Cooperating in the Commons

download Cooperating in the Commons

of 17

Transcript of Cooperating in the Commons

  • 8/3/2019 Cooperating in the Commons

    1/17

    1

    Michel CAMES

    MA in Development Studies

    Rural Development

    University of Leeds

    Essay - Semester 2

    1995/96

    Cooperating in the commons: an urgency for the poor

    In this essay, I shall aim to discuss the truism that resources held in

    common are prone to overexploitation. It has been claimed that the only

    escape from the dilemma of common pool resources - referred to as the

    tragedy of the commons by the seminal article of Hardin (1968) - could be

    found either in privatization of the resources or in converting them into state

    property. However this conventional wisdom has been challenged since.

    Hardins model fails to take into account the self-regulating capabilities ofusers assuming that users are unable to limit access or institute rules to

    regulate use. It confuses the open access with common property in which

    the individual interest is constrained by existing institutional arrangements.

    So if the adoption of the model relying overly sanguine on the option of

    privatization of common property resources is generally not more efficient

    and clearly less equitable, and the variant option of government control hasbeen unable to replace traditional communal controls with an effective

    alternative system, why, I refer to Milton M. R. Freeman (1989:92), is more

    effort not directed to re-establishing traditionally-based local-level

    management systems which much empirical evidence now suggests to be

    often more effective?

  • 8/3/2019 Cooperating in the Commons

    2/17

    2

    After attempting to answer this question, I will proceed to shed light on the

    causes for a gradual decline of common-property systems by using

    contemporary evidence from drought-prone areas of India. Next I will

    highlight why it is important to sustain such systems especially in regard ofthe rural poor. Pointing towards possible solutions to reinstate appropriate

    management systems allowing more ecological and social sustainable

    development will conclude this essay emphasizing that sustainable resource

    management is not intrinsically associated with any particular property-

    rights regime and a combination of conventional and traditional or neo-

    traditional regimes may in many cases be more advantageous.

    The Debate around the Maintenance of the Commons

    Since time immemorial, the structure and functioning of resource-regulating

    institutions has been based on customs, taboos and kinship. These informal

    regulations have been based on the principle of equity to its members

    generally at the expense of exclusion of others. Common property resources

    (CPRs) have been open for its users through an essentially closed mode of

    access to these resources.

    According to Runge, these arrangements closely resemble those that

    dominated the early stages of European economic development. With the

    forced enclosure movements of the 15th and 16th centuries, the common

    property typical of Western Europe declined. However, as he continues,

    recent research on the common field systems replaced by 18th-century

    enclosures continues to break down the conventional wisdom that enclosure

    was a prerequisite to the adoption of advanced agricultural methods. It

    would conclude that the major economic consequence of the enclosure was

    to redistribute the existing agricultural income and not to create additional

    income by increasing efficiency (Runge, 1986:623,632). Ciriacy-Wantrup

    and Bishop assert that overgrazing was not a cause for the historical

    reduction of the commons in Great Britain. One important factor was the

  • 8/3/2019 Cooperating in the Commons

    3/17

    3

    increased profitability for the feudal lord of grazing sheep for commercial

    wool production. They argue that, as forest lands on the European continent

    became increasingly profitable as sources of timber for sale vis--vis their

    traditional role as sources of subsistence, the feudal lords changed fromadministrators to profit-seeking entrepreneurs. As they concisely point out,

    this has been the true tragedy of the commons: the peasant was

    transformed from a co-equal owner on the commons with secure tenure to a

    landless worker on the feudal estate (Ciriacy-Wantrup and Bishop,

    1975:719-20).

    It has been a tragic truism to equate the dismantling of the commons withprogress and efficiency. It is Boulding who claims that:

    It is one of the great ironies of the French revolution that the egalite,

    which really meant equal distribution of estates among children and

    the abolition of primogeniture along with other hallmarks of

    aristocracy, is a sure recipe for equality of misery (...) (Boulding,

    1977:285).

    The solution to the tragedy of the commons would, according to Boulding,

    not lie in the adoption of equity principles as propagated by the French

    revolution, but in the acknowledgement of Malthus remedy of the great

    miserific vision:

    The answer is the segregation of misery through a class structure. (...)

    If we privatize the commons, we will create an upper class who owns

    and administers it. It will be administered well. There will be no

    overgrazing. (...) If the class structure can be preserved, if the fences

    hold through a combination of the threat system, the police and the

    military, and the opiates of religion, nationalism, and ideology, the

    system is pretty stable. Up to now one can almost say that this has

  • 8/3/2019 Cooperating in the Commons

    4/17

    4

    been the only successful answer to the tragedy of the commons

    (Boulding, 1977:285-86).

    This line of thought has also been justified by Hardin (1968) and Baden(1977). Hardin, who popularized the concept of the tragedy of the

    commons claims that if the commons can be justifiable at all, then only

    under conditions of low-population density (Hardin, 1968:1248) assuming

    that otherwise it is impossible to upkeep or institute CPR management

    systems. Baden, who argues that discussions involving the management of

    common pool resources often resemble religious arguments conducted by

    nontheologians, sees government action as a requirement in themanagement of common pool resources in the absence of collective

    management (Baden, 1977:138-39, emphasis added). However he

    obviously does not take this restriction seriously into account as no reference

    to action with collective management is given which could be an obstacle to

    the free-rider phenomenon. This ideology of resigning CPRs to private or

    state control as a panacea for the tragedy of the commons reflects,

    according to Grima and Berkes, the assumption of market-oriented societies

    of Western industrial nations that all valuable resources are individually

    owned, fully mobile and exchangeable in small increments in well-

    functioning markets (Grima and Berkes, 1989:37, quoting Bromley, 1985).

    Grima and Berkes argue that in many Western societies, the individual self-

    interest is seen as supreme. This could however not be extrapolated to many

    other societies where the individual is not the dominant locus of choice and

    the community is the relevant decision-making unit (Grima and Berkes,

    1989:37).

    Berkes assumes that where societies are fluid, with large numbers of

    individuals only in casual contact, all having access to the commons, the

    tragedy is relatively likely.

  • 8/3/2019 Cooperating in the Commons

    5/17

  • 8/3/2019 Cooperating in the Commons

    6/17

    6

    together with Western culture tending to emphasize competition as opposed

    to cooperation, would have nurtured Western ecologists to be overly

    indulgent with the concepts of competition, predation and parasitism, as

    opposed to positive ecological interactions such as cooperation,commensalism and mutualism (Berkes, 1989a:72,85).

    But besides this cultural bias against common-property regimes, other

    obstacles remain.

    According to Gibbs and Bromley, common-property regimes imply an

    acceptance of participatory approaches to resource management and more

    decentralized administration. This however would involve a major shift in therole of resource-management agencies and bureaucracies unaccustomed to

    sharing power (Gibbs and Bromley, 1989:31).

    Also the inherence of empirically derived indirect measures of stock

    circumstances adopted by many tradition-based local common-property

    systems to ascertain catch limits in fishing and hunting as being inferior and

    non-scientific compared to science-based rational management techniques

    constitutes an impediment to the introduction of more effective management

    institutions. As Freeman points out, an intuitive management approach

    based on feedback of information and learning does not require knowing

    various stock parameters nor undertaking complex modelling exercises, but

    determines new harvest levels by modification of an earlier empirically

    derived value.

    However, as he proceeds, until public awareness of the efficacy of traditional

    systems of management becomes widespread, public policy will continue to

    favour a conservative approach towards resource management, ensuring

    continuation of orthodox science-based approaches (Freeman, 1989:104-

    06).

  • 8/3/2019 Cooperating in the Commons

    7/17

    7

    The lack of commitment to establish or reinstate traditional or neo-

    traditional local-level management systems however can be sought only to

    some extent in the zeal of resource managers to privatize or nationalize

    CPRs having in mind the tragedy of the commons. Other causes, among thestrong resistance of authoritarian regimes and urban elites to relinquish

    political power to local institutions (Ruttan, 1984:399) and the urge of

    modernization by any possible means making societies throw overboard

    management practices in use since centuries contributes to the

    transformation of sustainably managed resource systems into open-access

    spheres attractive to free-riders.

    The answer to inefficient management of resources however does not lie in

    removing common-property systems - this only will throw out the baby with

    the bathwater - but in attempting to seek for solutions which can overcome

    constraints of these systems if they do not have to be re-created anew

    altogether.

    Causes of the decline of CPRs: indian evidence

    Common-property resources are often in decline for the regime managing

    them is dwindling or disappearing altogether. Jodha argues that increased

    marketability and value of products lead to enhanced profitability which

    becomes the guiding force behind the choice of enterprises and usage

    patterns of CPRs rather than the concern for their upkeep. He further points

    out that technological innovation often makes it physically easier to

    overexploit natural resources (Jodha, 1985:259-60).

    According to Goodland et al, increased participation in market economies

    which encourages the overexploitation for export of natural resources

    previously harvested for local subsistence is one major cause of common-

    property system breakdown (Goodland et al, 1989:151).

  • 8/3/2019 Cooperating in the Commons

    8/17

    8

    Structural adjustment policies are just one case in point. The demand for

    foreign exchange creates competition for resources among governments,

    concessionaires, and rural communities as well as a pressure to redefine

    property rights (Gibbs and Bromley, 1989:30).

    Referring to dry regions of India, Jodha argues that the main form of decline

    is the privatization of CPRs:

    Under various welfare programmes [mainly land reforms in the early

    1950s] CPR lands had been distributed to people for private use. CPR

    lands had also been illegally appropriated often with subsequentlegalization. The stated intention of privatization of CPRs was to give

    land to the poor who were landless or who had very little land. (...)

    The consequent decline in the area of CPRs, and the resultant

    overcrowding and degradation of CPRs have led to a considerable

    reduction in the overall quantity of CPR benefits for the poor (Jodha,

    1986:1178).

    Ensuing breakdown of traditional value systems also contribute to the

    dismantling of the commons. According to Gadgil and Iyer, small multi-caste

    village communities in which the different caste groups were linked to each

    other in a web of reciprocity favoured sustainable use of CPRs under

    communal management. However, as they argue, they are increasingly

    coming into conflict because of the destruction of traditional occupations and

    the erosion of their resource base (Gadgil and Iyer, 1989:240,252).

    Also the tradition of providing free inputs by common-property users and a

    common revenue fund for the maintenance of CPRs has been gradually

    eroded. According to Jodha, peoples contribution and common property

    resource revenue generated through auctioning of trees, etc. have

    disappeared and government grants or relief has proven to be a poor

    substitute for these traditional sources of upkeep (Jodha, 1985:251).

  • 8/3/2019 Cooperating in the Commons

    9/17

    9

    Another cause is population growth. Sustainable use of CPRs requires the

    number of parties sharing access to the resource to be not too large.

    However, as Jodha argues, increasing population density creates relativeresource scarcity which in turn is thought to induce privatization of resources

    for reasons of efficiency and internalization of gains from resource use

    (Jodha, 1985:256).

    Increased differentiation of the rural community can as well cause the

    management quality of CPRs to decline (Jodha, 1995:3282). Given the

    complimentarity between PPRs and CPRs in the rural economy and assumingthe concentration of PPRs in a few households of a village, as is often the

    case, the non-poor can reap more benefits from CPRs than the poor and

    consequently only the PPR owners may participate in preserving the CPRs

    primarily to reinforce their existing structure of income generation (Chopra

    et al, 1989:A-192).

    Investigations in a number of Karnatakan villages reveal that, according to

    Pasha,

    though CPRs play a crucial role in the household economy of the rural

    poor, it is the non-poor who get more benefits from CPRs in absolute

    terms. (...) though in relative terms the poor obtained a greater

    proportion of their income from them (Pasha, 1992:2502).

    Given a high ratio of income differentiation between non-poor and poor, the

    non-poors share is generally considerably higher than the poors despite the

    higher share in the relative income of the latter.

    However, rising disparities in PPR ownership of CPR users are not only a

    cause for a decline in the ability to manage CPRs sustainably, they are also

    an effect of the decline.

  • 8/3/2019 Cooperating in the Commons

    10/17

    10

    Consequences of the decline of CPRs

    or: Why maintaining CPRs is a necessity for the rural poor

    Although only limited empirical evidence exists in the Indian case, mostauthors agree that privatization has helped well-endowed land owners more

    than the poor (Jodha, 1985:260). The comparison of landholding size before

    and after the privatization indicates, as Jodha argues, that those who had

    relatively more land also got more land.

    The complete process of privatization of CPRs as it affected the rural

    poor involved three stages: (i) they were deprived of their right tocollectively use the CPRs, (ii) they were given individual title to small

    parts of privatized CPRs, and (iii) the circumstances disentitled them of

    the newly received lands. (...)

    Mere distribution of land, particularly of sub-marginal land, without the

    provision of necessary complementary resources was not sufficient to

    develop and cultivate the land (...). Rather than sticking to a small

    piece of land that could not be developed and used for want of other

    resources, these households preferred to sell or mortgage the land

    (...) (Jodha, 1986:1179).

    On further investigation the response of the poor is quite rational. As animal

    husbandry plays a very important role in the economy of small and marginal

    farmers (Pasha, 1991:A-27), small pieces of marginal land are not efficient

    in their agricultural and livelihood system because, as Gadgil and Iyer argue,

    when the resource involved is not being produced but foraged, it entails the

    use of relatively large tracts of land (Gadgil and Iyer, 1989:241).

    Jodha points out that livestock, because they are mobile, are less subject to

    the adverse impact of localized droughts than crops are. This advantage is

  • 8/3/2019 Cooperating in the Commons

    11/17

    11

    lost however, if a farmers livestock must depend solely on his own forage

    and water resources (Jodha, 1985:248).

    It is this hedge against environmental uncertainty inherent in CPRmanagement, still amplified by the right to be included in a group that

    provides a hedge against individual failure (Runge, 1986:632) that is

    reduced or lost by the decline of the CPRs.

    Through the interaction of privatization, sub-marginal CPR lands which have

    only been used as pasture land so far, have been converted into croplands.

    According to Jodha, in the case of the arid zone of Rajasthan, unlike thesituation in Europe following privatization of CPRs, it has invariably meant

    putting the land under plow. The consequences of this practice which strains

    the limited use-capability of the land are soil erosion and decline in overall

    crop yields (Jodha, 1985:260).

    On the other hand, due to the decline in size and the depletion of CPRs there

    has been a substantial increase in the number of sheep and goats. According

    to Jodha, the small ruminants could not only be sustained by degraded

    CPRs, but they also fit better in the changed migration patterns:

    In the context of the reduced CPRs, the migration of cattle has become

    more difficult than of small ruminants. Thus the sheep and goats often

    accused for destroying vegetation in the CPRs, seem to have become

    more important following the degradation of CPRs rather than vice

    versa (Jodha, 1990:A73-74).

    However, large ruminants such as draft animals have more and more

    difficulties to survive on the degraded CPRs. According to Pasha, the

    population of bullocks has decreased due to the high overhead cost of

    maintaining them on purchased fodder as the CPR lands have declined, or,

    where they survive on degraded CPR lands, these animals are subject to

  • 8/3/2019 Cooperating in the Commons

    12/17

    12

    many diseases, miscarriages, prolonged unproductive period, low growth

    and low productivity (Pasha, 1991:A-28).

    Jodha argues that the maintenance of such animals without the CPR facilitymeans diversion of a substantial proportion of marginal farm households

    crop lands from food and cash crops to fodder crops. The alternative option,

    i.e. reducing animal numbers to levels sustainable by own fodder/feed

    resources, implies the loss of own farm inputs, e.g. draft power and farm-

    yard manure (Jodha, 1990:A-66).

    It can be concluded that in dryland areas, as privatization raises the cost oflivestock raising and erodes the regions comparative advantage (Jodha,

    1985:262), it is the poor being most dependent on animal husbandry who

    lose out the most.

    Reinstating appropriate management systems

    Recognizing that reinstating or developing CPRs is required as a strategy to

    help the rural poor can lead us searching for possible approaches. As Jodha

    argues, one strategy could be to develop CPRs and improve their use

    through technological and institutional interventions.

    However, it may be pointed out that growth in the CPR productivity

    alone may prove counter-productive. At present the process of self-

    selection of CPR users, tend to induce mainly the poor to depend on

    these resources. CPR activities are low pay-off options. The poor

    chooses them as the opportunity cost of their labour is lower than the

    returns from CPR activities. An increase in CPR productivity will induce

    greater demand on CPRs (Jodha, 1986:1179).

    Rehabilitation of CPRs is, according to Jodha, less of an investment-cum-

    technological problem and more of a resource management problem.

  • 8/3/2019 Cooperating in the Commons

    13/17

    13

    In most areas, even natural regeneration itself can make CPRs more

    productive, provided the regeneration is permitted, through controlled

    and regulated use of resources. However, this cannot happen unlessthe CPRs are reconverted from open access resources to common

    property resources. In operational terms this would mean the re-

    establishment and enforcement of usage regulations and user-

    obligations towards CPRs (Jodha, 1990:A-77).

    Re-establishment and subsequent control mechanisms represent a far

    greater challenge for implementation than technological and institutionalinterventions from outsiders. While the latter necessitates merely a one-off

    activity to re-establish ecological equilibrium - mostly a both costly and futile

    intervention - the former implies the establishment of local institutional

    arrangements of CPR user groups which can regulate sustainable use of

    CPRs on a permanent basis. In the context of the current situation, this can

    sound utopian. As Pasha points out, in discussions with the poor households

    in villages in Karnataka, even these households largely prefer the available

    CPRs to be distributed among them as PPRs. Among other reasons for this

    reaction he assumes the lack through unequal distribution of CPR-based

    PPRs in the past and the lack of a proper policy by the government about the

    CPRs (Pasha, 1992:2503).

    This reaction however could suggest that basically the poor prefer a

    common-property regime provided that the principle of equity is respected

    and past injustices regarding the distribution of CPR based PPRs will be

    nullified - what will be unlikely to happen.

    On the other hand, as already noted above, when PPR ownership is

    widespread, preservation of CPRs by increasing their productivity promotes

    the interests of the majority in participatory institutions (Chopra et al,

    1989:A-194). To provide however an increasing population with CPR-based

  • 8/3/2019 Cooperating in the Commons

    14/17

    14

    PPR land is arithmetically nonsense: all the remaining CPR land would have

    to be distributed that each poor household could own a non-viable small size

    of marginal land.

    If however means can be found for establishing participatory institutions, the

    basic pre-condition for sustainable management of common lands would be

    met. A local CPR management regime could, according to Damodaran,

    institute following rules:

    All users have access to CPRs in their capacity as members of the

    community and no individual user enjoys any preferential access to theselands by virtue of any social and economic advantages vis--vis other fellow

    users. In some cases, he proceeds, restrictions are imposed on the number

    of livestock grazed by a grazier which is either prohibited or discouraged by

    a grazing fee by the community. The basic concept implicit in these

    measures is sustainable and equitable exploitation of the common land

    resources without doing away with open access to the lands bearing the

    resources (Damodaran, 1991:2214).

    Supporting collective action through the participation of local people in such

    management regimes however requires more than populist interventions. A

    collaboration of the stereotypical top-down and bottom-up approaches

    (Paul, 1989:104) has to be taken into account. Paul pleads for a synergy

    between governments and grassroots organizations - which have historically

    been antagonists - in the fight against poverty. This potential of

    collaboration would offer opportunities to the poor to participate and express

    their voice effectively particularly to enhance their self confidence and self

    reliance. As he argues, governments and grassroots organizations have

    different strengths which are complementary. In the context of poverty

    alleviation, there is a clear case for a division of labour that exploits their

    comparative advantage (Paul, 1989:100,105-06).

  • 8/3/2019 Cooperating in the Commons

    15/17

    15

    It is this common effort to empower the poor which could be more

    successful in the attempt to sustain CPR regimes and consequently maintain

    the ecological sustainability of CPRs.

    As Berkes argues, even that it may not be possible in many cases to turn

    back the clock, the knowledge base that would enable sustainable resource

    use nevertheless remains with local users. Hence, it makes management

    sense to leave as much control and responsibility as possible at the

    communal level while coordinating activities of users at the government level

    (Berkes, 1989b:238-239).

    As Runge puts it, it is the search for appropriate institutional responses

    which must respect both the traditions and the constraints of local needs in

    specific choice environments. There are no universal prescriptions for

    efficient and equitable resource management (Runge, 1986:633). Berkes

    proposes that combinations of property-rights regimes may in many cases

    work better than any single regime. The success of local-level management,

    for example, often depends on its legitimization by central government,

    involving the sharing of power between governments and local communities

    (Berkes et al, 1989:93).

    Rather than invoking the general superiority of one type of property

    institution, e.g. Hardins deterministic model (Berkes et al, 1989:93), a

    continuum of property rights, from pure rights of exclusion to pure rights of

    inclusion, depending on the nature of resource management problems paired

    with the need for more empirical research (Runge, 1986:633) may show us

    the way to explain resource use in complex socio-ecologic systems with

    more well-balanced models.

  • 8/3/2019 Cooperating in the Commons

    16/17

    16

    Bibliography

    Baden, John (1977), A Primer for the Management of Common PoolResources in Hardin, G. and Baden, J. (eds.), Managing the Commons, NewYork, Freeman

    Berkes, Fikret (1989a), Cooperation from the Perspective of Human Ecologyin Berkes, Fikret, Common Property Resources - Ecology and Community-Based Sustainable Development, London, Belhaven Press

    Berkes, Fikret (1989b), Multiple-Resource Cases and IntegratedDevelopment in Berkes, Fikret, Common Property Resources - Ecology andCommunity-Based Sustainable Development, London, Belhaven Press

    Berkes, F., Feeny D., McCay B. J. and Acheson J. M. (1989), The benefits of

    the commons in Nature, 340, pp. 91-93, 13 July

    Boulding, Kenneth E. (1977), Commons and Community: The Idea of aPublic in Hardin, G. and Baden, J. (eds.), Managing the Commons, NewYork, Freeman

    Bromley, D. W. (1985), Common property issues in internationaldevelopment in Developments, 5 (1), pp. 12-15

    Chopra, Kanchan, Kadekodi, Gopal K. and Murty M. N. (1989), Peoples

    Participation and Common Property Resources in Economical and PoliticalWeekly, pp. A-189-A-195,December 23-30

    Ciriacy-Wantrup S. V. and Bishop, Richard C. (1975), Common Property asa Concept in Natural Resources Policy in Natural Resources Journal, 15, pp.713-727, October

    Damodaran, A. (1991), Tragedy of the Commons and Comedy of CommonProperty Resources in Economical and Political Weekly, pp. 2213- 2215,September 21

    Freeman, Milton M. R. (1989), Graphs and Gaffs: A Cautionary Tale in theCommon-Property Resources Debate in Berkes, Fikret, Common PropertyResources - Ecology and Community-Based Sustainable Development,London, Belhaven Press

    Gadgil, Madhav and Iyer, Prema (1989), On the Diversification of Common-Property Resource Use by Indian Society in Berkes, Fikret, CommonProperty Resources - Ecology and Community-Based SustainableDevelopment, London, Belhaven Press

    Gibbs, Christopher J. N. and Bromley, Daniel W. (1989), InstitutionalArrangements for Management of Rural Resources: Common-Property

  • 8/3/2019 Cooperating in the Commons

    17/17

    17

    Regimes in Berkes, Fikret, Common Property Resources - Ecology andCommunity-Based Sustainable Development, London, Belhaven Press

    Goodland, Robert, Ledec, George and Webb Maryla (1989), MeetingEnvironmental Concerns Caused by Common-Property Mismanagement in

    Economic Development Projects in Berkes, Fikret, Common PropertyResources - Ecology and Community-Based Sustainable Development,London, Belhaven Press

    Grima A. P. Lino and Berkes, Fikret (1989), Natural Resources: Access,Rights-to-Use and Management in Berkes, Fikret, Common PropertyResources - Ecology and Community-Based Sustainable Development,London, Belhaven Press

    Hardin, Garrett (1968), The tragedy of the Commons in Science, 162, pp.

    1243-1248, 13 December

    Jodha, N. S. (1985), Population Growth and the Decline of CommonProperty Resources in Rajasthan, India in Population and DevelopmentReview, 11 (2), pp. 247-264, June

    Jodha, N. S. (1986), Common Property Resources and Rural Poor in DryRegions of India in Economical and Political Weekly, pp. 1169-1181, July 5

    Jodha, N. S. (1990), Rural Common Property Resources - Contributions and

    Crisis in Economical and Political Weekly, pp. A-65-A78, June 30Jodha, N. S. (1995), Common Property Resources and the EnvironmentalContext - Role of Biophysical versus Social Stresses in Economical andPolitical Weekly, pp. 3278-3283, December 23

    Pasha, Syed Ajmal (1991), Sustainability and Viability of Small and MarginalFarmers - Animal Husbandry and Common Property Resources inEconomical and Political Weekly, pp. A-27-A30, March 30

    Pasha, Syed Ajmal (1992), CPRs and Rural Poor - A Micro Level Analysis inEconomical and Political Weekly, pp. 2499-2503, November 14

    Paul, Samuel (1989), Poverty Alleviation and Participation - The Case forGovernment-Grassroots Agency Collaboration in Economical and PoliticalWeekly, pp. 100-06, January 14

    Runge, Carlisle Ford (1986), Common Property and Collective Action inEconomic Development in World Development, 14 (5), pp. 623-635

    Ruttan, Vernon W. (1984), Integrated Rural Development Programmes: AHistorical Perspective in World Development, 12 (4), pp. 393-401

    Wade, Robert (1988), Village Republics, Cambridge, University Press