COMMENTARY Forecasting fisheries collapse - PNAS · COMMENTARY Forecasting fisheries collapse ......

2
COMMENTARY Forecasting sheries collapse Steven D. Gaines 1 and Christopher Costello Bren School of Environmental Science and Management, University of California, Santa Barbara, CA 93106 When sustainably managed, wild harvests from the sea provide livelihoods and a vital source of protein for hundreds of millions of people (1, 2). If managed well, these benets are perpetually renewable. However, numer- ous challenges can compromise the sustain- ability of this natural bounty. Ironically, a signicant challenge arises because of the diversity of species caught in nearly all sh- eries. Although healthy diverse ecosystems can provide resilience against some perturba- tions, shing pressure in these ecosystems is almost always geared to the strongest, most economically valuable stocks. In the process of shing, many other species are incidentally caught including both (i ) species that nobody wants to catch but are costly to avoid, com- monly called bycatch, and (ii ) species with substantially lower economic value than tar- geted, highline stocks. Even when the target stock is perfectly managed, these incidentally caught stocks can collapse if their life history traits make them more susceptible to a given level of shing effort than target species. Without regular monitoring and strong man- agement of all species, these weak stocks may force the closure of otherwise highly prot- able sheries. One solution is to expand sci- entic assessments to all species affected by each shery, but this is prohibitively expen- sive. Fish are expensive to monitor, and as a result, even the majority of target species are currently not adequately assessed world- wide (3). Solving the weak stock problem requires new innovation. In PNAS, Burgess et al. (4) offer a unique forecasting tool to innovatively address this global challenge. If the looming collapse of overshed weak stocks could be foreseen well in advance, the environmental and economic costs of elimi- nating the problem before it occurs may be far less than the costs of restoring overharvested species after the fact. Overharvesting weak stocks or bycatch species often triggers a reg- ulatory shutdown of the entire shery to allow rebuilding (5). This rebuilding can last for many decades, because the life history traits that put the species at risk also mean that their recovery will be exceedingly slow. For exam- ple, weak stocks such as yelloweye rocksh in the highly diverse rocksh assemblage along the west coast of the United States only stands a 50% chance of recovery by 2047, despite signicant reductions in shing pressure (6). Burgess et al. (4) provide a simple, but effective, means of forecasting the stocks for which incidental catch presents a signicant future risk. The forecasts can project risk dec- ades into the future. Rather than requiring major new monitoring efforts, these forecasts can be made with readily available informa- tion. The clever logic underlying the unique tool is that future mortality from shing will be driven by shing pressure focused on tar- get species. These key species commonly have far more extensive monitoring data on current and past catch than do the weak stocks. The authors derive a measure of fu- ture risk from incidental catch called the T-score. This threat measure couples projec- tions of future shing mortality with differ- ences in life history traits between target and other species. Species with a T-score <1 are not at risk from incidental shing. As the T-score increases to >1, the weak stock is projected to become overshed, and if T > 2, incidental shing mortality is forecast to put the species at risk for extinction. Because the T- score can be forecasted well into the future, it could trigger proactive management actions that would substantially reduce the economic and ecological harm that occurs from the alter- native of collapse and rebuilding cycles. In addition to providing a valuable early warning system, we believe the framework developed by Burgess et al. has several broader implications. First, the clear articulation of the multispecies catch problem may help explain some previously unexplained patterns. For example, Costello et al. (3) produced a global analysis of a large number of previously unas- sessed sheries. One of the intriguing results was that large sheries (in terms of landings) tended to be in much better shape than small sheries. Although several factors likely contribute to this discrepancy, the paper of Burgess et al. (4) provides one possible expla- nation: large sheries are far more likely to be target stocks, whereas small sheries may in- clude many more species that are along for the ride and are often harvested incidentally. It is quite possible that with methods like this, interventions (such as those described below) could have been undertaken early and those species would not have been reduced to such low levels. Second, this forecasting tool could have important implications for the design of institutions to manage sheries. If manage- ment is constrained to merely regulate the shery as a common pool resource, then, on learning a species has a high T-score, managers are left with no choice but to decrease shing mortality on all species. The larger the discrepancy in life histories, the larger the costs of such reductions. However, under some other innovative management institutions, promising alternatives exist. Two key ones are as follows. (i ) Marine pro- tected areas (MPAs) could be implemented to protect the weaker species from extirpa- tion and continue permitting a higher sh- ing mortality outside the protected area. For this alternative to be really effective, there has to be some geographical difference be- tween the species that allows the MPA to protect the weak stock while incurring smaller costs on the harvest of the targeted species. (ii ) Multispecies individual trans- ferable quotas (ITQs): this rights-based approach provides a market signal to avoid bycatch. The idea here is that species with a high T-score get a lower quota, which rai- ses the price of catching those species. This creates a strong nancial incentive for sh- ermen to innovate and nd more selective ways to sh. Without a price signal, there is no particular reason shermen would try to avoid catching these weak stocks. This ap- proach has worked well in the West Coast Groundsh shery in the United States, where changes in shing gear from trawling to hook and line and avoidance of key weak stock hab- itats have dramatically reduced incidental catch of previously threatened species (7). Third, this technology should signicantly increase the value of information in a stock assessment. It is commonly believed that assessments must be done stock by stock. A typical assessment costs hundreds of thou- sands of dollars per species, which is pro- hibitive for most sheries. The Burgess et al. (4) approach allows us to predict the fate of many species from an assessment of only one species. Thus, the value of the stock assess- ment increases dramatically. Fishermen who benet from harvesting one group of species may, with this method, benet from a stock assessment on other species. Thus, they may Author contributions: S.D.G. and C.C. wrote the paper. The authors declare no conict of interest. See companion article on page 15943. 1 To whom correspondence should be addressed. E-mail: gaines@ bren.ucsb.edu. www.pnas.org/cgi/doi/10.1073/pnas.1315109110 PNAS | October 1, 2013 | vol. 110 | no. 40 | 1585915860 COMMENTARY

Transcript of COMMENTARY Forecasting fisheries collapse - PNAS · COMMENTARY Forecasting fisheries collapse ......

COMMENTARY

Forecasting fisheries collapseSteven D. Gaines1 and Christopher CostelloBren School of Environmental Science and Management, University of California, SantaBarbara, CA 93106

When sustainably managed, wild harvestsfrom the sea provide livelihoods and a vitalsource of protein for hundreds of millions ofpeople (1, 2). If managed well, these benefitsare perpetually renewable. However, numer-ous challenges can compromise the sustain-ability of this natural bounty. Ironically,a significant challenge arises because of thediversity of species caught in nearly all fish-eries. Although healthy diverse ecosystemscan provide resilience against some perturba-tions, fishing pressure in these ecosystems isalmost always geared to the strongest, mosteconomically valuable stocks. In the processof fishing, many other species are incidentallycaught including both (i) species that nobodywants to catch but are costly to avoid, com-monly called bycatch, and (ii) species withsubstantially lower economic value than tar-geted, highline stocks. Even when the targetstock is perfectly managed, these incidentallycaught stocks can collapse if their life historytraits make them more susceptible to a givenlevel of fishing effort than target species.Without regular monitoring and strong man-agement of all species, these weak stocks mayforce the closure of otherwise highly profit-able fisheries. One solution is to expand sci-entific assessments to all species affected byeach fishery, but this is prohibitively expen-sive. Fish are expensive to monitor, and asa result, even the majority of target speciesare currently not adequately assessed world-wide (3). Solving the weak stock problemrequires new innovation. In PNAS, Burgesset al. (4) offer a unique forecasting tool toinnovatively address this global challenge.If the looming collapse of overfished weak

stocks could be foreseen well in advance, theenvironmental and economic costs of elimi-nating the problem before it occurs may be farless than the costs of restoring overharvestedspecies after the fact. Overharvesting weakstocks or bycatch species often triggers a reg-ulatory shutdown of the entire fishery to allowrebuilding (5). This rebuilding can last formany decades, because the life history traitsthat put the species at risk alsomean that theirrecovery will be exceedingly slow. For exam-ple, weak stocks such as yelloweye rockfish inthe highly diverse rockfish assemblage alongthe west coast of the United States only standsa 50% chance of recovery by 2047, despitesignificant reductions in fishing pressure (6).

Burgess et al. (4) provide a simple, buteffective, means of forecasting the stocks forwhich incidental catch presents a significantfuture risk. The forecasts can project risk dec-ades into the future. Rather than requiringmajor new monitoring efforts, these forecastscan be made with readily available informa-tion. The clever logic underlying the uniquetool is that future mortality from fishing willbe driven by fishing pressure focused on tar-get species. These key species commonlyhave far more extensive monitoring data oncurrent and past catch than do the weakstocks. The authors derive a measure of fu-ture risk from incidental catch called theT-score. This threat measure couples projec-tions of future fishing mortality with differ-ences in life history traits between target andother species. Species with a T-score <1 arenot at risk from incidental fishing. As theT-score increases to >1, the weak stock isprojected to become overfished, and if T > 2,incidental fishing mortality is forecast to put thespecies at risk for extinction. Because the T-score can be forecasted well into the future, itcould trigger proactive management actionsthat would substantially reduce the economicand ecological harm that occurs from the alter-native of collapse and rebuilding cycles.In addition to providing a valuable early

warning system, we believe the frameworkdevelopedbyBurgess et al. has several broaderimplications. First, the clear articulation of themultispecies catch problemmay help explainsome previously unexplained patterns. Forexample, Costello et al. (3) produced a globalanalysis of a large number of previously unas-sessed fisheries. One of the intriguing resultswas that large fisheries (in terms of landings)tended to be in much better shape thansmall fisheries. Although several factors likelycontribute to this discrepancy, the paper ofBurgess et al. (4) provides one possible expla-nation: large fisheries are far more likely to betarget stocks, whereas small fisheries may in-cludemanymore species that are along for theride and are often harvested incidentally. It isquite possible that with methods like this,interventions (such as those described below)could have been undertaken early and thosespecies would not have been reduced to suchlow levels.Second, this forecasting tool could have

important implications for the design of

institutions to manage fisheries. If manage-ment is constrained to merely regulate thefishery as a common pool resource, then, onlearning a species has a high T-score,managers are left with no choice but todecrease fishing mortality on all species. Thelarger the discrepancy in life histories, thelarger the costs of such reductions. However,under some other innovative managementinstitutions, promising alternatives exist.Two key ones are as follows. (i) Marine pro-tected areas (MPAs) could be implementedto protect the weaker species from extirpa-tion and continue permitting a higher fish-ing mortality outside the protected area. Forthis alternative to be really effective, therehas to be some geographical difference be-tween the species that allows the MPA toprotect the weak stock while incurringsmaller costs on the harvest of the targetedspecies. (ii) Multispecies individual trans-ferable quotas (ITQs): this rights-basedapproach provides a market signal to avoidbycatch. The idea here is that species witha high T-score get a lower quota, which rai-ses the price of catching those species. Thiscreates a strong financial incentive for fish-ermen to innovate and find more selectiveways to fish. Without a price signal, there isno particular reason fishermen would try toavoid catching these weak stocks. This ap-proach has worked well in the West CoastGroundfish fishery in theUnited States, wherechanges in fishing gear from trawling to hookand line and avoidance of key weak stock hab-itats have dramatically reduced incidentalcatch of previously threatened species (7).Third, this technology should significantly

increase the value of information in a stockassessment. It is commonly believed thatassessments must be done stock by stock. Atypical assessment costs hundreds of thou-sands of dollars per species, which is pro-hibitive for most fisheries. The Burgess et al.(4) approach allows us to predict the fate ofmany species from an assessment of only onespecies. Thus, the value of the stock assess-ment increases dramatically. Fishermen whobenefit from harvesting one group of speciesmay, with this method, benefit from a stockassessment on other species. Thus, they may

Author contributions: S.D.G. and C.C. wrote the paper.

The authors declare no conflict of interest.

See companion article on page 15943.

1To whom correspondence should be addressed. E-mail: [email protected].

www.pnas.org/cgi/doi/10.1073/pnas.1315109110 PNAS | October 1, 2013 | vol. 110 | no. 40 | 15859–15860

COMMEN

TARY

be willing to help pay for that assessment (e.g.,through a landings tax).Finally, we believe that the real novelty of

the Burgess et al. method lies in the ob-servation that by accounting for ecologicaland/or economic relationships, we can learn alot about species X from studying species Y.This is an important insight that could trans-form our thinking about fisheries assessmentand management (8). However, this uniqueapproach is not a silver bullet. Importantly,it assumes that a stock assessment is availablefor the target species. This limits the geo-graphical scope of its application to the fewhundred fisheries around the world with for-mal stock assessments. However, expandingthe approach to use new “data poor stockassessment” techniques (9) could dramaticallyexpand the potential scope of this forecastingtool and provide the required input data ata fraction of the cost. Currently these data-

poor approaches are typically done ad hoc(one stock at a time), without recognizing thatstocks are linked through fishing technologyto many other species. The current paper usesa simple assumption for how fishingmortalityis linked across species to calculate theT-score. However, this basic approachcould be developed and applied much moregenerally. For example, observing the size

distribution for one species may tell yousomething about the status (current or fu-ture) of other species being caught in thesame fishery. Merging the principles ofdata-poor assessment with the authors’ in-sight that species are linked through harvesttechnology is a tremendously fruitful area offuture research.

1 Arnason R, Kelleher K, Willmann R (2009) The Sunken Billions:Economic Justification for Fisheries Reform (World Bank,Washington, DC).2 Srinivasan UT, Cheung WWL, Watson R, Sumaila UR (2010) Foodsecurity implications of global marine catch losses due to overfishing.J. Bioecon. 12(3):183–200.3 Costello C, et al. (2012) Status and solutions for the world’sunassessed fisheries. Science 338(6106):517–520.4 Burgess MG, Polasky S, Tilman D (2013) Predicting overfishing andextinction threats in multispecies fisheries. Proc Natl Acad Sci USA110:15943–15948.5 Hall SJ,MainprizeBM (2005)Managingby catch anddiscards: Howmuchprogress are wemaking and how canwe do better? Fish Fish 6(2):134–155.

6 Stewart I (2009) Rebuilding Analysis for Yelloweye Rockfish Basedon the 2009 Stock Assessment. National Marine Fisheries Service(Northwest Fisheries Science Center, Seattle, WA).7 National Oceanic and Atmospheric Administration (2012) TheWest Coast Groundfish IFQ Fishery: Results from the First Year ofCatch Shares (NOAA, Washington, DC).8 Punt AE, Smith DC, Smith ADM (2011) Among-stock comparisonsfor improving stock assessments of data-poor stocks: The “RobinHood” approach. ICES J Mar Sci 68(35):972–981.9 Wilson JR, Prince JD, Lenihan HS (2010) A management strategyfor sedentary nearshore species that uses marine protected areas asa reference. Marine Coastal Fisheries: Dynamics, Manage,Ecosyst Sci 2(1):14–27.

Fig. 1. Map of fisheries species diversity for FAO regions in exclusive economic zones (EEZs). Hashed lines denote where less than 50% of catch is identified to species. Diversity variesgreatly among countries, reflecting both biogeography and the historical development of fisheries. These species numbers reflect only commercially harvested species, not the broaderdiversity caught as bycatch. Data sources: Esri, GEBCO, NOAA, National Geographic, DeLorme, NAVTEQ, & Geonames.org. Images at bottom illustrate diversity challenges outlined inBurgess et al. (4). From Left to Right: Diverse catch in shrimp trawls, where most of the biomass is bycatch (photograph by Elliott Norse, Marine Conservation Institute/MarinePhotobank); bycatch of an albratross in a long line fishery (photograph by Projeto Tamar Brazil/Marine Photobank); weak stock species, Canary rockfish, whose overfished statusconstrains a diverse groundfish fishery along the west coast of the United States (photograph by Gerick Bergsma 2010/Marine Photobank); extreme example of high incidental mortalityfrom indiscriminate dynamite fishing (photograph from 2004 Berkley White/Marine Photobank).

15860 | www.pnas.org/cgi/doi/10.1073/pnas.1315109110 Gaines and Costello