Copy of Poverty and Inequality in India_ M.phil Thesis

download Copy of Poverty and Inequality in India_ M.phil Thesis

of 76

Transcript of Copy of Poverty and Inequality in India_ M.phil Thesis

  • 8/2/2019 Copy of Poverty and Inequality in India_ M.phil Thesis

    1/76

    A Study on Poverty and Inequality in India

    A REVIEW OF THE STUDIES ON POVERTY AND

    INEQUALITY IN INDIA

    Sukumar Nandi

    CONTENTS

    Introduction Page

    1

  • 8/2/2019 Copy of Poverty and Inequality in India_ M.phil Thesis

    2/76

    A Study on Poverty and Inequality in India

    Chapter 1: 1

    Concept of Poverty and Inequality

    Concept 2: 4

    Poverty in India

    Chapter 3: 20

    Studies on Inequality

    Chapter 4: 63

    Causes of Poverty and Inequality in India

    Chapter 5: 75

    Conclusion: The Anti-Poverty Programmes

    Notes 82

    Bibliography 99

    INTRODUCTION

    Poverty and inequality are complex phenomena and their major discussions and

    consequent policy implications deserve the attention of all concerned. A critical review

    of the academic research on these phenomena reveals a variety of perspectives. Major

    differences in this respect have characterized the discussions of the definition of

    poverty and its measurement on the one hand, and of the elaboration of the concept of

    inequality in the context of a developing economy on the other. Policy implications

    also differ in different studies, which is a natural outcome of the differences in

    approach. One of these approaches starts from the concept of subsistence level for

    defined with some standard norm of nutrition. A second approach has been to use

    income and expenditure data for constructing a poverty line below which poverty will

    2

  • 8/2/2019 Copy of Poverty and Inequality in India_ M.phil Thesis

    3/76

    A Study on Poverty and Inequality in India

    be said to exist. In this approach data relating to per capita income or expenditure are

    utilized to establish the concept of a poverty level. Broadly speaking, these two

    approaches distinguish the major studies on poverty so far undertaken in India.

    Measurement of economic inequality can be regarded as one aspect of the wider

    problem of securing social equity and justice. In a sense it is perhaps the most

    important aspect of the broader concept. Economic inequality prevents the realization

    of the goals of social equity and justice. Economic justice becomes an important issue

    in the context of widespread poverty; the contrast becomes sharper when there exist

    small islands of affluence in an ocean of poverty. The studies on inequality in India

    generally use such standard measures as the Lorenz ratio though other more refined

    measure have also been used. Poverty and economic inequality can be regarded as the

    twin aspects of the same problem. In India again the problem of poverty and inequality

    is further aggravated by caste stratification which is a prominent feature of her social

    and community life over and above the economic stratification as commonly found in

    capitalist economies.

    The objective of this dissertation is very modest. It attempts to make a brief

    survey of the major studies on the measurement of poverty and inequality in India. At

    the outset the theoretical position in respect of the concepts of poverty and inequality

    has been explained, and subsequently the various Indian studies on the two topics have

    been analyzed. Thus the dissertation has been divided into five Chapters. In the first

    chapter, we review economic theory relevant to the concepts of poverty and inequality.

    In the second chapter we deal with different measures that have been evolved for the

    study of poverty in India. In the third Chapter we take a critical look at the studies

    made about economic inequality in India. The fourth chapter is devoted to an attempt

    to piece together the factors which the different studies on poverty and inequality have

    shown to be the underlying causes of these disturbing phenomena. In the last chapter

    we have made a brief survey of the programmes adopted in India to launch a direct

    attack on poverty in the rural areas.

    3

  • 8/2/2019 Copy of Poverty and Inequality in India_ M.phil Thesis

    4/76

    A Study on Poverty and Inequality in India

    CHAPTER-1

    CONCEPT OF POVERTY AND INEQUALITY

    An analysis of the Indian economic situation reveals two features: First, while

    the economy has attained a modest trend rate of growth, the problem of poverty

    perpetuates. Secondly, in our plan documents the problem of distribution has not been

    completely left out of discussions relating to production, and the possibility of conflict

    between growth and distribution has not been explicitly recognized.1 The essence of

    this argument in favour of this is as follows: A very slow rate of growth along with

    inequality in income distribution has perpetuated poverty in India. A large proportion

    of population has to live without even the most essential needs of daily life because

    total national income is too small relative to the size of population; and secondly, the

    4

  • 8/2/2019 Copy of Poverty and Inequality in India_ M.phil Thesis

    5/76

    A Study on Poverty and Inequality in India

    distribution of this income is very uneven. This problem cannot be overcome if

    emphasis is not put simultaneously on economic growth and reduction of inequality.

    Even the highest attainable rate of growth cannot make a major impact on the problem

    of poverty in the foreseeable future if inequality is not reduced.

    There has been a clear recognition, from the First Five Year Plan onwards, of

    the need for special policies for the benefit of the poor. In fact, the justification of

    policies like land reforms, subsidies to the village industries, economic assistance to the

    backward communities and so on is to be partly found in the recognition of their

    problem, while the problem is explicitly stated in the plan documents, there always

    appears to exist a gap between the formulation and execution of policies which could

    be regarded as intended primarily for the benefit of the poor. Indeed, the attempt to

    identify the poor in operational terms has started only in recent years.

    At present the problem of poverty is being dealt with both unprofessional

    writing and in government policy documents and programmes with increasing

    frequency. Poverty is a complex phenomenon and at least its major dimensions require

    considerable attention if the problem is to be properly comprehended. We should,

    therefore, start with the basic question: What is poverty?

    A review of the academic research in the field and of government programmes

    dealing with this subject shows several perspectives which have characterized

    approaches to the definition of poverty. Three such perspectives can be clearly

    discerned from the literature.

    One such perspective to the definition of poverty uses income and expenditure

    data in order to establish a bench mark income figure below which poverty may be saidto exist.2 Thus a size distribution of incomes is constructed and per capita income data

    are widely used as a means of establishing the bench mark income figure. We can

    distinguish two aspects of the so-called size distribution of incomes. The first focuses

    attention on one end of the distribution, those with the lowest income or the poor,

    choosing a more or less arbitrary bench-mark income figure. Here one can study the

    magnitude of poverty either in terms of the absolute number of the poor, or one can

    look at the different degrees of poverty within the group designated as the poor.3 The

    second aspect comprises the degrees of inequality in the distribution of income and is

    5

  • 8/2/2019 Copy of Poverty and Inequality in India_ M.phil Thesis

    6/76

    A Study on Poverty and Inequality in India

    concerned with the whole of the distribution. The degree of inequality is generally

    measured by the Lorenz Curve or Gini Coefficient. While the first aspect deals with

    the absolute poverty level, the second deals with poverty in its relative sense.4

    The first approach has its limitations- incomprehensive coverage, inaccuracy of

    measurement, inconsistency of definition and a failure to include all the sources other

    than income which support the consumption of people in the lower rung of the

    economic ladder. In the Indian context, measures of supporting resources such as

    ownership of land and other assets, income in kind and private gifts should be included

    and these are very difficult to compile on the part of the statistician. Thus, income

    figures are not accurate especially for the two extreme economic classes- the poor and

    the rich. While the poor are ill-equipped to provide correct information required for

    proper income and expenditure studies, the rich are least inclined to reveal their true

    economic power. As a result, income and expenditure data tend to have a downward

    bias for both the groups: for the poor, lack of literacy and consciousness and the

    subsistence production system largely play their parts; for the rich, the reasons are

    completely different-lack of organization in the economy and steep progression in the

    direct tax laws include the rich to record their income on the lower side.

    The second perspective can be specified as a subsistence approach to the

    concept of poverty. People who cannot afford the minimum necessities for bare

    subsistence are defined as poor. But how are we to define the required minimum

    level? The minimum need is defined in terms of food consumption or more

    specifically, in terms of nutritional requirements. This is then converted into an income

    level for a particular base year.5

    But in a country of Indias size, with wide differences in geography, climate,

    habits and customs, nutritional requirements are found to vary across levels and

    patterns of living and diet. In such a situation, to develop an index of minimum needs

    it is necessary to take account of customary behavior. Therefore, such a subsistence

    definition of nutritional requirements; it also depends on subjective consideration like

    preferences and prejudices.

    A third perspective to the definition of poverty is concerned with the degrees of

    differences of welfare among different group of people who can be designated as

    6

  • 8/2/2019 Copy of Poverty and Inequality in India_ M.phil Thesis

    7/76

    A Study on Poverty and Inequality in India

    poor by the first two approaches mentioned in earlier paragraphs. This approach

    seeks to establish a measure of poverty by attaching appropriate weights, which vary

    inversely with the difference of income levels of the poor from the chosen poverty

    line.6

    Thus from the first approach, we have an income threshold definition of

    poverty, while the second gives a multinational definition of the same. But these

    approaches divide the population into poor and non-poor and cannot take into account

    the differences in the degree of intensity of poverty in the different income layers

    below the poverty line. This weakness is sought to be removed in the third approach.

    What lessons can be draw from the three approaches to the definition ofpoverty? One point which emerges is that these approaches try to define poverty in the

    context of economic factors only and, again, these definitions are concerned with the

    people in the lower strata of the income scale. But the concept of poverty should be

    seen in the context of society as a whole. As society is better seen as a series of

    stratified income layers, poverty should be conceived in the light of how the lower

    strata fare as compared to the people in the upper layers of distribution. Moreover,

    poverty means helplessness of the persons designated as poor as these people are at

    the lower end of a two-fold hierarchy of stratification along economic and social

    dimensions. In short, the poor are part of a set of stratification system within the

    society and they are ranked at the bottom of each hierarchy. The economic factors are

    significant in the sense that these constitute the most important dimensions of poverty;

    but these alone cannot fully describe the condition of the poor. Therefore, the

    definition of poverty should be broad-based, for it is only a proper identification of the

    poor that can determination of policies to solve the problem in a proper way.

    Measures of Inequality

    A variety of indices for the measurement of the degree of inequality are found

    in the literature on income distribution. These indices emphasis different aspects of the

    inequality phenomenon. Theoretically, these indices are not completely satisfactory;

    sometimes, they exhibit contradictory tendencies in the distribution of income unless

    7

  • 8/2/2019 Copy of Poverty and Inequality in India_ M.phil Thesis

    8/76

    A Study on Poverty and Inequality in India

    the latter adapts itself to a well defined family of distributions whose properties are

    completely known. Because of the limitation inherent in all measures of inequality,

    one may adopt a more general approach to the problem by laying down that any

    measure of inequality should be concerned with the distribution of a size variable (x)

    relative to the mean (M) or any other typical value of x. This principle is recognized in

    all the known measures of inequality. These well-known empirical measures of

    inequality are Lorenz Curve, the Gini Co-efficient, the Co-efficient of variation, the

    S.D. of logarithm etc. Before going into details about these measures, we discuss the

    methodology regarding the measurement of inequality of income.

    Conceptually, we can draw a distinction between the objective and the

    normative approaches to the measurement of inequality of income. As objective

    measurement, in itself, is not of interest and presupposes appraisal; the difference

    between the two approaches, in fact, emerges at the level at which normative

    considerations come up. Therefore, use of the word equality in the context of

    distribution of income necessarily involves normative judgment. This is so in both the

    situations. We may be interested in inequality in the distribution of income of a

    country at different points of time or, we may compare the inequality in the distribution

    of income of different countries at the same point of time.

    In the literature, we find two broad categories of the measures of inequality. On

    set of measures try to quantify the size of inequality in some objective sense by using

    some statistical measures of relative variation of income. Such measures include the

    variance, the co-efficient of variation, the Lorenz Curve, the Gini Co-efficient etc. On

    the other hand, there are indices that try to measure inequality in terms of some

    normative notion of social welfare- that is , when the level of income is given, a higher

    degree of inequality corresponds to a lower level of social welfare.7

    We now discuss the measures of inequality. It would not be wrong if we

    discuss some measures briefly while concentrating on others which have been used

    widely in the literature on inequality in income distribution in India.8

    Long ago Pigou maintained that any transfer of income from the poor to the

    rich, ceteris paribus, should increase inequality and diminish welfare.9 The common

    statistical measure of dispersion-variance-does satisfy the Pigou condition. But the

    8

  • 8/2/2019 Copy of Poverty and Inequality in India_ M.phil Thesis

    9/76

    A Study on Poverty and Inequality in India

    dependence of variance on the mean income level makes its position weaker; since one

    distribution with lower mean income level but greater relative variation around the

    mean registers smaller variance than another distribution with higher mean but smaller

    relative variation around the mean. To remove this weakness we take the square root

    of the variance and divide it by the mean to make it mean-independent. This is the co-

    efficient of variation.

    The Co-efficient of variation is sensitive to income transfer for all income

    levels. But sometimes it is desirable that we should attach lower importance to income

    transfers at the higher levels of income and greater importance to income transfer at the

    lower end of the income scale. This objective is fulfilled in another measure- the

    standard deviation of logarithm. Since standard deviation is derived from the logarithm

    of the actual income levels, the staggering effect of logarithm highlights the income

    transfers at the lower end of income distribution and minimizes the effect of the

    transfer at the higher levels. This feature makes this measure attractive, but this creates

    difficulty for other reasons. The severe contraction the income levels suffer-as they get

    higher and higher-denies this welfare measure its concavity to be a concave function of

    individual incomes, this measure can create difficulties.10

    When we get interested about the share of different deciles of population from

    the lower end in the national income, we take recourse to the Lorenz Curve. This curve

    depicts the percentages of the population arranged in ascending order according to their

    positions of the income scale on the horizontal axis and the percentages of total income

    enjoyed by each of these groups are shown on the vertical axis. If everyone has the

    same income, the Lorenz Curve will by the diagonal, which is called equality line.

    The deviation of the Lorenz Curve from the line of absolute equality is an index of

    inequality. One distribution is unequivocally more unequal than another only if the

    Lorenz Curve for the former lies below the Lorenz Curve for the latter throughout its

    range.

    The advantage of the Lorenz Curve lies in its use of the arithmetic scale. It is,

    again, independent of any assumption about the form of the distribution to which the

    observed data must conform. However, when the form of the distribution is known

    with certainty, the corresponding Lorenz Curve is uniquely determined by the values of

    9

  • 8/2/2019 Copy of Poverty and Inequality in India_ M.phil Thesis

    10/76

    A Study on Poverty and Inequality in India

    the distributional parameters. For different values of these parameters Lorenz Curves

    are obtained which are completely non-overlapping.11

    The use of Lorenz Curve as a means of measuring income inequality within the

    utilitarian framework has been justified in the literature.12 It has been shown that if

    social welfare is additively separable and if it is the sum of individuals-then the partial

    ordering of income distribution according to Lorenz Criterion is identical with the

    ordering implied by social welfare. This result holds irrespective of the form of the

    individual utility functions as long as they are concave.13 Intuitively, one might expect

    that the equivalence of partial orderings would hole for any symmetric social welfare

    function which is quasi-concave and increasing in individual utilities.14

    When the Lorenz Curves of two distributions intersect, there is ambiguity in

    comparison; that is, for comparative purposes, it is difficult to say which Lorenz Curve

    represents greater inequality. Gini introduced an analytical measure called the

    concentration ration or the Gini Coefficient, which is the ratio of the area between

    the equality line and the Lorenz Curve to the triangular region below the diagonal. It is

    defined as exactly one half of the relative mean difference-this is the arithmetic average

    of the absolute values of differences between all parts of incomes.

    ==

    =q

    j

    ji

    q

    i

    yymq

    G11

    2||

    2

    1

    Where m is the mean income of the poor, and q is the number of persons.

    After a bit of manipulation the formula reduces to 15

    ( )=

    ++=q

    i

    iqyimqq

    G1

    21

    211

    for y1 y2 y3 . yn

    Since the Gini Co-efficient takes note of differences between every pair of incomes, it

    is a direct measure of income inequality; it is also sensitive to transfer from the rich to

    the poor at every level.

    Gini Co-efficient is mean-independent, that is, it is invariant with respect to

    equi-proportionate change of incomes of all individuals. If the mean income of thedistribution changes, while there is no change in the inequality measure, the effect on

    10

  • 8/2/2019 Copy of Poverty and Inequality in India_ M.phil Thesis

    11/76

    A Study on Poverty and Inequality in India

    the measure of absolute poverty is certain. It moves inversely with the changes in the

    mean income. But measure of inequality being mean-independent, changes in mean

    income introduce complex difficulties in measuring of poverty in a relative sense. In a

    society with higher mean income inequality causes greater injustice compared to a

    society with lower mean income. This fact introduces ambiguity in the measurement of

    poverty in a relative sense.16

    Since the Gini Co-efficient is an index of inequality, the negative of it can be

    treated as a welfare function. But this function, being a linear function of income

    levels, is not a strictly concave group welfare function. As strict concavity is a

    desirable criterion for a welfare function. Gini co-efficient is thought to be weak on

    this point.17 But this measure takes into account any transfer of income from the poor

    to the rich in appropriate direction, and it is, though not strictly concave, is concave

    alright.18

    Atkinson proposed a new measure of inequality19 by an index:

    m

    YI

    *1* =

    Where Y* is the level of income per head and m is the mean of the income distribution.

    If the level of income is equally distributed, Y* would give the same level of social

    welfare as the present distribution.

    Moreover, in a separate measure,20 Atkinson introduced distributional objective

    through an explicit parameter, say E, which represents the weight attached by the

    society to inequality in the distribution. When the society is indifferent regarding the

    income distribution, the value of E becomes zero, and when the society is concerned

    only with the position of the lowest income group, the parameter becomes infinity. The

    index is:

    En

    i

    E

    fiY

    YiI

    =

    =

    1

    1

    1

    1

    1

    Where Y1 is the income of those in the 1-th income range, f1 is the proportion of the

    population with incomes in the 1-th range and Ythe mean income. This indexindicates the proportion of the present total income that would be required to achieve

    11

  • 8/2/2019 Copy of Poverty and Inequality in India_ M.phil Thesis

    12/76

    A Study on Poverty and Inequality in India

    this same level of social welfare as at present if income were equally distributed. The

    measure is an index of the potential gains from redistribution.

    The inadequacy of the index of income distribution as an index of the

    distribution of welfare has been pointed out by Bentozel.21 In this view, it is the

    distribution of consumption which has a direct bearing on the distribution of welfare.

    From the welfare point of view the welfare-creating properties of the distribution of

    income or consumption are important; these properties should be represented in the

    analysis of income inequality. Bentzels new measure seems to fulfill this condition.

    The construction of this index is as follows: Assuming that a group of individuals have

    the same welfare function u(c), where c denotes the level of consumption and f(c) is the

    frequency function of the level of individual consumption, the aggregate welfare (w)

    can be written as

    dccfcunW )()(0

    =

    Where n is the number of individuals. Suppose W* is the maximum

    aggregate welfare that could be obtained by a redistribution of consumption between

    the individuals. The difference between W* and W can be interpreted as the totalwelfare loss caused by the inequality in the individual consumption measured by

    *1**

    W

    WI =

    The ratio W/W* has been called welfare efficiency of distribution by Bentzel. But,

    in this analysis the precise relationship between distribution of consumption and

    distribution of welfare is not brought out very clearly. Again, since the shape of the

    welfare function u(c) is unknown, the definition of welfare efficiency of distribution

    is not useful for empirical analysis.22

    Sens Measure

    Sen has constructed a measure of poverty in an axiomatic framework.23 This

    measure takes into account the income distribution among the people designated as

    poor, that is, people below the poverty line. If yj is the income level of individual j,

    the individuals may be numbered in a non-decreasing order of income, satisfying

    12

  • 8/2/2019 Copy of Poverty and Inequality in India_ M.phil Thesis

    13/76

    A Study on Poverty and Inequality in India

    y1 y2 . yn

    If z is the poverty line and q is the number of people with income yi z, then for

    any person i q, there are exactly (q+1-i) people among the poor with at least as high a

    welfare level as person i. Let n be the total population. The poverty-measure P can

    be written as

    )1)(()1(

    2iqyiz

    nzqP +

    +=

    This measure of poverty P is closely related to Gini Co-efficient, and Sen has

    established a correspondence between Gini Co-efficient and his poverty measure.

    Defining the head-count ratio H as the ratio of the number of people below the

    poverty line, Sen(1976) has proved the relation

    P = H [I*-(1-I*)G]

    Where G is the Gini Co-efficient and I* reveals the percentage of the mean shortfall of

    incomes of the poor from the poverty line.24 From this relation an important policy

    implication follows: The aggregate welfare of the population can be increased by

    minimizing the inequality in the distribution of income.

    In any actual situation, the use of the measure P involves the specification of

    the welfare function. In such a choice, value judgment cannot be avoided. Moreover,

    this measure is concerned with only a part of the income distribution.

    Our analysis of the different measure of inequality leads finally to the following

    points: First, the literature is full of controversy regarding the practical relevance of the

    implicit welfare function, the shape of the welfare function and the question of ordering

    in the social welfare. Second, while descriptive measures like coefficient of variation,

    standard deviation of logarithm etc. lack motivation, purely normative measures seem

    to leave out of consideration several important characteristics of inequality.

    13

  • 8/2/2019 Copy of Poverty and Inequality in India_ M.phil Thesis

    14/76

    A Study on Poverty and Inequality in India

    Chapter-2

    Poverty in India

    The problem of poverty had attracted the attention of economists even before

    independence25 but as we are interested in the study of the post-independence period,

    we will not discuss this here. After independence a vast literature on poverty has

    emerged, the most important of this being Dandekar and Rath(1971), Ojha(1970),

    Minhas(1970), Bardhan(1970,1973) and Vaidyanathan(1974). Most of these studies

    take 1960-61 as a bench mark year for the purpose of comparison, and the data used by

    these studies cover periods up to 1968-69. These different studies come to different

    conclusions both as regards the definition of the minimum standard of living and

    regarding the number of people below the different studies are four in number: (i)

    differences in estimates of income and consumption; (ii) different concepts of adequate

    nutritional levels; (iii) differences regarding current price deflator to be used; and (iv)

    arbitrariness in the choice of some key conversion factors to overcome the lack of

    availability of appropriate disaggregated empirical data. Let us now explain these in

    turn.

    14

  • 8/2/2019 Copy of Poverty and Inequality in India_ M.phil Thesis

    15/76

    A Study on Poverty and Inequality in India

    First, for the calculation of the size distribution of income and/or consumption

    most of these studies depend on the data yielded by the National Sample Surveys. But

    there is discrepancy between NSS data and national income statistics prepared by the

    C.S.O. It is alleged that NSS data underestimates consumption expenditure for the

    upper income classes,26 which implies that the measure of poverty will not be affected

    but the measure of inequality will be. Secondly, the concepts of a minimum adequate

    level of nutrition and its purchasing power equivalent form the basis of all the studies

    that have tried to estimate the numbers of people living below the national poverty line.

    But different authorities give different estimates of nutritional requirements. Among

    these are: PPD, Planning Commission(1974), Sukhatma (1971) and Gopalan, Sastri and

    Balasubramanian(1971). Thirdly, as most of the income and consumption expenditure

    data are available initially at current prices, one has to deflate them to obtain real values

    for the purpose of inter-temporal comparisons. But the choice of a correct price

    deflator is difficult as different income groups possess different preference patterns,

    some buy commodities at ex-farm prices and some obtain commodities through

    exchange in kind. Again, prices for the identical commodities vary region wise. Thus

    conclusions vary because the researchers use different price deflators. While

    Minhas(1970) and Dandekar and Rath(1971) use the national income deflator,

    Bardhan(1970) uses the official Agricultural Labour Consumer Price Index for

    deflating the values of consumption of the rural poor and the Official Working Class

    Consumer Price Index for deflating the consumption of the urban poor.27 In this

    connection, it will not be out of place to mention the nature of price movement of

    different commodities in different parts of India. Mahalanobis(1962) had drawn our

    attention to the unequal movement of the prices of cereals for different decile groups of

    the population in rural India.28

    This was later corroborated by extensive tabulation ofNSS household budget data undertaken for the Government of India Committee on

    Distribution of Income and Levels of Living. Since cereals occupy a very important

    place in the consumer budget, specially for rural households, the above finding stresses

    the need of constructing inter-temporal consumer price indices separately for different

    fractile groups of population. Fourthly, in different studies, conversion factors have

    been used to build up a complete picture from fragmented data. The assumption in

    Dandekar and Rath(1971) is that the top 30 per cent of the population would have fared

    no worse in terms of consumption between 1960-61 and 1967-68 than the lower

    15

  • 8/2/2019 Copy of Poverty and Inequality in India_ M.phil Thesis

    16/76

    A Study on Poverty and Inequality in India

    income groups. On the other hand, Bardhan(1970) uses a conversion factor appropriate

    to the bottom 50 per cent of the population for the derivation of an estimate of total

    expenditure from expenditure on food items. From these it follows that there cannot be

    a correct estimate that can be derived from the assumption that are made in the

    studies noted above.

    With these preliminary observations we will now turn to an analysis of the

    Studies on Indian Poverty.

    In July, 1962 the Government of India set up a Study Group29 which

    recommended that a per capita annual consumption of Rs.240 at 1960-1961 prices

    should be considered as the nationally desirable minimum level of consumerexpenditure. This excluded expenditure on health and education, which was supposed

    to be provided free of cost by the state. This level of expenditure has often been taken

    as the poverty line and the proportion of people below this standard of consumption

    has been investigated by different economists. This notice of poverty line again

    constitutes the keystone for the exercise in long term planning that is presented in the

    Planning Commission document Notes on Perspective of Development, India 1960-

    1961 to 1975-76. It cannot be ascertained whether any competent statistical authority

    arrived at this figure after careful consideration. In fact, how this figure was reached

    remains up till now somewhat of a mystery to ordinary citizens. However, as this

    figure is important, we shall examine in greater detail.

    First, this official poverty standard, being essentially an absolute measure, is

    inadequate since this is based purely on money income and ignores other aspects of

    deprivation. No account is taken of poor quality housing, schools of health care which

    may be independent of low money income. Moreover, poverty may represents only

    one aspect of a more general powerlessness, an inability to influence ones

    environment.30 Of course, this aspect of poverty is neglected by almost all the poverty

    measure in use in India; such powerlessness on the part of the poor makes the problem

    of poverty doubly acute. We will turn to this aspect of the problem in the last section.

    Secondly, apart from methodological criticism, the presumption that the population

    would be provided education and health care free of cost by the State can be

    questioned. In fact, as nearly two-thirds of the population remain illiterate,31

    and the

    government health programme has not yet been able to cover all the villages in the

    16

  • 8/2/2019 Copy of Poverty and Inequality in India_ M.phil Thesis

    17/76

    A Study on Poverty and Inequality in India

    country, such an assumption simply ignores reality. As people are often forced to

    spend on medicine, inclusion of some expenditure on medicine in the consumer budget

    appears to be necessary and this makes the Rs.20 per month figure rather suspect.

    Thirdly, though the idea of nutritional norm has been accepted regarding food items in

    private consumption expenditure, in respect of non-food items like clothing and

    housing no yardsticks have been worked out on any scientific basis.

    The minimum standard of living prescribed by the Study Group is necessarily

    the biological minimum diet has been carefully worked out by Sukhatme(1965).32 He

    take into account various recommendation of the Food and Agricultural Organisation

    [FAO] and the Nutrition Advisory Committee [NAC]. Again he has made specific

    allowances for India in terms of availabilities and consumption habits; he has taken into

    account different requirements of persons in different age and sex groups and thus

    worked out two food baskets corresponding to a minimum concept and a medium

    concept. The cost of the minimum food basket (per day) has been worked out as

    Rs.0.5238 at 1960-61 prices or Rs.15.71 per month at 1960-61 prices. As compared

    with Sukhatmes estimate, the cost of a minimum diet prescribed by the FAO33 is

    Rs.18.26 at 1960-61 prices.

    Sometimes alternative standards have been defined in terms of minimum

    Calorie requirements, as in Ojha (1970) and Dandekar and Rath (1971). They have

    taken 2250 Calories is met from food grain and considering the food grains intake per

    person in different expenditure brackets as given by NSS data they have estimated the

    proportion of population below the poverty line.34

    On the basis of the recommendations of Dr. Patwardhan as mentioned in the

    Report of the Central Government Employees Pay Commission (1957-59), Bardhan

    (1973) has worked out the cost of the minimum diet recommended for an built in

    moderate activity.35 The diet consists of 15 0z. of cereals, 3 0z. of pulses, milk (4 0z)

    sugar and gur (1.5 0z), edible oils (1.25 0z), groundnut (1 0z) and vegetables (6 0z).

    These give 2100 calories and 55 grams of protein per day. Because of non-availability

    of prices, Bardhan leaves out the last two items i.e., groundnut and vegetables. For the

    determination of the cost of this minimum diet Bardhan adjusts the NSS rural retail

    prices to take account of the lower prices for non-monetized consumption. First, the

    cost of this minimum diet for adults is determined. Then he adjusts it by an adult-

    17

  • 8/2/2019 Copy of Poverty and Inequality in India_ M.phil Thesis

    18/76

    A Study on Poverty and Inequality in India

    equivalent ratio to obtain the cost of the minimum diet for an average person. Then he

    blows it up by using food to non-food expenditure ratio of the relevant expenditure

    group of the rural population from NSS data, to get the estimated minimum level of

    living for rural India to be Rs.28 per capita per month in 1968-69 in current prices.

    Bardhan (1973) has taken the food basket from the report of the Second Pay

    Commission and has used the rural retail prices from NSS estimates as is done by the

    Commission; but he has arrived at a much lower value. While in the former the cost of

    the minimum diet is Rs. 14.51 per month per adult unit, that is, Rs.11.61 per month per

    person basis, the corresponding figures in Bardhan are Rs.11.61 and Rs.9.61

    respectively. The lower figures of Bardhan can be traced to the following two elements

    in his calculation: First, he has neglected vegetables and ground-nuts from the food

    baskets; and secondly, he has adjusted the NSS based average retail prices to take into

    account the consumption of home grown articles on the part of rural consumers.

    Regarding the second consideration Rudra (1974) has taken exception on two points.36

    First, according to Rudra, the procedure adopted by Bardhan (1973) is arbitrary, as he

    overlooks the fact that it is not only the home grown part that is evaluated in the NSS

    data in prices different from the average retail prices; the cash purchased part in NSS

    expenditure data is evaluated in actual prices paid by the consumers, and not by the

    average retail prices independently estimated and separately presented by the NSS.

    While the price average in the NSS expenditure data regarding cash purchases is a

    weighted average, the rural retail prices are simple averages. Secondly, Rudra points

    out that the blow-up factor (46%) is not correct.

    We have discussed the nature and inadequacy of the concept of an absolute

    poverty line in India. Let us now turn to the studies on Indian poverty.

    Minhas (1970)37 has used the computations of Tewari (1968)38 to derive the

    estimates of per capita private consumption expenditure, which are at 1960-61 prices.

    He has, then, applied the NSS ratio of rural to urban consumption to obtain the

    estimates of rural average per Capita Consumption. These estimates of per capita

    overall consumption in rural area in 1960-61 prices, together with the percentage shares

    of different fractile groups of population in total consumption, derived from different

    NSS rounds, have been used to derive the average per Capita Consumption in 1960-61

    prices of each fractile group of the population over several years.

    18

  • 8/2/2019 Copy of Poverty and Inequality in India_ M.phil Thesis

    19/76

    A Study on Poverty and Inequality in India

    It will not be out of place if we reproduce here a table from Minhas:

    Table: Average Per Capita Consumption by Fractile Groups at

    1960-61 prices in 1956-57 and 1967-68: Rural India

    Fractile Group1956-57

    (Rs.)

    1967-68

    (Rs.)

    Poorest 5% 63 81

    5-10 88 110

    10-20 108 137

    20-30 133 16630-40 155 194

    40-50 180 222

    50-60 207 254

    60-70 240 292

    70-80 283 240

    80-90 351 414

    90-95 443 512

    Richest 5% 731 723

    Source: Minhas (1970) Table 2. Abridged

    We see that the richest 5% of Indians could enjoy a per Capita

    Consumption level of about Rs.2 in 1960-61 prices per day in the years 1956-57 and

    1967-68. Even this group cannot be termed as rich by the world standard, though they

    are at the topmost income level in the villages of India. The poorest 30% or the people,

    and the other extreme, live a life beyond the description and analysis of the economists

    and nutrition experts.

    19

  • 8/2/2019 Copy of Poverty and Inequality in India_ M.phil Thesis

    20/76

    A Study on Poverty and Inequality in India

    If the level of per Capita annual consumption expenditure of Rs.240 at 1960-61

    prices is accepted as a bare minimum, the percentage of people in rural India below this

    poverty line was 65 in 1956-57 and 50.6 in 1967-68. But in Minhas estimate the

    absolute number of people below the poverty line in rural India remained almost same

    215 million in 1956-57 and 210 million in 1967-68. If, however, a level of Rs.200 at

    1960-61 prices is taken as the minimum, the proportion of people below the poverty

    line would be 52.4 per cent in 1956-57 and 37.1 per cent in 1961. The steady decline in

    the proportion of people below the poverty line is, according to Minhas, largely

    explained by the growth of an average per Capita Consumption at a rate of 1.25 per

    cent per year over the period 1956-57 and 1967-68.

    As regards the identification of the rural poor Minhas be specified several

    classes to which most of them belong and these classes are:

    (a) Agriculture labour households without land, which formed 58 to 61 per cent

    of all agricultural labour household between 1956-57 and 1963-64.

    (b) Other rural labour household without land.

    (c) Agricultural labour household with land, which formed between 42 to 39

    per cent of agricultural labour households between 1956-57 and 1963-64.

    (d) Marginal farmers operating holdings below 5 acres in size.

    According to the estimate of Minhas, the total number of people in agriculture

    labour households in 1960-61 was 66.5 million of which about 26.5 millions belonged

    to households who operated some land as well. The corresponding estimates for non-

    agricultural rural labour were 15.8 and 6.8 millions respectively. Therefore, the total

    rural labour population in 1960-61 was estimated to be 82.3 millions and of these 33.3

    millions belonged to households who operated some land also. Minhas estimated that

    about 79 per cent of the population of these households had a per capita annual level of

    consumption of less than Rs.200 at 1960-61 prices in the year 1956-57. Minhas further

    stated that the percentage of poor among the agricultural labour population declined to

    75 in 1960-61, which corresponded to about 50 million in absolute numbers.39

    While Minhas is concerned with rural poverty only, Ojha (1970) deals with

    both rural and urban poverty for the year 1960-61 and only rural poverty for the year

    1967-68. In his study Ojha accepts 2250 Calories as the barest minimum intake per

    capita per day for a representative Indian. He further assumes that people in urban

    20

  • 8/2/2019 Copy of Poverty and Inequality in India_ M.phil Thesis

    21/76

    A Study on Poverty and Inequality in India

    areas derive 66 per cent of 2250 calories from food grains; for the people in rural areas

    that percentage is 80. he then compares the actual food consumption in grams per head

    of rural and urban population using the NSS data [16th round].41 This means that to

    attain the nutritional minimum per capita daily consumption should be 518 grams in

    rural areas and 532 grams in urban areas. After some modifications of the estimates of

    food grains intake he finds that the average level of food grains intake per person was

    below the standard for expenditure levels up to Rs.15-12 per capita per month at 1960-

    61 prices. Regarding the urban population the corresponding expenditure level for

    which deficiency in consumption existed was Rs.11-13 per capita per month at 1960-61

    prices. On his basis Ojha finds that in 1960-61 about 51.8 per cent of rural population

    lived below the poverty line, and for the urban population the proportion of those

    considered as poor was only 7.6 per cent.

    Ojhas conclusion regarding poverty in the urban area is surprising because of

    the following reasons. First, the urban households tend to spend a smaller percentage

    of their incomes on food grains, which Ojha has accepted in his calculation. But this

    again means that urban households derive a comparatively larger fraction of the

    required 2250 calories from food other than food grains gives greater calorie value

    compared to the same spent on items other than food grains, the minimum expenditure

    levels for the required 2250 calories should be higher in urban areas.42 Secondly, since

    unit prices of food grains in urban areas are higher than in rural areas, expenditure in

    urban areas for food grains should be higher.43 Though Ojha takes the nutritional norm

    for urban are as 432 grams, which is 86 grams lower than the rural requirement of 518

    grams (and this means that smaller volume of expenditure is involved), the urban

    people must procure additional calories from food items other than food grains, and

    again they are to purchase these at higher prices. These points seem to have beenmissed by Ojha and that is why his estimated poverty line for the urban area is as low

    as Rs.11-13 per Capita per month, and much lower than the figure estimated for the

    rural areas. From these it seems that the proportion of population in urban areas below

    the poverty line is much higher than the estimate of Ojha indicates.

    Regarding the year 1967-68, Ojha calculates that about 70 per cent of rural

    households were living below the poverty line. Moreover, the degree of nutritional

    21

  • 8/2/2019 Copy of Poverty and Inequality in India_ M.phil Thesis

    22/76

  • 8/2/2019 Copy of Poverty and Inequality in India_ M.phil Thesis

    23/76

    A Study on Poverty and Inequality in India

    Capita annual consumption expenditure below the stipulated minimum i.e., Rs.170 at

    1960-61 prices.

    Regarding urban consumption, D R find from NSS data that urban households

    secure the minimum Calories requirement of 2250 at levels where their consumption of

    food grains and substitutes reaches 490 grams per person per day. Again, while a rural

    household at Rs.170 per capita per annum spends 78.56 per cent on food, an urban

    household at Rs.271 per capita per annum spend only 70.26 per cent on food; again of

    this 70.26 per cent only 36.45 per cent goes on food grains and substitutes and the

    remaining 33.81 per cent is spent on other items of food. Finally, the prices of food

    grains which an urban household at an expenditure level of Rs.271 per capita per

    annum pays are almost 25 per cent higher than the prices paid by a rural household at

    expenditure level of Rs.170 per capita per annum. Hence an annual per capita urban

    expenditure of Rs.271 is to be regarded as equivalent to an annual per capita rural

    expenditure of Rs.170. Now D R find that about 48.64 per cent on urban population

    in 1960-61 could not afford the diet consumed by the group with an annual per capita

    expenditure of Rs.271. Thus 48.64 per cent of urban population lived below the

    poverty line.

    According to D R the NSS estimate of average per capita consumption in

    1967-68 is an underestimate. What is unacceptable to them regarding the NSS estimate

    is that NSS estimate of rural per capita consumption estimate of Rs.239.8 (at 1960-61

    prices) in the year 1967-68 is about 7 per cent lower than the corresponding NSS

    estimate in 1960-61; again, it is about 11 per cent lower than the consumption estimate

    for 1967-68 derived from the national income statistics. Using the national income

    deflator D R find that the average per capita consumption of the lowest 5 per cent

    rural fractile group in 1967-68 is 94 per cent of that in 1960-61, whereas for the

    topmost 5 per cent fractile group the estimate of average per capita consumption is only

    73 per cent of that in 1960-61. Now such a large differential decline in per capita

    consumption of the richest 5 per cent is not acceptable to D R, as this goes against

    their a prior judgment that during the sixties there has been an obvious increase in

    inequality in the structure of the Indian rural economy.

    It is clear that the position taken by D R rests on whether the NSS estimate of

    average per capita consumption is an under estimates or not. On this point Bardhan

    23

  • 8/2/2019 Copy of Poverty and Inequality in India_ M.phil Thesis

    24/76

    A Study on Poverty and Inequality in India

    (1974)46 is of the view that the deflating of private consumer expenditure data by the

    national income deflator is improper. Bardhan cites the study of Radhakrishnan,

    Srinivasan and Vaidyanathan (1974) who have worked out a general consumer price

    index on the basis of NSS weights for ten commodity groups and wholesale prices data

    issued by the office of the Economic Adviser to the Government of India.47 The

    Radhakrishnan, Srinivasan and Vaidyanathan (R-S-V) index is 178.1 in 1968-69 taking

    1960-61 figure as 100, but for the same period national income deflator increases from

    100 to 169.8. Now if the R-S-V index is used, not only is the NSS estimate for per

    Capita real consumption for 1967-68 below that for 1960-61, but the official estimate

    for 1967-68 will also be lower than that for 1960-61. Thus Bardhan (1974) asserts that

    NSS estimate should not be discarded simply because it establishes a decline in the per

    Capita real Consumption during the sixties.

    But the observation of D-R regarding the increasing under-estimation of the

    consumption of the rich in NSS estimate is endorsed by Bardhan (1974) and other

    economists,48 though no satisfactory explanation of this is yet available. The

    explanation given by D-R is as follows:

    The NSS secures its estimates of consumer expenditures by interviewing a

    random sample of rural and urban households and inquiring from them about their

    consumer expenditure during the previous month. The limitations of this procedure are

    well known. For instance, a number of items of consumer expenditure, such as clothing

    and other consumer durables, which a household would purchase less frequently than

    once every month, are likely to be missed by this procedure and hence the expenditure

    on them is likely to be under-estimated. These are the items which are more important

    in the consumer expenditure of the rich than the poor and they become more important

    as the rich become richer. It is also known that the upper middle and the richerhouseholds, both in rural and urban areas, have become increasingly inaccessible to the

    NSS investigators who are after all class III government servants.

    But the relative infrequency of the purchase of some consumer durables and

    articles of high consumption need not lead to underestimation as the NSS is canvassed

    in a number of sub-rounds spread throughout the year and so the seasonality, if any, in

    the purchase of consumer durables should not lead to any bias. Moreover, in any given

    24

  • 8/2/2019 Copy of Poverty and Inequality in India_ M.phil Thesis

    25/76

    A Study on Poverty and Inequality in India

    sub-round the random sampling procedure of the survey will ensure that purchasers of

    cloth are not systematically excluded.

    Now R-S-V have shown that the estimates of consumption at current prices

    derived from National Income and the NSS data a are in close agreement for the period

    1954-55 to 1963-64, but thereafter the two series differ considerably. These authors

    conclude that the relatively close agreement between the NSS and official series for

    some years does not necessarily indicate the absence of systematic bias in the two

    series and similarly the divergence between the two series for the later years of the

    sixties does not necessarily indicate the presence of such bias. But R-S-V have not

    given any explanation for the divergence of the two series from 1963-64 onwards.

    Turning now to other studies we find that the study of Vaidyanathan (1974a,

    1974b) takes an income level of Rs.132 per year to denote poverty and finds that the

    proportion of rural population living below the poverty line is 15.7 per cent in 1960-61.

    Now the poverty line drawn by Vaidyanathan is much lower compared to the estimates

    of others and there is little surprise that the number of the poor will be considerably

    lower.49 However, Vaidyanathan (1974a) has presented the following estimate of the

    proportion of rural population with per Capita Consumption expenditure below Rs.20

    per month at 1960-61 prices. According to NSS estimate, the percentage of people

    living below the poverty line was 59.5 in 1960-61; it increased to 67.8 in the year 1967-

    68. Again, according to official estimate, the respective percentages are 58.8 and 57.8,

    which shows that the level of poverty remained more or less same during the sixties,

    though the number of people below the poverty line increased.

    The study of Bardhan (1970, 1970a, 1973) uses NSS data for distribution of

    consumer expenditure, but uses a different minimum level of income of Rs.15.00 per

    month at 1960-61 prices and Rs.28.4 at 1968-69 prices for the two years respectively.

    Bardhan then argues that the national income deflator (which rose from 100 in 1960-61

    to 170 in 1967-68) as used by Minhas (1970) and Dandekar and Rath (1971) is not an

    appropriate price index to use, as it does not accurately reflect the set of prices facing

    the poor consumer.50 This is due to the following reasons. First, national income

    includes both investment and consumption goods and as such the national income

    deflator cannot be a suitable index for studying changes in consumption. Secondly, the

    national income deflator covers the prices the prices of both agricultural and industrial

    25

  • 8/2/2019 Copy of Poverty and Inequality in India_ M.phil Thesis

    26/76

    A Study on Poverty and Inequality in India

    commodities. The weight of the latter items in the budget of the poor is much lower

    than the national average and hence the national income deflator is very likely to have

    understated the rise in the prices paid by the rural poor. This is more so when the

    prices of agricultural commodities have risen at a much faster rate than the prices of

    manufactured items.

    For the above reasons, Bardhan uses an alternative deflator which is the

    agricultural labour consumer price index. This index is based on the Labour Bureau

    series of consumer price index number for agricultural labourers constructed on the

    basis of NSS rural retail prices and weighting diagrams obtained from the Second

    Agricultural Labour Enquiry. Bardhan finds that the number of the rural poor

    increased from about 135 million in 1960-61 to 230 million in 1968-69, that is, the

    percentage of the rural population living below the prescribed minimum increased from

    somewhat less than 38 per cent in 1960-61 to about 54 per cent in 1968-69. This result

    is in sharp contrast to the conclusion reached by Minhas (1970).

    It is contended that the high figure of population below the poverty line in

    1968-69 may be traced to the consumer price index used by Bardhan. 51 But Bardhan

    has defended these indices by computing several alternative indices and showing their

    agreement.

    The study of Bhatty (1974)52 is concerned with the extent of rural poverty in

    1968-69. The object of his study is to present a measure of absolute poverty in terms of

    per capita income, which takes into account the inequality of income distribution

    among the poor. Moreover, Bhatty is interested about the incidence of poverty in

    different regions of rural India and among different classes of the rural population. To

    avoid arbitrariness, Bhatty has set five poverty levels, which, in terms of per capita

    annual income in 1968-69 prices are: Rs.180, Rs.240, Rs.300, Rs.360 and Rs.420.

    Since the study is concerned with a single year, 1968-69, no comparison is undertaken

    regarding the change in poverty level of the country. Taking Rs.360 as the minimum

    per capita annual income, Bhattys study reveals that about 67.15 per cent of all rural

    households lived below the poverty line. If only agricultural labourer households are

    considered, then about 82.84 per cent of them live below the poverty line, whereas for

    the non-agricultural households this percentage is 69.7. Thus the incidence of poverty

    is most severe among agricultural labourers.

    26

  • 8/2/2019 Copy of Poverty and Inequality in India_ M.phil Thesis

    27/76

    A Study on Poverty and Inequality in India

    Bhatty has also tried to calculate for India the magnitude of Sens poverty

    measure P, the result of which is summarized in the following table:

    Sens Poverty measure P for India, 1968-69

    Poverty line: rupees per Capita per annum

    180 240 300 360 420

    (i) All occupation classes 0.101 0.188 0.279 0.363 0.435

    (ii) Cultivators 0.107 0.187 0.269 0.345 0.415

    (iii) Agricultural labourers 0.098 0.220 0.336 0.440 0.521

    (iv) Non-agricultural workers 0.171 0.155 0.251 0.344 0.425

    Source: Bhatty (1974) Tables 7-10, pp. 316-17

    From the table we find that of the three occupational classes, agricultural labourers are

    the most deprived. Bhatty has also analysed in detail the level of poverty in different

    states. He has identified the five poorest states in the country - Gujrat, Tamil Nadu,

    Madhya Pradesh, Rajasthan and Orissa and explained the region wise variations of

    poverty level. He shows that while the incidence of poverty among the agricultural

    labourers is the highest in Gujrat and the lowest in Punjab, the non-agricultural workers

    are worse off in Madhya Pradesh. According to Bhatty, the relative incidence of

    absolute poverty in the rural population of different states depends on many factors,

    such as, land-man ratio, topography and quality of land, rainfall, irrigation, cropping

    pattern, rural institutional structure etc. Thus this study points to the fact that any study

    on poverty should be based on the diversity of different regions and it is pointless to

    calculate any uniform measure of poverty for India as a whole.

    The importance of regional study for ascertaining the poverty level has been

    emphasized also by Panikar, whose study is based on condition in Kerala. 53 The author

    is concerned with the question of choice of a nutritional measure used by Dandekar and

    Rath and the Nutrition advisory Committee. Panikar establishes the fact that D-R have

    27

  • 8/2/2019 Copy of Poverty and Inequality in India_ M.phil Thesis

    28/76

    A Study on Poverty and Inequality in India

    overestimated the number of the poor in Kerala, as the minimum diet accepted by D-R

    is in fact the India average.

    Indira Rajaraman (1975) discusses the incidence of poverty in the Punjab

    between 1960-61 and 1970-71.54 In the year 1960-61, the lowest two deciles of

    population accounted for 10.4 per cent of total consumption, while in the year 1970-71,

    they accounted for only 8.9 per cent of total consumption. Again, during the same

    period the share of the topmost decile increased from 23.2 per cent to 24.7 per cent.

    Taking a consumption level of Rs.16.36 at 1960-61 price, Rajaraman finds that about

    18.4 per cent of total population of Punjab lived below that consumption level. The

    poverty line for the year 1970-71 has been estimated at a consumption level of

    Rs.33086 at current prices, and the author has shown that the percentage of the poor has

    increased from 18.4 to 23.3 in ten years. It is seen in this study that poverty is most

    intense among the agricultural workers, as about 22.6 per cent of households lived

    below the poverty line in 1960-61 and in the year 1970-71, this percentage went up to

    about 40.5. In this respect, Rajaramans study is consistent with those of Bhatty (1974)

    and Bardhan (1970).55 Like Bhatty, Rajaraman also finds that incidence of poverty

    among the cultivators is comparatively low. While the increased incidence of poverty

    among the agricultural labour households is significant statistically, this is not the case

    with the cultivating households.

    In a different type of study based on the socio-economic survey data derived

    from the sample households distributed all over Bangalore City, Hanumappa (1978)

    has shown that 24.35 per cent of all households can be considered as poor in the

    context of their monthly income.56 But the study is mainly concerned with the effect of

    family size and education on the pattern of income distribution and so we will not

    pursue it further.

    We now take up for consideration an important study based on Kerala which

    will explain the difference between the conclusions of D-R and Panikar.57 In the study

    of D-R, Kerala is seen to have the largest percentage of population below the poverty

    line, 90.75 per cent in rural areas and 88.89 per cent in urban areas. The study on

    poverty by Centre of Development Studies (1975) has prepared a balance sheet

    compiled for Kerala and then compares it with the NSS data used by D-R. It is

    revealed that part of the explanation for the high proportion of the poor, as given by D-

    28

  • 8/2/2019 Copy of Poverty and Inequality in India_ M.phil Thesis

    29/76

    A Study on Poverty and Inequality in India

    R, is that the NSS has underestimated certain items of food such as banana, coconut

    and fish entering into the diets of these people and as a result the extent of main

    nutrition in Kerala has been somewhat exaggerated. Whereas the per capita per day

    calories intake is 1619 calories for all food items according to the food balance sheet of

    this study (1975). Thus, the study reveals that 48 per cent of the population in Kerala

    lived below the poverty line in 1960-61.

    But the important point which the study reveals is that per Capita Consumption

    of food does not depend on per capita income alone, so that while a low consumption

    of food may indicate under-nourishment, it need not necessarily mean poverty.

    Moreover it is shown that per capita consumption of food in a region depends on per

    capita production of food and the pattern of the distribution of land holdings; further,

    the degree of inequality is negatively correlated with increases in food consumption.

    One conclusion of this study is that the availability of food cannot be treated as a

    function of income and price alone, but it may depend also on physical factors such

    as output in the region and institutional factors such as distribution of land holdings.

    Further, the above study suggests that we require more through scrutiny of

    regional variations in diet patterns before we draw the poverty line by counting calories

    with the help of size distribution of consumption expenditure derived from NSS data.

    A lack of uniformity in the structure of poverty in India has been highlighted by

    Vaidyanathan (1974), D-R (1971), Bhatty (1974) and Bardhan (1973). Vaidyanathan

    finds that six States- Andhra Pradesh, Kerala, Madhya Pradesh, Tamil Nadu, Orissa

    and Uttar Pradesh had a higher percentage of people below the poverty line than the

    national average in the year 1960-61. Again, the level of poverty is very much lower in

    Assam and Punjab. But in D-R study the intensity of rural poverty is greater than the

    All India average in eight States and these are: Kerala, Andhra Pradesh, Maharashtra,

    Tamil Nadu, Assam, West Bengal, Orissa, and Bihar. Again, barring Rajasthan, U.P.,

    Bihar, Jammu and Kashmir and Assam, the other eleven States show a greater

    percentage of the poor living in urban areas compared to the All India average in 1960-

    61.

    While in Bhattys study a greater concentration of poverty is seen in four States

    (Gujrat, Tamil Nadu, Rajasthan and Madhya Pradesh), Bardhans study reveals that

    29

  • 8/2/2019 Copy of Poverty and Inequality in India_ M.phil Thesis

    30/76

    A Study on Poverty and Inequality in India

    higher levels of poverty have been registered in West Bengal, Bihar, Kerala and Orissa.

    Such inter-state variations in the percentage of people below the poverty line

    underscores the importance of the study of poverty on a regional basis. One cal also

    infer a high degree of correlation between the incidence of poverty and the pattern of

    the production of cereals, as, state wise, poverty seems to be higher in the non-wheat

    zones stretching from eastern India to the Malabar Coast. While this is just a reflection

    based on the available data, such a hypothesis (i.e., incidence of poverty being highly

    correlated with the pattern of cereal production) requires further detailed investigation

    for its acceptance.

    All the above-mentioned studies suffer from two general weakness, if any, in

    NSS data will render the studies inaccurate. NSS data are based on stratified random

    sampling and so the sample households must represent all the rural and urban

    households in the country. But, as definitions have changed to some extent in different

    NSS rounds, doubts can be expressed regarding the comparability of NSS data in

    different years. Moreover, samples from the same universe give comparable results,

    but when sampling is done at two different points of time, the Universe is bound to

    change. This is likely to be reinforced by planned economic development. Whether

    data from different samples drawn at two separate points of time are comparable or not

    is a matter of considerable doubt.

    Secondly, though rural consumption in NSS data includes non-monetised

    consumption, the latter may be of two types commodities produced at home and

    commodities simply derived from nature. While the first category can be valued by

    using ex-farm prices, the second category cannot be valued at all. It is our contention

    that the second category of commodities represents some sort of free good derived

    from nature which is unique in a rural agricultural country with a largely disorganized

    and demonetized economy. To an NSS investigator such commodities are either not

    mentioned at all or, even when mentioned, are likely to be neglected because of their

    largely no-economic character. This is more so because of the existing studies that the

    per capita per day barest minimum consumption should be 2250 calories and a sizeable

    section of Indian population cannot afford it. But the number of such poor people is

    increasing, though percentage-wise the size of the poor may be falling. Should we say

    that a man may survive without the barest minimum consumption day after day?

    30

  • 8/2/2019 Copy of Poverty and Inequality in India_ M.phil Thesis

    31/76

    A Study on Poverty and Inequality in India

    Accordingly, either the barest minimum has to be further lowered, or we should

    concede the fact that people derived their necessary calories from the consumption of

    commodities, only a fraction of which can be brought within the economic categories.

    While the first weakness is common to any method of induction in statistics i.e.,

    any representative sample may lose its representative character with change in the

    universe, second weakness points to the more fundamental fact that the economic

    categories used for the measurement of rural consumption should be more broad-based

    so that the way of living of the rural poor can be analyzed in greater detail.

    31

  • 8/2/2019 Copy of Poverty and Inequality in India_ M.phil Thesis

    32/76

    A Study on Poverty and Inequality in India

    Chapter-3

    Studies on Inequality

    Wide disparity in the living standards of the Indian population in both rural and

    urban areas has attracted the attention of a number of economists who have tries to

    measure the change in the degree of inequality in the income distribution and that in

    consumption expenditure. Moreover, attempts have been male to compare the degree

    of inequality existing in India with the same in other countries. A survey of the

    existing literature in this respect should be preceded by a discussion of the following

    points, as clarification of these points will facilitate the evaluation of the existing

    literature.

    First, it is difficult to compare the per capita income of a developing country

    like India with that of a developed country because of the limited scope of national

    income accounts in the former.58 Moreover, objection has been raised in the use of

    exchange rates to convert all figures to a common standard and it is recognized that

    exchange rates may be poor guide to purchasing power. As the study of David (1972)

    suggests the true gap regarding the real per capita income between the United the

    United States and other countries is only four-ninths of that indicated by exchange rate

    conversion.59

    Secondly, while it is difficult to generalize about inter-country differences

    because of heterogeneities of different sorts historical, physical and regional in

    addition to the purely economic, we can still arrive at some conclusion regarding the

    effect of growth on size distribution of income by shifting to inter-temporal

    comparisons. This is as follows: Though inequality is generally low in the pre-

    industrialization stage, it tends to rise with the growth of towns and cities which emerge

    and flourish with capitalistic enterprise and growing commerce. Concentration of

    capital occurs with the growth of firms and urbanization increases regional disparity.

    But beyond this early phase it is difficult to generalize about the pattern of the change

    in the inequality-index as economic development proceeds. Kuznets maintains that the

    degree of inequality is lower in the developed economy compared to the less developed

    countries.60 Kuznets has been supported by others and these authors, after a careful

    32

  • 8/2/2019 Copy of Poverty and Inequality in India_ M.phil Thesis

    33/76

    A Study on Poverty and Inequality in India

    scrutiny of the size-distribution of income of some countries, maintain that the

    distribution of income tends to be more equal, the longer and the more thoroughly the

    country has been exposed to the processes of social and economic transformation after

    the advent of industrialization.61

    We may now turn our attention to the studies on inequality in India. The RBI

    Study (1962) gas two parts: in the first, the method of estimation and the average state

    of income distribution during the period 1953-54 to 1956-57 have been described; and

    in the second, changes in the income distribution from Period I (1953-54 to 1954-55) to

    Period II (1955-56 to 1956-57) has been analysed. This study was undertaken under

    the guidance of Ojha and Bhatt (1964). Taking the household as the income-receiving

    unit, it attempts to present the pattern of income distribution in the households sector

    only, which comprises household, not-corporate business (including agriculture), and

    private collectives like temples, educational institutions and charitable foundations.

    The household sector is divided into three income groups: (i) low income group with

    annual income below or equal to Rs.3000, (ii) households with an annual income

    between Rs.3001 and Rs.25,000 and (iii) top income group with annual income above

    Rs.25,000.

    The essence of the method of estimation used in the study is the integration of

    the income tax data with the consumer expenditure data from the National Sample

    Survey (NSS). The integration is indirect as the study does not use either the actual

    expenditure given in the NSS data or the actual income for those with annual

    expenditure equal to or below Rs.3000. Again, the proportion of population and the

    size of the households in various expenditure brackets given in the NSS data on

    consumer expenditure are used for the following: First, to estimate independently from

    the population data (i) the distribution of rural and urban households between low

    income groups and high income groups, and (ii) the total number of households in the

    rural and urban areas separately. Secondly, to estimate independently from the national

    income data the distribution of personal consumption expenditure between the rural and

    urban sectors and between low income and high income groups within each sector.

    The savings made and taxes paid are then added to derive personal disposable income

    and personal income respectively of the various income groups.

    33

  • 8/2/2019 Copy of Poverty and Inequality in India_ M.phil Thesis

    34/76

    A Study on Poverty and Inequality in India

    Moreover, personal incomes accruing to households in the top income group

    are obtained directly from the income tax data on the assumption that each salary

    earner assessed to tax represents one household. Income tax data are also used in the

    estimation of personal income accruing to households in the high income non-salary

    earners group both in urban and rural areas in so far they are obtained as residual

    magnitudes. The distribution of incomes and households in this group is also done

    from income tax data. The independently estimated households and incomes are then

    put together to derive the pattern of income distribution.

    The study reveals that for the period 1953-54 to 1956-57 the top decile accounts

    for 28 per cent of personal income, while the bottom decile obtains only 3 per cent.

    The Lorenz ratio for disposable income is only slightly lower (0.335) than that for

    personal income (0.340). Income distribution is more uneven in the urban sector than

    in the rural sector; the urban sector concentration ratio for personal income is 0.40,

    while this ratio for the rural sector is only 0.31.

    Ojha and Bhatt (1964) then conclude as follows:

    Contrary to general impression, the degree of inequality in income distribution

    in India does not seem to be higher than in some of the advanced economies.

    This conclusion of the authors goes against the thesis of Kuznets and the empirical

    findings of Morgan (1953) and others. This view has been challenged by Ranadive

    (1965), Swamy (1965) and Mueller and Sarma (1965). Though the debate is primarily

    concerned with the above conclusion of Ojha and Bhatt is primarily concerned with the

    above conclusion of Ojha and Bhatt rather than with the index of inequality as revealed

    in their study, this has cast some doubt on the basis on which the study of Ojha and

    Bhatt depends.

    According to Ranadive (1965), the RBI study is marred by a lack of

    appreciation of the need for an appropriate concept of personal income, an incorrect

    use of NSS data for deriving size distribution of household income and by what seems

    to be a methodological error which has resulted in over-estimation of households in the

    high income groups. A close scrutiny of the RBI study shows that the number of

    households in the high income group is over-estimated, which is revealed by the fact

    that the number of households in non-salary earners group is about six times higher

    than the number of the corresponding group in the tax data. Again, according to

    34

  • 8/2/2019 Copy of Poverty and Inequality in India_ M.phil Thesis

    35/76

    A Study on Poverty and Inequality in India

    Ranadive, the concept of income in the study excludes some elements and so the

    personal disposable income in high income groups is likely to be underestimating.

    Thus the under-estimation of income and/or over-estimation of households in the

    higher income groups might account for the sharp difference of this study with the

    thesis of Kuznets (1963) supported by some empirical studies.

    Mueller and Sarma (1965) have pointed out that the assumption in the study of

    Ojha and Bhatt leads to a downward bias in income inequality and they have ignored an

    important body of data, which is a survey conducted by NCAER in 1960 with a

    stratified probability sample of 4400 families in 30 cities and towns all over India. 62

    Mueller and Sarma have shown that NCAER income distribution is much more

    unequal than the OJha and Bhatt distribution. Moreover, the saving estimates in RBI

    study do not correspond with the NCAER estimate. Criticising the thesis of Ojha and

    Bhatt, Swamy (1965) also contends that the pattern of income distribution in India

    supports the thesis of Kuznets.

    Lydall (1960) assumes that Pareto Law of distribution63 holds in India. He

    then makes use of income-tax statistics of individuals and Hindu undivided families,

    and converts the NSS 10th round data from household to a per-person basis, the income

    of each household being divided by the number of persons in that household. He

    further assumes that average number of persons covered by each tax assessment is

    about three. The result of his study is as follows. The top ten per cent of Indians

    account for 34 per cent of pre-tax income and 33 per cent of post-tax income in 1955-

    56. The corresponding figures for United Kingdom in 1954 are 30 per cent and 25 per

    cent respectively. But Lydall is cautious regarding any comparison of income

    distribution because coverage of income-tax is much smaller in India compared to U.K.

    and the estimate of direct income distribution in India is absent.

    Since Lydalls study is based on income tax data, we do not get any reliable

    picture of the pattern of income distribution as a whole in the fifties.

    Mukherjee and Chatterjee (1967) have utilised NSS data and the national

    income estimates to indicate broadly the behavior pattern of income distribution. The

    premises of the study are as follows:

    35

  • 8/2/2019 Copy of Poverty and Inequality in India_ M.phil Thesis

    36/76

  • 8/2/2019 Copy of Poverty and Inequality in India_ M.phil Thesis

    37/76

    A Study on Poverty and Inequality in India

    The implication of Swamys study is that the process of industrialization causes

    shifts in relative weights of different sectors; and without radical changes in the

    institutions, inequality in the income distribution must inevitably rise over time.

    Neglect of this aspect, according to Swamy, is the principal cause why some income

    distribution studies show a decline in the disparity in the income distribution. Further,

    Swamy has estimated that inequality remained more or less stable in rural areas, but

    increased in urban areas, which is reinforced by the fact that the proportion of

    population increased in urban areas over the period. This increased the disparity

    between rural and urban areas.

    Modifications tot the Ojha and Bhatt method have been suggested by Ranadive

    (1973) to allow for not dissaving by poorer income groups and for possible tax evasion

    in the top income groups. Ranadive adopts two extreme alternatives: (i) where

    households with annual income less than Rs.2000 in the urban sector and with income

    less than Rs.720 in the rural sector are assumed to have zero net savings and all evaded

    tax payments are assumed to have zero net savings and all evaded tax payments are

    assumed to be fully reflected in consumption and/or savings, and (ii) where households

    with annual income less than Rs.3000 in the urban sector and with income less than

    Rs.1200 in the rural sector are assumed to have negative savings, which constitute 25

    per cent of the total urban savings in the case of the former and 14 per cent of the total

    saving in the case of the former and 14 per cent of the total savings in the case of the

    latter. As for evaded tax payments, they are not reflected in consumption and/or

    savings, so that the estimated amount of tax evasion is added to the disposable income

    of the tax-paying classes. Now case (ii) should show higher inequality than case (i) due

    to the assumptions relating to savings and tax evasion.

    Ranadives estimate shows that in the year 1961-62, the bottom 20 per cent of

    population accounted for 7.6 to 7.8 per cent of total income, and top 20 per cent

    accounted for 45.5 to 46.7 per cent. The Lorenz ratio was between 0.351 and 0.367.

    The assumption of Ranadive that in the savings group total saving is distributed in

    proportion to consumption expenditure has been questioned by Bardhan (1974).

    Ahmed and Bhattacharya (1972) have tried to integrate the size distribution of

    consumer expenditure obtained from NSS data with the size distribution of income

    before tax, obtained from income tax data, to estimate the size distribution of per capita

    37

  • 8/2/2019 Copy of Poverty and Inequality in India_ M.phil Thesis

    38/76

    A Study on Poverty and Inequality in India

    personal income in India in three different periods, 1956-57, 1960-61 and 1963-64.

    They have followed the technique developed by Lydall (1961) and their study is a more

    systematic and rigorous extension of the earlier attempt of Ahmed (1971). This

    approach is based on two assumptions: (i) income (before tax) equals consumer

    expenditure in the lower ranges of per capita consumer expenditure, and (ii) the

    distribution of per capita personal income before tax is symptotically Paritian for high

    values of per capita income and has the same slope as the distribution of assesses by

    size of incomes before tax.

    The results of the study of Ahmed and Bhattacharya are as follows: For the first

    fit, where Pareto Curve is fitted to the size distribution of income before tax taking all

    income classes above Rs.20,000, the Lorenz Ratio is 0.418 for 1956-57, 0.379 for

    1960-61 and 0.372 for 1963-64. Again, for the second fit, that is where Pareto Curve is

    fitted taking the last interval of income before tax as Rs.100,000 and above, the Lorenz

    ratio is 0.408 for 1956-57, 0.382 for 1960-61 and 0.361 for 1963-64. However, this

    result has been qualified by the authors with two points: First, considering the fact that

    price increases have been more sharp for the lower income groups than for the higher

    income groups, this decreases in the inequality in nominal income distribution may be

    more illusory than real. Secondly, this decline, the authors suspect, may be traced to

    the inherent weaknesses of the two sets of data.

    Bardhan (1974) points out that the first assumption of Ahmed and Bhattacharya

    rules out dis-savings in the lower income brackets and so it leads to some

    understatement of inequality. Moreover, considering the fact that the number of

    income tax assesses is not even 1 per cent of Indian population and rural rich are

    mostly beyond the net of income tax authority, the technique of fitting Pareto

    distribution in the Indian contest may very well distort the picture.

    On the basis of NSS data Vaidyanathan (1974) analyses inter-State variations in

    the levels of inequality. Vaidyanathan shows that data from the 18th and the 22nd

    rounds suggest a negative association between the Lorenz Ratios of consumption and

    per capita consumption expenditure, though the coefficients are not statistically

    significant. The study further reveals that, in rural India, greater inequality in the

    distribution of land is associated with more uneven distribution of consumption.

    Moreover, the pattern of land operation has influenced the degree of consumption

    38

  • 8/2/2019 Copy of Poverty and Inequality in India_ M.phil Thesis

    39/76

    A Study on Poverty and Inequality in India

    inequality. This result is quite consistent with a priori judgment; as land is the most

    important source of income in rural areas and as production structure is largely

    disorganized the holding of land gives important leverage to the owners who reap the

    advantages of a hierarchical society.

    Vaidyanathan calculates the changes in Lorenz ratios during the decade 1957-

    58 to 1967-68; for rural India the inequality index (LR) has decreased from 0.334 in

    1957 to 0.203 in 1967-68. But the variations over the States are not uniform; while for

    Andhra Pradesh, Assam and Madhya Pradesh the decline is sharp (more than all-India

    average), other States like Punjab and West Bengal do not show any significant

    decline.67

    The regional variation of inequality in rural India has been analyzed by Bhatty

    (1974) also. He has divided the rural population (workers) into three categories-

    cultivators, agricultural labourers and non-agricultural workers. Then he presents the

    Gini Coefficient of inequality in income distribution for India for 1968-69. Inequality

    is found to be highest in Gujrat followed by Uttar Pradesh, Mysore and Tamil Nadu;

    and it is lowest in Orissa followed by Assam, Bihar, Kerala and Rajasthan.

    Income distribution is most unequal among the cultivators, as Bhatty has

    shown, the LR is 0.493. Again, the degree of inequality is lowest among the

    agricultural labourers with LR 0.27; the position of the non-agricultural workers lies in

    between the two with LR 0.377. But in Punjab-Haryana, the Gini coefficie