the creation of competitive advantage depends on the availability of firm specific

    assets,

    ii) as a consequence of innovation in company and inter-company organization (lean organization, total

    quality, networks, industrial districts) relevant knowledge is no longer under the direct control either

    of the entrepreneurs or top management, as it is also spread at less prominent levels in the company

    hierarchy and, outside, by customers and suppliers who become an integral part of an enhanced

    business system (Jensen, 1993; Jensen and Meckling, 1992);

    iii) growing international market integration and a more intense competitive dynamics remarkably rise, in

    the main industries, the critical mass of intangible investments required to compete on wider and

  • 7/31/2019 Corp Gov and Stakeholder Theory

    4/24

    Arturo Capasso - Stakeholders Theory and Corporate Governance

    4

    wider markets; therefore, in many firms the relative weight of intangible assets has reached levels by

    far higher than in the past.

    This paper aims to integrate the resource-based view (Barney, 1991) with the stakeholder theory

    (Freeman, 1984; Donaldson and Preston, 1995), looking at the most important intangible assets as

    entrenched in some of the firms stakeholders. This lens might be useful for examining the relevance that,

    in several cases, stakeholders should have in corporate governance. Furthermore, it provides a

    theoretical basis to investigate some noteworthy issues in the field of business ethics.

    The paper is organized as follows. After a brief description of the historical development of different

    corporate governance systems, in the next three sections we first discuss the role of intangible assets as

    a source of sustainable advantage in the economic value creation process; we then describe the impact

    of intangible assets on the corporate financial structure and the allocation of residual claims and finally

    we develop the idea of systemic value of the firm as the combination of shareholders value and

    stakeholders value. A section on the studys conclusive remarks and implications for future research

    concludes.

    1. Historical background

    In the last decades of the 20th century, the economical and political collapse of central planned

    economies, concluding the long-standing diatribe between public or private ownership of the production

    means, has diverted the attention of management scholars, politicians and other interested observers on

    the meaningful differences existing within capitalistic world, among the various capitalist models2.

    The differences date back to the period when technological innovation, progress in transportation and

    communications, international trade growth, brought about, in the main industries, a remarkable increase

    of the firm minimum efficient size, conditioning the development of a modern industrial system to the

    availability of financial resources and managerial capabilities exceeding the endowment of the original

    entrepreneurs. In order to regulate the acquisition and the use of these resources, it was necessary to set

    up suitable legal, organizational and financial instruments, which caused the getting over of a perfect

    identity between the firm and the entrepreneur, with significant implications for corporate governance

    (Berle and Means, 1932; Chandler, 1962, 1977).

  • 7/31/2019 Corp Gov and Stakeholder Theory

    5/24

    Arturo Capasso - Stakeholders Theory and Corporate Governance

    5

    In each country, historical, economical, and political factors have got industrial development to follow

    distinctive routes that have not only characterized the ownership and organizational structures of the

    firms, but the evolution of the institutional and economic environment as well (Shleifer and Vishny, 1996;

    Pagano and Volpin, 2000). Nonetheless, even if the peculiarities of different countries have outlived the

    markets integration process, in the last decades, a widespread discontent for the traditional models of

    corporate governance has emerged together with a great interest in the experiences of other countries

    (Roe, 1993; Kester, 1992).

    In the US, such a phenomenon fully showed during the eighties, in a long season of hostile takeovers,

    leverage buyouts, proxy fights (Jarrel et al., 1988; Jensen, 1988). In Europe - with the notable

    exception of the UK - the takeover-mania has undoubtedly been less pervasive, but interest in the

    debate on corporate governance has livened up as a consequence of a general reconsideration of the

    State intervention in the economy. Privatizations have indeed characterized the economic policies of the

    leading European countries, even if outlined programs have not always been carried out, everywhere,

    with comparable resoluteness and results. Furthermore, even in Germany and Japan the typical

    governance models - grounded either on banks controlling interests or on intricate cross-shareholding

    webs - have proved largely inadequate, seriously deteriorating the myth of the general dedication of allfirm's participants to the commonweal (Watanabe and Yamamoto, 1993; Tricker, 1994, Yafeh, 2000).

    At the beginning of the 21th century, we assist to a general disbelieving of those forms of business

    organization that played a fundamental role in the economic development of the leading industrialized

    countries: the public company in the US and in the UK, the bank or state-owned corporations in

    continental Europe, the keiretsu in Japan.

    The crisis of traditional models clearly demonstrates how corporate governance is the thorny question in

    the evolution of the capitalistic society: on the one hand the international integration process urges to

    accelerate a series of important changes, affecting firm ownership and organizational structures, on the

    other hand existing situations are so deeply rooted in the culture and institutional environment of each

    country that getting over them requires a long difficult process. Therefore, the growing interest in the

    topic of corporate governance is not simply academic, but gives evidence for the search of an

    explanatory theory in order to develop appropriate solutions to relevant practical problems.

  • 7/31/2019 Corp Gov and Stakeholder Theory

    6/24

    Arturo Capasso - Stakeholders Theory and Corporate Governance

    6

    2. Economic value creation and intangibles assets

    In business literature there is a widespread consensus in recognizing the economic value creation as the

    main objective of the firm, independently of its ownership and organizational structures. Maximizing the

    economic value created by the business system as a whole - seen as the capitalization of the expected

    return above that required to keep the resources involved available to the firm in the long run - is

    unanimously considered a neutral goal, all main stakeholders could share. In order to create and

    maximize economic value firms have to develop and safeguard rent positions cutting off competition or,

    according to the strategic management terminology, a sustainable competitive advantage (Porter, 1985).

    According to the resource based view (RBV) of the firm, in dynamic and efficient markets, a realistically

    sustainable competitive advantage must inevitably be rooted in some unique or idiosyncratic resource

    controlled by the firm (Barney, 1991). This resource should be necessarily out of the marketor, in

    other terms, not autonomously negotiable. For if the source of a competitive advantage - whether or not

    it consists of human, physical, locational, organizational or legal capital - could be expanded in its supply

    by competitors, the returns for the firm would be brought down to normal level by competitive pressure

    (Teece, 1988).

    This consideration leads to adjust the definition of intangible asset, restricting it to the sole resource thatcannot be object of autonomous transactions, so excluding all those assets that, even if by nature

    intangible, can be, all the same, autonomously traded (i.e.: a patent or a trademark). According to such

    a definition, all intangible assets can be traced to the fundamental categories of knowledge and trust and

    the firm can be well defined - paraphrasing Sraffa - as a system to produce knowledge by means of

    knowledge (Penrose, 1959; Winter, 1987; Grant, 1996, 2002). Knowledge-based assets are

    promising as a source of sustainable advantage because firm-specificity, social complexity and causal

    ambiguity make them hard for rivals to imitate.

    The accrued intangible assets on one side contribute to increase the perceived value of good and service

    provided, on the other side can be either increased and renewed by means of the learning process or

    lost when the firm develop entropic processes spoiling its wealth of knowledge and trust. The

    knowledge embodied in the organizational systems and procedures and the trust placed by the markets

    in the firm constitute the intangible assets - in the strict sense - apt to ensure a sustainable competitive

    advantage to the firm.

  • 7/31/2019 Corp Gov and Stakeholder Theory

    7/24

    Arturo Capasso - Stakeholders Theory and Corporate Governance

    7

    The hypothesis discussed in this paper is that the crisis of traditional institutional structures in the main

    industrialized countries, together with either local or contingent reasons, may have its common root in

    the growing relevance intangibles have taken in the composition of firm's assets.

    To be unambiguous, the relevance of intangibles is no actual news, as firm success has always been due

    to its distinctive business idea just the same way it has depended on the efficiency of such material

    activities as raw material acquisition, manufacturing, sale and distribution. Anyhow, there are some

    innovative aspects it is worth stressing:

    i) owing to progressive fading of the residual barriers to competition, in more and more industries, the

    possibility of creating economic value is qualified by the availability of firm specific assets, eluding

    the laws of supply and demand since they are not autonomously negotiable;

    ii) as a consequence of innovation in company and intercompany organization (lean organization, total

    quality, networks, industrial districts) relevant knowledge is no longer under the direct control either

    of the entrepreneurs or top management, as it is also spread at less prominent levels in the company

    hierarchy and, outside, by customers and suppliers who become an integral part of an enhanced

    business system (Jensen, 1993; Jensen and Meckling, 1992).

    iii) growing market integration and a more intense competitive dynamics remarkably rise, in the mainindustries, the critical mass of intangible investments required to compete on wider and wider

    markets; therefore, in many firms, the relative weight of intangible assets has reached levels by far

    higher than in the past.

    3. Intangible assets and corporate financial structure

    The growing proportion of intangible components on firm total value radically affects corporate

    ownership and governance not only because of the absolute dimensions of the required investments, butalso because of global risk increase due to the specific irreversible characteristics of intangible assets.

    In the economic systems based on financial intermediation, where closely held companies prevail, the

    rise in the volume of intangible investments required to compete effectively, can make the controlling

    shareholders unable to adequately finance firm development. Especially in those industries where

    competitive conditions demand conspicuous investments in intangible assets, the survival of companies

    with a limited equity-base or even controlled by single entrepreneurial families, has become more and

  • 7/31/2019 Corp Gov and Stakeholder Theory

    8/24

    Arturo Capasso - Stakeholders Theory and Corporate Governance

    8

    more difficult. In the few cases it happens, the controlling shareholders, even when they can rely on

    remarkable wealth accrued during many generations, cannot benefit of an effective portfolio

    diversification. They are, therefore, considerably risk adverse, hindering intangible assets development,

    thence the crisis in governance structures where a single controlling shareholder maintains a leading role

    (Capasso, 1995).

    On the other hand, those systems based on the security market - though fitter to bear substantial equity-

    financed investments - experienced the well-known problems due to the public company as a prevailing

    business organization model. Actually, an increasing presence of intangible assets adds further

    impediments to public company efficiency because:

    i) intangible assets enhance the information asymmetries, that are to a certain extent, irreducible

    because their removal could make the firm suffer greater damage due to the disclosure of

    confidential facts (Diamond, 1985; Myers and Majluf, 1984);

    ii) asymmetric information create a gap between the intrinsic economic value and the market value of

    companies, so producing adverse selection phenomena in the capital market (Brennan, 1990;

    Capasso 1995);

    iii) lack of active shareholders may cause deviant behaviours as executives could use their discretionarypowers in order to maximize their personal utility and manage the company according to their

    peculiar risk-adversion, that is usually higher than the average risk-adversion of a well diversified

    shareholder (Amihud and Lev, 1981);

    iv) some investments in intangible assets are particularly apt either to operate accounting make-ups or

    to hide managerial perquisites and unscrupulous behaviours of controlling shareholders; examples

    can be provided by the capitalization of useless R&D costs or by those expenses justified by the

    rather vague definition ofcompany image.

    Furthermore, either in the intermediary-based systems or in the market-based ones, since many

    intangible assets cannot be integrated in an autonomously tradable proprietary asset, they cannot be

    considered under the direct control of the company, as they are embodied in other stakeholders:

    managers, employees, customers, suppliers.

    This is probably the crucial remark: the inseparable connection between such relevant assets as

    knowledge and trust and some of the main stakeholders could actually subordinate the firm competitive

  • 7/31/2019 Corp Gov and Stakeholder Theory

    9/24

    Arturo Capasso - Stakeholders Theory and Corporate Governance

    9

    effectiveness to the permanence of these stakeholders within the existing business combination. This is

    particularly observable in all the companies whose critical factors for success are represented by the

    professional capabilities of the staff, but also in those firms owing their competitive advantage to their

    belonging either to an industrial district or to a network of interdependent firms.

    As a rule, when the critical factors for success in a particular industry are embedded in the main

    stakeholders, the company's possibility of safeguarding its intangible asset-base depends on its capacity

    in fulfilling the legitimate claims of those stakeholders who are part of its competitive strength.

    Stakeholder claims can be, according to the circumstances: wage incentives, occupational security and

    good working environment; reliable products, after sale assistance, stable relationships; or more in

    general the respect of those implicit contracts and moral obligations that are a consequence of bounded

    rationality and contractual incompleteness (Shleifer and Summers, 1988). The higher costs borne to

    satisfy such claims are the costs to produce, maintain and strengthen knowledge and trust (Kreps,

    1984). They allow the main stakeholders to extract a quasi-rent, rewarding them with returns higher

    than the current market value of the resources provided or with products or services more valuable than

    the price charged. Obviously, this does not mean that the stakeholders contribution to the value created

    is lower than the return they get; it only means that in some circumstances stakeholders get a share ofthe economic value created by the business system, which can no longer be regarded as shareholders

    exclusive belonging (Myers, 1990; Charreaux and Desbrires, 2001).

    Summing up, the presence of intangible assets modifies the allocation of residual claims as company

    performance can substantially affect the wealth of those stakeholders embodying some of the critical

    factors for company success; at the same time, intangible assets qualitatively modify the company

    financial needs, as intangible assets' higher riskness and their reduced cautional value demand a larger

    equity-base (Williamson, 1988).

    In order to analyze the interrelation between the two problems and find out possible viable solutions, it

    might prove interesting to suggest a systemic approach the company financial structure. From that,

    analysis there could emerge reflections on the relation between the formal and substantial aspects of

    corporate governance as well as important insights for what concerns the evolution of ownership

    structures and governance models.

  • 7/31/2019 Corp Gov and Stakeholder Theory

    10/24

    Arturo Capasso - Stakeholders Theory and Corporate Governance

    10

    4. Systemic value and corporate governance

    A systemic reconsideration of company financial structure requires an in-depth analysis of the

    relationship between investments and financing decisions, thoroughly investigating the company financial

    structure as the premise for the allotment of ownership claims on its future cash flow3.

    Several interpretations can be given of this statement. From a simplified perspective, it is easily

    understandable that the value of the company investments belongs to shareholders and debtholders in

    proportions reflecting the respective contributions and the contractual arrangements. Anyway if we

    move our attention on the dynamic nature of value, regarding it as the total amount of future unlevered

    discounted cash-flows, we can observe that the debt-equity ratio set the share of operating cash flows

    to be assigned to debtholders and the residual amount available for managers. Managers, in their turn

    will use it - according to circumstances and in different proportions - either to remunerate shareholders

    or to plow back into the business. In other words, the presence of a managerial discretionary power on

    the use of free cash flows brings in a further group of agents competing for the allotment of the company

    economic value (Jensen, 1986).

    The growing importance given by the evolution of competitive dynamics to intangible assets complicates

    the problem even more. If the economic cycle of the company is based on accrued intangible assets,that are continuously utilized to produce new intangibles, attainable results will no longer be so

    appropriable and transferable as either monetary or monetary-measurable quantities are and their

    allotment will not be so easy.

    Business economists have traditionally focused their attention on the company value from the

    shareholder point of view (Rappaport, 1986), and even the most popular profitability indicators - such

    as net income, operating margin, ROE or ROI - measure the company performance in terms of increase

    in shareholder equity or in total value for both shareholders and debtholders (Donaldson, 1984).

    Truly it is not possible to claim that these approaches belong to an obsolete stage of the industrial

    development; there are indeed a lot of companies where - either because of the simplicity of the

    production process or because of the strong overlapping among different stakeholder categories - such

    parameters as net income, ROI or shareholder wealth, are still the fundamental landmarks for business

    management. Anyway, we cannot ignore that for many companies, intangible assets are, to a larger and

    larger extent, critical factors for success, and even in many industries usually regarded as traditional,

  • 7/31/2019 Corp Gov and Stakeholder Theory

    11/24

    Arturo Capasso - Stakeholders Theory and Corporate Governance

    11

    hardware components are quickly losing moment with respect to the soft ones, if not in terms of

    absolute economic consistency, at least as source of competitive differential4.

    The analysis of those phenomena, in order to assess their impact on the evolution of ownership

    structures and corporate governance, requires an approach bringing the value of a business system as a

    whole within the traditional framework of the company balance sheet. In particular, this can be achieved

    by outlining a systemic balance sheet, comparing the value of all the assets included in the business

    system with its financial structure, considered in its twofold function of financing source definition and

    allocation of claims on expected future cash flows.

    The systemic balance sheet has no direct connection with the firm's book, where we find mainly tangible

    assets and, only on certain terms, the intangible ones. It is just a way of expressing the identity between

    the market value of assets and liabilities. More precisely the asset side displays the market value of all

    the resources contributing to the company development, including those intangible assets who are not

    directly controlled by the company, such as capabilities and trust it shares with managers, employees,

    customers, and suppliers. From this perspective, intangible assets can be divided into three main

    categories: firm-based, organization-based and people-based (Exhibit 1).

    Firm-based intangible assets are not particularly interesting for the present analysis: a company can usethem at its convenience, as well as transfer them, either temporarily or forever, via autonomous

    transactions. The same for people-based intangible assets: since they are not firm specific, they have

    autonomous market value. In order to use them a company must remunerate their respective owners on

    the basis of what they could have earned if using the same resources in an alternative way (Hall, 1994).

    Our interest, therefore, focuses on organization-based intangible assets (shared by the firm's internal

    organization and its stakeholders); they are, indeed, the only ones that really fit in the restricted definition

    of intangible assets, as stated above. Among them we can distinguish (even if the distinction is not

    always clear) relational assets deriving from the relationship existing between the company and its

    shareholders and those assets that, even if not autonomously negotiable, can be regarded as parts of the

    corporate wealth in so far as they are parts of the company organizational and procedural structure and

    do not depend, in some cases, on people working in it. In the logic of valuation, such assets are the

    goodwill in the strict sense: it cannot be assessed apart, but must be added to the equity value. As a

    matter of fact a differential due to assets that cannot be autonomously assessed but that give an

  • 7/31/2019 Corp Gov and Stakeholder Theory

    12/24

    Arturo Capasso - Stakeholders Theory and Corporate Governance

    12

    important contribution to value creation has always been observed by business economists (Guatri,

    1994); anyway valuation models put into practice have only and always considered that part of the

    economic value increase pertaining to shareholders or, at the most, to shareholders and creditors

    (Copeland et al., 1994).

    If on the contrary we want to determine the value of a business system, we must figure out the present

    value of future systemic cash-flows, including the above-market returns transferred to the main

    stakeholders (quasi-rent5).

    The net present value of the so calculated cash-flows can be divided as follows:

    i) the market value of each single company-based asset;

    ii) the goodwill in strict sense, as the market value of the firm-based intangible assets (pertaining to

    equity-holders and debtholders);

    iii) the systemic goodwill as the present value of the expected future cash-flows produced by

    organization-based intangible assets (pertaining to all the stakeholders on the basis of formal or

    implicit contracting).

    The liabilities side will show the total amount of debt and equity, at their current market values, duly

    quantified on the basis of debtholders and shareholders expected cash-flows. In particular, for listedcompanies, equity can be subdivided in two parts: the former representing the market value of company

    share as calculated according to all publicly available information, the latter corresponding either to the

    higher or to the lower value inferred on the basis of information available only to insiders (management

    or controlling shareholders). The likely unbalance between assets and liabilities represents the systemic

    equity that corresponds to the present value of the quasi-rents that will be distributed to the

    stakeholders with whom the firm shares the critical intangible assets. Under this perspective, the

    systemic equity include the capitalization of those advantages obtained by major shareholders,

    executives or employees such as: managerial perquisites, fringe benefits, above-market wages,

    overstaffing, but also those benefits provided to customers and suppliers in terms of reduced transaction

    costs, as a consequence of a reliable and trustworthy cooperation.

    The capitalization of the stakeholders claims on a certain amount of the economic value created by the

    business system can be assimilated into an additional equity posting (systemic equity), with a lower

    seniority with respect to debt but in any case contributing to the financing of the firm systemic value.

  • 7/31/2019 Corp Gov and Stakeholder Theory

    13/24

    Arturo Capasso - Stakeholders Theory and Corporate Governance

    13

    Such an explanation can find an underlying rationale in the relevant idiosyncratic investments, made by

    the main stakeholders in order to enforce their relations with the company. As the value of these

    investments would vanish in case the company run into bankruptcy, stakeholders, just like shareholders,

    can be considered residual claimants too6.

    Moreover the contract incompleteness which can be credited to the intangible contents of exchanged

    products and services, has induced to try out new institutional settings in risk and return sharing among

    different stakeholders. So contractual or organizational formulas recently carried out can be seen as an

    attempt to give some stakeholders an ideal share in the company equity. Such an attribution, even if it

    cannot be consider as the allocation of actual ownership claims on company future cash-flows,

    represents the substantial (but not legal) premise in order to establish some particular stakeholder

    claims.

    Obviously a company in default towards its stakeholders does not run into legal consequences, as it

    happens in case of default towards debtholders, but it will probably suffer the loss of that part of

    company's wealth embodied in the relation between the company and those stakeholders whose claims

    have not been met. It is now possible to imagine the systemic balance sheet as it appears in Exhibit 2.

    Under this point of view, the stakeholders can be described as a virtual shareholder, contributing themost part of the systemic equity and getting a share of the economic value created by the company.

    Therefore, in analyzing real situations, the first problem consists in identifying those shareholders the firm

    main intangibles depend on. For instance, it is believable that in a medium-sized family business,

    intangible assets are primarily made up of the fiduciary relationship existing among the partners and of

    the entrepreneurial heritage, the founder left to her/his heirs. As far as there are no relevant interests of

    other people involved, the passing from a traditional vision to a systemic one could not be so important.

    Conversely, there are particularly complicated cases in which listed companies carry on business

    strongly depending on the competence of individual professionals7.

    This is, for instance, the case of advertising firms, merchant banks, newspapers, where conflicts of

    interests might rise between virtual and actual shareholders. The origin of these conflicts is mainly in the

    fact that virtual shareholders press for being acknowledged, according to circumstances, adequate

    relevance either in the allocation of created value, either in corporate governance. Even the liabilities side

  • 7/31/2019 Corp Gov and Stakeholder Theory

    14/24

    Arturo Capasso - Stakeholders Theory and Corporate Governance

    14

    must therefore be analyzed and weighted in order to distribute powers, risks, and returns, among

    different stakeholders.

    The knotty question consists in ensuring all the shareholders (both actual and virtual) the possibility to

    participate or, more plausibly, to control corporate governance. When professional managers are

    entrusted with the definition of corporate strategy and policies - and in the major companies no different

    solution seem workable - each part must be given, in proportion to contributions provided and risks

    borne, the possibility of somehow controlling managerial decisions. This is very important since the

    managerial role is actually delicate, as they have to mediate between shareholders and stakeholders. The

    obvious risk is that stakeholder theory might be used to cover traditional managerial opportunism, so

    largely described in literature (Berle and Means, 1932; Marris 1964; Fama and Jensen, 1983). From

    this particular point of view, the suggested methodology can reduce managerial discretion and set a

    legitimate limit to stakeholders claims. The acknowledgment of a systemic goodwill as the economic

    value created by organization-based intangible assets (due to stakeholders different from shareholders

    and creditors) could enable to control that stakeholders' returns exceeding the market value of either the

    work done or the resources provided, may take place within the limits of the systemic value that they

    originate inside the organization, therefore, without damaging either shareholders' or debtholders'legitimate claims.

    Conclusions

    In the last decades, corporate governance has become a highly controversial issue and traditional

    governance models are everywhere under a complex transformation process. In those economic

    systems traditionally based on financial intermediation, governments have worked to strengthen the

    security markets by promoting the efficiency and the transparency in negotiations. In market-based

    systems, institutional investors, already significant shareholders in many important public companies,

    have modified their traditional not interfering in corporate governance and have shown a growing

    activism as management interlocutors and controllers (Black, 1993; Bhide, 1993; Pound, 1994).

    Furthermore, in most countries, leaving aside prevailing financial models, there have been important

    initiatives to regulate the composition and the functions of company boards, aiming to increase their

  • 7/31/2019 Corp Gov and Stakeholder Theory

    15/24

    Arturo Capasso - Stakeholders Theory and Corporate Governance

    15

    representativeness and strengthen their controlling power on the managerial decisions (Cadbury, 1993;

    Lorsch, 1995, Pound, 1995).

    As a whole, it seems that different corporate models are converging towards a renewed public company

    model, with shareholding divided among active institutional investors and governed by an influential

    management-independent board. The convergence may be confirmed at least for companies working in

    global industries, since, for those companies, the size of the critical mass of intangible investments

    demands such an equity-base hardly sustainable, either by a single entrepreneurial group, or even by a

    bunch of allied shareholders. In these companies, the institutional investors' involvement can offer

    outstanding contribution to the effectiveness of mechanisms that, by conveying to the investors credible

    signals, reduce the gap between stock market evaluation and the company actual economic value.

    Moreover, further advantages could derive from a clearer distinction between management and board

    functions. Executives should be responsible for the company strategy definition and implementation

    whereas directors should set goals and play a role of active well informed supervision on the managerial

    activities.

    In this regard we note a very animated debate about the opportunity of granting the main stakeholders

    board representation, according a procedure that is usually followed by many companies and thatsomewhere is required by the law, as in the case of the two-tier board system of the main German

    companies.

    The theme is controversial: as a general principle, power and responsibility should be closely correlated

    in each company. According to such a principle, corporate governance should be a privilege of those

    who bear the economic risk (apparently the shareholders). When examining this interpretation more

    deeply, we realize it can be shared only by companies where governance implies no delegation

    mechanisms and the production process makes use of easily available generic factors whose acquisition

    can be regulated by complete (or quasi-complete) contracts. In those organizations where ownership

    dispersion compels shareholders to delegate power and responsibility or where the contracts regulating

    the acquisition of production means and the sale of goods and services are, for the most part,

    incomplete, the economic risk is not exclusively borne by shareholders but by some stakeholders as

    well. The intangible nature of the main inputs and outputs of the economic process contributes to

    enhance contractual incompleteness and the number of people whose earnings are, residual (Fama and

  • 7/31/2019 Corp Gov and Stakeholder Theory

    16/24

    Arturo Capasso - Stakeholders Theory and Corporate Governance

    16

    Jensen, 1983, Milgrom and Roberts, 1992). The need to reduce transaction and agency costs due to

    contractual incompleteness and the presence of intangible assets shared with third parties has made

    companies test new organizational solutions, consisting in strengthening relations with customers and

    suppliers in inter-company networks and in establishing contractual relations with managers and

    employees including the explicit or implicit sharing of risk and returns.

    The circumstance for which some intangible assets are not directly available for the company, as they

    are shared with other people (managers, employees, customers, suppliers) subordinates their

    effectiveness, and even their permanence within the existing economic coordination, to the satisfaction of

    those people's claims. The claims are, according to circumstances: wage incentives, occupational

    security and good working environment, reliable products, high service level, the respect of tacit

    agreements and implicit contracts.

    The proposed systemic approach to corporate governance is a working hypothesis, to be integrated

    and improved, in order to provide a theoretical framework to evaluate the impact of the growing

    importance of intangible assets. Furthermore, the model might allow discriminating the importance of the

    different stakeholders and the legitimization of their claims on the economic value created according to

    their specific contribution to the corporate systemic equity.From this perspective, stakeholders can be regarded as virtual shareholders whose legitimate claims

    have, with regard to the company systemic equity, a relation similar to the one linking the shareholder

    expected returns to equity value. The company that does not meet its stakeholders' claims, could lose all

    the capital of competencies and trust that is a basic condition to create economic value. Eventually, it

    can be interesting to observe how reshaping the stakeholders theory from the point of view of the

    systemic value, can help to define possible development ways to the multifaceted debate on business

    ethics.

    First of all recognizing stakeholders the role of virtual shareholders gives the possibility of making clearer

    the relations of correlation and opposition among the various interest focusing on the business, handling

    them always within an economic logic. In particular defining systemic value creation as the firm capacity

    to continue its production of new resources by means of the previously produced resources, gives

    managers a goal that is either sharable by the main stakeholders either ethically correct, since it can

  • 7/31/2019 Corp Gov and Stakeholder Theory

    17/24

    Arturo Capasso - Stakeholders Theory and Corporate Governance

    17

    secure the firm's survival, optimize the use of scarce resources, and maximize the total value produced

    for the benefit of the whole economy.

    Moreover, the adopted framework could help to identify a fair criterion to classify the stakeholder

    interest (Donaldson and Preston, 1995). To such a purpose assigning virtual shares of the systemic

    equity in proportion to the contribution given by different stakeholder groups, or by individual

    stakeholders to the firm's global value, could reveal possible imbalance in the division of created

    economic value.

    All that, makes the directors' task particularly difficult since, even if they could be interested party, they

    are called to draw up the main contracts, setting up, this way, mechanism to distribute created systemic

    value (Aoki, 1980). In this prospective the problem of boards' formation and empowering must be

    differently reviewed, that is renouncing to set prearranged representation rules. It is, instead, necessary

    to identify those companies or industries where, for certain categories of stakeholders, it is recognizable

    a specific significant contribution to the process creating systemic value, so the presence of own

    representatives in the board could be regarded as the formal acknowledgment of a virtual participation

    in the company equity.

  • 7/31/2019 Corp Gov and Stakeholder Theory

    18/24

    Arturo Capasso - Stakeholders Theory and Corporate Governance

    18

    REFERENCES

    AMIHUD Y.,LEV B.,Risk Reduction as a Managerial Motive for Conglomerate Mergers, Bell Journalof Economics, n. 12, 1981.

    AOKI M., A model of the firm as a stockholder-employee cooperative game, American EconomicReview, n. 70, 1980.

    AOKI M.,GUSTAFFSON B.,WILLIAMSON O.E.,The Firm as a Nexus of Treaties, Saga Pubblisher,London, 1990.

    BARNEY J.B.,Firm Resources and Sustained Competitive Advantage, Journal of Management, n. 17,1991.

    BASILE L.,CASAVOLA PThe Firm as an Institution: Recent Evolution in the Contractual Perspective,mimeo, 1993.

    BECHT M., BOLTON P., ROELL A. Corporate Governance and Control European CorporateGovernance Institute - Finance Working Paper n. 2/2002 October 2002.

    BERGLF E.,Capital Structure as a Mechanism of Control: A Comparison of Financial Systems, inAoki et al., 1990.

    BERLE A.A., MEANS G.C., The Modern Corporation and Private Property, Commerce ClearingHouse, New York, 1932.

    BHIDE A.,The hidden cost of stock market liquidity, Journal of Financial Economics, n. 34, 1993.

    BLACK B.S., Institutional Investors and Corporate Governance: The Case for Institutional Voice,Journal of Applied Corporate Finance, n. 3, 1993.

    BRENNAN M.J,Incentives, Rationality, and Society, Journal of Applied Corporate Finance, v. 7 - n. 2,1994.

    BRENNAN M.J.,Latent Assets, Journal of Finance, n. 45, 1990.

    BRIOSCHI F., BUZZACCHI L., COLOMBO M.G, Risk Capital Financing and the Separation ofOwnership and Control in Business Group, Journal of Banking and Finance, n. 13, 1989.

    CADBURY A.,Thoughts on Corporate Governance, Corporate Governance, v. 1 - n. 1, 1993.

    CAPASSO A., Firm Internal Organization, Stock Market Efficiency and Equity Value, EconomiaAziendale, n. 3, 1995.

    CHANDLER A.D.,Strategy and Structure. Chapters in the Hystory of American Industrial Enterprise,

    The MIT Press, Cambridge, MA, 1962.

  • 7/31/2019 Corp Gov and Stakeholder Theory

    19/24

    Arturo Capasso - Stakeholders Theory and Corporate Governance

    19

    CHANDLER A.D., The Visible Hand. The Managerial Revolution in American Business, HarvardUniversity Press, Cambridge, MA, 1977.

    CHARREAUX G.,DESBRIRES P.Corporate Governance: Stakeholder value versus Shareholder value working paper Universit de Bourgogne, march 2001.

    COFFR.W. When Competitive Advantage Does not Lead To Performance: The Resource-Based

    View And Stakeholder Bargaining Power Organizational Science, September 2001.

    COPELAND T.E., KOLLER T., MURRIN J., Valuation: Measuring and Management the Value ofCompanies,John Wiley & Sons,New York, 1991.

    DONALDSON G.,Managing Corporate Wealth, Praeger, New York, 1984.

    DONALDSON T.,PRESTON L.E.,The stakeholder theory of the corporation: Concepts, evidence, andimplications, Academy of Management Review, n. 20, 1995.

    DOSI G.,TEECE D.J.,Organizational Competencies and the Boundaries of the Firm, working paper -University of California at Berkeley, n. 93-11, 1993.

    EVAN W.M.,FREEMAN R.E.,A Stakeholder Theory of the Modern Corporation: Kantian Capitalism,in Beauchamp, Bowie, 1988.

    FAMA E.F., JENSEN M.C., Agency Problems and Residual Claims, Journal of Law, Economics &Organization, n. 26, 1983.

    FREEMAN R.E., REED D.L., Stockholders and Stakeholders: A New Perspective on CorporateGovernance, Pitman, Boston, 1984.

    FREEMAN R.E.,Strategic Management: A Stakeholder Approach, Pitman, Boston, 1984.

    GRANT R.M., The Resourced-Based Theory of Competitive Advantage: Implications for StrategyFormulation, California Management Review, spring, 1991.

    Grant RM. 1996. Toward a knowledge-based theory of the firm. Strategic Management

    Grant RM. 2002. Contemporary Strategy Analysis: Concepts, Techniques, Applications,

    GUATRI L., The valuation of the firm Blackwell Publishers, Oxford, 1994.

    HALL R., A Framework Linking Intangible Resources and Capabilites to Sustainable CompetitiveAdvantage, Strategic Management Journal, n. 14, 1993.

    HART O.D.,Firms, Contracts, and Financial Structure, Oxford University Press, Oxford, 1995.

    HART O.D.,MOORE J.,Property Rights and the Nature of the Firm, Journal of Political Economy, n.98, 1990.

    JARRELL G.A.,BRICKLEY J.,NETTER J.,The Market for Corporate Control: The Empirical Evidencesince 1980, Journal of Economic Perspectives, n. 2, 1988.

  • 7/31/2019 Corp Gov and Stakeholder Theory

    20/24

    Arturo Capasso - Stakeholders Theory and Corporate Governance

    20

    JENSEN M.C., Agency Costs of Free Cash Flows, Corporate Finance and Takeovers, AmericanEconomic Review Papers and Proceedings n. 76/1986.

    JENSEN M.C.,Eclipse of the Public Corporation, Harvard Busienss Review, sep-oct, 1989.JENSEN M.C., MECKLING W.H., Specific and General Knowledge, and Organizational Structure, inWerin e Wijkander, 1992.

    JENSEN M.C.,MECKLING W.H.,Theory of the firm: Managerial behaviour, agency costs and ownershipstructure, Journal of Financial Economics, n. 3, 1976.

    JENSEN M.C., The Modern Industrial Revolution, Exit and the Failure of Internal Control Systems,Journal of Finance, n. 48, 1993.

    JOHNSON H.T.,KAPLAN R.S.,Relevance Lost, Harvard Business School Press, Boston, 1987.

    Journal 17(winter special issue): 109-122.

    KESTER W.C., Governance, contracting, and investment horizons: A look at Japan and Germany,Journal of Applied Corporate Finance, n. 5, 1992.

    KREPS D.M.,Corporate Culture and Economic Theory, working paper - Stanford University GraduateSchool of Business, Palo Alto, 1984.

    KUHN J.W.,The Managerial Challenge of New Constituencies, working paper - Columbia UniversityGraduate School of Business, New York, 1987.

    LORSCH J.W.,Empowering the board, Harvard Business Review, jan-feb, 1995.LOWENSTEIN L.,Management Buyouts, Columbia Law Review, n. 85, 1985.

    MARRIS R.,The Economic Theory of Managerial Capitalism, McMillan, New York, 1964.

    MARSHALL A.,Principles of Economics, McMillan, London, 1920.

    MILGROM P.,ROBERTS J.,Economics, Organization and Management, Prentice Hall, Englewood Cliffs,1992.

    MITCHELL R.K., AGLE B., WOOD D.J.Toward a theory of stakeholder identification and salience:

    defining the principle of who and what really counts Academy of Management Review Vol. 22 n.4/1997.

    MONKS R.A.,MINOW N.,Corporate Governance, Basil Blackwell, Cambridge, 1995.

    MYERS S.C.,Still Searching for Optimal Capital Structure, Sloan School of Management MIT, Boston,1990.

    PAGANO M.,VOLPIN P.The Political Economy of Corporate Governance Workng Paper n. 29CSEF Universit di Salerno, December 2000

    PENROSE T.E.,The Theory of the Growth of the Firm, Oxford University Press, Oxford, 1959.

  • 7/31/2019 Corp Gov and Stakeholder Theory

    21/24

    Arturo Capasso - Stakeholders Theory and Corporate Governance

    21

    POUND J.,The Promise of the Governed Corporation, Harvard Business Review, mar-apr., 1995.

    POUND J.,The Rise of the Political Model of Corporate Control, New York University Law Review,

    March, 1994.PRAHALAD C.K.,Comments, Journal of Applied Corporate Finance, n. 6, 1993.

    PRESTON L.E., H.J. SAPIENZA, Stakeholder managementand corporate performance, Journal ofBehavioral Economics, n. 19, 1990.

    RAPPAPORT A.,Creating Shareholder Value. The New Standard for Business Performance, The FreePress, New York, 1986.

    RAPPAPORT A., The Staying Power of the Public Corporation, Harvard Business Review, jan-feb,1990.

    RIBCZYNSKI T.M., Industrial Finance System in Europe, U.S., and Japan, Journal of EconomicBehaviour and Organization, n. 4, 1984.

    ROE M., Strong Managers, Weak Owners: The Political Roots of American Corporate Finance,Princeton University Press, Princeton, 1994.

    SHLEIFER A., VISHNY R.W., A Survey of Corporate Governance - NBER Working Paper No.W5554 April 1996

    SHLEIFER A.,SUMMERS L.H.,Breach of Trust in Hostile Takeovers, in Auerbach, 1988.

    SIMON H.A.,A behavioral model of rational choice ,Quarterly Journal of Economics n. 69, 1955TEECE D.J.,Contributions and Impediments of Economic Analysis to Strategic Management, workingpaper - University of California, Berkeley, 1988.

    THE ECONOMIST, Watching the Boss. A Survey of Corporate Governance, The Economist, n. 29,1994.

    TRICKER R.I., German Two Tier Boards and the Bank Share Holdings - The Case ofMetallgesellschaft, Corporate Governance, v. 2 - n. 3, 1994.

    WERIN L.,WIJKANDER H.,Contracts Economics, Basil Blackwell, Oxford, 1992.

    WILLIAMSON O.E.,Corporate Finance and Corporate Governance, Journal of Finance, n. 43, 1988.

    YAFEH Y.,Corporate Governance In Japan: Past Performance And Future Prospects

  • 7/31/2019 Corp Gov and Stakeholder Theory

    22/24

    Arturo Capasso - Stakeholders Theory and Corporate Governance

    22

    Exhibit 1

    INTANGIBLE ASSETS CLASSIFICATION

    firm-based organization-based people-based

    Patents embodied in the organization Professional skills

    Licences Systems and procedures Generic capabilities

    Trademarks Organizational routines Standard know-how

    Data-base Corporate culture

    Copyright

    Industrial designs shared with stakeholders

    Supplier/customer networks

    Total quality

    Learning capabili ties

    Innovation capabilities

    Product dif ferentation

    Customer satisfaction

  • 7/31/2019 Corp Gov and Stakeholder Theory

    23/24

    Arturo Capasso - Stakeholders Theory and Corporate Governance

    23

    Exhibit 2

    SYSTEMIC BALANCE SHEET

    ASSETS LIABILITIES

    DebtTangible Assets * present value of expected future

    * current market value of tan ible assets a ments to debtholders* current market value of autonomously

    negotiable intangibles

    Equity* resent value of ex ected future

    a ments to shareholderson the basis of ublicly available

    information

    Goodwill* firm-based intangible assets

    Control Premium

    * increase or decrease of the e uit value

    Systemic Goodwill on the basis of insider information* organization-based intangible asset * resent value of controllin share-

    holders benefits and perquisites

    Systemic Equity* resent value of ex ected future

    uasi-rent of the firm stakeholders

    = VALUE OF THE BUSINESS = VALUE OF THE BUSINESS

    SYSTEM AS A WHOLE SYSTEM AS A WHOLE

  • 7/31/2019 Corp Gov and Stakeholder Theory

    24/24

    Arturo Capasso - Stakeholders Theory and Corporate Governance

    24

    FOOTNOTES

    1 For a recent survey of theorethical contributions in this field see Becht et al.(2002)2 Academic scholars and practitioners usually discuss of different capitalist models distinguishing theAnglo-Saxon model, based on security market and public companies, from models based on closelyheld companies, long term shareholders and massive bank financing, like those developed in Germany,

    Japan, France and Italy (Roe, 1993; The Economist, 1994).3 The concept is well expressed by Jensen and Meckling at the beginning of their well-knowncontribution on agency costs. "We do not use the term capital structure because that term usuallydenotes the relative quantities of bonds, equity, warrants, trade credit, etc., which represent the

    liabilities of a firm. Our theory implies that there is another important dimension to this problem

    - namely the relative amounts of ownership claims held by insiders (management) and outsiders

    (investors with no direct role in the management of the firm)." (1976, p. 305).4 Johnson and Kaplan acknowledge this when they affirm: "A company's economic value is notmerely the sum of the values of its tangible assets, whether measurable at historic cost,

    replacement cost, or current market value prices. It also includes the value of intangibles assets:

    the stock of innovative products, the knowledge of flexible and high quality productionprocesses, employee talent, and morals, customer loyalty and product awareness, reliable

    suppliers, efficient distribution networks and the like....reported earnings cannot show the

    company's decline in value when it depletes its stock of intangible resources." (1987, p. 202).5 The concept of quasi-rent, originally introduced by Marshall (1920) is thoroughly explained in all themain textbooks of industrial economics, in particular see Milgrom and Roberts (1992)6 In this perspective it is particularly explanatory to compare the situation of a supplier, who deeplyinvested in transaction-specific assets to develop a stable relation with a particular company, with aninvestor, who owns a certain amount of company shares, holding them in a well diversified equityportfolio. Likely, the supplier's net worth will depend on company performance even more than the

    investor's one. Furthermore a possible bankruptcy would hurt with major strength the supplier than theinvestor who can sell his/her shares in a liquid and efficient market at the very beginning of the crisis(Bhide, 1993)..7 According to a respected economic newspaper "The particular problem is how to handle the stockmarket relationship of 'people' business, where not only do all the assets walk out of the front

    door every evening saying 'goodnight' to the security man, but often the business has to be

    continually recreated because innovation and relationships are more important than franchises

    or contracts." (B. Riley "When shareholders own less than they think" Financial Times 19/7/1995).