Cook - Two Approaches to Social Structure Exchange Theory and Network Analysis.pdf

download Cook - Two Approaches to Social Structure Exchange Theory and Network Analysis.pdf

of 20

Transcript of Cook - Two Approaches to Social Structure Exchange Theory and Network Analysis.pdf

  • 8/10/2019 Cook - Two Approaches to Social Structure Exchange Theory and Network Analysis.pdf

    1/20

    Two Approaches to Social Structure: Exchange Theory and Network Analysis

    Author(s): K. S. Cook and J. M. WhitmeyerSource: Annual Review of Sociology, Vol. 18 (1992), pp. 109-127Published by: Annual ReviewsStable URL: http://www.jstor.org/stable/2083448.

    Accessed: 19/10/2014 21:14

    Your use of the JSTOR archive indicates your acceptance of the Terms & Conditions of Use, available at.http://www.jstor.org/page/info/about/policies/terms.jsp

    .JSTOR is a not-for-profit service that helps scholars, researchers, and students discover, use, and build upon a wide range of

    content in a trusted digital archive. We use information technology and tools to increase productivity and facilitate new formsof scholarship. For more information about JSTOR, please contact [email protected].

    .

    Annual Reviewsis collaborating with JSTOR to digitize, preserve and extend access toAnnual Review of

    Sociology.

    http://www.jstor.org

    This content downloaded from 132.208.246.237 on Sun, 19 Oct 2014 21:14:13 PMAll use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions

    http://www.jstor.org/action/showPublisher?publisherCode=annrevshttp://www.jstor.org/stable/2083448?origin=JSTOR-pdfhttp://www.jstor.org/page/info/about/policies/terms.jsphttp://www.jstor.org/page/info/about/policies/terms.jsphttp://www.jstor.org/page/info/about/policies/terms.jsphttp://www.jstor.org/page/info/about/policies/terms.jsphttp://www.jstor.org/page/info/about/policies/terms.jsphttp://www.jstor.org/stable/2083448?origin=JSTOR-pdfhttp://www.jstor.org/action/showPublisher?publisherCode=annrevs
  • 8/10/2019 Cook - Two Approaches to Social Structure Exchange Theory and Network Analysis.pdf

    2/20

    Annu.

    Rev. Sociol.

    1992.

    18:109-27

    Copyright

    ?

    by Annual

    Reviews

    Inc. All rights

    reserved

    TWO

    APPROACHES

    TO

    SOCIAL

    STRUCTURE:

    Exchange

    Theory

    and

    Network

    Analysis

    K.

    S.

    Cook

    and

    J.

    M.

    Whitmeyer

    Department

    of Sociology,

    University

    of

    Washington, Seattle, Washington

    98195

    KEY WORDS:

    social

    exchange,

    exchange

    networks,

    power,

    social networks

    Abstract

    Much convergence

    exists

    between

    exchange

    theory

    and

    network

    approaches

    to social structure.

    Starting

    with the

    work of Emerson,

    exchange

    theory

    increasingly

    has considered

    social

    structure

    explicitly,

    as both product

    and

    constraint.

    Exchange

    theory

    and network

    analysis

    both conceptualize

    social

    structureas a configurationof social relationsand positions, i. e. as a set of

    actors diversely

    linked into

    networks.

    Exchange

    theory

    and

    most

    work

    in

    network

    analysis

    are based

    on

    similar conceptions

    of the

    actor.

    Where ex-

    change theory

    and network

    analysis

    differ

    is in their

    view of

    the

    links between

    positions.

    Exchange

    theory

    stresses

    the exchange

    aspects

    of

    all ties

    and

    contends that

    the appropriate

    etwork

    in

    any

    analysis

    is one that

    contains

    all

    relevant

    exchange

    relations.

    Network

    analysis

    tends

    to

    be more catholic

    about

    the nature

    of the

    links.

    INTRODUCTION

    Social structure

    s

    one

    of the

    central

    concepts

    in sociological

    analysis.

    It

    is

    also at the core

    of

    many of the

    most

    influential theories

    within

    the

    field of

    sociology.

    Durkheim,

    Parsons,

    Levi-Strauss,

    Marx,

    Weber,

    Merton,

    Coser,

    109

    0360-0572/92/08

    15-0109$02.00

    This content downloaded from 132.208.246.237 on Sun, 19 Oct 2014 21:14:13 PMAll use subject toJSTOR Terms and Conditions

    http://www.jstor.org/page/info/about/policies/terms.jsphttp://www.jstor.org/page/info/about/policies/terms.jsphttp://www.jstor.org/page/info/about/policies/terms.jsphttp://www.jstor.org/page/info/about/policies/terms.jsp
  • 8/10/2019 Cook - Two Approaches to Social Structure Exchange Theory and Network Analysis.pdf

    3/20

    110 COOK&

    WHITMEYER

    Blau, Coleman,

    and many others have developed conceptions of social

    structure n their attempts o provide explanatory

    rameworks hat encompass

    both humanbehavior and institutionalpersistence and change. Our task here

    is to begin to

    specify how two different literatures

    within sociology can be

    brought ogether n

    the analysis of social structure nd

    structural orms. These

    two

    traditionsare

    exchange theory and network approaches o structure.To

    accomplish this task

    we provide a brief statement of historical

    context,

    placing this chapter

    n the relevantstreamof work thathas been conductedon

    the

    topic of social structure. This

    statement

    is

    followed by reviews of the

    commonalities and

    differences in the approaches o structure aken by ex-

    change theoristsand network analysts. We conclude with comments about

    future developments linking these two traditions.

    A

    fairly comprehensive treatment of the different

    approaches to social

    structurecan be found in the volume edited by Peter

    Blau (1975). Various

    conceptions of social structureare presentedby authors

    hat include Bierstedt,

    Blau, Bottomore, Coleman, Coser, Goode, Homans,

    Lenski, Lipset, Merton,

    Parsons, and

    Wallace. Blau identifies three major

    approaches o social struc-

    ture:

    (i)

    social structure s a

    configuration f

    social

    relationsandpositions, (ii)

    social

    structure

    as

    the substratum hat underlies all of social life and history,

    and

    (iii) social structureas

    a

    multidimensional

    pace

    of

    the differentiated

    social positions of

    the people in a society or other

    collectivity (Blau

    1975:14).

    The

    approach

    o social structure

    adoptedby

    exchange

    theorists

    (including

    Blau

    1964) and a

    majorityof the network analysts is the first alternative,the

    configurationalapproach.

    We

    focus

    primarilyupon

    this

    general approach

    o

    social

    structure.We

    omit from our discussion

    the structuralism haracteristic

    of

    Levi-Strauss

    (though

    this is

    mentioned, by

    Ekeh

    1974,

    as a distinct

    tradition

    within

    exchange theory)

    and

    subsequent

    developments along

    this

    line.

    What

    Blau refers

    to

    as

    the multidimensional pproach

    s

    characteristic f

    his

    more recent work

    (e.g.

    Blau

    1977).

    In the next section we first review the

    treatmentof social structure

    by exchange

    theoristsand then move

    to

    network

    approaches.

    SOCIAL

    STRUCTURE:

    AN EXCHANGE PERSPECTIVE

    Exchange

    theorists advancea basic

    image

    of social structureas a

    configura-

    tion

    of

    social relations

    among

    actors

    (both

    individual and

    corporate),

    where

    the

    relations involve the

    exchange

    of valued items

    (which

    can be

    material,

    informational,

    symbolic, etc). Exchange theory increasingly

    has

    involved

    explicit

    consideration of social

    structure,

    as

    both

    product

    and

    constraint,

    typically

    in the form

    of

    networks

    of social

    relations.

    We will comment on the

    similarities and differences

    in

    the

    perspectives

    on social structure

    of three of

    the

    principal

    exchange

    theorists in historical

    progression.

    This content downloaded from 132.208.246.237 on Sun, 19 Oct 2014 21:14:13 PMAll use subject toJSTOR Terms and Conditions

    http://www.jstor.org/page/info/about/policies/terms.jsphttp://www.jstor.org/page/info/about/policies/terms.jsphttp://www.jstor.org/page/info/about/policies/terms.jsphttp://www.jstor.org/page/info/about/policies/terms.jsp
  • 8/10/2019 Cook - Two Approaches to Social Structure Exchange Theory and Network Analysis.pdf

    4/20

    EXCHANGE HEORY

    AND NETWORK NALYSIS 111

    Homans' View

    of Social Structure

    Homans' (1961, 1964) primarypurpose

    was the study of

    the

    subinstitution-

    al or elementary orms of behavior.Homans developed a theory of social

    behavior based primarilyupon behavioral

    principles

    of analysis. He

    took as

    the domain of his explanatory

    framework (1961:3),

    the actual social be-

    havior of individuals

    in direct contact

    with one another. He refers

    to this

    behavior as

    elementary

    and clearly distinguishes

    t from behaviorthat

    can

    be

    defined

    as

    obedience to the

    norms of a

    society (including

    role-related be-

    havior). Role-conforming

    behaviorwas institutionalized

    ehavior, thus actual

    behavior was defined by Homans as

    subinstitutional.

    For Homans, social structuresemerge from elementaryforms of behavior

    and

    change

    over

    time

    in

    response

    to changes

    in

    this

    behavior

    by aggregates.

    (He does not address

    n

    any detail the complex interplay

    between microlevel

    processes and aggregate evel outcomes.)

    He argued hat

    the similar behavior

    of

    enough people

    can alterexisting social structures

    nd institutions

    and

    even,

    under some

    conditions, replace

    them.

    Sometimes the

    great

    rebellions and

    revolutions, cracking the institutional

    crust, bring out elementary

    social be-

    havior hot and straight

    rom the fissures Homans 1961:398).

    His

    analysis

    of

    social behavior enduresas a classic in sociology precisely becausehis vision

    of

    the underpinnings

    f social structureand

    institutional orms

    is

    straightfor-

    ward and is linked

    so clearly to the actions of individuals

    (i.e.

    to their

    responses to rewarding

    and punishing

    circumstances).

    Though the

    focus of Homans' theoretical framework

    was the relations

    between actors

    in

    direct contact with

    one

    another,

    he

    did

    acknowledge

    the

    structural

    mportance

    of indirectexchange

    relations.

    An

    example

    is the social

    relationbetween employees of the

    same employer,

    who are related indirectly

    in second-orderexchange relations through theircommon link to the same

    employer.

    In this sense the

    basic format for

    exchange

    network

    analysis

    existed in the earliest formulations.

    Blau's Early View of Social

    Structure

    While Homans' work

    is

    distinctly microsociological

    in

    character,

    Blau's

    (1964) major treatise on exchange

    and power

    is an

    explicit

    statement

    of the

    micro-macro inkage problem,

    before micro-macro

    ssues became

    a fashion-

    able

    topic

    in

    sociology

    in the

    1980s (e.g.

    Alexander

    et al

    1987,

    Collins 1981,

    Cook

    1991,

    Huber

    1991, etc).

    Blau's focus

    was the

    development

    of

    a

    theory

    of

    social structure

    and institutions based

    upon

    a

    sound

    microfoundation,

    a

    theory

    of social

    exchange.

    Two

    major

    featuresdifferentiateBlau's

    work from

    that of

    Homans.

    First,

    Blau did not base his

    theory

    of

    exchange upon

    behavioral

    principles;

    instead he introducedaspects

    of micro-economic

    rea-

    soning

    into his

    analysis

    of

    distinctly

    social

    exchange

    (see

    Heath

    1976).

    Second, recognizing

    that social structureshave

    emergent

    properties,

    he ex-

    tended the

    theory beyond

    subinstitutional

    phenomena.

    This content downloaded from 132.208.246.237 on Sun, 19 Oct 2014 21:14:13 PMAll use subject toJSTOR Terms and Conditions

    http://www.jstor.org/page/info/about/policies/terms.jsphttp://www.jstor.org/page/info/about/policies/terms.jsphttp://www.jstor.org/page/info/about/policies/terms.jsphttp://www.jstor.org/page/info/about/policies/terms.jsp
  • 8/10/2019 Cook - Two Approaches to Social Structure Exchange Theory and Network Analysis.pdf

    5/20

    112 COOK

    & WHITMEYER

    Blau discusses processes like group

    formation, cohesion, social

    integra-

    tion,

    opposition, conflict, and dissolution in terms of principles of

    social

    exchange. In his view various forms of social association generated by

    exchange

    processes over time come to

    constitutequite complex social struc-

    tures

    (and

    substructures).The coordinationof action in large

    collectivities is

    made possible

    by common values in the social system which

    mediate the

    necessary

    indirect exchanges. Thus Blau's

    theory moves far beyond

    direct

    contact between

    individual actors,

    incorporating omplex indirect exchange

    processes.

    Structural change in both

    small and large social structures is

    analyzed

    in

    terms of social forces like

    differentiation, ntegration,organiza-

    tion, and opposition. Blauand, subsequently,Emerson(1972a,b) both made

    power processes centralto their analysis of

    the emergenceof social

    structures

    and

    structural

    change.

    Emerson's

    Exchange Network

    Theory and Related

    Developments

    Of

    the three

    major heorists,

    Homanswas the most

    psychological

    in focus and

    thus in

    many

    respects

    the most

    microsociological. Blau focused attentionon

    the more macro

    level, emphasizingmicroprocesses

    primarily

    as

    a foundation

    for

    building a

    more complex theory of

    emergentprocesses

    in social structures

    and

    institutional

    hange.

    Emerson

    developed a behavioralmodel of individual

    action

    but emphasizedthe shift to a

    more macro level

    of

    analysis through

    he

    incorporation

    of

    collective actors and networks into his formulation.

    As

    Turner

    1986:304) puts it, Emerson's approach removesmuch of the

    vague-

    ness

    surrounding

    Homans' and Blau's

    conceptualizations

    f

    social

    structures

    as 'institutional

    piles'

    and

    'organized

    collectives'. Social structure

    n

    network

    analysis

    has a

    more

    precise

    definition

    as

    patterns

    of connections

    among

    actors

    in networks of

    exchange relations.

    In his

    seminal

    work

    on

    exchange

    theory

    Emerson

    (1972ab) produced

    a

    well-developed

    formulationbased

    upon behavioralprinciples(similar

    to

    those

    found in

    Homans' work). He embeddedhis

    generalpower/dependenceprinci-

    ple (1962, 1964)

    in the

    context

    of an

    exchange

    theoretical

    rameworkwhich

    took

    as

    its

    psychological base,

    behavioral

    principles

    of

    reinforcement,

    satia-

    tion,

    extinction,

    etc.

    Part

    II

    (1972b)

    of

    this

    work

    takes

    social structureas the

    central

    subject

    matterand includes

    rudimentary

    heoreticalstatements

    regard-

    ing mechanisms of structural hange (see Cook 1987:216-7 for a description

    of the model of

    social

    structure

    developed

    in

    Part

    II).

    Emerson

    (1972a:41)

    noted two

    major shortcomings

    with Homans'

    be-

    havioral

    formulation.

    First,

    it

    had

    no

    real

    conception

    of

    society except

    as an

    aggregation

    of

    individual

    behavior.

    In

    this

    sense

    its

    conception

    of

    social

    structurewas

    too

    rudimentary.Second,

    it

    treated

    as

    given

    he

    social context

    surrounding

    behaving persons,

    that

    is,

    the social

    structuresand structural

    changes

    that

    sociologists

    seek to

    comprehend.

    This content downloaded from 132.208.246.237 on Sun, 19 Oct 2014 21:14:13 PMAll use subject toJSTOR Terms and Conditions

    http://www.jstor.org/page/info/about/policies/terms.jsphttp://www.jstor.org/page/info/about/policies/terms.jsphttp://www.jstor.org/page/info/about/policies/terms.jsphttp://www.jstor.org/page/info/about/policies/terms.jsp
  • 8/10/2019 Cook - Two Approaches to Social Structure Exchange Theory and Network Analysis.pdf

    6/20

    EXCHANGE

    HEORY

    AND

    NETWORK

    NALYSIS

    113

    An

    actor in

    Emerson's

    theory

    is

    conceived as

    a

    point

    where

    many ex-

    change

    relations

    connect

    (1972b:57).

    The

    actor

    can be a

    person, a

    corporate

    group

    (or

    collective

    actor),

    or a

    role-occupant.

    This

    conception

    of

    actor

    makes

    the

    theory

    applicableat

    different

    evels

    of

    analysis,

    and the

    theory has

    been

    applied

    to

    relations

    between

    individuals,

    organizations,

    and

    even

    nation-

    states.

    The

    primary

    ocus is

    upon

    exchange

    relationsas

    the

    building

    blocks

    for

    more

    complex

    social

    structures

    alled

    exchange

    networks

    or

    corporate

    groups

    (involving

    intragroup

    exchanges).

    As

    Emerson

    (1972b:60)

    notes,

    the con-

    cept of an

    exchange

    relation, and

    the

    principles

    which

    surround

    t,

    provide a

    basis

    for

    studying the

    formation

    and

    change

    of

    social

    structuresas

    enduring

    relations

    among

    specified

    actors,

    with the

    exchange

    relationsas

    the

    structural

    unit.

    Exchange

    networks

    are

    viewed

    as

    connected

    sets of

    exchange

    relations.

    An

    early,

    important

    advance

    was the

    distinction

    between

    positive and

    negative

    exchange

    connections. If

    an

    actor's

    exchange

    in

    one

    relation

    is

    positively

    related to

    the

    actor's

    exchange in

    another

    relation, the

    relations

    are

    positively

    connected;

    f

    the

    relationship

    s

    negative,

    they

    are

    negatively connected'

    (for

    further

    discussion

    see

    Emerson

    1972b).

    A

    primaryfocus of the

    subsequent

    theoreticaland

    empiricalwork

    (e.g.

    Cook

    1987)

    has

    been

    on

    specification

    of

    the principlesof exchangeandpower thatapplyto differentkindsof network

    structures

    (which

    Emerson

    referred

    to as

    structural

    prototypes, such as

    monopoly

    structures,stratified

    networks,

    circles, and

    chains). In

    particular,

    attention has

    been

    focused

    on

    the

    relationship between

    types of

    exchange

    connections and

    the

    distributionof

    power

    and

    dependence

    among

    actors

    in

    various

    network

    structures

    e.g. Cook

    &

    Emerson

    1978, Cook et al

    1983,

    etc).

    Structural

    hange

    is

    viewed in

    the

    theory

    as a

    consequence

    of

    various

    social

    processes

    (e.g. coalition

    formation)

    n

    exchange networks and

    within

    corporategroups nitiated, n part, becauseof apowerimbalanceeitherwithin

    the

    exchange

    relation

    (relational

    power

    imbalance) or

    within the

    exchange

    network

    structure

    structuralpower

    imbalance) (see

    Gillmore

    1987,

    Cook

    &

    Gillmore

    1984,

    Cook

    &

    Emerson

    1978, Emerson

    1981,

    Molm

    1989,

    Cook

    1990,

    etc).

    In

    conclusion,

    exchange

    network

    theory,

    initiated

    with

    Emerson's

    work

    (e.g.

    1972a,b and

    subsequent

    work)

    and

    continuing

    in

    that of

    others

    (e.g.

    Cook

    1977,

    Cook

    & Emerson

    1978,

    Willer

    &

    Anderson

    1981,

    Markovsky

    et

    al 1988, etc), has attempted o fuse perspectivespreviously considered in-

    compatible

    (see

    Blau

    1975,

    Merton

    1975),

    incorporating

    both

    psychological

    factors and

    social

    constraints

    n

    terms

    of

    alternatives

    and

    opportunity

    struc-

    'The

    actual

    definitions

    (Emerson

    1972b:70)

    are: a

    negative

    connection

    is one in

    which

    an

    increase in

    the

    frequency

    or

    'magnitude '

    of one

    exchange in

    which an

    actor is

    involved

    produces

    or

    implies

    a

    decrease

    in a

    second

    such

    exchange.

    A

    positive

    connection

    is one in

    which an

    increase in one

    exchange in

    which

    an actor

    is

    involved

    producesor

    stimulates an

    increase in

    a

    second

    such

    exchange.

    This content downloaded from 132.208.246.237 on Sun, 19 Oct 2014 21:14:13 PMAll use subject toJSTOR Terms and Conditions

    http://www.jstor.org/page/info/about/policies/terms.jsphttp://www.jstor.org/page/info/about/policies/terms.jsphttp://www.jstor.org/page/info/about/policies/terms.jsphttp://www.jstor.org/page/info/about/policies/terms.jsp
  • 8/10/2019 Cook - Two Approaches to Social Structure Exchange Theory and Network Analysis.pdf

    7/20

    114 COOK& WHITMEYER

    tures. This is, in our view, the majoraccomplishment

    of recent developments

    in exchange theory (referred to as either

    structuralversions of exchange

    theory or exchange network heory). It is thismore recentversion of exchange

    theory which is most

    compatiblewith the fundamental iew of social structure

    embedded in much

    of the work in network

    analysis. We now turn to an

    explicit consideration

    of the relationshipbetween

    exchange theory and net-

    work analysis, beginning

    with an overview of what network analysis

    is.

    LINKING EXCHANGE

    AND NETWORKAPPROACHES

    What is Network

    Analysis?

    In

    discussing the potential

    for linking these two

    traditionsof work in sociolo-

    gy we must begin with

    one key difference. Exchangetheory s really the

    name

    of a class of theories all of which have much

    in common (e.g. the theories of

    Homans, Blau, Emerson, Thibaut& Kelley,

    Coleman etc). Exchange

    theory

    can be seen as

    an

    approach o interactionand structure

    based on two princi-

    ples: (i) The actor

    can be modeled as motivated

    by interests or rewards/

    punishments-i.e. all behaviorcan be seen

    as so motivated; ii)

    most interac-

    tion consists of the exchange of valued (though not necessarily material)

    items. Network analysis,

    on the other hand, has been less theoretically

    and

    more empirically

    driven (see

    Wellman 1983). Network analysis

    is

    rooted

    in

    the

    empirical

    observation

    that

    patterns

    of interaction

    of

    many

    actors can

    be

    looked at as networks.

    A

    narrowconception

    of network analysis

    exists, which considers it a type

    of structural

    nalysis.

    Network

    analysts.

    .

    . try

    to describe

    [regular

    net-

    work patterns] and

    use

    their descriptions

    to learn

    how network structures

    constrain social behavior

    and social

    change (Wellman 1983:157).

    This

    version of

    network

    analysis contends,

    in

    agreement

    with the

    structuralist

    position

    in

    Sociology

    (e.g.

    Blau

    1977, Mayhew 1980),

    that all

    important

    social

    phenomena

    can

    be

    explained primarily,

    if

    not completely, by

    social

    structure.The network

    version of this

    position

    is

    professed by,

    for

    example,

    Berkowitz

    (1982),

    Wellman

    (1983),

    Skvoretz

    (1990), and,

    to

    some

    extent,

    Burt

    (1982b).

    For three reasons, we take

    a broaderview of network

    analysis.

    First, many

    network-related tudies

    do not fit with the more

    narrow

    conception

    of the

    structuralist pproach,

    such

    as studies of the creation

    and/or maintenance

    of

    networks

    (e.g.

    Galaskiewicz 1982,

    Mizruchi& Stearns

    1988),

    or with studies

    that

    investigate

    the

    influence of non network

    factors on network

    characteris-

    tics

    (e.g.

    Feld

    1981,

    Fischer

    1982,

    Laumann&

    Marsden

    1982).

    We wantedto

    include these. Second, by excluding

    considerationof the

    individual

    actor,

    the

    narrow

    structuralistapproach

    excludes

    linkage

    of

    network

    analysis

    with

    exchange theory.

    We consider such

    a

    linkage

    to be both natural

    and

    potential-

    This content downloaded from 132.208.246.237 on Sun, 19 Oct 2014 21:14:13 PMAll use subject toJSTOR Terms and Conditions

    http://www.jstor.org/page/info/about/policies/terms.jsphttp://www.jstor.org/page/info/about/policies/terms.jsphttp://www.jstor.org/page/info/about/policies/terms.jsphttp://www.jstor.org/page/info/about/policies/terms.jsp
  • 8/10/2019 Cook - Two Approaches to Social Structure Exchange Theory and Network Analysis.pdf

    8/20

    EXCHANGE HEORYAND NETWORK

    NALYSIS 115

    ly fruitful. Third, some

    network structuralists

    re less strictly structuralist n

    practice than in principle

    (e.g. Burt 1982b).

    Numerous reviews of network analysisexist (e.g. Mitchell 1974, Berko-

    witz 1982 ch. 1,

    Wellman 1983, Marsden 1990),

    so

    the history

    we present

    here is brief. The contemporaryarea of

    network analysis has been

    formed

    through

    a

    cross-fertilizationof work

    from several different disciplines, with

    different

    empirical

    and

    even theoretical aims. We can identify

    at least three

    sources for networkanalysis:empiricalwork

    in social anthropology

    e.g. Bott

    1957, Mitchell 1969,

    Kapferer1972), the practiceof sociometry (e.g.

    More-

    no 1951), and more abstractmathematical

    models and theory such

    as biased

    net theory (Rapoport1957) and graph theory(e.g. Hararyet al 1965). As is

    evident in this review, the diversity of origins continues

    in the present

    diversity

    of

    subjects

    of empirical

    research and structural nterests (e.g. net-

    work

    structure

    as an independentor dependent

    variable).

    The

    development

    of network analytic tools

    and

    techniques

    proceeded

    rapidly, beginning

    in the

    early 1970s,

    among anthropologists

    and sociolo-

    gists. Debate among

    the early network analysts

    focused not only on

    the

    appropriatemeasures

    of

    importantconcepts

    and methods of

    data collection

    (e.g. observation, diaries, surveys), but also on whetheror not there was

    anything

    to be called network

    theory.

    To some

    extent,

    this debate

    con-

    tinues. Positions on the

    issue

    range

    from that of

    Barnes

    (quoted

    in

    Mitchell

    1974:282): there

    s no such thing as a theory of social networks,

    to that of

    Burt (1982b) who formulated

    a

    structural heory

    of action

    to

    provide

    theoreti-

    cal underpinning or

    network conceptions

    of structure.

    According

    to Marsden

    (1990:453),

    much network

    analysis

    can

    be

    viewed

    as

    part of

    a research

    program

    o

    develop

    social structural

    measures. These

    measurescan then be utilized

    by

    various theorists

    n their efforts

    to include in

    their theories and

    empirical

    research measures of

    social

    structural

    concepts

    (e.g. range,

    centrality,

    and

    density

    of actors' social networks-see

    Marsden

    1990 for

    a

    comprehensive

    review). For example,

    network

    analysis

    has been

    combined

    with

    functional analysis

    and role theory. Recently, proposals

    have

    been

    made to

    combine it with

    expectation

    states

    theory (Fararo

    & Skvoretz

    1986)

    and with

    Giddens'

    structuration

    heory (Haines 1988).

    From

    the

    beginning

    some network analysts

    used

    exchange

    theory

    to

    pro-

    vide

    the theoretical

    basis

    for

    the

    analysis

    of the

    social interactions

    they

    represented

    n

    network terms (e.g. Kapferer 1972,

    Whitten

    & Wolfe

    1974,

    etc).

    Various authors

    (e.g.

    Turner

    1986, 1987,

    Collins

    1988,

    etc)

    have

    commentedon the

    potential

    for

    linking

    exchange

    and network

    approaches

    o

    social structure.Collins (1988:412),

    for

    example,

    remarksabout

    the

    growing

    awareness

    of

    the

    connection between

    networks

    and

    market or

    exchange

    theories...

    two

    conceptions

    of how

    individuals

    link

    together

    into

    a

    larger

    social

    structure.

    n an

    influential

    review

    piece,

    Mitchell

    (1974)

    argued

    that

    This content downloaded from 132.208.246.237 on Sun, 19 Oct 2014 21:14:13 PMAll use subject toJSTOR Terms and Conditions

    http://www.jstor.org/page/info/about/policies/terms.jsphttp://www.jstor.org/page/info/about/policies/terms.jsphttp://www.jstor.org/page/info/about/policies/terms.jsphttp://www.jstor.org/page/info/about/policies/terms.jsp
  • 8/10/2019 Cook - Two Approaches to Social Structure Exchange Theory and Network Analysis.pdf

    9/20

    116

    COOK&

    WHITMEYER

    transactional heories

    (including

    exchange

    theory)

    formed a natural

    alliance

    with network concepts.

    Kapferer

    (1972) even

    proposed

    exchange

    theory

    as

    themost suitablebasis for networkanalysis (quoted n Mitchell 1974:282).

    We agree with

    Kapferer.

    However, since

    exchange

    theory

    and network

    analysis are

    different

    types of entities,

    it is

    difficult to talk

    about

    integrating

    them without

    clarifying

    the specific

    ways

    in which they

    are compatible

    or

    incompatible

    as perspectives.

    One obvious

    but relatively

    unimportant

    iffer-

    ence is

    in

    how

    these approaches

    are

    practiced-how

    hypotheses

    are tested,

    how

    the data

    are gathered

    and analyzed,

    etc. More critical

    for the

    issue of

    linkage between

    them

    are compatibilities

    and incompatibilities

    n (a ) their

    views of action, i.e. the modelsof the actorunderlying ach approach,and (b)

    their

    views of structure.We

    discuss each of these

    topics, along

    with some

    prescriptions

    regarding future

    developments

    that

    might integrate

    aspects of

    these

    two traditions

    n

    ways

    quite

    fruitful for sociologists.

    The Individual-Level

    Model

    No

    two theoretical

    approaches

    are compatible,

    nor

    can they be linked

    effec-

    tively,

    if

    they

    have

    fundamentally

    different

    models of the

    individual actor.

    We believe thatmost work in networkanalysisis at least compatiblewith the

    exchange theory premise

    of the

    actor as motivated

    by

    interest

    or reward/

    punishment.

    However,

    that which

    is not compatible

    cannot be linked

    with

    exchange

    theory.

    For

    example,

    Haines

    (1988)

    advocates basing

    network

    analysis

    in Giddens's conception

    of agency -an

    alternative

    ndividual-level

    model incompatible

    with

    that of exchange

    theory.

    Similarly,

    Fararo

    &

    Skvoretz

    (1986)

    suggest

    basing

    network

    analysis

    in

    expectation

    states

    theory.

    This work may be compatible

    with

    exchange

    theory,

    but only

    if

    the

    individual

    level models

    of

    expectation

    states

    theory

    and exchange

    theory

    are

    compatible,

    which seems

    dubious

    (see, e.g.,

    Berger

    et

    al

    1972b).

    Burt

    (1982b)

    claims

    to have

    a different model

    of the actor,

    but

    this is an

    overstatement.Exchange theory

    analysis

    holds

    (i)

    for

    any

    model

    of

    the actor

    wherein the

    actor

    pursues

    interests

    whatever

    they may

    be,

    and

    (ii)

    where

    at

    least some of

    the interests

    are satisfied

    through

    social interaction.

    Exchange

    theory

    makes

    no commitment

    o the

    origin

    of those

    interests, although

    some

    individual exchange

    theorists do

    have their

    preferred

    supplementary,

    more

    microlevel

    models on this

    point.

    These

    may

    conflict

    with

    Burt's

    model

    which

    says

    that

    an actor's interests

    stem

    from the actor's network

    position.

    Howev-

    er,

    Burt's model

    is

    fully

    compatible

    with the

    most

    basic

    principles

    of ex-

    change

    theory. Namely,

    Burt's

    actors

    do have

    interests,

    some

    of

    which

    they

    do

    pursue

    and

    obtain

    through

    social

    interaction.

    Biased-net

    theorists

    (e.g.

    Fararo& Skvoretz 1987,

    Skvoretz

    1990)

    claim

    that

    no individual-level

    model is

    necessary,

    a

    position

    which

    echoes

    the

    views

    of other non

    network structuralists

    uch

    as

    Mayhew

    (1980)

    and

    Blau

    (1977).

    This content downloaded from 132.208.246.237 on Sun, 19 Oct 2014 21:14:13 PMAll use subject toJSTOR Terms and Conditions

    http://www.jstor.org/page/info/about/policies/terms.jsphttp://www.jstor.org/page/info/about/policies/terms.jsphttp://www.jstor.org/page/info/about/policies/terms.jsphttp://www.jstor.org/page/info/about/policies/terms.jsp
  • 8/10/2019 Cook - Two Approaches to Social Structure Exchange Theory and Network Analysis.pdf

    10/20

    EXCHANGE

    HEORY

    AND NETWORK

    NALYSIS

    117

    Biased-net

    theory describes

    and even seeks

    to explain (see Skvoretz

    1990)

    network

    structure as

    global

    or regional deviations

    from

    randomness (or

    biases ),possibly in a numberof differentdimensions.Contrary o the stated

    claim

    that no model of

    the actor

    is necessary, this

    theory implies

    and indeed

    requires

    a certain

    model of the

    actor.

    Namely,

    actors must exhibit

    these

    biases,

    and apart from

    the biases

    there can be no

    other deviation

    of actors'

    behavior

    from randomness arge

    and widespreadenough

    to distortthe

    picture

    of the network.

    This model of

    the actor

    clearly is different

    from

    that of

    exchange theory and

    makes these

    two approaches

    ncompatible.2

    One assumption

    concerning

    the model of

    the actor is critical

    to much

    work

    in networkanalysisand exchange theory.This is theassumption hatthe same

    model of the

    actor can

    be used

    for organizations or

    perhaps

    specific types of

    organizations

    such as

    corporations)and

    for individual

    humans. This

    assump-

    tion is widespread

    among

    network

    analysts whose

    actors are organizations

    (e.g.

    Laumannet al

    1985,

    Mizruchi

    1989, 1990ab),

    and widespread among

    exchange

    theorists (e.g.

    Emerson 1972b,

    Markovsky

    et al 1988)

    and

    indeed

    some other theorists

    in sociology (e.g.

    Berger et

    al 1989).

    Yet

    both a priori

    considerationsand empirical

    evidence call

    the assumption

    into question (see Caputo1989, Stinchcombe 1989). Social organizationsare

    made up

    of entities

    with their own interests

    and

    capable

    of acting autono-

    mously;

    human

    beings

    are not. For example,

    in his analysis

    of

    the

    creationof

    institutions

    by

    corporatedonor

    and

    nonprofitdonee organizations

    o

    reduce

    the transaction osts

    of donations, Galaskiewicz

    (1982)

    must make use

    of the

    differences

    of interests

    within organizations.

    The issue

    of the

    validity

    of the

    organizational

    actor

    is related to the

    extensive debate (cf

    Mizruchi&

    Schwartz 1987)

    between the

    resource

    depen-

    dence and

    the social class positions

    over the purpose

    of

    intercorporate

    ies

    in

    the form

    of

    interlocking

    directorates.

    The resourcedependenceposition

    (Per-

    ucci &

    Pilisuk

    1970,

    Pfeffer

    1972, 1987,

    Pfeffer &

    Salancik

    1978,

    Berkowitz

    et al 1978/1979,

    Burt et al

    1980,

    Burt

    1983,

    Mizruchi

    1989, 1990a,b)

    argues

    that

    intercorporate

    ies are

    created

    for

    the

    purpose

    of

    maximizing

    corporate

    profit

    through

    lessening corporate

    dependence,

    and

    that

    they

    are

    effective at

    this. This

    perspective

    is

    strongly

    related

    to the

    exchange theory perspective,

    with the

    actors

    involved being organizational

    actors (Berger

    et

    al

    1989).

    The

    class

    position (Zeitlin

    1974,

    Domhoff

    1975,

    Soref

    1976,

    Useem

    1978, 1979,

    1984,

    Bonacich

    &

    Domhoff

    1981,

    Gogel & Koenig 1981, Palmer 1983,

    Palmer et

    al

    1986,

    Bearden

    &

    Mintz

    1987,

    Soref &

    Zeitlin

    1987,

    Johnsen &

    Mintz

    1989)

    argues

    that

    intercorporate

    ies

    are created as

    a result

    of human

    individuals

    (or

    families) pursuing

    their

    own class interests.

    This

    position

    is

    2Some biases

    may generate

    structurewhich

    resembles

    that

    generated

    by exchangeprocesses.

    However,

    our

    concern

    here is with differences

    in the

    underlying

    models

    of the actor.

    This content downloaded from 132.208.246.237 on Sun, 19 Oct 2014 21:14:13 PMAll use subject toJSTOR Terms and Conditions

    http://www.jstor.org/page/info/about/policies/terms.jsphttp://www.jstor.org/page/info/about/policies/terms.jsphttp://www.jstor.org/page/info/about/policies/terms.jsphttp://www.jstor.org/page/info/about/policies/terms.jsp
  • 8/10/2019 Cook - Two Approaches to Social Structure Exchange Theory and Network Analysis.pdf

    11/20

    118

    COOK& WHITMEYER

    also

    compatible

    with exchange theory

    if it is accepted

    that

    elite

    individuals'

    personal

    nterests

    are

    congruentwith

    their

    class interests.

    Most

    versions of

    the

    class perspectivefit this formulation.The elite network may be seen as an

    example

    of a social

    circle, a type of social

    structure

    which Emerson

    (1972b)

    explains

    in exchange

    terms. Here, however,

    the actorsare

    human

    ndividuals.

    There is some

    empirical

    evidence

    for

    each position.

    The centrality

    of

    financial

    institutions n

    intercorporate

    etworks,

    for example,

    has

    been

    well

    established

    (Mariolis

    1975, Sonquist

    &

    Koenig 1975,

    Mintz

    & Schwartz

    1981,

    Mizruchi

    1982,

    Stokman et

    al 1984).

    Mizruchi

    (1989,

    1990b)

    has

    shown

    that

    intercorporate

    etwork positions,

    especially

    the existence

    of

    in-

    direct links throughfinancial institutions,predict similarityof political be-

    havior

    (contributions

    o PACs). On

    the other hand,

    Bearden

    & Mintz

    (1987)

    found that

    while banks were

    indeed central

    in the

    intercorporate

    network,

    bankers as

    individuals

    were not prominent

    n linking

    roles. Johnsen

    &

    Mintz

    (1989)

    looked

    at the director

    network,

    the

    dual see Breiger

    1974,

    Berko-

    witz 1982)

    of the intercorporate

    etwork, and

    found

    social ties generally

    to

    be

    causally prior

    to intercorporate

    inks between

    individuals.

    Studies have

    found

    a

    low rate

    of reconstitution

    of directorate

    ies that

    are

    accidentally

    broken

    (Koenig et al 1979, Palmer 1983, Palmeret al 1986).

    As

    a comment

    on both positions

    we may add

    Galaskiewicz's

    (1989)

    points,

    in

    his

    presentation

    of unresolved questions

    concerning

    interorganizational

    networks

    at the metropolitan

    evel,

    that

    (a)

    ties

    created

    for one reason may

    be

    used

    for

    another p. 82);

    and (b)

    creating

    ies for

    some

    purpose

    does not

    mean

    necessarily

    that

    they

    will be effective (p. 86).

    Similarly,

    we

    may

    note

    that it

    is

    possible

    that interlocking

    directorate

    ies are

    created according

    to individual

    human interests, yet

    other organizational

    behavior

    is best

    explained

    by

    the

    dependence

    of

    organizational

    actors.

    This issue is not

    yet

    resolved.

    The View

    of

    Structure

    We can distinguish

    two

    general

    conceptions

    of structure

    n

    network analysis.

    The more common

    view conceives

    of structureas

    a

    pattern

    of

    particular

    ies

    between

    actors,

    where variation

    n

    the network

    n

    the

    existence

    or

    strength

    of

    ties

    is

    meaningful

    and consequential.

    The other

    conceives

    of structure

    as a

    general

    deviation

    from random ies

    for

    particular

    roups,

    or

    perhaps

    he entire

    network.

    In

    other words,

    the

    first view sees structureas a composition of

    particular

    ties,

    the

    second sees

    structure

    as

    a

    general

    perhaps

    multi-

    dimensional

    deviation from randomness.

    The second

    view

    is

    the

    biased

    net

    perspective

    (e.g. Rapoport

    1957,

    Fararo&

    Skvoretz 1987).

    The first

    view is

    taken

    by

    virtually all

    other network analysts

    and

    is

    also

    that of exchange

    theorists

    (Collins

    1988).

    Thus the

    general

    view of structure

    of most

    network

    analysts

    and

    exchange

    theorists s

    the same.

    Wheredifferences

    exist

    is in

    their

    views

    of the details

    of

    This content downloaded from 132.208.246.237 on Sun, 19 Oct 2014 21:14:13 PMAll use subject toJSTOR Terms and Conditions

    http://www.jstor.org/page/info/about/policies/terms.jsphttp://www.jstor.org/page/info/about/policies/terms.jsphttp://www.jstor.org/page/info/about/policies/terms.jsphttp://www.jstor.org/page/info/about/policies/terms.jsp
  • 8/10/2019 Cook - Two Approaches to Social Structure Exchange Theory and Network Analysis.pdf

    12/20

    EXCHANGE

    HEORYAND

    NETWORK NALYSIS

    119

    structure-the

    ties. These

    differences constitute the greatest

    challenge to

    compatibility

    and linkage between the two approaches.

    In brief,

    fitting their

    theoreticalbase, exchange theoristsassume that ties consist of the exchange

    of valued items.

    Fitting their more empirical

    startingpoint,

    network analysts

    are

    frequently

    more catholic

    about the content of ties (Marsden

    1990).

    However, there is much variation

    in the

    treatment of content, between

    networkanalysts

    and even within the work of

    individualscholars.

    Frequently,

    this

    depends

    on the aspect

    of the structure-action elationship

    being

    in-

    vestigated.

    Therefore, we look

    at some of the

    network analysis literature o

    examine the compatibility

    of

    the exchange theory

    stance with

    various treat-

    ments of tie content.

    Virtuallyall studies that undertake

    o show

    the effects of action on structure

    clearly take

    ties to consist

    of exchange. That is, studies that

    look at the

    construction

    or

    maintenance

    of networks

    (e.g.

    Verbrugge

    1979, Wellman

    1979, Burt 1982a, Feld 1981,

    1982, 1984,

    Galaskiewicz 1982, Palmer et

    al

    1986, Suitor

    1987, Mizruchi& Steams 1988,

    Barley 1990, S.

    L. Feld

    & J.

    J.

    Suitor, unpublished

    paper,3

    N. P.

    Hummon, unpublishedpaper4)

    or

    which

    analyze the

    effect

    of

    variation

    in

    personal characteristics

    or

    the interests

    of

    actorson variation n networkcharacteristicse.g. Fischer 1982, Laumann&

    Marsden 1982,

    K.

    E. Campbell

    & B. A. Lee,

    unpublished

    papers5)specify

    the ties

    in

    their

    networks

    explicitly

    or

    implicitly

    as

    exchange

    ties.

    Thus, they

    are

    entirely compatible

    with

    exchange

    theory.

    The

    reasoning

    behind

    Granovetter's

    various

    arguments

    (Granovetter

    1973, 1983) concerning

    the

    creationand

    effects

    of

    strong

    and weak ties

    is in

    accord

    with

    exchange theory

    principles. For example,

    stronger ies mean

    more secure access to resources;

    thus

    those

    with fewer

    personal

    resourcesare more

    likely

    to rely

    on

    strong

    ties

    (Granovetter

    1983).

    A

    few studies undertake

    o show the effect

    of

    structurenot,

    or not only,

    on

    action

    but

    on

    affect (e.g.

    Fischer 1982, Marsden1983).

    These

    studies too take

    an

    exchange

    view

    of

    ties.

    For example,

    Fischer

    (1982)

    finds that network

    density

    is

    positively

    related

    to

    feeling

    better

    for

    low-income respondents,

    but

    negatively

    related for high-income

    respondents.

    For

    an

    explanation

    he

    sug-

    gests

    that low-income

    people

    are better

    off with dense

    cliques because,

    unlike

    high-income

    people, they

    lack the

    material

    and social resources

    to

    manage

    dispersed networks (p. 150).

    3S. L. Feld, J.

    J.

    Suitor,

    Mothers and bestfriends: alternative

    sources

    of social support or

    young

    married women

    in

    seven

    western countries. Paper

    pres. at X

    Sunbelt Social Network

    Conf.,

    1990,

    San Diego, Calif.

    4N. P. Hummon,

    Organizationalstructures

    and networkprocesses:

    an explorationof

    ex-

    changeprocesses. Paper

    pres. at

    X Sunbelt

    Int.

    Social Network

    Conf.,

    1990, San Diego, Calif.

    5K. E. Campbell, B. A. Lee,

    Personal

    networks in urbanneighborhoods:

    description

    and

    variation, 1991. B.

    A. Lee, K.

    E. Campbell,Neighbor

    networksof

    blacks and whites, Paper

    pres. at

    ASA Annu. Meet., 1990,

    Washington,

    DC

    This content downloaded from 132.208.246.237 on Sun, 19 Oct 2014 21:14:13 PMAll use subject toJSTOR Terms and Conditions

    http://www.jstor.org/page/info/about/policies/terms.jsphttp://www.jstor.org/page/info/about/policies/terms.jsphttp://www.jstor.org/page/info/about/policies/terms.jsphttp://www.jstor.org/page/info/about/policies/terms.jsp
  • 8/10/2019 Cook - Two Approaches to Social Structure Exchange Theory and Network Analysis.pdf

    13/20

    120

    COOK

    &

    WHITMEYER

    The

    difficulties arise with some studies that examine

    the effect of structure

    on

    action,

    or in

    some cases, on

    other aspects of structure. The exchange

    theoryposition concerningthis relationship s that therelevantnetwork s one

    that

    consists of all relevant and

    important ies due to

    exchange (i.e. of valued

    items)

    and only those ties. Granovetter 1985) has

    called for acknowledging

    the

    close embeddedness of

    behavior in networks of

    interpersonal elations.

    Since

    interpersonal

    relations

    are virtually always

    exchange relations, the

    exchange theory position is

    completely

    in

    agreementwith

    his

    argument.

    The exchange theory

    position is compatible with

    many network analysis

    studies

    (e.g.

    Marsden

    1983, 1987, Coleman 1988,

    Ridley & Avery 1979).

    However, according to this position, many otherstudies are too permissive.

    They include certain types of

    ties without

    theoretical justification (i.e.

    specification in

    exchange

    terms); they leave out

    important ypes of ties and

    important actors. They also

    fail to pay enough

    attention to the interplay

    between interestsand the items

    being exchanged and to the

    differing

    effects of

    complementary,common,

    and

    opposing

    interests. Thus

    they

    fail to

    perceive

    the structural

    mplications

    of

    these few-actor interactional

    complexities.

    As

    examples,

    we consider

    the

    widely used concept of the directionality

    of ties as

    well as some recent work on centrality.

    The

    directionality of ties

    frequently

    is

    an

    important

    factor

    in

    network

    analyses. For

    example,

    Knoke

    &

    Burt

    (1983)

    define

    prestige

    to be a measure

    of the

    degree

    to which

    an actor

    is

    the

    object

    of

    connections.

    However,

    whenever a relationconsists of

    exchange, any purported

    directionality

    comes

    from

    specifying only one side

    of the

    exchange.

    In

    such a

    case, apparent

    directionality

    is due

    to the

    incomplete specification

    of content and is a

    spurious

    factor. For

    example,

    Knoke

    & Burt

    (1983;

    see

    also Burt

    1987)

    measure the prestige of physicians in terms of being solicited for advice. But

    this is

    an

    exchange:

    the solicitation is

    exchanged

    for advice

    (Blau 1955,

    Homans 1961). The connection could

    just as easily

    be specified

    with

    the

    opposite

    directionality,

    .e.

    being

    the

    object

    of

    advice-giving. Thus, prestige

    stems not

    from

    directionality

    but from the content of the

    exchange

    relations

    and

    the

    asymmetry

    involved.

    Centralitygenerally

    is

    taken to

    mean network

    position-conferred

    advan-

    tage.

    In the

    network

    analytic literature,

    more

    attention

    has been

    given

    to

    its

    specification

    and

    measurement han

    to

    any

    other

    issue

    (e.g.

    Bonacich

    1972,

    1987, Freeman

    1979,

    Knoke & Burt

    1983,

    Marsden

    1982, 1983, 1987,

    Mizruchi et

    al

    1986, Stephenson &

    Zelen

    1989,

    Friedkin

    1991). Recently

    some new

    measures have been devised

    specifically

    for

    centrality

    in com-

    munication networks

    in

    which exchange

    is

    ignored

    (Stephenson &

    Zelen

    1989,

    D. L.

    Kincaid, unpublished

    paper,6Friedkin

    1991). Exchange theory

    6D. L. Kincaid,

    Communicationnetworkdynamics:

    cohesion, centrality,

    and

    cultural

    evolu-

    tion,

    1990

    This content downloaded from 132.208.246.237 on Sun, 19 Oct 2014 21:14:13 PMAll use subject toJSTOR Terms and Conditions

    http://www.jstor.org/page/info/about/policies/terms.jsphttp://www.jstor.org/page/info/about/policies/terms.jsphttp://www.jstor.org/page/info/about/policies/terms.jsphttp://www.jstor.org/page/info/about/policies/terms.jsp
  • 8/10/2019 Cook - Two Approaches to Social Structure Exchange Theory and Network Analysis.pdf

    14/20

    EXCHANGE HEORY

    AND NETWORK NALYSIS 121

    claims that interactions,and by extension the effects of network structureon

    action

    and structure, occur only due to the exchange value of the items

    transferred which may be material, symbolic, informational,etc).7 There-

    fore, when the exchange relations in the

    network are obscured, the causal

    processes involved in centralitywill be likewise hidden. When the exchange

    relations are excluded, the results are

    likely to be spurious if not in error.

    Not all studies involving

    communication networks are at odds with ex-

    change theory. The effect of network

    structure in Bonacich (1990), for

    example, is explained as the effect of

    network position on the expected

    relative gain from communicatingversus not communicating.Network struc-

    ture is shown to affect the likelihood of anactorcommunicating n the kind of

    communicationdilemma situations studied by Bonacich. In Laumann &

    Knoke

    (1989; see also Galaskiewicz

    1979, Knoke 1983) ties

    in the com-

    municationnetworkspersist due to the actors' dependenceon the information

    and

    the similarities in the actors' interests.

    Exchange theory, however, suggests an

    alternative to be tested against

    explanations

    in terms of

    communication

    networks which

    ignore exchange

    processes. First, all exchange links relevant to the behavior which

    is

    the

    dependent variable should be included in the analysis (see Galaskiewicz

    1989). For example, Kincaid (see footnote 6) presents a network of com-

    municationconcerning family planningfor

    a Koreanvillage (from Rogers &

    Kincaid

    1981). Are there exchange links to people

    with interests

    in

    the

    behaviors n question that are not

    represented n the communication

    network?

    If

    so,

    it is

    likely that exchange theory would make

    different calculations

    of

    centrality

    and

    perhaps

    even different

    predictions

    concerning

    its effects.

    Second,

    ties

    should be considered

    n terms of the valued items

    exchanged.

    According to exchange theory, the very existence of a tie or

    link, including

    a

    communicationtie, suggests the existence of interested

    exchange

    between

    two parties. The content of the communicationsmay be influential,

    but even

    so the

    communicationmust be considered

    in the context of an

    exchange

    of

    valued

    items, whether hese are

    the

    communications

    hemselves

    (i.e.

    in terms

    of

    informationalor symbolic value) or other items.

    For

    example,

    for the

    measures

    of

    centrality

    he

    proposes

    for social

    in-

    fluence networks, Friedkin(1991) provides

    a theoreticalbasis

    in

    the

    form of

    coefficients meant to represent one actor's

    influence on another.

    For an

    exchange theorist, however,

    this

    is

    insufficient,

    because the

    interactional

    process goes unspecified. If

    the influence does not occur

    through exchange

    processes

    in the

    given network, exchange theory suggests

    that

    relevant ex-

    change processes

    are

    being ignored

    and

    that the effects

    of

    the

    given

    influence

    'Exchange theory

    does

    acknowledge

    the

    effect of

    previously existing ties,

    that

    is,

    of

    ongoing

    exchange relationships.

    This content downloaded from 132.208.246.237 on Sun, 19 Oct 2014 21:14:13 PMAll use subject toJSTOR Terms and Conditions

    http://www.jstor.org/page/info/about/policies/terms.jsphttp://www.jstor.org/page/info/about/policies/terms.jsphttp://www.jstor.org/page/info/about/policies/terms.jsphttp://www.jstor.org/page/info/about/policies/terms.jsp
  • 8/10/2019 Cook - Two Approaches to Social Structure Exchange Theory and Network Analysis.pdf

    15/20

    122

    COOK& WHITMEYER

    channels are

    possibly spurious. If the

    influence does

    correspond o

    exchange

    processes,

    collapsing these into coefficients

    obscures

    the most interesting

    effects of structure.Thusexchange theorysuggests that analysis in light of the

    exchange processes

    necessarily occurring

    (e.g.

    in

    terms of

    the

    in-

    terdependencies

    among the

    actors) should be more

    revealing of

    both the

    effects

    of structure

    and the

    underlyingpower and

    influence

    processes.

    Exchange

    theorists have

    made (and experimentally

    demonstrated)

    at least

    one

    importantdiscovery which has had

    some influence

    in

    network

    analysis.

    This

    is the

    difference between

    positively and negatively

    connected

    exchange

    networks and their

    implications for

    network-conferred

    dvantage see Emer-

    son 1972b, Cook et al 1983, Yamagishiet al 1988). We refer to this structural

    property

    as

    polarity.

    8

    One

    reason types of

    connections or polarity s

    impor-

    tant is that for

    many networks,

    the

    distributionof power and

    influence may

    depend on the

    polarity of the network

    (Cook

    et

    al

    1983). Thus, Bonacich

    (1987)

    modified

    his

    earlier(1972) measureof

    centralityso that

    it would apply

    not just

    to positively connected

    networks

    but to negatively connected

    net-

    works as

    well

    (see

    also

    Marsden 1987; P.

    Kappelhoff,

    unpublishedpaper9).

    The

    theoretical reasoning behind

    the

    concept of

    polarity

    in

    exchange

    networktheory can contribute o a solutionof the debate between structural

    equivalence

    (roughly, having equivalent

    ties

    to

    the same other actors-from

    Lorrain & White

    1971) and

    cohesion (roughly, being

    closely tied

    to each

    other)

    as

    explanations of the

    similarity

    of

    actors' behavior

    (e.g.

    Friedkin

    1984, Burt

    1987, Erickson

    1988, Mizruchi

    1989,

    1990a,

    Galaskiewicz

    &

    Burt

    1991). Cohesion is bound into

    the veryconcept

    of

    structural

    quivalence

    (Borgatti & Everett

    1992).

    Thus, it is impossible to

    distinguish

    structurally

    between

    two-step

    (indirect)

    cohesion

    and

    structural

    quivalence

    (M.

    S.

    Miz-

    ruchi,

    unpublished

    paper0).

    Burt

    (1987)

    recognizes

    this but

    makes

    it

    clear

    that at

    the heartof

    the debate

    is a

    dispute

    over

    the

    process causing

    behavioral

    similarity. Cohesion

    operates

    as

    an

    infectious process; structural

    quivalence

    operates

    as

    a noninfectious

    process, perhaps through

    imitation.10

    Exchange theory suggests that the two

    processes are

    theoretically

    compat-

    ible

    and possible, even within

    the same

    network,

    and

    that which process

    is

    likely

    to

    be dominant is

    itself affected

    by

    a

    structural

    property, namely,

    polarity.

    In

    a

    positively

    connected

    network,

    it

    is

    probable

    that cohesion

    processes

    will

    be

    stronger.

    The common

    interestsof the

    indirectly

    connected

    8We introduce a

    new term here as a

    shorthand or types of connections and/or

    degrees

    of

    connectivity. The term can apply either to

    entire networks

    (e.g. all relations are

    negatively

    connected) or to

    subnetworks e.g. some relations are

    negative and some are positive

    as

    in

    a

    mixed

    network. See

    Yamagishi

    et

    al

    1988.)

    9P. Kappelhoff, Power in exchange

    systems: a new look at

    the Coleman-modelof collective

    action, 1990

    10M.

    S.

    Mizruchi, Cohesion,

    equivalence,

    and

    similarity of behavior:

    a theoretical

    and

    empirical assessment, 1990.

    This content downloaded from 132.208.246.237 on Sun, 19 Oct 2014 21:14:13 PMAll use subject toJSTOR Terms and Conditions

    http://www.jstor.org/page/info/about/policies/terms.jsphttp://www.jstor.org/page/info/about/policies/terms.jsphttp://www.jstor.org/page/info/about/policies/terms.jsphttp://www.jstor.org/page/info/about/policies/terms.jsp
  • 8/10/2019 Cook - Two Approaches to Social Structure Exchange Theory and Network Analysis.pdf

    16/20

    EXCHANGE HEORY

    AND NETWORK

    NALYSIS 123

    actors make it

    likely that infectious processes will

    lead to similar behaviors

    (see Laumann

    & Knoke 1989). In a negatively connected

    network,

    however,

    these infectious processes are not likely, and it is probable that structural

    equivalence processes will be

    more dominant (see

    Mizruchi 1990a).

    To sum up,

    network analysis differs importantly

    rom exchange theory

    in

    two

    ways.

    First, some network analysts claim to

    use a different

    individual-

    level model, or

    to use none. However,

    with the notable exception of

    biased-

    net theory, the individual-level

    models of exchange

    theorists and network

    analysts are fundamentallycompatible,

    if not identical.

    Second, and

    most

    critically, network analysts and

    exchange theorists

    tend to view

    certain

    aspects of structuredifferently. Their views of what structure s and the

    relation between action and structure

    are highly

    similar. However, they

    frequently

    differ in their view of

    the natureof the ties that make up networks.

    For exchange

    theorists, network ties consist of exchange

    relations

    of valued

    items, and what

    matters causally is the exchange

    value (i.e. due to

    actors'

    interests) of the items exchanged.

    Many network

    theorists are much more

    catholic, and allow a variety of types

    of ties independently

    of any exchange

    of

    valued items. There is no theoretical

    specification in network analysis

    of

    the

    content of the

    tie or social relationship

    representedas a link between

    actors

    or

    a line

    between

    nodes

    in

    a network. Exchange

    theory suggests

    ways

    of

    constructingalternative,

    perhaps

    superior, explanations

    of events within net-

    works and of

    network effects than

    do some of the

    more atheoreticalversions

    of

    network analysis. Whether the

    network analysis

    or the exchange theory

    position is a

    more fruitful approach

    can only be

    resolved through future

    empirical and theoretical work.

    CONCLUSION

    In

    the past fifteen years

    there

    has

    been a kind of convergence among

    some

    of

    the

    approaches

    to social structure

    n

    sociology.

    Two

    generally

    compatible

    approachesare

    exchange theory

    and networkanalysis. As Collins (1988:412)

    points out,

    These models

    picture

    individual

    actors

    as both

    free

    and

    con-

    strained.Humanbeings have

    the

    capacity

    to createor negotiate

    whatever

    hey

    can

    at any moment

    in time. But

    they always

    act in a structured ituation,

    so

    that the consequences and conditions

    of their creativity

    and

    negotiation

    are

    nevertheless patternedby largerrelationshipsbeyond their control. More-

    over, as we have argued

    n

    this

    review, exchange

    theory and networkanalysis

    have similar conceptions of both

    action and structure.

    It

    is

    true that

    some

    network

    analysts

    have downplayedany

    consideration

    of the

    individual

    actor,

    and some exchange

    theorists have undertheorized

    ocial structure.Neverthe-

    less,

    the

    images

    of structureand action Collins

    presents

    have become

    fused

    and

    are both reflected

    in

    recent developments

    n exchange

    network

    heory

    and

    in

    much work

    in

    network analysis.

    This content downloaded from 132.208.246.237 on Sun, 19 Oct 2014 21:14:13 PMAll use subject toJSTOR Terms and Conditions

    http://www.jstor.org/page/info/about/policies/terms.jsphttp://www.jstor.org/page/info/about/policies/terms.jsphttp://www.jstor.org/page/info/about/policies/terms.jsphttp://www.jstor.org/page/info/about/policies/terms.jsp
  • 8/10/2019 Cook - Two Approaches to Social Structure Exchange Theory and Network Analysis.pdf

    17/20

    124

    COOK

    &

    WHITMEYER

    It is a

    measure of the progress achieved that earlier statements

    regarding

    what is central o structural nalysis in

    sociology clearly viewed

    these alterna-

    tives as incompatible (e.g. Blau 1975, Stinchcombe 1975). Nevertheless,

    further

    theoretical refinements will be required to flesh out

    the un-

    derdevelopedfeatures of this emerging

    general model of social

    structureand

    action

    (see

    Hechter 1991).

    In

    conclusion

    it is important o

    reiteratea point often lost in debates about

    the relative

    merits of particular

    heoreticalapproaches:no single perspective

    or

    approach

    network analysis and

    exchange theory included) can explain all

    social and culturalphenomena see, e.g.

    Merton 1975). Even the

    marriageof

    networkand exchange approacheswouldnot be able to lay claim tothe role of

    grand theory in

    sociology.

    Nevertheless, the convergence of

    these

    two

    approaches

    does have the potentialto be broader n scope and more

    powerful

    in

    explanatory

    erms than either approachalone. For this to happen,

    however,

    more work needs to

    be done clarifying points

    of

    useful articulationas

    well as

    areas

    of

    conflict

    or

    mutual exclusivity.

    Our

    review

    chapter

    s an

    attempt

    to

    initiate this

    task.

    ACKNOWLEDGMENTS

    The authors'

    names have been listed

    alphabetically. We acknowledge an

    earlier

    grant

    from the

    National Science Foundation

    SES8519319),

    to K.

    S.

    Cook,

    M. R.

    Gillmore,

    and T.

    Yamagishi,

    for

    support

    of the

    development

    of

    exchange network theory.

    Literature Cited

    Alexander, J. C.,

    Giesen, B.,

    Munch, R.,

    Smelser, N. J. eds. 1987. The Micro-

    Macro

    Link. Berkeley: Univ.

    Calif.

    Press

    Barley, S. R. 1990. The alignment

    of technol-

    ogy and

    structure through

    roles and

    net-

    works. Admin.

    Sci. Q.

    35:61-103

    Bearden, J., Mintz, B. 1987. The

    structure f

    class

    cohesion: the corporate network and

    its

    dual. See

    Mizruchi & Schwartz 1987,

    pp. 187-207

    Berger, J., Eyre,

    D. P., Zelditch, M. 1989.

    Theoretical structuresand the micro/macro

    problem. In Sociological

    Theories in

    Pro-

    gress: New

    Formulations,ed. J. Berger,M.

    Zelditch, B. Anderson, pp. 11-32. New-

    bury Park, Calif:

    Sage

    Berger, J.,

    Zelditch, M.,

    Anderson, B., eds.

    1972a. Sociological Theories in

    Progress,

    Vol. 2.

    Boston:

    Houghton

    Mifflin

    Berger, J., Zelditch, M.,

    Anderson, B.,

    Cohen,

    B. P.

    1972b. Structural

    aspects

    of

    distributive

    ustice:

    a status value formula-

    tion.

    See Berger et al

    1972a,

    pp.

    119-46

    Berkowitz, S.

    D.

    1982. An Introduction to

    Structural

    Analysis.

    Toronto: Butterworths

    Berkowitz, S. D., Carrington,P. J., Koto-

    witz,

    Y., Waverman,

    L.

    1978/1979. The

    determination

    of

    enterprise

    groupings

    through

    combined

    ownershipand director-

    ship

    ties. Soc. Networks

    1:75-83

    Blau,

    P. M. 1964.

    Exchange and Power

    in

    Social Life.

    New York:

    Wiley

    Blau, P. M., ed.

    1975. Approaches

    to the

    Study of Social

    Structure.

    New York:

    Free

    Blau,

    P. M. 1977. Inequality

    and Heterogene-

    ity. New York:

    Free

    Bonacich, P. 1972.

    Technique

    for analyzing

    overlappingmemberships. In Sociological

    Methodology

    1972,

    ed.

    H. L.

    Costner, pp.

    176-85.

    San

    Francisco:Jossey-Bass

    Bonacich,

    P. 1987.

    Power and centrality:

    a

    family of measures.

    Am.

    J. Sociol.

    92:

    1170-82

    Bonacich,

    P. 1990.

    Communicationdilemmas

    in

    social

    networks: an experimental

    study.

    Am.

    Sociol. Rev. 55:448-59

    Bonacich,

    P., Domhoff,

    G.

    W. 1981. Latent

    This content downloaded from 132.208.246.237 on Sun, 19 Oct 2014 21:14:13 PMAll use subject toJSTOR Terms and Conditions

    http://www.jstor.org/page/info/about/policies/terms.jsphttp://www.jstor.org/page/info/about/policies/terms.jsphttp://www.jstor.org/page/info/about/policies/terms.jsphttp://www.jstor.org/page/info/about/policies/terms.jsp
  • 8/10/2019 Cook - Two Approaches to Social Structure Exchange Theory and Network Analysis.pdf

    18/20

    EXCHANGE THEORY

    AND NETWORKANALYSIS 125

    classes and

    group membership.

    Soc. Net-

    works 3:175-96

    Borgatti,S. P., Everett, M. G. 1992.

    Notions

    of position in social network analysis. In

    Sociological Methodology 1992,

    ed.

    P.

    V.

    Marsden.

    Washington, DC: Am.

    Sociol.

    Assoc. In press

    Bott, E. 1957. Family and Social Network:

    Roles, Norms, and External

    Relationships

    in Ordinary Urban Families.

    London:

    Tavistock

    Breiger, R. L. 1974. The duality of persons

    and

    groups. Soc. Forces 53:181-90

    Burt, R.

    S.

    1982a.

    A

    note on cooptation and

    definitions of constraint. See

    Marsden &

    Lin 1982, pp. 219-33

    Burt, R. S. 1982b. Toward a Structural

    Theory of Action. New York:

    Academic

    Burt, R. S. 1983. Corporate Profits and

    Cooptation: Networks of Market Con-

    straints and

    Directorate Ties in the Amer-

    ican

    Economy. New York: Academic

    Burt,

    R. S.

    1987. Social contagion

    and inno-

    vation: cohesion versus structural

    equiva-

    lence. Am. J. Sociol. 92:1287-335

    Burt,

    R.

    S., Christman,K. P.,

    Kilburn,

    H. C.

    Jr. 1980. Testing a structural

    theory

    of

    corporatecooptation: nterorganizational i-

    rectorate ies as a strategyfor avoiding mar-

    ket constraintson profits. Am.

    Sociol. Rev.

    45:821-41

    Caputo,

    D. A. 1989. Network

    perspectives

    and

    policy analysis:

    a

    skeptical

    view.

    See

    Perrucci &

    Potter 1989, pp.

    111-17

    Coleman,

    J.

    S.

    1988. Free riders and zealots:

    the role of social networks. Sociol.

    Theory

    6:52-57

    Collins,

    R.

    1981. On the microfoundations

    of

    macrosociology. Am. J. Sociol.

    86:984-

    1014

    Collins,

    R.

    1988. Theoretical

    Sociology.

    San

    Diego: HarcourtBrace Jovanovich

    Cook,

    K.

    S.

    1977.

    Exchange

    and

    power

    in

    networks of interorganizationalrelations.

    Sociol.

    Q. 18:62-82

    Cook,

    K.

    S.,

    ed.

    1987.

    Social

    Exchange

    Theory. Newbury Park,

    Calif:

    Sage

    Cook,

    K.

    S. 1990.

    Linking

    actors and struc-

    tures: an

    exchange

    network

    perspective.

    In

    Structures

    of

    Power and

    Constraint,

    ed. C.

    Calhoun,

    M.

    W.

    Meyer,

    W.

    R. Scott. Cam-

    bridge: Cambridge

    Univ. Press

    Cook, K. S. 1991. The microfoundationsof

    social structure.See

    Huber 1991, pp. 29-45

    Cook,

    K.

    S., Emerson,

    R. M. 1978.

    Power,

    equity,

    and

    commitment in

    exchange

    net-

    works. Am.

    Sociol. Rev.

    43:721-30

    Cook,

    K.

    S., Emerson,

    R.

    M., Gillmore,

    M.

    R., Yamagishi,

    T. 1983. The distribution

    f

    power

    in

    exchange

    networks:

    theory

    and

    experimental

    results. Am. J. Sociol. 89:

    275-305

    Cook,

    K.

    S., Gillmore,

    M. R. 1984.

    Power,

    dependence, and coalitions.

    InAdvances in

    Group Processes, ed.

    E.

    Lawler, 1:27-58.

    Greenwich, Conn: JAI

    Domhoff, G. W. 1975. Social clubs, policy

    planning groups, and corporations:

    a net-

    work study of ruling class cohesiveness.

    In-

    surgent Sociol. 5:173-84

    Ekeh, P. P. 1974. Social Exchange

    Theory:

    The

    Two

    Traditions.

    Cambridge, Mass:

    HarvardUniv.

    Press

    Emerson,

    R.

    M. 1962. Power-dependence

    e-

    lations. Am. Sociol. Rev. 27:31-40

    Emerson, R. M.

    1964.

    Power-dependence

    e-

    lations: two experiments. Sociometry

    27:282-98

    Emerson, R. M. 1972a. Exchangetheory, part

    I: a psychologicalbasis for social exchange.

    See

    Berger

    et

    al

    1972a, pp.

    38-57

    Emerson,R. M. 1972b.Exchangetheory, part

    II: exchangerules

    and networks. See

    Berger

    et

    al

    1972a, pp.

    58-87

    Emerson,

    R. M. 1981. Social

    exchange

    theory.

    In Social

    Psychology:

    Sociological

    Perspectives,

    ed. M.

    Rosenberg,

    R.

    Turner,

    pp.

    30-65. New

    York: Academic

    Erickson,B.

    H. 1988.

    The relationalbasis

    of

    attitudes.

    In

    Social Structures:

    A

    Network

    Approach, ed. B. Wellman, S. D. Berko-

    witz, pp.

    99-121.

    Cambridge:

    Cambridge

    Univ. Press

    Fararo,

    T.

    J., Skvoretz,

    J.

    1986.

    E-state

    structuralism:

    a

    theoretical

    method. Am.

    Sociol.

    Rev. 51:591-602

    Fararo,

    T.

    J., Skvoretz,

    J.

    1987.

    Unification

    research programs: integrating

    two struc-

    tural theories.

    Am.

    J. Sociol. 92:1183-

    1209

    Feld,

    S.

    L.

    1981. The focused

    organization

    of

    social

    ties. Am. J. Sociol. 86:1015-35

    Feld,

    S. L.

    1982. Social

    structuraldetermi-

    nants of similarity among associates. Am.

    Sociol. Rev. 47:797-801

    Feld,

    S. L.

    1984.

    The

    structured

    use of

    per-

    sonal associates. Soc. Forces

    62:640-52

    Fischer, C. S. 1982. To Dwell

    Among

    Friends: Personal Networks in

    Town

    and

    City. Chicago:Univ. Chicago

    Press

    Freeman, L. C. 1979. Centralityn social net-

    works:

    conceptual

    clarification. Soc. Net-

    works 1:215-39

    Friedkin, N.

    E.

    1984.

    Structural

    ohesion

    and

    equivalence explanations

    of

    social homo-

    geneity. Sociol. Methods Res. 12:235-61

    Friedkin, N.

    E.

    1991. Theoretical

    oundations

    for

    centrality

    measures. Am. J.

    Sociol.

    96:1478-504

    Galaskiewicz,

    J.

    1979.

    Exchange

    Networks

    and

    Community

    Politics. Beverly

    Hills,

    Calif:

    Sage

    Galaskiewicz, J. 1982.

    Modes

    of resource

    allocation:

    corporate

    contributionsto

    non-

    profit organizations.

    See Marsden & Lin

    1982, pp.

    235-53

    This content downloaded from 132.208.246.237 on Sun, 19 Oct 2014 21:14:13 PMAll use subject toJSTOR Terms and Conditions

    http://www.jstor.org/page/info/about/policies/terms.jsphttp://www.jstor.org/page/info/about/policies/terms.jsphttp://www.jstor.org/page/info/about/policies/terms.jsphttp://www.jstor.org/page/info/about/policies/terms.jsp
  • 8/10/2019 Cook - Two Approaches to Social Structure Exchange Theory and Network Analysis.pdf

    19/20

    126

    COOK &

    WHITMEYER

    Galaskiewicz, J. 1989. Interorganizational

    networksmobilizing action at the

    metropoli-

    tan level. See Perrucci & Potter 1989, pp.

    81-96

    Galaskiewicz, J., Burt, R. S. 1991. In-

    terorganization ontagion and corporatephi-

    lanthropy.Admin. Sci. Q. 36:88-105

    Gillmore, M. R. 1987. Implicationsof general

    versus restrictedexchange. See Cook 1987,

    pp. 170-89

    Gogel, R., Koenig,

    T.

    1981. Commercial

    banks, interlocking directorates and eco-

    nomic power: an analysis of the primary

    metals industry. Soc.

    Probl.

    29:117-28

    Granovetter,M. 1973. The strength of weak

    ties. Am. J. Sociol. 78:1360-80

    Granovetter,M. 1983. The strength of weak

    ties: a

    network theory revisited. Sociol.

    Theory 1:201-33

    Granovetter, M. 1985. Economic action and

    social structure: he problem of embedded-

    ness. Am. J. Sociol. 91:481-510

    Haines, V. A. 1988. Social network analysis,

    structuration theory and the holism-

    individualism debate. Soc. Networks 10:

    157-82

    Harary, F., Norman, R. Z., Cartwright, D.

    1965. StructuralModels: An Introduction o

    the Theory of Directed Graphs. New York:

    Wiley

    Heath,

    A.

    1976. Rational Choice and

    Social

    Exchange:

    A

    Critique of Exchange Theory.

    Cambridge:CambridgeUniv.

    Press

    Hechter, M. 1991. From exchange to struc-

    ture. See Huber 1991, pp. 46-50

    Homans, G. C. 1961. Social Behavior:

    Its

    Elementary Forms. New York: Harcourt

    Brace

    Homans,

    G. C. 1964.

    Bringing

    men

    back

    in.

    Am. Sociol. Rev. 29:809-18

    Huber, J.,

    ed.

    1991. Macro-Micro

    Linkages

    n

    Sociology. Newbury Park,

    Calif:

    Sage

    Johnsen, E., Mintz,

    B.

    1989.

    Organizational

    versus class components

    of director

    net-

    works.

    See

    Perrucci

    &

    Potter

    1989, pp.

    57-

    80

    Kapferer, B. 1972. Strategy

    and

    Transaction

    in

    an

    African Factory. Manchester, Eng:

    Manchester Univ.

    Press

    Knoke,

    D. 1983.

    Organization sponsorship

    and influence reputation

    of social

    influence

    associations. Soc. Forces

    61:1065-87

    Knoke, D., Burt, R. S. 1983. Prominence.In

    Applied

    Network

    Analysis:

    A

    Methodolog-

    ical

    Introduction,

    ed.

    R. S.

    Burt,

    M. J.

    Minor, pp.

    195-222.

    Beverly

    Hills:

    Sage

    Koenig, T., Gogel, R., Sonquist,

    J. 1979.

    Models

    of

    the

    significance

    of

    interlocking

    corporate

    directorates.

    Am.

    J.

    Econ.

    Soc.

    38:173-83

    Laumann,

    E.

    O., Knoke,

    D. 1989.

    Policy

    net-

    works of the

    organizational

    tate:

    collective

    action

    in

    the

    national

    energy

    and

    health do-

    mains. See Perrucci

    &

    Potter1989, pp.

    17-

    55

    Laumann,

    E.

    O.,

    Knoke, D.,

    Kim,

    Y-H.

    1985. An organizationalapproach o policy

    formation:

    a

    comparativestudy

    of

    energy

    and health

    domains.

    Am.Rev.

    Sociol.

    50:

    1-

    19

    Laumann,

    E.

    O.,

    Marsden,P.

    V. 1982.

    Mi-

    crostructural nalysis

    in

    interorganizational

    systems.

    Soc. Networks

    4:329-48

    Lorrain,

    F., White, H.

    C. 1971.

    Structural

    equivalence of

    individuals

    in social

    net-

    works. J. Math.

    Sociol.

    1:49-80

    Mariolis,

    P. 1975.

    Interlocking

    directorates

    and the

    control

    of corporations.

    Soc.

    Sci. Q.

    56:425-39

    Markovsky,

    B., Willer,

    D., Patton,

    T.

    1988.

    Power

    relations

    n exchange

    networks.

    Am.

    Sociol.

    Rev.

    53:220-36

    Marsden,

    P. V.

    1982. Brokerage

    behavior

    in

    restrictedexchangenetworks.

    See

    Marsden

    &

    Lin

    1982, pp. 201-18

    Marsden,

    P.

    V. 1983. Restricted

    access

    in

    networks and models

    of power.

    Am. J.

    Sociol.

    88:686-717

    Marsden,

    P. V. 1987.

    Elements

    of interactor

    dependence.

    See Cook 1987, pp.

    130-48

    Marsden, P. V. 1990. Network data and

    measurement.

    Annu.

    Rev. Sociol.

    16:435-

    63

    Mayhew, B. H.