Conservatism Fixedeffects

40
RE-EXAMINING ACCOUNTING CONSERVATISM: THE IMPORTANCE OF ADJUSTING FOR FIRM HETEROGENEITY ALAN G. HUANG School of Accounting and Finance, University of Waterloo, Ontario, Canada N2L 3G1 Email: [email protected] YAO TIAN School of Business, University of Alberta, Alberta, Canada T6G 2R6 Email: [email protected] TONY S. WIRJANTO School of Accounting and Finance and Department of Statistics and Actuarial Science, University of Waterloo, Ontario, Canada N2L 3G1 Email: [email protected] Version: March 2011 Abstract In this paper, we examine the role of firm heterogeneity of earnings in measuring accounting conservatism. Prior studies have documented the extent of accounting conservatism (in the form of the asymmetric response of accountings earnings to news) and its tendency to increase over time. However, many of these studies implicitly assume that unobserved firm-specific characteristics (known as firm heterogeneity or firm-specific fixed-effects) are unimportant to earnings determination. We find that after allowing for firm-specific fixed-effects in the earnings determination, (i) the level of accounting conservatism is smaller in magnitude than previously documented, and (ii) conservatism does not increase monotonically over time as has been claimed in prior studies. Our results echo recent studies that call for firm-level measures of conservatism, and emphasize the importance of allowing for firm heterogeneity in measuring accounting conservatism. Keywords: returns; earnings; firm-specific fixed-effects; asymmetry; conservatism. * We are solely responsible for all remaining errors.

description

konservatisme

Transcript of Conservatism Fixedeffects

Page 1: Conservatism Fixedeffects

RE-EXAMINING ACCOUNTING CONSERVATISM: THE IMPORTANCE OF ADJUSTING FOR FIRM HETEROGENEITY

ALAN G. HUANG School of Accounting and Finance, University of Waterloo, Ontario, Canada N2L 3G1 Email: [email protected]

YAO TIAN School of Business, University of Alberta, Alberta, Canada T6G 2R6 Email: [email protected]

TONY S. WIRJANTO School of Accounting and Finance and Department of Statistics and Actuarial Science, University of Waterloo, Ontario, Canada N2L 3G1 Email: [email protected]

Version: March 2011

Abstract

In this paper, we examine the role of firm heterogeneity of earnings in measuring accounting

conservatism. Prior studies have documented the extent of accounting conservatism (in the form

of the asymmetric response of accountings earnings to news) and its tendency to increase over

time. However, many of these studies implicitly assume that unobserved firm-specific

characteristics (known as firm heterogeneity or firm-specific fixed-effects) are unimportant to

earnings determination. We find that after allowing for firm-specific fixed-effects in the earnings

determination, (i) the level of accounting conservatism is smaller in magnitude than previously

documented, and (ii) conservatism does not increase monotonically over time as has been

claimed in prior studies. Our results echo recent studies that call for firm-level measures of

conservatism, and emphasize the importance of allowing for firm heterogeneity in measuring

accounting conservatism.

Keywords: returns; earnings; firm-specific fixed-effects; asymmetry; conservatism.

* We are solely responsible for all remaining errors.

Page 2: Conservatism Fixedeffects

1

1. INTRODUCTION

Accounting conservatism is an important characteristic of the Generally Accepted Accounting

Principles (GAAP). It refers to “the differential verifiability required for recognition of profits

versus losses” (Watts, 2003). Many empirical studies have attempted to quantify the extent of

accounting conservatism. In a seminal publication, Basu (1997) studies the timeliness of earnings

recognition with respect to stock returns (as a measure for news) in a piecewise linear regression

model. He finds that earnings reflect “bad news” faster than “good news”, providing empirical

evidence of accounting conservatism. Employing Basu’s (1997) measure as well as a number of

other measures, Givoly and Hayn (2000) show that accounting conservatism has increased over

time.1

In this paper, we reexamine the appropriateness of the model specifications used in Basu (1997)

in the context of firm heterogeneity. We focus on the Basu (1997) measure, since it is the most

widely used conservatism measure in the literature (Ryan, 2006). Basu (1997) and many

subsequent papers on accounting conservatism typically use a pooled ordinary least squares

(OLS) approach to estimate their empirical models of accounting conservatism, where earnings

is regressed on stock returns and negative/positive return regimes. This approach inadvertently

neglects the panel structure of the data and treats unobserved and unobservable firm-specific

characteristics as homogeneous and, thus, unimportant to the determination of earnings. In

particular, the OLS measure obscures the cross-sectional variation in conservatism by assuming

that all firms are homogeneous.2 Our findings show that there are significant cross-sectional

variations (due to unobserved firm heterogeneity or firm-specific fixed-effects) in earnings. By

ignoring firm heterogeneity, the pooled OLS regression model essentially forces return to be the

sole determining factor of the cross-sectional variations in earnings. This can result in an omitted

1 Studies of accounting conservatism that focus on high-tech versus low-tech firms include Kwon, Qin, and Han (2006), and studies that focus on the banking industry include Alali and Jaggi (2011) and Anandarajan, Francis, Hasan, and John (2011). In addition, non-US studies of conservatism include Elbannan (2011) for an emerging market, and Anandarajan, Francis, Hasan, and John (2011) for a large number of international markets. 2 Some studies control for industry fixed-effects (for example, Ahmed et al. 2002, Ahmed and Duellman 2007, Francis et al. 2009, Khan and Watts, 2009). Doing so ameliorates the cross-sectional variation problem but does not remove it. Controlling for industry fixed-effects assumes that firms within an industry are homogenous and thus ignores the cross-sectional variation of conservatism within the industry. The adjustment of firm- and time-fixed-effects is also used in other settings in accounting. For example, Beaver and Ryan (2000) use fixed-effects to model the persistent bias in book-to-market ratios due primarily to unconditional conservatism, and use time-specific effects to capture economy wide temporal variation.

Page 3: Conservatism Fixedeffects

2

variable bias in the parameter estimates of the regression model, and thus can lead to an

erroneous inference about the extent of and trend in accounting conservatism.

Our study is motived by recent studies that call for controlling for firm heterogeneity in

estimating measures of conservatism. The literature suggests that conservatism is associated with

firm- and economy-specific factors such as contracts (including debt and compensation

contracts), litigation, taxation and regulation (Watts, 2003). Adjusting for these firm-level

heterogeneities yields a firm-level measure of conservatism. However, traditional conservatism

measures are not designed to capture these firm-level variations. Notably, Ryan (2006)

comments that “(s)uch measures are currently not available and are desperately needed in order

to address many research questions empirically.” It is not until recently that firm-level

conservatism measures were introduced in the literature.3 For example, based on the return

decomposition model of Vuolteenaho (2002), Callen, Segal, and Hope (2010) define the ratio of

unexpected current earnings to total earnings shocks as a firm-level conservatism measure. Khan

and Watts (2009) specify the asymmetric earnings timeliness coefficient in Basu (1997) as a

linear function of firm-specific characteristics of size, market-to-book and leverage, and

substitute these characteristics into the Basu regression to arrive at a firm-level conservatism

measure.

In this paper we provide another refinement of Basu (1997) for firm-level conservatism. Since

there are potentially many factors that affect variation in conservatism,4 and since the literature is

inconclusive on which factors to use, we use a parsimonious setting of firm fixed-effects to

control for firm-specific heterogeneity. The literature suggests that fixed-effects provide a

mechanism to control for unobservable firm-specific effect in a number of settings. For example,

observing that leverage is stable over time for individual firms, Lemmon, Roberts and Zender

(2008) find that the unobserved firm-specific effects (as measured by fixed-effects) are

responsible for the majority of cross-sectional variation in capital structure. In particular, related

3 Controlling for fixed-effects is a popular way to derive firm-specific measures. For example, Ramirez and Hachiya (2006) use fixed-effects to measure firm-specific organizational capital. 4 For example, Watts’s (2003) survey paper suggests that conservatism is associated with contracts, litigation, taxation and regulation, and Khan and Watts (2009) choose size, market-to-book and leverage as the primary factors that affect conservatism.

Page 4: Conservatism Fixedeffects

3

to this paper, Ball, Kothari and Nikolaev (2011) recently recommend that researchers interested

in measuring conservatism in the Basu (1997) framework should control for firm-specific effects

in order to avoid potentially spurious inferences.

To provide evidence of firm heterogeneity in the earnings regression, we show that a substantial

part of the total variation in earnings is attributed to cross-sectional differences. In fact, the

unidentified cross-sectional fixed-effects account for more variation in earnings as the traditional

returns-earnings specification. The adjusted R-square from a regression of earnings on just firm-

specific fixed-effects is 13% in our constant sample of 691 firms from 1976 to 2005. In contrast,

the adjusted R-square from the traditional earnings regression (Basu, 1997) is 10% only.5 These

results are in line with Lemmon, Roberts and Zender (2008), who call for a fixed-effects study,

and provide empirical support for Ball, Kothari and Nikolaev’s (2011) recommendation to

control for fixed-effects in estimating the Basu (1997) asymmetric earnings timeliness.

Due to the strength of the cross-sectional variations, and hence the importance of firm

heterogeneity in earnings determination, we explicitly incorporate firm-specific fixed-effects into

Basu’s regression model. We then use this refined model to reexamine the extent of accounting

conservatism and its trend over time. We find that, after allowing for firm-specific fixed-effects

in the earnings regression, the level of accounting conservatism is much smaller in magnitude

than previously documented. In addition, contrary to Givoly and Hayn (2000), we do not find

clear evidence to support the assertion that, over time, there is a monotonic increase in

accounting conservatism.

We also conduct a number of sensitivity analyses to ensure that our results are robust to different

model specifications and alternative measures of accounting conservatism, such as employing

different samples, and using cash flows from operations as a proxy for news (Ball and

Shivakumar 2006). Overall, our results highlight the importance of allowing for firm

heterogeneity in the regression models that use asymmetric response of accounting earnings to

news as a conservatism measure.

5 Consistent with these results, model specification tests conducted in this paper reject the assumption of firm homogeneity.

Page 5: Conservatism Fixedeffects

4

Our econometric refinements of the Basu (1997) specifications are intended to provide an

agnostic firm-level measure of conservatism. As such, this paper joins several recent studies in

addressing the efficacy of the Basu measure. Dietrich, Muller and Riedl (2007) show that the

Basu specification gives rise to evidence consistent with accounting conservatism even in the

absence of accounting conservatism; that is, Basu (1997) overstates the occurrence of accounting

conservatism. Patatoukas and Thomas (2009, 2010) further support the views espoused by

Dietrich, Muller and Riedl (2007) by arguing that the scale variable used in the Basu (1997)

regressions entails an effect that biases the Basu estimator. Contrasting these views, Givoly,

Hayn and Natarajan (2007) claim that Basu’s (1997) measure understates accounting

conservatism. In addition, Ball, Kothari and Nikolaev (2011) challenge the views of Patatoukas

and Thomas (2010) by arguing that the bias in the Basu estimator is in fact caused by the

correlation between the expected values of earnings and return. Ball, Kothari and Nikolaev

(2011) advocate for using fixed-effects in the Basu (1997) regression to correct for this bias. Our

paper takes this suggestion seriously: we explicitly control for firm fixed-effects. We also

contribute to the literature by showing that controlling for fixed-effects considerably weakens the

trend of conservatism.

The remainder of the paper is organized as follows. In section 2, we briefly review studies on

accounting conservatism and present the pooled OLS earnings regression model originally

employed in Basu (1997) to measure the extent of accounting conservatism. In section 3, we

discuss the potential shortcomings of the pooled OLS regression model, and introduce the fixed-

effect model to overcome some of these problems. In Section 4, we first demonstrate the

importance of firm heterogeneity in earnings determination, and then report the findings on the

extent of accounting conservatism and its trend over time after allowing for firm-specific fixed-

effects in the earnings regression. We conduct four sets of sensitivity analysis in Section 5 to

demonstrate the robustness of our results. Finally, Section 6 concludes.

2. ACCOUNTING CONSERVATISM

Over the years, a considerable amount of research has investigated the extent of accounting

conservatism, its impact on the quality of financial reporting, and its trend over time. In these

Page 6: Conservatism Fixedeffects

5

studies, researchers have introduced a number of definitions of conservatism. For instance,

Belkaoui (1985) broadly defines conservatism as “reporting the lowest values of assets and

revenues and the highest values of liabilities and expenses.” Taking a balance-sheet perspective,

Penman and Zhang (2002) define conservative accounting as “choosing accounting methods and

estimates that keep the book values of net assets relatively low.” Basu (1997) argues that

“conservatism in the balance sheet is of dubious value if attained at the expense of conservatism

in the income statement, which is far more significant”. Taking an income-statement perspective,

he defines accounting conservatism as “the practice of reducing earnings in response to ‘bad

news’, but not increasing earnings in response to ‘good news’.” In this paper, we adopt Basu’s

convention and define accounting conservatism in terms of the asymmetric timeliness of

earnings to reflect “good news” and “bad news”.

To measure the extent of accounting conservatism, Basu (1997) proposes a piecewise linear

regression:

ititititititit uRDDRPEPS )(/ 32101 (1)

In the above regression, itEPS is the earnings per share of firm i in fiscal year t, 1itP is the price

per share of firm i at the beginning of the fiscal year t, itR is the discretely compounded annual

return of firm i in fiscal year t, and itD is a dummy variable set equal to 1 when 0itR (bad

news) and to 0 when 0itR (good news); and itu is the unobserved zero-mean error term. In (1),

the slope coefficient, ,3 measures the incremental responsiveness of earnings to bad news over

earnings to good news. It is expected to be positive and significant under a conservative

reporting system. Basu (1997) estimates this model as a pooled cross-sectional regression and

finds that earnings is about four and a half times ( 66.4/)( 131 ) as sensitive to negative

returns as it is to positive returns. These results provide strong evidence for accounting

conservatism.

Since the publication of Basu (1997), the above framework has been widely adopted to measure

the extent of accounting conservatism. It is, in fact, the “most widely used conservatism measure

Page 7: Conservatism Fixedeffects

6

in the literature” (Ryan, 2006). Givoly and Hayn (2000) use Basu’s (1997) measure as well as

other measures to examine the trend in conservatism over time. Estimating the model in a pooled

OLS regression model using the intersection of firms in Standard and Poor’s Compustat and the

Center for Research in Security Prices (CRSP) from 1950 to 1998, these authors find that the

timely recognition of “bad news” relative to “good news” increased over time. In other words,

the authors document that there is an increasing trend in accounting conservatism.

Like most studies on earnings-returns relation, Basu (1997) and Givoly and Hayn (2000)

estimate the returns-earnings relation by using the standard pooled OLS approach. It is important

to note that the pooled OLS estimator in equation (1) treats sample observations as being serially

uncorrelated for a given firm with homoskedastic errors across firms and time periods. However,

as we will show empirically in Section 4 of this paper, this assumption is rather restrictive. In

fact, we find there are significant cross-sectional variations (i.e., firm heterogeneity) in earnings

determination. In the presence of this firm heterogeneity, the pooled OLS estimates of

'3210 ),,,( in (1) are biased and inconsistent. This is our underlying motivation to refine

Basu’s (1997) model by explicitly allowing for firm-specific fixed-effects. We then use the

refined model to reexamine the extent of accounting conservatism and its trend over time.

3. MODEL DEVELOPMENT—ACCOUNTING FOR FIRM HETEROGENEITY

There are two methods to account for firm heterogeneity: the fixed-effects model and the

random-effects model. On one hand, the fixed-effects model can be estimated using three

alternative approaches: between-firms, within-firms, and Least Squares Dummy Variable

(LSDV) estimations. This model is particularly suitable when the differences between individual

firms can be reasonably viewed as parametric shifts in the regression function itself. For

instance, an example for this is, when the cross-sections used in the estimation represent a

broadly exhaustive sample of the population of firms. On the other hand, if the cross-sections are

drawn from a larger population, so that the sample firms may not be reasonably considered

exhaustive, then it is more appropriate to view firm-specific terms in the sample as randomly

distributed over the full cross-sections of firms, and to instead apply the random-effects model.6

6 See, for example, Greene’s (2003) textbook for an illustration of fixed-effects and random-effects models.

Page 8: Conservatism Fixedeffects

7

In untabulated results, 7 we perform a series of model specification tests in our sample to

determine the most appropriate panel-data regression model for equation (1). Our test results

confirm the presence of firm-specific effects and suggest that estimates of the parameters in the

linear piece-wise earnings regression in equation (1) obtained by the pooled OLS are biased and

inconsistent. Furthermore, our test results favor the fixed-effects model with the LSDV

estimation approach over the RE model and other fixed-effects models. Consequently, our

subsequent analyses in the remainder of the paper will focus on estimates obtained from the

LSDV/FE specification.

Let i=1,…,N denote firms, and Tt ,...,1 denote time periods. The fixed-effects model is

specified as follows:

,)(/2

32101 u +F RDDR =PEPS it

N

jjitjitititititit

(2)

where ijtF is the firm dummy variable (i.e., 1ijtF for j=i and 0ijtF for ji ; i,j=2,…N), j

is the individual firm-specific effect which is assumed to be time invariant, and itu is the

unobserved zero-mean error term. In the context of our study, j includes firm-specific

characteristics of a company that are candidates for additional explanatory variables in the

model. If there is no firm heterogeneity in the data, this model would reduce to the original Basu

model as 0j for all j. Note that the regression model in equation (2) can be extended to

include time fixed-effects as follows:

,)(/22

32101 u +YF RDDR = PEPS it

T

sstis

N

jjitjitititititit

(3)

where stiY is the time dummy ( 1 = Ysti for s = t and 0 = Ysti for ts ; s,t = 2,…T). Consistent with

the literature that calls for firm-level conservatism measures (e.g., Ball, Kothari and Nikolaev,

2011), in this paper we choose to present results from regression (2) to emphasize the importance

of allowing for firm heterogeneity in measuring accounting conservatism. We note that adding

7 The results are available from the authors upon request.

Page 9: Conservatism Fixedeffects

8

time fixed-effects does not change the qualitative results appreciably. The estimation results are

available upon request.

4. EMPIRICAL RESULTS

In this section, we will first describe the sample, and provide empirical evidence on the

importance of firm heterogeneity. We will then use the refined model in equation (2) to account

for firm-specific fixed-effects and reexamine the extent of accounting conservatism and its trend

over time.

4.1 Data

Our sample covers NYSE/AMEX/NASDAQ firms for the period of 1976-2005. We first

consider a constant sample where firms have non-missing observations in all years of the entire

sample period. In robustness checks, we use an alternate sample that allows for new listings and

de-listings of firms. The accounting data used in this study are retrieved from Compustat, and the

return data are from CRSP. The dependent variable in equation (1), ,/ 1itit PEPS is calculated as

earnings per share (Compustatvariable EPSPX) divided by the lagged-one fiscal-year-end

closing price (Compustat variable PRCC_F). Firm’s annual stock return is defined as the

cumulative monthly returns for the period from 9 months before the fiscal year end to 3 months

after the fiscal year end. Finally, as in Basu (1997), we winsorize the top and bottom 1% of the

earnings and returns variables to exclude outliers. This results in a final sample of 691 firms for

the time period from 1976 to 2005.

In addition, in robustness checks, we use cash flows from operation (Compustat variable

OANCF) to proxy for economic gains/losses. Since cash flows from operation is only available

after 1988, we construct a constant sample of firms over the period from 1988 to 2005 by

requiring firms to have a non-missing value in accruals and cash flows from operations every

year. This alternative sample has a total of 995 firms.

4.2 Evidence of the Importance of Firm Heterogeneity

Page 10: Conservatism Fixedeffects

9

We now show that the variations in earnings and returns for the pooled sample are attributed

mainly to firm-specific cross-sectional variations. Table 1 reports the full-sample standard

deviations, the time-series mean of cross-sectional standard deviations, and the cross-sectional

mean of time-series standard deviations of individual firms on earnings and stock returns. We

observe that the means of the cross-sectional volatilities for both variables are almost as large as

the pooled volatility, whereas the means of the time-series volatilities of the individual firms are

much smaller. As a further illustration of this point, Figure 1 plots the ratios of the cross-

sectional volatility of each variable to its pooled counterpart over time. As shown in the figure,

the high ratios between the means of the cross-sectional sample volatilities and pooled sample

volatility are not due to any particular sub-periods, as the ratios remain high across time.

Collectively, Table 1 and Figure 1 show that it is the between-firm differences instead of within-

firm differences that drive the pooled sample variations.

[Table 1 about here.]

[Figure 1 about here.]

The fact that the sample variation of return is mainly driven by cross-sectional variation justifies

the use of LSDV/FE.8 However, it is important to point out that the original Basu model does

not account for the between-firm differences. By ignoring the firm-specific fixed-effects, the

pooled OLS model essentially forces the returns to be the sole factor determining the cross-

sectional variations (firm heterogeneity) in earnings. This can lead to an omitted variable bias in

the returns-earnings regression, and consequently an erroneous interpretation of the extent of

accounting conservatism. In our refined model, we capture this unobserved firm heterogeneity

using the firm-specific fixed-effects in equation (2).

Before we estimate the fixed-effects regression of equation (2), it is necessary to examine how

much of the documented “conservatism” effect (as captured by the returns variable) in Basu’s

pooled OLS model is attributable to the unobserved firm-specific fixed-effects. To this end, we

8 If there is little cross-sectional variation in return, then a between-firms regression, which averages variables over time across firms, would also be appropriate, since in this case what matters is the time-series changes in variables. This is the approach taken by Grambovas, Giner and Christodoulou (2006).

Page 11: Conservatism Fixedeffects

10

use the analysis of covariance (ANCOVA) to decompose the variations in the earnings due to the

different factors based on the following piecewise linear fixed-effects regressions in (a) to (f).9

u +F = PEPS it

N

jjitjitit

201/ (a)

u +Y= PEPS it

T

sstisitit

201/ (b)

u +YF = PEPS it

T

sstis

N

jjitjitit

2201/ (c)

u +RDDR = PEPS ititititititit )(/ 32101 (d)

u F RDDR = PEPS it

N

jjitjitititititit

232101 )(/ (e)

u +YF RDDR = PEPS it

T

sstis

N

jjitjitititititit

2232101 )(/ (f)

The ANCOVA results are reported in Table 2. Each column in Table 2 corresponds to a different

specification in (a)-(f). The numbers in each column, excluding the last row, are fractions of total

Type III partial sum of squares for each model. That is, the partial sum of squares for each effect

is scaled by the aggregate partial sum of squares of all effects in the model, to sum each column

to unity. As a result, the values in the table correspond to the fractions of the model’s sum of

squares due to particular effects. A special case arises when there is only one effect in the

model. In this case, the total explained sum of squares is due to that effect only. For instance, in

column (a), when only firm-specific fixed-effects are included in the model, the estimate takes

on a value of 1.00 (or 100%).

[Table 2 about here.]

The last row of Table 2 reports the value of the adjusted R-square for each specification. Column

(a) in the table shows that firm-specific fixed-effects alone account for 13% of the observed 9 Lemmon, Roberts and Zender (2008) use a similar method in the context of capital structure determinants and find that the traditional determinants for capital structure explain little of firms’ actual leverage once firm fixed-effects are controlled for.

Page 12: Conservatism Fixedeffects

11

variation in earnings. Column (d) represents the results from the pooled OLS model in Basu

(1997). The value of the adjusted R-square for this particular specification is 10%, lower than

that from the model with only firm-specific fixed-effects. Column (e) shows our proposed

specification, which adds the firm-specific fixed-effects to the Basu model in column (d). The

adjusted R-square rises from 10% in column (d) to 20% after including the firm-specific fixed-

effects. In addition, a substantial 82% of the explanatory power in this model is captured solely

by the firm-specific fixed-effects.10 In summary, the results of the variance decomposition show

that earnings contain a nontrivial firm-specific component that is not captured by the pooled OLS

specification in Basu (1997). Since a substantial part of the total variation in earnings emanates

from the cross-sectional differences, there is a need to control for firm fixed-effects in the Basu

(1997) model.

4.3 Empirical Results on the Extent of Accounting Conservatism and its Trends

4.3.1 The Extent of Accounting Conservatism

Given the presence of firm-specific fixed-effects in the returns-earnings relation, we adopt a

panel-data methodology to estimate the refined Basu model to account for firm-specific fixed-

effects and reexamine the extent of accounting conservatism. For comparison purposes, we also

estimate the original Basu model using the pooled OLS approach, and report the estimation

results from both models in Table 3.11

[Table 3 about here]

As Table 3 shows, the refined model has a much larger adjusted R-square than the original

model (i.e., 0.196 versus 0.097), suggesting a better fit for the refined model. Also, both models

produce statistically significant estimates for the parameters ( 0 , 1 , and 3 ), all with expected

10 We also observe in Table 2 that the contribution from the year fixed-effects is significant. In this paper, we follow the literature and focus on the effect of firm heterogeneity in earnings determination. As previously noted, including the year fixed-effects in the earnings regression does not change the qualitative results. 11 The standard R-squared value is not an appropriate goodness-of-fit measure for panel-data regressions since it can yield numerical values outside the interval [0,1]. Instead, a generalization of the R-squared value due to Theil (1961) is reported for LSDV/FE regressions. The Theil R-squared value is defined as one minus the sum of squared errors divided by the sum of squares of the (transformed) dependent variable.

Page 13: Conservatism Fixedeffects

12

signs. Recall that 0 captures the current recognition of unrealized gains from the prior period.

The estimated coefficients of 0 are positive and highly significant in both models, suggesting a

delayed recognition of gains in a conservatism accounting system. The estimates of 2 in both

models are very small in magnitude and statistically insignificant, suggesting that the current

recognition of prior-period gains (as captured by the constant term, 0 ) does not change with the

type of news received in the current period.

The estimates of the coefficient 3 (which measures the incremental responsiveness of earnings

to bad news) are positive and statistically significant in both models, providing evidence for

accounting conservatism. However, the estimated 3 from the refined model is much smaller in

magnitude than that from the original model (0.139 versus 0.205). A test of the hypothesis that

3 = 0.205 in the refined model is strongly rejected at below the 1% significance level, indicating

that the refined model gives different levels of accounting conservatism than the original model

does. In particular, according to the original model, earnings is about 8.59 (= (0.027 +

0.205)/0.027) times as sensitive to negative returns as it is to positive returns, while the refined

model suggests that earnings is about 4.48 ( = (0.040 + 0.139) /0.040) times as sensitive to

negative returns as it is to positive returns. A comparison of the estimate of 3 and the ratio of

131 /)( between the pooled OLS model and their counterparts in the LSDV/FE model

reveals that they are significantly different at the 1% level. Overall, these results suggest that

after correcting for firm heterogeneity, the actual extent of accounting conservatism is only about

one half of the level as previously documented.

4.3.2 The Trend in Accounting Conservatism

In examining the trend in conservatism over time, Givoly and Hayn (2000) estimate the Basu

(1997) model using pooled OLS and find that the timely recognition of “bad news” relative to

“good news” has increased over time. Their results provide evidence for an increasing trend in

accounting conservatism.12

12 In the Appendix, we replicate Givoly and Hayn’s (2000) analysis based on Basu’s measure in our sample. Using their sample period, our replication results are very close to what they have reported. However, their findings appear

Page 14: Conservatism Fixedeffects

13

Given the ubiquity of the Basu model to measure conservatism (Ryan, 2006), and given the

significant difference in our findings regarding the extent of accounting conservatism after

allowing for firm-specific fixed-effects, it is worthwhile to reexamine the trend in accounting

conservatism by using the refined Basu model that explicitly accounts for firm heterogeneity. To

this end, we divide the full sample period into sub-periods with a five year interval, as well as

sub-periods corresponding to business cycles defined as periods from NBER business recession

to NBER business peak. We estimate both the original pooled OLS model and our refined

LSDV/FE model over these various sub-periods. We report the estimation results in Table 4.

[Table 4 about here.]

A number of observations warrant discussion. First, contrary to the findings in Givoly and Hayn

(2000), the refined model does not show an increasing trend in conservatism, as evidenced in

both the estimate of 3 and the ratio of 131 /)( . As for 3 , its estimates from the refined

model are positive and significant in each of the five-year intervals from 1976 to 2005, providing

evidence of accounting conservatism in each sub-period. However, the estimated values of 3

from the refined model show an overall declining trend over time. This indicates that, the first

half of the sample period has a larger estimate of 3 than the second half. In particular, the

estimate of 3 drops from 0.132 in the sub-period of 1976-1980 to 0.033 in the sub-period of

1996-2000. This indicates a significant reduction in asymmetry during this period. An exception

is the sub-periods of 1986-1990 and 2001-2005, during which the estimate rose from 0.072 in

1981-1985 to 0.147 in 1986-1990, and from 0.033 in 1996-2000 to 0.065 in 2001-2005

respectively. As for 131 /)( , the conservatism trend as measured by this ratio in the refined

model is relatively stable across these sub-periods. The ratio, which measures the sensitivity of

earnings to bad news relative to their sensitivity to good news, always exceeds unity, suggesting

a greater tendency of firms to recognize bad news in a more timely fashion than good news.

Once firm-specific fixed-effects are incorporated into the regression specification, there is no

to be both sample specific and estimation-method specific. In particular their main findings are reversed once the sample period is extended to cover the period of 1995-2004.

Page 15: Conservatism Fixedeffects

14

clear evidence that the incremental responsiveness of earnings to bad news is stronger in later

years than in early years. Overall, our results cast serious doubts on the assertion that the trend of

conservatism is increasing over time.

Second, similar to the results reported in Table 3, the estimated values of 3 and 131 /)( in

the refined model are consistently smaller than their counterparts in the original model in all sub-

periods, providing evidence that the results reported in Table 3 for the whole sample is not likely

caused by a particular sub-period. The estimated values in the former are usually one half or a

third of those in the original model, confirming that after incorporating firm heterogeneity in the

earnings regression, the measured degree of accounting conservatism is weaker than previously

reported.

Finally, the estimate value of 1 , which measures earnings’ responsiveness to good news, in the

refined model is larger than that in the original Basu model. A comparison between the first half

and the second half of the sample period reveals that the estimate of 1 tends to decrease over

time in both the original pooled OLS and the refined LSDV/FE models. These results indicate

that (i) controlling for firm heterogeneity results in earnings being more responsive to good news

than is the original Basu (1997) setting and (ii) not only is earnings less responsive to bad news

over time, it is also less responsive to good news over time—that is, earnings is less sensitive to

news. Overall, these results further weaken the argument of asymmetric timeliness of earnings of

Basu (1997), in that earnings’ responsiveness to news is now less asymmetric.

When the sample period is partitioned according to the NBER business cycles, the results are

similar. The estimated value of 1 in the refined model shows a steady decline from 0.076 in

1976-1979 to 0.023 in 2001-2005, which is again consistent with the idea that earnings reflect

positive returns on a less timely basis over the business cycles. The corresponding estimates

of 3 show a similar pattern to those obtained for the five-year intervals. In addition, the estimate

of 131 /)( over the business cycles shows a similar pattern to the ratio obtained over the sub-

periods with the five-year interval. Again, the evidence corroborates that earnings are also less

timely in reflecting bad news over time.

Page 16: Conservatism Fixedeffects

15

5. SENSITIVITY ANALYSES

5.1 An Alternate Sample Allowing for New Listings and Delistings

Our previous results use the sample filtering procedure of Givoly and Hayn (2000), which

require all firm-year observations to be non-missing. While this sample selection procedure

makes our study more comparable to Givoly and Hayn (2000), we note that Basu (1997) does

not impose this condition. We now confirm the robustness of our results by using the Basu

(1997) sample selection procedure that allows for new listings and delistings of firms.

Specifically, to allow for meaningful fixed-effects regression, we require that each firm has at

least 10 observations in our sample period of 30 years. This sample covers 6,041 firms, with an

average cross section of 3,623 firms. Compared with the 691 firms in Tables 3 and 4, this sample

is about four times larger. We then repeat the exercises of Tables 3 and 4 with this sample. The

results are presented in Table 5. We observe that the results are similar to, if not better than,

those presented in Tables 3 and 4—the percentage reduction in the estimate of 3 in Table 5 is

generally larger than that in Tables 3 and 4. In other words, for the full sample, after controlling

for firm fixed-effects, (1) the degree of conservatism is much smaller in both the full-sample

(Panel A) and each of the five-year sub-periods (Panel B) as indicated by the estimated values of

3 and 131 /)( ,13 and (2) conservatism is decreasing over time as suggested by the estimates

of 3 or remains relatively stable as suggested by the estimates of 131 /)( . In sum, these

results reiterate the findings in Tables 3 and 4.

[Table 5 about here.]

5.2 The Returns-Cash Flow Regression

The basic reasoning in Basu (1997) is that the parameter 3 in equation (2) or (3) captures a

more sensitive relationship between earnings and returns when returns are negative. However, it

13For each of the five-year sub-periods, we further require that firms have three non-missing observations in that sub-period for the fixed-effects adjustment to be meaningful.

Page 17: Conservatism Fixedeffects

16

is possible that a significant estimate of 3 is driven instead by the changes in returns.

Abarbanell and Bernard (1992), Sloan (1996) and Ball and Bartov (1996), for instance, argue

that the market may not fully understand the earnings process. In particular, Abarbanell and

Bernard (1992) reason that the market tends to over-react to bad news. Therefore, it is possible

that the market believes that negative earnings changes are more permanent than positive

earnings changes. This would give rise to the estimate of 3 being driven by changes in returns

rather than being a measure of earnings conservatism as suggested by Basu (1997). The key

question here is whether the market properly interprets earnings changes. To facilitate this

interpretation, we follow Basu (1997) and decompose earnings into its cash flow and accrual

components. This leads to a piecewise linear cash flows regression with firm-specific fixed-

effects:

,)(/2

32101 u +F RDDR =PCFO it

N

jjitjitititititit

(4)

where CFO denotes cash flows from operation. If the significance of the coefficient 3 in

equation (2) is due to accruals anticipating bad news, then when cash flows is used as the

dependent variable in the regression as in equation (4), the significance of 3 in equation (4)

should be diminished or, better, vanished. The results in Table 6 confirm that this is the case.

[Table 6 about here.]

Table 6 shows that the magnitudes of the estimates of 3 are invariably much smaller than those

in the earnings regression. This is particularly the case for the LSDV/FE estimates reported in the

table. Moreover, for the sub-periods of 1994-2000 and 2001-2005, the LSDV/FE estimates of 3

are not significant. This is in line with the above accruals hypothesis of earnings conservatism:

Current period cash flow is more likely to be affected by poor performance of firms, and, thus,

the observed increased sensitivity between current period cash flow and current returns are, to

some extent, driven by the changing nature of the returns.14

14 We note that the estimate of 3 for the sub-period of 1988-1993 is significant (with a t-statistic of 3.20).

However, at 0.070, the magnitude of the estimate is small.

Page 18: Conservatism Fixedeffects

17

We further provide an alternative measure of earnings conservatism: the implied effect of

accruals, defined as the difference between the estimated coefficient of 3 from the earnings

regression and the estimated coefficient of 3 from the cash flows regression. If the accrual

hypothesis of conservatism is true, the implied effect of accruals should be small and a large

effect would indicate the existence of conservatism. The results are reported in the Table 7.

[Table 7 about here.]

The estimates of the pooled OLS model provide evidence of accounting conservatism, as

illustrated by a large and significant difference between the estimates in columns 1 and 2.

However, the LSDV/FE estimates indicate that the differences between the two estimates are

small in magnitude and not statistically significant at the 5% level. Interestingly, the difference

in the sub-period of 1988-1993 is negative, implying that earnings may have been boosted by

accruals when firms’ poor performance is anticipated by returns. However, this difference has a

t-statistic of 0.45 only. Thus, after controlling for the firm-specific fixed-effects, the evidence of

accounting conservatism diminishes. Tables 6 and 7 are consistent with our previous findings

that accounting conservatism is much weaker than has been documented.

5.3 Including Lagged Returns in Basu’s (1997) Model

Kothari and Sloan (1992), Collins, Kothari, Shanken and Sloan (1994), and Beaver and Ryan

(2000), among others, examine how well current and past returns explain current earnings. They

find that returns in all three previous periods contain information about current earnings. Based

on this argument, we extend the specification in equation (2) to allow for past returns to explain

current earnings.15 The inclusion of the firm-specific fixed-effects leads to the following panel-

data specification:

323222121203132121111001/ itititititititititit DDDD RRRR = PEPS

u +F RD RD RD RD it

N

jijtiitititititititit

233332232113130 )()()()( (5)

15 Ryan and Zarowin (2003) study a similar specification without incorporating firm-specific fixed-effects.

Page 19: Conservatism Fixedeffects

18

In equation (5), the parameters ),,,( 13121110 measure the impacts of current and past returns

on current earnings. The parameters ),,,( 23222120 are the shifting coefficients when there is

bad news in returns in the period, and the parameters ),,,( 33323130 are the shifting coefficients

on returns when there is bad return news in the period. If the accounting system is conservative

and earnings reflect news for up to three prior periods, we should expect each of the estimates in

),,,( 33323130 to be positive. Moreover, the sum of coefficients, ,33323130 measures

the aggregate degree of conservatism (i.e., the incremental responsiveness of earnings to

negative news above that to positive news in the three years after the news occurs).

The estimation results of equation (5) are provided in Table 8. A comparison between the pooled

OLS and LSDV/FE results again re-emphasizes the importance of controlling for firm-specific

fixed-effects in the earnings regression. In particular, the extent of accounting conservatism as

measured by the pooled OLS estimates ,30 3231, , 33 is uniformly greater than their LSDV/FE

counterparts, both in the full sample (Panel A) and in sub-periods of 1980-1989, 1990-2000, and

2001-2005 (Panel B).

Furthermore, there is no evidence of an increasing trend of conservatism from the LSDV/FE

regression. First, recall that the estimate of the coefficient 30 measures the shift in the

association between returns and earnings when returns are negative. Between 1980 and 2000,

there is a decreasing trend in the incremental responsiveness of earnings to bad news; the

coefficient estimate then stabilizes in the period of 2001-2005. Second, the responsiveness of

earnings to lagged returns displays a similar declining trend, as shown in the smaller estimates of

3231, and 33 over time. Consequently, the aggregate indicator of accounting

conservatism, ,33323130 also declines over time. In sum, the results in Table 8

corroborate our previous findings that conservatism is weaker than has been documented once

firm fixed-effects are controlled for.

5.4 Alternative measures of Accounting Conservatism

Page 20: Conservatism Fixedeffects

19

Dietrich, Muller and Riedl (2007) argue that Basu’s (1997) approach to assess asymmetric

timeliness can yield biased estimates when earnings information affects returns. In light of such

criticisms, we follow Ball and Shivakumar (2006) to use alternative models to measure

accounting conservatism. These models do not rely on the returns-earnings relation to measure

conditional conservatism. Rather, they rely on the relationship between accruals and cash flows.

Operating cash flows are used to determine good news versus bad news. The asymmetrically

timely recognition of bad news would result in a greater association between accruals and cash

flows relative to good news. This argument suggests that we can use itA (the total accruals of

firm i in fiscal year t scaled by total assets) as the dependent variable in the piecewise linear

panel-data regression. The independent variable, itCFO , is the operating cash flows of firm i in

fiscal year t (Compustat variable OANCF) scaled by total assets (Compustat variable AT). This

leads to the following three piecewise linear accruals panel-data regressions. The first one is

based on the cash flow model:

it

N

jjitjititititit uFCFODDCFOA

23210 )( (6)

where itD is a dummy variable set equal to 1 if itCFO is negative and 0 otherwise. In the second

and third models, we control for other variables that could potentially affect accruals. In

particular, the second model is based on the linear accrual model proposed by Dechow and

Dichev (2002):

it

N

jjitjititititititit uFCFOCFOCFODDCFOA

212113210 )( , (7)

and the third model is based on the linear accrual model proposed by Jones (1991):

,)(2

213210 it

N

jjitjititititititit uFGPPEREVCFODDCFOA

(8)

where itREV is the change in revenue ( itREV , measured as Compustat variable SALE) in year t,

1 itit REVREV , and itGPPE is the gross property, plant, and equipment (Compustat variable

PPEGT). Each variable in equations (6), (7) and (8) is scaled by total assets.

Page 21: Conservatism Fixedeffects

20

As a further robustness check, we follow Ball and Shivakumar (2006) and consider, instead of

the level, the change in cash flow, ,1 ititit CFOCFOCFO as another financial reporting

measure to proxy for good and bad news. We repeat the estimation of equations (6), (7) and (8)

with itCFO in place of itCFO and define itD based on itCFO .

The results from estimating the above three models are reported in Table 9 for the pooled OLS

and LSDV/FE specifications. In Panel A, the level of CFO is used to proxy for economic loss. In

Panel B, the change in CFO is used to proxy for economic loss. The asymmetry implies that the

coefficient on the interaction terms ( itit CFOD in Panel A and itit CFOD in Panel B) should be

positive. This is confirmed in Table 9. That is, in panel A, the incremental loss coefficients are

all positive, ranging from 0.627 to 0.735 across the three accrual models for the pooled OLS

specification, and from 0.600 to 0.655 for the LSDV/FE specification. The LSDV/FE estimates

of the asymmetry are consistently smaller than those from the pooled OLS model. However the

F-test rejects the pooled OLS specification in favor of the LSDV/FE specification at the 5% level

of significance. In Panel B, again all of the incremental loss coefficient estimates are positive,

ranging from 0.071 to 0.199 for the pooled OLS specification, and from 0.032 to 0.104 for the

LSDV/FE specification, with the LSDV/FE estimates uniformly smaller than the pooled OLS

estimates. Once again, the pooled OLS specification is rejected at the 5% level of significance in

favor of the LSD/FE specification. These results are consistent with the earlier results using

stock return serving as a proxy for economic loss.

[Table 9 about here.]

Overall, the results obtained from Table 9 confirm the findings that a timely loss-recognition

plays an important role in accounting for accruals when we use either the level of, or the change

in, cash flows as a proxy for gains and losses. More importantly, the magnitude of asymmetric

responsiveness of earnings to bad news declines once firm-specific fixed-effects are controlled

for. The decline is particularly substantial with the change in cash flows serving as a proxy for

economic gains or losses. For example, in Panel B, the Jones model has a coefficient estimate on

Page 22: Conservatism Fixedeffects

21

CFOD of 0.119 in the pooled OLS regression. The coefficient estimate reduces to only 0.032

in the LSDV/FE regression, amounting to a reduction of over 70%.

In summary, the results emerging from our previous sensitivity analyses reinforce the importance

of incorporating firm specific fixed-effects in the models intended for measuring accounting

conservatism.

6. CONCLUSION

In this paper, we demonstrate that a significant part of the total variation in the earnings is

attributed to the cross-sectional differences. Given the importance of firm heterogeneity, we

propose to refine the original Basu (1997) model of accounting conservatism to explicitly

account for firm-specific fixed-effects. We then use the refined model to reexamine the extent of

accounting conservatism and its trend over time. We find that the estimated incremental

responsiveness of earnings to bad news is not as strong as previously documented, and that there

is no clear trend of an increase of accounting conservatism over time. We conduct sensitivity

analyses to demonstrate that our results are robust to different model specifications.

Our results echo recent studies that call for firm-level measures of conservatism. Noting that

conservatism is associated with a number of firm-specific factors (Watts, 2003), Ryan (2006)

comments that firm-specific measures are “desperately needed” for empirical studies. In a

response to Ryan (2006), Ball, Kothari and Nikolaev (2011) recommend that researchers

interested in measuring conservatism in the Basu (1997) framework should control for firm-

specific effects in order to avoid potentially spurious inferences. We provide empirical supports

for the call in Ball, Kothari and Nikolaev (2011) by showing that a substantial part of the total

variation in earnings is attributed to cross-sectional differences. Furthermore, focusing on the

most widely used conservatism measure of Basu (1997) (Ryan, 2006), we show that accounting

conservatism does not appear to show an increasing trend, contrary to what is previously

believed. In sum, our study demonstrates the importance of adjusting for firm heterogeneity in

examining accounting conservatism.

Page 23: Conservatism Fixedeffects

22

REFERENCES

Abarbanell, J. S. & Bernard, V. L. (1992). Tests of analysts’ overreaction/underreaction to earnings information as an explanation for anomalous stock price behavior. Journal of Finance 47, 1181-1207.

Ahmed, A.S., Billings, B.K., Morton, R.M. & Stanford-Harris, M. (2002). The role of accounting conservatism in mitigating bondholder-shareholder conflicts over dividend policy and in reducing debt costs. The Accounting Review 77, 867-890.

Ahmed, A. S. & Duellman, S. (2007). Accounting conservatism and board of director characteristics: an empirical analysis. Journal of Accounting and Economics 43, 411-437.

Alali, F. & Jaggi, B. (2011). Earnings versus capital ratios management: Role of bank types and SFAS 114. Review of Quantitative Finance and Accounting 36, 105-132.

Anandarajan, A., Francis, G., Hasan, I. & Kose, J. (2011). Value relevance of banks: Global evidence. Review of Quantitative Finance and Accounting 36, 33-55.

Ball, R. & Bartov, E. (1996). How naive is the stock market's use of earnings information? Journal of Accounting and Economics 21, 319 - 337.

Ball, R., Kothari, S.P. & Nikolaev, V.A. (2011). Econometrics of the Basu asymmetric timeliness coefficient and accounting conservatism. Working Paper, University of Chicago Booth School of Business.

Ball, R. & Shivakumar, L. (2006). The role of accruals in asymmetrically timely gain and loss recognition. Journal of Accounting Research 44, 207–242.

Basu, S. (1997). The conservatism principle and the asymmetric timeliness of earnings. Journal of Accounting and Economics 24(1): 3–37.

Beaver, W. & Ryan, S. (2000). Biases and lags in book value and their effects on the ability of the book-to-market ratio to predict book return on equity. Journal of Accounting Research 38, 127-148.

Belkaoui, A. (1985). Accounting Theory. San Diego: Harcourt Brace Jovanovich International Edition.

Callen, J., Segal, D. & Hope, O. (2010). The pricing of conservative accounting and the measurement of conservatism at the firm-year level. Review of Accounting Studies 15, 145-178.

Collins, D., Kothari, S. P., Shanken, J. & Sloan, R. (1994). Lack of timeliness and noise as explanations for the low contemporaneous return-earnings association. Journal of Accounting and Economics 18, 289-324.

Dechow, P. M. & Dichev, I. D. (2002). The quality of accruals and earnings: The role of accrual estimation errors. The Accounting Review 77 (Supplement), 35-59.

Page 24: Conservatism Fixedeffects

23

Dietrich, J., Muller, K. & Riedl, E. (2007). Asymmetric timeliness tests of accounting conservatism. Review of Accounting Studies 12, 95-124.

Elbannan, M. A. (2011). Accounting and stock market effects of international accounting standards adoption in an emerging economy. Review of Quantitative Finance and Accounting 36, 207-245.

Francis, B., Hasan, I., Park, J.C. & Wu, Q. (2009). Gender differences in financial reporting decision-marking: evidence from accounting conservatism. Working paper, Rensselaer Polytechnic Institute.

Givoly, D. & Hayn, C. (2000). The changing time-series properties of earnings, cashflows and accruals: Has financial reporting become more conservative? Journal of Accounting and Economics 29, 287-320.

Givoly, D., Hayn, C. & Natarajan, A. (2007). Measuring Reporting Conservatism. The Accounting Review 82, 65-106

Grambovas, C.A., Giner, B. & Christodoulou, D. (2006). Earnings conservatism: Panel data evidence from the European Union and the United States. Abacus 42, 354–378.

Greene, W. H. (2003). Econometric analysis. Prentice-Hall Inc., New Jersey.

Jones, J. (1991). Earnings management during import relief investigations. Journal of Accounting Research 20(2), 193-228.

Khan, M., & Watts, R. (2009). Estimation and empirical properties of a firm-year measure of accounting conservatism. Journal of Accounting and Economics 48, 132-150.

Kothari, S. P. & Sloan, R. (1992). Information in prices about future earnings: Implications for earnings response coefficients. Journal of Accounting and Economics 15, 143–171.

Kwon, S. S, Qin, Y. & Han, J. (2006). The effect of differential accounting conservatism on the “over-valuation” of high-tech firms relative to low-tech firms. Review of Quantitative Finance and Accounting 27, 143-173.

Lemmon, M. L., Roberts, M. R. & Zender, J. F. (2008). Back to the beginning: persistence and the cross-section of corporate capital structure. Journal of Finance 63, 1575-1608.

Patatoukas, P. N. & Thomas, J. (2009). Evidence of conditional conservatism: Fact or artifact? Working Paper.

Patatoukas, P. & Thomas, J. (2010). More evidence of bias in the differential timeliness measure of conditional conservatism. The Accounting Review, Forthcoming.

Penman, S. H. & Zhang, X. (2002). Accounting conservatism, the quality of earnings, and stock returns. The Accounting Review 77, 237-264.

Ramirez, P. G. & Hachiya, T. (2006). Measuring firm-specific organizational capital and its impact on value and Productivity: Evidence from Japan. Review of Pacific Basin Financial Markets and Policies 9, 549-574.

Page 25: Conservatism Fixedeffects

24

Ryan, S. G. (2006). Identifying conditional conservatism. European Accounting Review 15, 511- 525.

Ryan, S. G. & Zarowin, P. A. (2003). Why has the contemporaneous linear returns-earnings relation declined? The Accounting Review 78, 523-553.

Sloan, R. G. (1996). Do stock prices fully reflect information in accruals and cash flow about future earnings? The Accounting Review 71, 289-316.

Theil, H. (1961). Economic Forecast and Policy. Amsterdam: North-Holland.

Vuolteenaho, T. (2002). What drives firm-level stock returns. Journal of Finance 57, 233–264.

Watts, R. (2003). Conservatism in accounting, Part I: Explanations and implications. Accounting Horizons 17(3): 207-221.

Page 26: Conservatism Fixedeffects

25

Table 1 Pooled and Cross-sectional Standard Deviations of Earnings and Returns

Earnings Return

Full-sample volatility

Mean of cross-sectional

volatilities

Mean of time-series volatilities

Full-sample volatility

Mean of cross-sectional

volatilities

Mean of time-series volatilities

0.105 0.098 0.053 0.392 0.363 0.132

This table reports the full-sample standard deviations, the time-series means of cross-sectional standard deviations,

and the cross-sectional means of time-series standard deviations of individual firms on earnings and stock returns.

Earnings are computed as earnings per share (Compustat variable EPSPX) divided by lagged fiscal year-end closing

price (Compustat variable PRCC_F), and returns are measured as the cumulative monthly returns for the period of 9

months before the fiscal year end to 3 months after the fiscal year end. Our constant sample consists of 691 firms

from 1976 to 2005 from Compustat. A constant sample requires no missing observation in each of the sample year

for each firm.

Page 27: Conservatism Fixedeffects

26

Table 2 Variance Decompositions of Returns-Earnings Relation

Specification Variable (a) (b) (c) (d) (e) (f) Firm FE (

j ) 1.00 0.53 0.82 0.44

Year FE ( s ) 1.00 0.47 0.47

Returns ( itR ) 0.16 0.09 0.04

Dummy ( itD ) 0.00 0.00 0.00

Returns*Dummy ( itit RD ) 0.84 0.09 0.05

Adjusted R2 0.13 0.11 0.24 0.10 0.20 0.30 This table presents the variance decomposition for model specifications with or without firm/year fixed-effects. The

regression equations are:

u +F = PEPS it

N

jjitjitit

201/ (a)

u +Y= PEPS it

T

sstisitit

201/ (b)

u +YF = PEPS it

T

sstis

N

jjitjitit

2201/ (c)

u +RDDR = PEPS ititititititit )(/ 32101 (d)

u F RDDR = PEPS it

N

jjitjitititititit

232101 )(/ (e)

u +YF RDDR = PEPS it

T

sstis

N

jjitjitititititit

2232101 )(/ (f)

where EPS = earnings per share, P = price, R = return, j is the firm dummy, s is the year dummy, and Dit equals

1 if Rit< 0 and 0 otherwise. In each specification, we compute the type III partial sum of square for each variable and

then normalize the square of each variable by the sum of the type III squares of the specification. Both firm and time

effects are modeled as parametric shifts in the intercept terms of the regressions as in the LSDV framework.

Page 28: Conservatism Fixedeffects

27

Table 3 Extent of Accounting Conservatism

Estimation Method

0 1 2 3 R2

Pooled OLS (1) 0.078 [64.01]

0.027 [10.93]

0.001 [0.42]

0.205 [25.25]

0.097

LSDV/FE (2) 0.103 [5.87]

0.040 [16.29]

0.004 [1.59]

0.139 [16.94]

0.196

This table reports the estimation results from both the original and refined Basu’s model of accounting conservatism.

Basu’s (1997) model is specified as:

u RDDR = PEPS ititititititit )(/ 32101

The refined Basu model after accounting for firm-specific fixed-effects is specified as:

u F RDDR = PEPS it

N

jjitjitititititit

232101 )(/

In these specifications, EPS = earnings per share, P = price, R = return, i is the firm dummy, and Dit equals 1 if

Rit< 0 and 0 otherwise. In Pooled OLS, i = 0 for all firms. LSDV/FE refers to least square dummy variable method

with fixed-effects. R-square for the LSDV/FE model is calculated based on Theil (1961). The numbers in square

brackets are the t-statistics.

Page 29: Conservatism Fixedeffects

28

Table 4 Trend in Accounting Conservatism

Pooled OLS LSDV/FE

Sub-period 1 3 131 /)( Adj. R2 1 3 131 /)( Theil’s R2

1976-1980 0.038 0.256 7.74 0.092 0.051 0.132 3.59 0.496 [6.91] [8.39] [9.25] [4.49] 1981-1985 0.018 0.215 12.94 0.12 0.021 0.072 4.43 0.524

[3.29] [10.84] [4.25] [3.77] 1986-1990 0.032 0.292 10.13 0.16 0.055 0.147 3.67 0.52

[4.39] [16.44] [7.48] [7.99] 1991-1995 0.033 0.259 8.85 0.09 0.051 0.089 2.75 0.453

[5.58] [10.98] [8.35] [3.62] 1996-2000 0.006 0.076 13.67 0.048 0.008 0.033 5.13 0.384

[1.28] [6.46] [1.69] [2.69] 2001-2005 -0.005 0.247 -48.40 0.088 0.023 0.065 3.83 0.474

[-0.91] [13.27] [3.74] [3.47] Pooled OLS

LSDV/FE

By economic cycle

1 3 131 /)( Adj. R2

1 3 131 /)( Theil’s R2 1976-1979 0.053 0.226 5.26 0.105 0.076 0.097 2.28 0.57

[7.72] [6.98] [10.82] [3.10] 1980-1989 0.035 0.248 8.09 0.139 0.052 0.108 3.08 0.368

[8.97] [16.98] [13.50] [7.44] 1990-2000 0.018 0.122 7.78 0.065 0.028 0.054 2.93 0.267

[5.00] [11.58] [7.55] [5.05] 2001-2005 -0.005 0.247 -48.40 0.088 0.023 0.065 3.83 0.474

[-0.91] [13.27] [3.74] [3.47] This table reports the estimation results on the trend in accounting conservatism over time using both the original

and refined Basu’s model of accounting conservatism. The original Basu (1997)’s model is specified as:

u RDDR = PEPS ititititititit )(/ 32101

The refined Basu’s model after accounting for firm-specific fixed-effects is specified as:

u F RDDR = PEPS it

N

jjitjitititititit

232101 )(/

where EPS = earnings per share, P = price, R = return, i is the firm dummy, and Dit equals 1 if Rit< 0 and 0

otherwise. In Pooled OLS, i = 0 for all firms. The numbers in square brackets are t-statistics.

Page 30: Conservatism Fixedeffects

29

Table 5 Estimating Conservatism with an Alternate Sample Allowing for New Listings and Delistings of Firms

Panel A: Full-sample regression results

0 1 2 3 R2

Pooled OLS 0.033 -0.002 0.023 0.457 0.073

[22.31] [-0.84] [8.91] [69.26]

LSDV/FE 0.004 0.023 0.028 0.281 0.244

[0.05] [0.82] [10.71] [39.93]

Panel B: Regression results by sub-periods

Pooled OLS LSDV/FE

Sub-period 1 3 131 /)( Adj. R2

1 3 131 /)( Theil’s R2 1976-1980 0.036 0.446 13.39 0.099 0.053 0.237 5.47 0.486

[9.18] [21.13] [13.50] [11.24]

1981-1985 0.020 0.344 18.20 0.078 0.032 0.087 3.72 0.414

[4.57] [21.87] [7.03] [12.62]

1986-1990 0.001 0.468 469.00 0.087 0.025 0.206 9.24 0.455

[0.11] [31.23] [3.99] [12.62]

1991-1995 -0.003 0.502 -166.33 0.074 0.027 0.174 7.44 0.447

[-0.70] [31.23] [6.01] [9.99]

1996-2000 -0.017 0.361 -20.24 0.053 -0.001 0.150 -149.00 0.387

[-4.29] [29.42] [-0.21] [10.99]

2001-2005 -0.032 0.426 -12.31 0.065 0.010 0.036 4.60 0.424

[-6.86] [26.00] [2.10] [2.04]

This table reports the estimation results of accounting conservatism using both the original Basu model (Pooled OLS) and the refined model of fixed-effects (LSDV/FE) using an alternate sample that allows for firm new listings and delistings. We require that each firm has at least 10 observations in our sample period of 30 years. This sample covers 6,041 firms, with an average cross section of 3,623 firms. In Panel B, we further require that firms have three non-missing observations in each of the five-year sub-periods. The numbers in square brackets are t-statistics.

Page 31: Conservatism Fixedeffects

30

Table 6 The Returns-Cash Flows Relation

Pooled OLS LSDV/FE

Sub-period 1 3 1 3

1988-1993 0.035 0.141 0.050 0.070

[5.85] [6.26] [9.00] [3.20]

1994-1999 0.005 0.125 0.036 0.011

[1.08] [7.01] [8.45] [0.69]

2000-2005 0.050 0.053 0.050 -0.010

[9.19] [2.86] [10.10] [-0.59]

Notes: The regression equation is:

,)(/2

32101 u +F RDDR =PCFO it

N

jjitjitititititit

where CFO = cash flows from operations per share, P = price, R = return, i is the firm dummy, and Dit equals 1 if

Rit< 0 and 0 otherwise. In Pooled OLS, i = 0 for all firms. The CFO variable is only available after 1988. The

constant sample is between 1988 and 2005 and consists of 995 firms in total. The numbers in square brackets are

the t-statistics.

Page 32: Conservatism Fixedeffects

31

Table 7 The Implied Effect of Accruals

Pooled OLS, 3 LSDV/FE, 3

Earnings

regression

Cash Flows

regression

Earning

Regression

Cash Flows

Regression

Sub-period

Column

(1)

Column

(2)

Column

(1)-(2)

Column

(1)

Column

(2)

Column

(1)-(2)

1988-1993 0.441 0.141 0.300 0.043 0.070 -0.026

[9.35] [6.26] [5.73] [0.79] [3.20] [0.45]

1994-1999 0.188 0.125 0.062 0.062 0.011 0.051

[9.31] [7.01] [2.32] [2.70] [0.69] [1.83]

2000-2006 0.357 0.053 0.303 -0.009 -0.010 0.001

[4.15] [2.86] [3.45] [-0.10] [-0.59] [0.07]

Notes: For the earnings regression, the regression equation is:

u F RDDR = PEPS it

N

jjitjitititititit

232101 )(/ ,

and for the cash flows regression, the equation is:

,)(/2

32101 u +F RDDR =PCFO it

N

jjitjitititititit

where EPS = earnings per share, CFO = cash flows from operations per share, P = price, R = return, i is the firm

dummy, and Dit equals 1 if Rit< 0 and 0 otherwise. In Pooled OLS, i = 0 for all firms. The estimate of is

reported in the table. The constant sample is between 1988 and 2005 and consists of 995 firms in total. The numbers

in square brackets are the t-statistics.

Page 33: Conservatism Fixedeffects

Table 8 Estimation Results for the Extended Basu model with Lagged Returns

Panel A: Full sample, 1979-2005

Method 0 10 11 12 13 20

21 22 23 30 31 32 33 3332

3130

(Adj.)

R2

Pooled OLS 0.08 0.04 0.02 0.01 0.01 0.01 0.01 0.01 0.01 0.15 0.21 0.13 0.1 0.59 0.2155

[40.75] [17.87] [9.17] [4.62] [3.39] [2.35] [6.05] [4.35] [2.33] [19.01] [27.02] [17.04] [12.36] {1907.8}

LSDV/FE 0.09 0.05 0.03 0.02 0.01 0.01 0.01 0.01 0.01 0.12 0.19 0.11 0.08 0.5 0.2892

[5.64] [19.71] [10.95] [6.41] [5.39] [3.04] [6.79] [5.20] [3.32] [16.08] [24.43] [14.50] [9.69] {1096.9} Panel B: By economic cycle, 1980-2005

Method 0 10 11 12 13 20

21 22 23 30 31 32 33 3332

3130

(Adj.)

R2

1980-1989 Pooled OLS 0.1 0.05 0.01 0.01 -0.01 0 0.01 0 0 0.19 0.23 0.14 0.11 0.67 0.2572

[33.17] [12.22] [4.05] [2.10] [-1.90] [-0.23] [1.77] [1.15] [-0.52] [13.69] [16.24] [9.72] [7.43] {703.8}

LSDV/FE 0.15 0.05 0.02 0.01 0 0.01 0.01 0.01 0 0.14 0.18 0.09 0.05 0.46 0.412

[5.67] [13.81] [5.24] [3.41] [0.09] [1.84] [2.99] [2.07] [0.72] [9.79] [12.34] [6.25] [3.42] {190.9}

1990-2000 Pooled OLS 0.06 0.03 0.02 0.01 0.02 0 0.01 0.01 0.01 0.1 0.14 0.1 0.08 0.42 0.145

[21.67] [8.34] [4.83] [3.69] [4.56] [0.25] [4.35] [4.15] [3.55] [9.68] [12.91] [8.97] [6.37] {467.3}

LSDV/FE 0.06 0.04 0.02 0.02 0.02 0 0.01 0.01 0.01 0.06 0.11 0.07 0.05 0.29 0.3119

[[2.74] [9.71] [6.22] [4.36] [4.96] [-0.95] [3.22] [3.51] [3.16] [6.20] [9.60] [6.25] [3.75] {141.3}

2001-2005 Pooled OLS 0.06 0.05 0.03 0.01 0.01 0.01 0.02 0.01 0.01 0.16 0.25 0.14 0.07 0.62 0.2452

[11.38] [8.05] [5.44] [1.19] [2.02] [1.52] [4.15] [1.36] [1.85] [8.90] [15.11] [8.53] [4.68] {490.6}

LSDV/FE 0.04 0.06 0.04 0.02 0.01 0.01 0.03 0.01 0.01 0.06 0.17 0.05 0.01 0.29 0.5238

[0.93] [9.08] [6.78] [2.50] [1.18] [1.76] [4.66] [1.56] [1.44] [3.34] [9.06] [2.97] [0.76] {39.6}

Notes: The regression equation is: 323222121203132121111001/ itititititititititit DDDD RRRR = PEPS

u +F RD RD RD RD it

N

jijtiitititititititit

233332232113130 )()()()( , where EPS = earnings per share, P = price, R = return, i is the firm

dummy, and Dit (Dit-1 /Dit-2/Dit-3) equals 1 if Rit, (Rit-1 /Rit-2 /Rit-3) is smaller than 0 and 0 otherwise. The data are from 1979 to 2005. In Pooled OLS, i = 0 for all

firms. In the sub-period analysis, we drop year 1979 and report only three business cycles. Numbers in square brackets are t-statistics, and numbers in curly brackets are chi-statistics from the Wald tests.

Page 34: Conservatism Fixedeffects

Table 9 Estimation Results from Alternative Models of Accounting Conservatism

Panel A: Proxy for economic loss, the Level of Cash flow (CFO) < 0

CFO Model

Pooled OLS LSDV/FE

DD Model

Pooled OLS LSDV/FE

Jones Model

Pooled OLS LSDV/FE

Intercept -0.005 -0.058 -0.009 -0.069 0.008 0.042

[-4.85] [-3.27] [-8.60] [-3.95] [6.83] [2.47]

CFOt -0.477 -0.584 -0.558 -0.611 -0.471 -0.581

[-55.97] [-56.31] [-63.59] [-59.05] [-57.36] [-59.21]

CFOt-1 0.067 0.057

[20.18] [16.84]

CFOt+1 0.063 0.050

[18.05] [14.21]

∆REVt 0.095 0.099

[41.41] [43.82]

GPPEt -0.034 -0.068

[-27.73] [-24.25]

Dt 0.031 0.028 0.024 0.026 0.025 0.027

[14.33] [12.70] [11.52] [11.66] [12.15] [12.99]

DtCFOt 0.735 0.655 0.627 0.600 0.714 0.610

[59.01] [41.52] [49.15] [37.84] [60.25] [40.90]

R-squared (%) 18.15 35.4 21.54 36.97 27.15 42.86

F-test for FE 4.27 3.90 4.40

Page 35: Conservatism Fixedeffects

34

Table 9 cont’d Panel B: Proxy for economic loss, change in cash flow (∆CFO) < 0

CFO Model

Pooled OLS LSDV/FE

DD Model

Pooled OLS LSDV/FE

Jones Model

Pooled OLS LSDV/FE

Intercept -0.042 -0.104 -0.044 -0.110 -0.037 -0.025

[-40.79] [-5.76] [-43.98] [-6.13] [-31.80] [-1.36]

CFOt -0.176 -0.298 -0.334 -0.379

[-33.39] [-41.63] [-47.67] [-47.88]

CFOt-1 0.088 0.064

[23.54] [16.70]

CFOt+1 0.080 0.059

[21.68] [16.17]

∆REVt 0.089 0.098

[36.69] [40.48]

GPPEt -0.052 -0.087

[-42.20] [-29.25]

∆CFOit -0.122 -0.060 -0.116 -0.075

[-25.20] [-12.46] [-25.34] [-15.88]

Dt 0.026 0.022 0.020 0.018 0.033 0.034

[21.01] [19.02] [16.39] [15.47] [28.94] [31.34]

Dt∆CFOt 0.199 0.104 0.071 0.047 0.119 0.032

[26.23] [13.14] [12.23] [8.18] [17.54] [4.16]

R-squared (%) 11.23 31.8 14.25 33.21 19.07 34.6

F-test for FE 4.83 4.52 3.80

In Panel A, the regression equation for the CFO model is:

it

N

jjitjititititit uFCFODDCFOA

23210 )(

The equation for the DD model is:

it

N

jjitjititititititit uFCFOCFOCFODDCFOA

212113210 )(

And the equation for the Jones model is:

it

N

jjitjititititititit uFGPPEREVCFODDCFOA

2213210 )(

In the above equations, A = accruals, CFO = cash flow from operations, REV is the change in revenue, GPPE is the gross property, plant, and equipment, and Dit equals 1 if CFOit< 0 and 0 otherwise. All these variables are scaled

by lagged total assets. In Pooled OLS, i = 0 for all firms. In Panel B, CFO is replaced by the change in CFO

(∆CFO), and Dit= 1 if ∆CFOit< 0 and 0 otherwise. The numbers in square brackets are the t-statistics.

Page 36: Conservatism Fixedeffects

35

Figure 1 The Ratios of Cross-sectional Volatility

over Pooled Volatility for Earnings and Returns over Time

Page 37: Conservatism Fixedeffects

36

Appendix: Replication of Givoly and Hayn’s (2000) Results Based on Basu’s Measure and

Discussion on Firm Composition of Full Sample

Using pooled OLS regressions and the full sample of firms in the intersection of Compustat and

CRSP from 1950 to 1998, Givoly and Hayn (2000)—hereafter “GH”—show that the asymmetric

response of earnings to return using Basu’s (1997) measure has increased over time. As a reality

check, Table A-1 presents Basu’s (1997) results for five-year sub-periods, using GH’s full

sample derived from the intersection of Compustat and CRSP from 1963 to 2004 and estimation

method.

[Table A-1 here.]

A general observation from the Table is that the asymmetric response of earnings to return ( 3 )

shows an increasing trend during the sample period studied in GH. This finding is consistent

with GH. However, in the last two sub-periods of the sample (1995-2004), the asymmetric

response is declining. Thus, the statement of an increase in the asymmetric response of earnings

to return appears to be sample-specific, in addition to being estimation-method specific.

In showing the increase in accounting conservatism, GH use not only Basu’s (1997) measure, but

also accruals level to proxy for conservatism. GH present the accruals level results using a

constant sample. Part of the reason for using a constant sample is the changing composition of

firms in the full sample during the sample period, which is shown in Figure A-1.

[Figure A-1 here.]

From Figure A-1, we observe that the number of firms included in the sample varies

substantially over time: the sample started with 803 firms in 1963, peaked to 5,570 firms in

1997, and dropped to 3,397 firms in 2005. A comparison of Table A-1 with Table 4, where the

trend in the asymmetric response of earnings to return is shown for a constant sample, reveals

that much of the increase in the asymmetric response documented in GH is attributed to new

Page 38: Conservatism Fixedeffects

37

listings. Given the degree of the changing composition of firms, we believe that focusing on a

constant sample in studying the returns-earnings relation retains a consistent sample and,

therefore, helps us to address the question of whether the returns-earnings relation has changed

over time for the same firms. Therefore, we rely on a constant sample most of the time in this

paper.

Page 39: Conservatism Fixedeffects

38

Table A-1 Replication of Givoly and Hayn (2000)

Sub-period 0 1 2 3 Adj. R2

1963-1964 0.072 -0.004 0.023 0.137 0.144

1965-1969 0.068 -0.003 0.016 0.067 0.172

1970-1974 0.094 0.007 0.033 0.105 0.081

1975-1979 0.144 -0.017 0.057 0.346 0.123

1980-1984 0.073 -0.021 0.008 0.250 0.109

1985-1989 0.036 -0.004 -0.009 0.407 0.142

1990-1994 0.014 0.014 -0.015 0.449 0.083

1995-1999 0.021 0.007 -0.021 0.293 0.086

2000-2004 0.000 0.005 -0.033 0.363 0.057

Notes: The regression equation is: ititititititit uRDDRPEPS )(/ 32101 , where EPS = earnings

per share, P = price, R = return, and Dit equals 1 if Rit< 0 and 0 otherwise. We strictly follow Givoly and Hayn

(2000) to derive a sample of firms from the intersection of Compustat and CRSP from 1963 to 2004. The numbers

in square brackets are the t-statistics.

Page 40: Conservatism Fixedeffects

39

Figure A-1 The Number of Firms over Time in the Full Sample